Calc. III
Calc. III
Module III
Mekelle University
Faculty of Business and Economics
Department of Economics
Mekelle
April 2004
TABLE OF CONTENTS
IV.TECHNIQUES AND APPLICATIONS OF INTEGRAL CALCULUS ..... 83
4.1. INTRODUCTION ................................................................................ 83
4.2. ANTIDERIVATIVES AND THE INDEFINITE INTEGRAL ...................................... 83
4.3. TECHNIQUES OF INTEGRATION & THE GENERAL POWER RULE ....................... 84
4.4. DEFINITE INTEGRALS ......................................................................... 95
4.4.1. Properties of Definite Integrals.............................................................. 95
4.4.2. Area under a Curve.................................................................................. 97
4.4.3. The area of a region between two curves .............................................. 99
4.5. SOME ECONOMIC APPLICATIONS OF DEFINITE INTEGRALS:........................... 102
4.5.1 Consumers’ Surplus and producers’ Surplus ........................................ 102
4.5.2. Distribution of income ..................................................................... 106
4.5.3. Continuous Money Streams............................................................ 107
4.5.4. Continuous Money Streams within a Period............................... 108
4.6. IMPROPER INTEGRALS .................................................................. 109
4.8. DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS ........................................................... 111
4.8.1. First Order Differential Equations................................................. 111
4.8.1.1 First order linear differential equations with constant coefficient and term....................... 112
Application of the Non-Homogenous case: Dynamic model of the market price .... 115
82
IV.TECHNIQUES AND APPLICATIONS OF INTEGRAL
CALCULUS
4.1. Introduction
“C”, f (x ) = 2 x + C
Thus,
∫ f ′(x )dx = f (x ) + C
Where
• The sign ∫ is read as “Integration of…”
• The term f ' ( x ) is the integrand
• The term dx as usual is w. r. t. “X”
• The term C is Constant of integration/an element of indefinite
integral.
Antiderivative involves finding f ( x) + C from f ' ( x). That is
∫ f ' ( x)dx = f ( x) + c
83
The inverse relationship between differentiation and integration
helps us to set the formula for integration directly from
differentiation formula.
Example:
1. ∫ 2dx = 2 x + c
2. ∫ − 8dx = −8x + c
b) Constant Multiple Rule: for ∫ kf ( x )dx = k ∫ f ( x )dx
Example:
1. ∫ 2 x 7 dx = 2 ∫ x 7 dx
−10
∫ 10 x dx =10∫ x
−10
2. dx
xn +1
D) Simple Power Rule: For ∫ x dx = + c for n ≠ -1
n
n +1
Examples:
1. Evaluate the indefinite integral of the following problems.
a) ∫ 3xdx
1
b) ∫x 3
dx
c) ∫ x dx
d) ∫ (x + 2)dx
e) ∫ (3x )
− 5 x 2 + x dx
4
x +1
f) ∫ x
dx
84
Solution
3x 1+1 3x 2
a) +c = +c
1+1 2
x −3+1 −1
b) +C = 2 +C
− 3 +1 2x
1
+1
x2 2
c) + C = x 3/ 2 + C
1 3
+1
2
1 2
d) x + 2x + C
2
∫( )
3 x 5 5 x 3 1x 2
3 x − 5 x + x dx =
4 2
− + +C
e) 5 3 2
3x 5 5 x 3 x 2
= − + +C
5 3 2
x +1 x 1 1
f) ∫ x
dx = ∫ x
+ dx =
x
∫ x dx + ∫
x
dx
2 x 1 / 2+1 x −1 / 2+1
= + C, + C2
3 − 1/ 2 + 1
2 2/3
= x + C ,+2 x 1 / 2 + C 2
3
2 3/ 2
= x + 2 x1 / 2 + C
3
Since all the functions that we have come up with after integration
have unknown C term, all the integrations that involve C are known
as indefinite integral. Some times, when initial conditions are
given, the particular solution can be calculated.
