Business Model Design and The Performance of Entrepreneurial Firms
Business Model Design and The Performance of Entrepreneurial Firms
Business Model Design and The Performance of Entrepreneurial Firms
By
Christoph Zott
INSEAD
Euro-Asia Center 006
Boulevard de Constance
77305 Fontainebleau Cedex
FRANCE
Telephone: 33 1 6072 4364
Fax: 33 1 60 72 42 23
E-mail: [email protected]
and
Raphael Amit
The Wharton School
University of Pennsylvania
3620 Locust walk
Philadelphia, PA 19104-6370
Telephone: (215) 898-7731
Fax: (215) 573-7189
E-Mail: [email protected]
August 3, 2006
Both authors contributed equally to this article. Christoph Zott gratefully acknowledges financial support
from the Alliance Center for Global Research & Development, and the Rudolf and Valeria Maag
Fellowship in Entrepreneurship. Raffi Amit acknowledges generous financial support of the Wharton e-
business initiative (a unit of the Mack Center for Technological Innovation at the Wharton School), and
the Robert B. Goergen Chair in Entrepreneurship at the Wharton School. Both authors thank Iwona
Bancerek, Amee Kamdar, and Jenny Koelle for their research assistance. We are grateful to Rich Burton
and to two anonymous reviewers for helpful comments. For insightful comments during the development
of this study, we would like to thank Eric Bradlow, Hubert Gatignon, Lorin Hitt, Ha Hoang, Quy Huy,
Aba Krieger, Anita McGahan, Werner Reinartz, Nicolaj Siggelkow, Belen Villalonga, and seminar
participants at Washington University in St. Louis and at the Wharton School.
Business Model Design and the Performance of Entrepreneurial Firms
Abstract
We focus on a particular organization design issue – namely, the design of an organization’s set of
boundary-spanning transactions – to which we refer as business model design, and ask how business
model design affects the performance of entrepreneurial firms. Specifically, by extending and integrating
theoretical perspectives that inform the study of boundary-spanning organization design, we propose
hypotheses about the impact of efficiency-centered and novelty-centered business model design on the
performance of entrepreneurial firms. To test these hypotheses, we developed and analyzed a unique data
set of 190 entrepreneurial firms that were publicly listed on U.S. and European stock exchanges. The
empirical results show that novelty-centered business model design matters to the performance of
entrepreneurial firms. Our analysis also shows that this positive relationship is remarkably stable across
time, even under varying environmental regimes. As well, we find indications of potential diseconomies
of scope in design; that is, entrepreneurs’ attempts to incorporate both efficiency- and novelty-centered
Keywords: Organization design, new organizational forms, business model, design themes, organization
coordinated activity systems; it can be conceived of as an open system that interacts with its environment
(Thompson 1967). Its subsystems can be classified either “internal” or “boundary-spanning” (Daft 2004).
Substantial research on organization design has focused on internal design issues such as centralization,
span of control, personnel ratios, and lines of authority (e.g., Nystrom and Starbuck 1981). Some
scholars, however, have observed that organizations are increasingly “experimenting with their
governance of transactions, that is, adopting new ways of structuring their boundaries” (Foss 2002, p. 1).
A growing body of work on organizational forms has gradually shifted attention from internal design
toward modes of organizing and managing transactions with the firm’s environment (e.g., Ilinitch,
D’Aveni and Lewin 1996, Lewin and Volbverda 1999, Miles and Snow 1986, Romanelli 1991). While
this body of research has enhanced our understanding of how managers and entrepreneurs set
organizational boundaries, important questions remain open. For example, how can the design of an
organization’s set of boundary-spanning transactions be described and measured, and what do we know
These questions provide the point of departure for this study. Recent advances in communication
and information technologies, such as the emergence and the swift expansion of the Internet, and the rapid
decline in computing and communication costs have accentuated the possibilities for the design of new
boundary-spanning organizational forms (Daft and Lewin 1993, Foss 2002, Ilinitch et al. 1996).1 Indeed,
these developments have opened new horizons for the design of business models by enabling firms to
change fundamentally the way they organize and engage in economic exchanges, both within and across
firm and industry boundaries (Mendelson 2000). According to Brynjolfsson and Hitt (2004), information
technologies have changed fundamentally the ways in which firms interact with suppliers as well as
customers. This emerging stream of work on boundary-spanning designs complements a large body of
1
literature that points to the links between internal organization design issues, such as the degree of
decentralization, the structure of incentives, and the implications on productivity for investment in
information technologies (e.g., see Bresnahan, Brynjolfsson and Hitt 2002, or Ichniowski, Kochan,
Levine, Olson and Strauss 1996). This paper builds on the shift in perspective from viewing organization
organizational design.