Examples,
1
1. Given f (x ) = & f (1) = 2, find f ( x )
x2
Solution
85
1
f (x ) = ∫ dx
x2
= ∫ x − 2 dx
x − 2+1
= +C
− 2 +1
1
=− +C
x
But f (1) = −1 + C = 2
C = 2 +1 = 3
−1
Thus f ( x ) = +3
x
Solution
2
0.04 X
TC = ∫ MCdx = ∫ (32 − 0.04 x )dx = 32 x − 2
+C
=32X -0.02X2 +C
But, TC (1) = 50
TC (1) = 32 − 0.02(1) + C = 50
C= 50.02-32
C=18.02 which is Fixed Cost
Thus, TC = 32x-0.02x2+18.02
2
TC (200) = 32(200)- x 200 2 + 18.02
100
= 6400-800+18.02
= 5600+18.02
= 5618.02
e) The General Power Rule:
86
Consider also
∫ 2 x( x + 1) 3 dx =
2
du
Let x2+1 = U and = 2x
dx
du u4 1
Thus, ∫ U 3 dx = + C = ( x 2 + 1) 4 + C
dx 4 4
dx n +1
Leibniz Rule
Example:
Evaluate the following problems
1..∫ 3(3 x − 1) 4
Solution
du
let (3x − 1) = U , Thus =3
dx
du
= ∫ U ⋅ dx
4
dx
U 4+1
= U 4 du = +C
4 +1
1
= (3x − 1) 5 + C
5
2. ∫ (2 x + 1)( x2 + x)dx
Solution
du
let ( x 2 + x) = U and = 2x + 1
dx
du
= ∫ U ⋅ dx
dx
= ∫ udu
1
= U2 +C
2
1
(
2
= x2 + x + C
2
)
87
3. ∫ 3x x 3 − 2 dx
2
Solution
du
let ( x 3 − 2) = U and = 3x 2
dx
du
= ∫ U
1/ 2
dx
dx
∫U
1/ 2
du
U 1 / 2+1
= = +C
1
+1
2
2
= x3 − 2
3
( 3/ 2
+3 )
∫ x(− 4x )2
4. 2
+ 3 dx
Solution
dU 1 dU
Let 3-4x2 = U and = −8 X and (− )( )=X
dx 8 dx
− 1 du
= ∫ U 2 ( dx
8 dx
−1 du
8 ∫ U2
dx
⋅ dx
=
−1U 3
+C
8 3
−1
= (3 − 4 x 2 ) 3 + C
24
7 x2
5. ∫ 4x3 − 5
dx
Solution
dU 1 du
Let 4x3-5=U and = 12X 2 as a result we have = x 2 and
dx 12 dx
7 du
= 7 x2
12 dx
Thus,
7 x2
∫ 4x3 − 5
dx is,
= ∫ 7 x 2U −1 / 2 dx
88
7 du
=∫ ⋅ U −1 / 2 dx
12 dx
7
∫U
−1 / 2
du =
= 12
1/2
7 U
( )( ) + C
12 1
2
7
= (4 x 3 − 5) + C
6
6. ∫ 1 − 3 x dx
Solution
du
Let U= 1-3x and = −3 as a result, we have
dx
−1
du = -3dx and dx = du
3
= ∫ U 1 / 2 dx
−1
∫U
1/ 2
du
= 3
− 1 1/ 2
3 ∫
U du
1 U 1 / 2+1
= − +C
3 1
+1
2
−1 U 3/ 2
= +C
3 3
2
=
−2
9
( 1 − 3x ) + C 3
89
F. Integration of Logarithmic & Exponential Functions
Like what we have done in relation to the derivative of non-
algebraic functions, here we will present the integration of the
logarithmic functions first accompanied by the integration of
exponential functions. Concerning the integration of logarithmic
functions, let’s begin with example. The general power rule of
integration applies only when n ≠ -1; i.e.
du U n +1
∫U ⋅ dx = + C iff n ≠ -1.