transactions as business model design, and we ask: How can business model design be measured, and
how does it affect firm performance? Along the lines of Amit and Zott (2001, p. 511), we formally define
the business model as depicting “the content, structure, and governance of transactions designed so as to
create value through the exploitation of business opportunities.” That is, a business model elucidates how
an organization is linked to, and how it engages in economic exchanges with, external stakeholders in
Designing the business model is a salient issue for entrepreneurial firms who are less constrained
by path dependencies and inertia than more established firms (Stinchcombe 1965). Following Bhide
(2000) we define entrepreneurial firms as relatively young organizations that have the potential of
attaining significant size and profitability. These firms must solve coordination problems in a world of
novelty and systemic change (Langlois 2005). Their performance therefore often critically depends on
boundary-spanning organizational arrangements (Hite and Hesterly 2001). One of the central design tasks
of entrepreneurs is, consequently, to delineate the ways in which their new businesses transact with
suppliers, customers, and partners. As Ireland et al. (2001, p.53) note, entrepreneurs often “try to find
fundamentally new ways of doing business that will disrupt an industry’s existing competitive rules,
leading to the development of new business models.” Christensen (2001), for example, highlighted the
shift in the locus of profitability in the computer industry as companies, such as Dell, pioneered non-
1
According to Brynjolfsson and Hitt (2004), the costs of automated information processing have fallen
more than 99.9% since the 1960s.
2
integrated and flexible business models in which production and distribution were organized in novel
ways. Even when entrepreneurial firms replicate the business models of existing organizations (Aldrich
1999), they may have to adapt these designs to their own particular market niche (McGrath and
MacMillan 2000).
Although recent work in entrepreneurship and organization theory has begun to address the
important role of design in the entrepreneurship process (Hargadorn and Douglas 2001, Romme 2003,
Van de Ven, Hudson and Schroeder 1984), relatively little is known about the specific trade-offs and
performance implications of business model design, which can be far-reaching. For example, Hargadorn
and Douglas (2001, p. 494) attribute the failure of Prodigy, an on-line service in which investors had
invested $600 million, to the mismatch between the design of its business model and customer needs.
In this paper we identify two critical dimensions of business model design, which we denote as
“efficiency-centered” and “novelty-centered” design themes. Anchoring our reasoning in the transaction
cost perspective (Milgrom and Roberts 1992, Williamson 1975) and in Schumpeter’s theory of innovation
(Schumpeter 1934), we offer hypotheses about the impact of business model design themes on the
performance of the focal entrepreneurial firm, taking into consideration the potentially moderating role of
the environment. Efficiency-centered business model design refers to the measures that firms may take to
achieve transaction efficiency through their business models. It aims at reducing transaction costs for all
transaction participants. Novelty-centered business model design refers to new ways of conducting
economic exchanges among various participants. It can be achieved, for example, by connecting
previously unconnected parties, by linking transaction participants in new ways, or by designing new
transaction mechanisms. These design themes are neither orthogonal (for instance, novel design elements
may engender lower transaction costs), nor are they mutually exclusive: Both may be present in the
design of any given business model. Moreover, the design themes are not exhaustive. Business models
may be characterized by other value-creation themes. These could include “lock-in,” which refers to
designs that attempt to retain stakeholders, and “complementarities,” which refer to designs that
emphasize the bundling of goods, activities, resources, or technologies (Amit and Zott 2001). We focus
3
herein on efficiency- and novelty-centered designs in the interest of building and testing parsimonious
theory.