n
dx n +1
But, the following formula applies when n = -1. That is
du
∫U
−1
⋅ dx = ln |u| + C
dx
We use absolute value to protect it from being negative & the whole
logarithm undefined. This formula is a direct result of the fact that
d ln x 1
=
dx x
Thus,
1
∫ x dx = ∫ x
−1
dx = ln | x | +C
d ln u du 1
Similarly, when U is a function of X, = ⋅
dx dx u
1 du
∴∫ ⋅ dx = ln | u | +C
u dx
∫ (4 x + 1) 4dx
−1
a)
∫ ( x − 3)( x − 6 x + 1)
−1
b) 2
dx
Solution
a) Let 4x + 1 = U
du
=4
dx
du
Thus, ∫ U −1 ⋅ dx = ln | 4 x + 1 | +C
dx
90
b) Let u(x) = x2 – 6x + 1
du ( x)
= 2 x − 6 =2(x-3)
dx
1 du
(X-3)=
2 dx
Thus,
du
∫ ( x − 3)( x − 6 x + 1) −1 dx = ∫ U −1 ( 1
2
2 dx
) dx
1 du 1
= ∫ U −1 dx = (ln | u |) + C
2 dx 2
1
= ln | x 2 − 6 x + 1 | +C
2
= ln x 2 − 6x + 1 + C
x 4 − 2x3 + 4x 2 − 7x − 1
c) ∫ x 2 − 2x
dx
x −1
= ∫ ( x + 4) + dx …Using division of rational functions
2
x − 2x
2
x −1
= ∫ (X + 4)dx + ∫ x
2
dx
2
− 2X
1 3 1
= x + 4 X + ∫ ( x 2 − 2 x) −1 ( )(2)( x − 1) dx
3 2
=
1 3
3
1
(
x + 4 x + ln | x 2 − 2 x | + C
2
)
1 3
= x + 4 x + ln x 2 − 2 x + C
3
dx
de u de u
, give U = f ( x), = u ' ( x)e u , thus, ∫ e u u ' ( x)dx = e u + C
dx dx
91
Example
Evaluate the indefinite integral of the following
∫ 2 xe
x2
a) dx
Solution
du
Let x2=U and = 2X
dx
∫ U ' ( x )e
u
dx
Thus, = e u + C
2
= ex + C
∫x
3
b) 2
e x dx
Solution
1
Let x3 = U, U’(x) = 3x2 and manipulating it little, we get x2 = U ' ( x)
3
1 u du 1 x3
3 ∫ dx
= e ⋅ dx = e + C = 1 e x3 + C
3 3
Solution
TR = ∫ MRdx = ∫ 6e
0.01 x
dx
= 600e0.01 +C
♠
Let 0.01 x = U(x)
U’(x) = 0.01
1
U’(x) =
100
100u’(x) = 1
600 u’(x) = 6
92
But Revenue= 0, when output x = 0, thus 0 = 600 + C
C = -600
TR = 600e0.01x – 600
TR (100) = 600 (e0.01 x 100 –1)
= 1030.97
G. Integration by Parts
Although the previous rules of integration are important elements in
the day to day mathematical toolkits of economists when dealing
with integration problems, there are problems which require us
more. Some of these problems are solved using the concept of
integration by parts.
We know that
d
(u ( x)m( x)) = u' m + m' u
dx
d
∫ dx (um) dx = ∫ u' mdx + ∫ m' udx
um = ∫ um' dx + ∫ mu ' dx
dm du
um = ∫ u dx + ∫ m dx
dx dx
um = ∫ udm + ∫ mdu
∴ ∫ udm = um − ∫ mdu.
93
integrable. If you confront with a dilemma give priority to the easily
integrable part. Any way, let’s see examples for they make ideas
simple and clearer.
Examples
1. ∫ xe
x
dx
Solution
Dividing it into X part and exdx part let U= x and
dm = exdx so that m = ∫ dm = ∫ e dx = e x and du = dx
x
∫ xe dx =xe x − ∫ e x dx + C
x
= xex - ex+C
2. ∫X
2
ln xdx
Solution
Dividing it into X part and exdx part let U=ln x and dm = X2dx, we
1 1
have m = ∫ dm = ∫ x 2 dx = x 3 and du= dx
3 x
Using the formula ∫ udm = um − ∫ mdu and directly inserting the values
94
4.4. Definite Integrals
Let f(x) be a function and “a” and “b” be real numbers. The definite
integral of f(x) over the interval from X=a to X=b denoted by
b
∫ f ( x)dx
a is the net change of an anti-derivative of f(x) over the
interval. Thus, if F(x) is an antiderivative of f(x), then we have
b
∫ f ( x)dx = F ( x)
b
a
= F (b) − F (a )
a
∫
a
f ( x)dx = F (b) − F ( x) = F (b) − F (a )
a
Example:
Evaluate the defnite integrals of the following
3
∫ x dx
3
1.
1
x 3+1 3
= + C
3 + 1 1
1 3
= x4 + C
4 1
1 1
= ⋅ 3 4 + C − ⋅ 14 + C
4 4
81 1
= −
4 4
= 20
95
b b
1. ∫ Kf ( x)dx = K ∫ f ( x)dx,
a a
b b b
2. ∫ [ f ( x) ± g ( x)]dx = ∫ f ( x)dx ± ∫ g ( x)dx
a a a
b c b
3. ∫ f ( x)dx = ∫ f ( x)dx + ∫ f ( x)dx,
a a c
for a < c < b
a
4. ∫ f ( x)dx = 0
a
b a
5. ∫
a
f ( x)dx = − ∫ f ( x)dx
b
5
1. ∫ 3x
2
dx
2
2
2. ∫e
3x
dx
−1
1 2
3. The marginal cost function for a company is MC= x − 2 x + 120
100
birr per unit, where X is output produced. Find the net increase in
cost when output increases from 100 units to 105 units.
Solution
∫ 3x dx =
2
2
1.
3 x 2+1 5
= + C
2 +1 2
=5 −2
3 3
= 125 – 8
= 117
2.
2
∫e dx =
3x
−1
1 2
= e3x + C
3 −1
1 1
= e 6 − e −3
3 3
1 1
= e6 − 3
3 3e
96
1 e9 − 1
=
3 e 3
= 134.46
3.
105
∫ MCdxdx
100
105
1
= ∫ 100 x − 2 x + 120 dx
2
100
1 3 105
= x − x 2 + 120 x
300 100
= 100.42
Exercise
Try the following problems.
1. Suppose that the marginal profit for a company is
MP=100+50X-3X2. Find the total profit earned from the sale of
three additional units if 5 units are currently being produced.
2. For a number of years the annual worldwide rate of oil
consumption was growing exponentially with a growth
constant of about 0.07. At the beginning 1970, the rate was
about 16.1 million barrels of oil/year. Let R(t) denote the rate
of oil consumption at time (t) where t is the number of years
since the beginning of 1970. Then a reasonable model of R(t)
is given by
R (t) =16.1e0.07t
How much oil was consumed between 1975 and 1980?
The answers are $888 and 0.465 for the first and second questions
respectively.
Y Y=f(x)
a b X
97
Let f(x) be a function that is continuous and non-negative for all X
between “a” and “b” where a<b, determine the area of the shaded
region lying beneath the curve Y=f(x) and above the X-axis from
X=a to X=b. The area of the shaded region is calculated using the
fundamental theorem of calculus stated above. It is given by
b b
∫ f ( x)dx = F (b) − F ( x)
a a
= F (b) − F (a )
Examples
Solution
Area
2
= ∫ f ( x)dx
1
2
= ∫ ( x 2 − 1)dx
1
2
1
= x 3 − x
3 1
8 1
= − 2 − − 1
3 3
= 4/3
Solution
Area
1
= ∫ (4t + 1) dt
2
3 1
1 4t + 1
=
4 3 0
1 5 3 13
= −
4 3 3
31
=
3
98
Solution
Y=X
2
1
1 2
Area=
2
∫ xdx
1
2
1
= x2 + C
2 1
1
= 2−
2
3
=
2
∫ [ f ( x) − g ( x)]dx
a
99
Example
1. Find the area of the region between Y= 2x2–4x + 6 and
Y = -X2 +2X+1 from X=1 to X=2
Solution
Over the range of values X=1 to X=2, the function Y= 2x2–4x + 6
lays above the function Y = -X2 +2X+1. To check which function is
greater, let’s sketch the graph with in the interval [1, 2].