To test our hypotheses, we have developed a unique data set that contains detailed information
about the business models of 190 entrepreneurial firms that were listed on a public exchange between
1996 and 2000. We measure each business model design theme as a variable at a particular point in time,
and we regress these variables on a range of performance measures. Overall, we find that business model
design matters to the performance of entrepreneurial firms. Our most robust finding relates to the positive
association between novelty-centered business model design and firm performance. Our analysis shows
that this positive relationship is remarkably stable across time, even under varying environmental
regimes. Our results also indicate that entrepreneurs’ attempts to design both efficiency- and novelty-
This paper builds on and extends earlier work that has considered business models in the context
of organizational performance. Focusing primarily on the impact of network effects on the stock market
value of e-commerce firms, Rajgopal, Venkatachalam and Kotha (2003) examine how network effects
interact with the firm’s business model, measured as a categorical variable (i.e., content provider, portal,
financial services, e-tailer, or auction site). In our analysis, we focus primarily on the design of the
business model (rather than on network effects), and on its direct impact on firm performance, both
theorerically as well as empirically; our proposed measures of business model design are continuous and
apply to a broad range of firms. Filson (2004) studies the impact on firm value of the competitive
strategies of Amazon.com, Barnesandnoble.com, CDNow, and N2K. We, too, focus on firms that derive
at least some of their revenue through transactions that are executed on the Internet. However, we
examine in detail the impact of business model design, distinct from the competitive strategy of a firm
(Zott and Amit 2006), on firm value. Moreover, we look at a large sample of firms in the U.S. and
Europe.
This study, then, attempts to make several contributions to the organization design literature.
First, we refine concepts and measures for examining the design of a firm’s business model. The
4
importance of research on transaction designs as new organizational forms has been recognized in earlier
studies, (e.g., Foss 2002, Rindova and Kotha 2001). We contribute to this literature through the
development of granulated concepts for operationalizing and measuring business model designs. Second,
we provide a theoretical extension of the transaction costs perspective and of Schumpeter’s theory of
innovation. By integrating into these theories bargaining theory, we develop the performance implications
of business model design under varying regimes of environmental munificence, specifically for
entrepreneurial firms whose transactions are enabled by information and communication technologies.
There is little prior theory on this issue. Third, drawing on a large and a unique hand-collected data set
about business model design themes, we test the linkage between these design themes and focal firm
performance. Although we we build on earlier studies that examine how business models are linked to
firm performance (e.g, Rajgopal et al. 2003), we believe that this is the first study to operationalize,
measure, and test the performance consequences of business model design themes. Further, by
highlighting the pivotal role that business model design plays in the performance of entrepreneurial firms
In summary, in this paper we argue theoretically and show empirically that the business model is
a useful unit of analysis for research on boundary-spanning organization design, as well as a locus of
innovation that has hitherto been largely overlooked by entrepreneurship research. Rindova and Kotha
(2001, p.1277) have pointed out the need for “a broader and more dynamic understanding of
configured to generate a stream of value-creating products and services.” The concept of the business
model fulfills these requirements, and thus can potentially help advance the emerging body of research on
The remainder of the paper is organized as follows: The subsequent section presents our theory
and hypotheses. It is followed by sections describing our data and methods and our results. We conclude
with a discussion of our findings and implications of our study for future research.
5
THEORY AND HYPOTHESES DEVELOPMENT
To develop measures of business model design, configuration theory provides a useful starting
point because it considers holistic configurations, or gestalts, of design elements (Miles and Snow 1978).
Configurations are constellations of design elements that commonly occur together because their
interdependence makes them fall into patterns (Meyer, Tsui and Hinings 1993). The design elements of a
business model are the content, structure, and governance of transactions. In this paper, we follow
Miller’s (1996) suggestion to view configuration as a variable rather than as a deviation from an ideal
type. Miller states that, “Configuration…can be defined as the degree to which an organization’s elements
The relevant question then is the following: What are the common design themes that orchestrate
and connect a business model’s elements? Miller (1996) mentions innovation and efficiency as possible
design themes. This choice appears particularly appropriate for the study of business models adopted by
entrepreneurial firms as the two themes reflect fundamental alternatives for entrepreneurs to create value
under uncertainty. Novelty and efficiency play important roles for the emergence of new organizations
because entrepreneurs can create new designs and/or reproduce and copy existing ones (Aldrich 1999).
Imitation-based approaches towards business creation are often associated with an emphasis on lower
costs, i.e., increased efficiency (Zott 2003). Since these themes are not mutually exclusive, any given
business model design can be novelty-centered and efficiency-centered at the same time.
Business Model Design, Firm Performance, and the Moderating Role of the Environment
We hypothesize that the design of an entrepreneurial firm’s business model, which is centered
specifically on the themes of novelty and/or efficiency, is associated with the performance of that firm.
This association can be broken down into two effects: One effect relies on the total value-creation
potential of the business model design, and the second effect considers the impact of business model
design on the firm’s ability to appropriate the value that its business model creates.