Y = 2x2 – 4x + 6
6
R
-1
1 2
Y = x2 + 2x + 1
Hence, the area of the shaded region is
∫ [(2 x )]
2
R= 2
) (
− 4 x + 6 − − x 2 + 2 x + 1 dx
1
2
= ∫ (2 x − 4 x + 6 + x 2 − 2 x − 1 dx )
2
2
= ∫ (3x − 6 x + 5 dx)
2
2
= x3 − 3 x 2 + 5 x 1
[
= 2 − 3( 2) + 5( 2) − 1 − 3(1) + 5(1)
3 2
] [ 3 3
]
= [8 − 12 + 10] − [1 − 3 + 5] = 6 − 3 = 3
2. Find the area of the region between Y=X2 and Y=X2-4x+4
from X=0 to X=3
Solution
If we sketch both functions, we get
Y=X2 Y=X2-4x+4
0 1 3
100
To find the point of inter section X2 = x2-4x+4
0 =-4x + 4
X=1
Since no line completely lies above the other over the shaded
region, we need to calculate the area from X=0 to X=1 and from
X=1 to X=3.
Thus, area is given by
0 0 1
1 3
= ∫ (−4 x + 4)dx + ∫ (4 x − 4)dx
0 1
1 3
= − 2x 2 + 4x + 2x 2 − 4x
0 1
[ ]
= 2 + 18 − 2 − [2 − 4] = 2 + 6 + 2 = 10
∫ (x )
− (−e x ) dx
2
−1
2
= ∫ (x )
+ e x dx
2
−1
2
1 3
= x + ex
3 −1
8 −1
= + e 2 − + e −x
3 3
2 -1
=3+e –e
Solution
In this case let’s check for points of intersection get the interval
Thus, x2 + 2x + 3 = 2x + 4
x2 = 1
x = ±1
f(x) 3 3 11
X -2 -1 0 1 2
g(x)
0 4 8
101
Y = 2x + 4 > Y = x2 + 2x + 3
g(x)>f(x)
1
Area = ∫ (2 x + 4 − x )
− 2 x − 3 dx
2
−1
1
∫ (− x + 1)dx
2
−1
−1 3 1
=∫ x +x
3 −1
− 1 1
= + 1 − − 1
3 3
−1 1 2 4
= + 1 − + 1= 2 − =
3 3 3 5
Px = 8 – x
P X
O 8
1 7 Graphically
2 6
3 5 Px
8 Consumer’s Surplus
5 4
5 3
6 2
7 1 P=3
8 0 3
Px=8-x
5 8 x
102
Using integral calculus assuming the relationship between price and
quantity demanded is continuous,
5 5 5
1
CS = ∫ [(8 − x ) − 3]dx = ∫ (5 − x)d = 5 x − x 2
0 0 2 0
= [25 − 12.5]
= 12.5
Area of the shaded region using the law of triangle is given as
= (8-3) (5-0)X0.5
1
Shaded region = (8-3) (5-2) x = 12.5
2
Examples:
1. Find the consumer’s surplus at price of $8 if the demand
1
function is given by P = 20 - x
2
Solution
To find point of intersection, find x at P =8. That is,
1
8 = 20 − x
20
1
x = 12
20
x = 240
Hence, the consumers’ surplus is given by
240
1
CS = ∫ (20 − x − 8)dx
0
20
240
1
= 12 x − x 2
40 0
1
= 12(240) − (240 x 240)
40
= [12(240) − 6(240)]
103
Producer’s surplus: is the excess of money that the producer
actually receives over what she is willing to accept/receive. If
supply function, written as a function of price, is given by S (x) and
we want to obtain producers’ surplus at price P and corresponding
quantity supplied x , we can use the general formula specified below:
x
PS = = ∫ P − S ( x)dx That is
0
S(x) = P
PS
p
Y =P
Example
104
300
1
= ∫ 18 − 500 x
2
dx
0
300
1
= 18 x − x3
15000 0
a) Consumers’ surplus
b) Producers’ surplus
c) Social welfare assuming the economy is two-sector
Warlasian economy.
1
P x
= 20 −
20
x
1 2
P x
= 2+
500
x
Solution
To find the market price and quantity,
1 1
⇒ 20 − x = 2+ x2
20 5000
1 1
⇒ x2 + x − 18 = 0
5000 20
⇒ x 2 + 250 x − 90,000 = 0
⇒ X2 + 250X+ 15575 = 10575
Now, it is easy to deal with the problem. Insert the values in the
formulae so that you will come up with the answers.
105
200
1
CS = ∫ 20 − 20 x − 10 dx = 1000
0
200
1
PS = ∫ 10 − 2 − 5000 x
dx = 1067
2
0
Social welfare is the sum of total consumers’ surplus and producers’
surplus.
SW = CS + PS = 2067
Note in the table that the lowest paid 40% of the population
receives only 18% of the income, whereas if income were
absolutely equally distributed, they would get 40% of the income.
In fact, if income were equally distributed, the data would lie along
the 45-degree line. In actuality, the data always lie along a curve
below the line, a curve called a Lorenz curve. The further this curve
moves from the 45 degree line, the more unequal the income
distribution.
100
Cumulative Cumulative 80
Percent of Income
percentage percentage
of people of income 60
2 0
20 6 40
40 18
20
60 35
80 59
100 100 20 40 60 80 100
Percent of people
As a measure of inequality, we use the so-called Gini coefficient of
inequality “g” defined by
g = Area between the Lorenz curve and the line y = x
Area under the line y = x
106
The numerator is a definite integral whose value is between 0 and
½; the denominator has a value of exactly ½. Thus, g is between 0
(absolute equality) and 1 (absolute inequality). If y = f(x) is the
equation of the Lorenz curve, the formula for g takes the simple
form
1
g = 2∫ [x − f ( x)]dx
0
Example
Sketch the Lorenz curves y = x 2 and y = x 5 on the same graph and
determine the corresponding Gini coefficients.
Solution
The graphs are shown in Figure below. The required Gini coefficients
are
x2 x3 1 1
[ ]
1
g = 2∫ x − x 2 dx = 2 − ∫ =
0 2 3 0 3
and
x2 x6 1 2
[ ]
1
g = 2∫ x − x dx = 2 − ∫ =
5
0 2 3 0 3
Y
100
.80
.60 Y=x
.40 Y = x2
.20
Y = x5
x
.20 .40 .60 .80
P = fe − rt
107
Written in this from, the equation tells us the present value P of F
dollars that will be received t years from now, assuming that
interest is compounded continuously at the annual rate r.
Example
Bethel knows that she will need to replace her car in 3 year How
much would she have to put in the bank today at 8% interest
compounded continually in order to have the $12,000 she expects
to need 3 years from now?
Solution
We apply the boxed formula, remembering that the interest rate of
8% must be written in its decimal form.
T
PV = ∫ R(t )e − rt dt
0
Example
Suppose the ABV Company takes a more optimistic view and
estimates that the new machine will produce income at the rate R
(t) = 10,000 + 200t. What is the present value of this income
stream, again assuming interest at 9% compounded continuously
and a lifetime of 8 years?
108
Solution
8
PV = ∫ (10,000 + 200t )e −0.09t dt
0
8 8
= ∫ 10,000e −0.09t dt + ∫ 200te −0.09t dt
0 0
∞
PV = ∫ R (t )e − rt dt
0
∞ T
R ( t ) e − rt dt
∫ R(t ) dt = Limr →∞ 0
e − rt ∫
∞
C 1−δ − 1
U (c) = ∫ e − Bt Ldx
0 1 − δ
109
Where
• U(c) is the utility function the social planner maximizes,
• -B is the discount rate agents assign to future consumption,
• C is percapita consumption
• L is the size of population
• And δ is the inverse of the intertemporal elasticity of
substitution.
Now we have faced some what new, but definite integral, problem
in this function. Such type of integral is known as improper
integrals. An improper integral is an integral which is bounded by
either (− ∞, ∞ ) , (c, ∞ ) , or (− ∞, c ) where c is a constant. This limit of
integration is infinite. To find out the value of this integral use the
formula:
∞ b
∫
f ( x ) dx
a) For f ( x)dx = lim b→∞ a∫
a
∫
∫ f ( x ) dx
f ( x ) dx = lim a → −∞ a
−∞
c b
= Lim a →−∞ ∫ f ( x)dx + Limb→∞ ∫ f ( x)dx
a c
Examples
110
∞
1
1. Find the value of ∫ x dx and
1
determine its status of
convergence.