6
Business models can create value by enhancing the customers’ willingness to pay or by
decreasing suppliers’ and partners’ opportunity costs, for example, through improved transaction
efficiency. The total value created by a business model is also a function of the competitive alternatives,
in other words, the market power of the focal firm’s business model vis-à-vis rival business models. The
total value created is the value created for all business model stakeholders (focal firm, customers,
suppliers, and other exchange partners). It is the upper limit for the value that can be captured by the focal
How does business model design influence the competing claims to total value created by
different stakeholders to the business model? Drawing on Brandenburger and Nalebuff (1995) and
Brandenburger and Stuart (1996), we reason that the value eventually appropriated by the focal firm
hinges on the bargaining power of the focal firm relative to other business model stakeholders. Thus, the
overall effect of a business model design theme on firm performance is partly determined by the
bargaining position of the focal firm. This reasoning suggests a positive association between the design of
the business model and the performance of the focal firm if, for a given level of competition, the focal
firm’s business model design creates value, and it does not decrease its bargaining power relative to other
relationship between business model design and the performance of an entrepreneurial firm (McArthur
and Nystrom 1991). Munificence, dynamism, and complexity are all important dimensions of the
environment that could be examined (Dess and Beard 1984). In this paper, we focus on munificence,
because it captures the availability of resources, which is a key challenge for entrepreneurial firms.
According to Randolph and Dess (1984) and McArthur and Nystrom (1991), munificence influences the
survival and growth of existing companies, as well as the ability of new firms to enter the market. The use
view of organizations that treats environments as arenas in which all compete for resources (Pfeffer and
Salancik 1978, Aldrich 1979). This perspective seems particularly relevant for entrepreneurial firms,
7
which depend critically on external resources, and, in particular, on the receptivity of capital and product
Consistent with these arguments, and building on the work of Aldrich (1979), Dess and Beard
(1984), and Tushman and Anderson (1986), we define munificence as the extent to which the
environment supports growth. Specifically, in this paper, munificence refers to the scarcity or abundance
of critical resources required to create and implement business model designs. As we argue below, the
performance prospects of ventures with novelty- and/or efficiency-centered business model designs may
vary with the availability and costs of resources that entrepreneurs can access.
designs, lies the act of innovation, which can be defined as “employing existing resources in a different
way, in doing new things with them, irrespective of whether those resources increase or not” (Schumpeter
1934, p. 68). This Schumpeterian logic of innovation through recombination of resources is consistent
with the emphasis of this paper on entrepreneurial firms that rely on new technologies to transact with
external stakeholders. For example, a firm could use the Internet to reconfigure the ways in which its own
competencies are linked with those of its customers (Von Hippel and Katz 2002). The essence of
novelty-centered business model design is the conceptualization and adoption of new ways of conducting
economic exchanges, which can be achieved, for example, by connecting previously unconnected parties,
by linking transaction participants in new ways, or by designing new transaction mechanisms. Business
model innovation may complement innovation in products and services, methods of production,
distribution or marketing, and markets (Schumpeter 1934). A novel business model either creates a new
market – eBay is a case in point – or innovates transactions in existing markets – Priceline.com and Dell
are cases in point. Dell, for instance, implemented a customer-driven build-to-order business model,
which replaced the traditional build-to-stock model of selling computers through retail stores
8
Thus, the business model may serve not only to exploit an opportunity for wealth creation, but its
design may be part of the opportunity development process in and of itself. The entrepreneur-as-designer
can co-create opportunities, for example, by drawing on new information and communication
Business model innovation may give rise to entrepreneurial rents (Rumelt 1987). These
monopoly-type rents may accrue to business model stakeholders between the time an innovation is
introduced and the time it is diffused. Although we expect a positive primary effect of novelty-centered
business model design on the performance of entrepreneurial firms, entrepreneurial rents may accrue to
all stakeholders in the business model. Thus, in order to predict the overall effect of novelty-centered
business model design on the performance of the focal entrepreneurial firm, we must also consider the
effect of novelty-centered design on the ability of that firm to appropriate the value that its business
model generates. This ability depends on such factors as (i) the switching costs of other business model
stakeholders; (ii) the focal firm’s ability to control information, (iii) the ability of other stakeholders to
take unified action vis-à-vis the focal firm, and (iv) the replacement costs of other stakeholders (see Coff
1999: 122). For example, the higher the switching costs of other business model stakeholders, the greater
the focal firm’s bargaining power vis-à-vis these stakeholders, and the greater its ability to appropriate
rent. Similarly, the focal firm’s bargaining power and its ability to appropriate rent is positively affected
by factors that give it greater control of information, reduce the ability of other stakeholders to take
unified action against it, or lower the replacement costs of other stakeholders,
We suggest that, on average, an increase in business model novelty will not decrease the focal
entrepreneurial firm’s ex-post bargaining power relative to other business model stakeholders. The focal
firm is the innovator, and its business model is the locus of innovation. The higher the degree of business
model novelty, the higher the switching costs (i) for the focal firm’s customers, suppliers and partners, as
alternatives to doing business with the focal firm may not be readily available. The other determinants
(ii)-(iv) of the focal firm’s bargaining power identified by Coff (1999) are unlikely to be systematically
affected in one direction or the other. Hence, the focal firm’s bargaining power vis-à-vis these parties is
9
unlikely to be diminished through novelty-centered business model design. Therefore, considering the
positive effect of novelty-centered business model design both on total value created and on the ability of
the focal firm to capture that value, we expect a positive effect of novelty-centered business model design
In periods of high resource availability, novelty-centered business model design will matter more
to performance than in periods of resource scarcity. In times of high resource munificence, entrepreneurs
can more easily persuade, negotiate and coordinate with resource holders, and teach them about the merits
of their innovative business model designs; their dynamic governance costs (e.g., persuasion costs) are
lower (Langlois 1992; Langlos and Robertson 1995). Entrepreneurs have thus easier access to the
resources necessary to support and implement their business model innovations, such as investments in
complementary assets. In other words, in environments characterized by high resource munificence, the
advantages derived from novelty-centered business models are accentuated, while our arguments about
the bargaining power of firms with novel business models continue to hold. Entrepreneurial firms with
novelty-centered business model designs are poised to take advantage of the greater willingness of
customers to spend, and they will not suffer a decrease in their aggregate bargaining power vis-à-vis other
business model stakeholders. Thus, novel business model design is more distinctly associated with higher
firm performance when resources are abundant than when they are scarce.
organizations, or business models. In other words, entrepreneurs may choose to imitate rather than
10
innovate – to do similar things as established organizations, yet do these things in a more efficient way
(Aldrich 1999, Zott 2003). To examine the performance implications of efficiency-centered business
models, we build on the transaction cost perspective (Milgrom and Roberts 1992, Williamson, 1975,
1983). This appears appropriate because this perspective, like the business model construct, refers to the
information asymmetry and complexity, determine that transactions will be organized into markets or
hierarchies in ways that minimize transaction costs and maximize performance. Researchers generally
assume that economic actors whose transactions are not aligned with appropriate governance structures
are “more likely to display poor financial performance … than those whose transactions are properly
aligned” (Silverman 2001, p. 484). Poppo and Zenger (1998) have explicitly modeled the performance
implications of the transaction cost perspective. And Milgrom and Roberts (1992) have elaborated on the
effect that both transaction costs, in the form of coordination, and motivation costs have on firm
performance. These studies suggest that there is an important direct relationship between the design of
Efficiency-centered design refers to the measures that firms may take to achieve transaction
efficiency through their business models; the construct focuses on business model design and is not
intended to capture all means by which a firm can strive for efficiency (e.g., through a reduction of
production costs). The essence of an efficiency-centered business model is the reduction of transaction
costs. This reduction can derive from the attenuation of uncertainty, complexity, or information
asymmetry (Williamson 1975), as well as from reduced coordination costs and transaction risk (Clemons
and Row 1992, Langlois 1992, Milgrom and Roberts 1992). The order-tracking feature in Amazon’s
business model, for example, is aimed at enhancing transaction transparency and, therefore, constitutes an
efficiency-centered design element. It reduces the cost of providing information to the logistics company,
and it induces more customers to check on their packages than would do if they did not have access to the
feature (Brynjolfsson and Hitt, 2004). Other efficiency-centered design elements are intended to increase
the reliability and simplicity of transactions, reduce the asymmetry of information among transaction
11
participants, speed up transactions, enable demand aggregation, reduce inventory, provide for transaction
scalability, or reduce the direct and indirect costs of transactions. Consider Baxter ASAP, which lets
hospitals electronically order supplies directly from wholesalers. By reallocating its saved resources (the
costs of data entry), the company was able to offer additional value-adding services to its customers
(Brynjolfsson and Hitt 2004). Consequently, we expect a positive primary effect on firm performance of