Solution
∞ b
∞
1
2. Find ∫x
1
2
dx
Solution
∞ b b
1 1 − 1 −1
∫1 x 2 dx = Limb→∞ ∫1 x 2 dx = Limb→∞ x 1 = Limb→∞ b + 1 = 1
Since limit does exist, the integral converges.
3. Now it is time for you to check whether you have grasped the
concept or not. To this end, why don’t you handle this problem? Use
0
dx
your paper and pen right now! ∫ 3
− ∞ (1 − 2 x ) 2
The order of the ODE is that of the highest derivative; that is, if the
highest derivative in an ODE is order of n, then it is an nth order
ODE. When the functional form of the equation is linear, then it is a
linear ODE.
Let have illustrations!
111
•
a) a1 y (t ) + a 2 y (t ) + x(t ) = 0 This is 1st order linear ODE.
• dy
Where ⇒ y (t ) =
dt
⇒ a1 ,&a 2 are constants
⇒ x(t ) Known function of time
•• •
b) a1 y (t ) + a 2 y (t ) + a3 y (t ) + x(t ) = 0 This is 2nd order linear ODE
•• d2y
Where y (t ) =
dt 2
1
c) log y& (t ) + = 0 is non-linear first order ODE.
y (t )
dy
Such an equation is + u (t ) y = w(t )
dt
When u (t) and w (t) are constants, it is first order linear differential
equations (LDE) with constant coefficient and constant term.
When w (t) = 0, it reduced to homogenous 1st order LDE
W (t) w(t ) ≠ 0, is it know as not-homogenous case
112
Y = e − at + c
Y = e c ⋅ e − at
From the solution, it can be seen that the objective and solution of
solving differential equation is not numeric value rather t is the time
path of y (t).
Thus, Yc = Ae − at
dy
By assuming Y to be constant = 0 and we’ll have ay = b and
dt
b
YP =
a
b
∴ The general solution will be Y (t ) = Yc + Yp = Ae − at +
a
But when t=0, our equation will be reduced to
b
Y (t ) = Ae − at +
a
b
Y (o) = A +
a
b
A = Y( 0 ) −
a
Hence, we finally come up with
113
b b
Yt = Y( 0 ) − e − at +
a a
When b = 0, Y (t) turns to the homogeneous case
Examples
dy
a) Solve + 4 y = 0. and Y (o) = 1
dt
Y (t ) = Ae − at
Y (o) = Ae 0
1=A
A=1
∴ Y (t ) = e −4t
dy
b) Solve + 2 y = 6 and Y (0) =10
dt
Solution
b b
Yt = Y (o) − e − at +
a a
6 6
Yt = 10 − e −2t +
2 2
Yt = 7e − 2t +3
114
Application of the Non-Homogenous case: Dynamic model of the market
price
The objective in this section is to see whether a free enterprise
economy without any form of government intervention can bring a
price which will satisfy both consumers and producers and whether
this price will be stable [ deviances from the equilibrium position will
not bring a sustained change in price and the equilibrium state will
be maintained again with some adjustments] or knife
edge[unstable] through fulfilling the economic interest of both
producers and consumers. Let’s begin with simple model of market.
Equation α − βρ = −γ + δρ
α + γ = (δ + β ) ρ
α +γ
P= ⇒ it is some positive constant
u+β
dp
= m(Qs − Qd ) Where m>0
dt
dp
= − m(γ + δρ − α + βP)
dt
= m(−γ + α ) + m(δ + β ) P
dp
+ − m(δ + β ) P = − m(γ + α ) Using the formula stated above, we get
dt
115
− m(γ + α ) − m (δ + β ) t − m(γ + α )
⇒ P(t ) = e + This is identical to the
− m(δ + β − m(δ + β )
γ + α − m (δ + β ) γ + α
expression P (t ) = P(0) − e +
γ + β δ +β
[ ]
Pt = (0) − P e − m (δ + β ) t + P
P(0) − P
Pt = +P
e m (δ + β ) t
price “Pt”. This implies that the market (equilibrium) price and
concomitant quantity are stable.
116