In order to predict the overall effect of an efficiency-centered business model design on the
performance of an entrepreneurial firm, however, we must also consider the effect of efficiency-centered
design on the ability of the firm to appropriate the value that its business model generates. As in the case
of novelty-centered business model design, this ability depends on the focal firm’s bargaining power,
which is a function of (i) the switching costs incurred by other business model stakeholders, (ii) the focal
firm’s ability to control information, (iii) the ability of other stakeholders to take unified action vis-à-vis
the focal firm, and (iv) the replacement costs of other stakeholders (see Coff 1999). How does efficiency-
centered design affect these factors? As stated above, such business model design aims at reducing
transaction costs, for example, through simplified transactions, reduced transaction complexity or deep
linkages among business-model stakeholders that often do not require transaction-specific investments
(consider the use of web services). These characteristics of efficiency-centered business model design are
likely to affect the switching costs (i) for all business model stakeholders in the same direction so that, in
the aggregate, the balance of power among these parties will not shift; importantly, the focal firm’s
Another central aspect of efficiency-centered design is that it enables better information flow
among stakeholders and reduces information asymmetries among the parties, thus limiting the control
over information (ii) that any stakeholder can have. This aspect, in general, does not negatively affect the
focal firm’s bargaining power. Moreover, the third determinant (iii) of the focal firm’s bargaining power
identified by Coff (1999) –the ability of other business model stakeholders to take unified action against
the focal firm– is unlikely to be systematically affected in one direction or the other by design efficiency.
12
Lastly, it should be noted that reducing direct transaction costs (e.g., search, transportation, and
coordination costs) as a result of efficiency-centered business model design increases the pool of potential
customers, as well as partners and suppliers, and thus implies a consequent reduction in the cost to the
focal firm of replacing such stakeholders (iv), which tends to increase the firm’s bargaining power.
These arguments suggest that, on balance, a more pronounced efficiency-centered business model
design does not decrease the focal firm’s bargaining power relative to other business model stakeholders.
We therefore expect a positive main effect of efficiency-centered business model design on the
When resources are scarce and not readily available to entrepreneurs, efficiency-centered
business model design assumes greater importance as a differentiating factor among business models than
in periods of resource munificence. In tough economic environments, consumers and businesses spend
and invest less; cost savings become relatively more important as a driver of value creation.
Entrepreneurial firms are more volatile than established organizations (Stinchcombe, 1965); therefore,
they are quite sensitive to such changes. Conversely, during times of high environmental munificence,
total value can be enhanced, for example, by tapping additional revenue streams. In other words, in
environments characterized by low resource munificence, the advantages derived from reduced
transaction costs are accentuated, while our arguments about the bargaining power of firms with efficient
business models continue to hold. Entrepreneurial firms with efficiency-centered business model designs
are poised to take advantage of transaction cost savings, and they will not suffer a decrease in their
aggregate bargaining power vis-à-vis other business model stakeholders. Thus, efficient business model
design will be more distinctly associated with higher performance of an entrepreneurial firm when
13
the entrepreneurial firm will be stronger than in environments with high
resource munificence.
Interaction between Novelty- and Efficiency-centered Business Model Design and Performance
Do the above arguments imply that entrepreneurs should embrace both efficiency-centered and
novelty-centered business model deisgns? Indeed, the need for balancing design elements has been
recognized by researchers who highlight the benefits for entrepreneurs of reconciling distinct aspects of
design, such as the familiar and the unfamiliar (Hargadorn and Douglas 2001), conformity and
differentiation (Deephouse 1999), and reliability and distinctiveness (Lounsbury and Glynn 2001).
Achieving such balance can help entrepreneurs build much-needed legitimacy (Zott and Huy 2006),
which can be considered a pre-requisite for venture growth and performance (Zimmerman and Zeitz
2002). This line of reasoning suggests that novelty and efficiency can be complementary design themes,
and thus the effect of their interaction on performance could be positive. First, increasing the degree of
novelty of a business model may enhance the return on efficiency-centered design. As previously
discussed, novelty-centered business model design makes a business model more distinctive, and this may
result in increased switching costs for other business model stakeholders because of fewer comparable
alternatives. Hence, by emphasizing business model novelty, the focal firm may be better positioned to
appropriate some of the value it creates through increased efficiency. Second, increasing the emphasis on
efficiency-centered design may enhance the return on design novelty. Novel business models that are also
designed for efficiency may appeal to a wider range of customers (i.e., not only to those who are intrigued
by its novel elements, but also to those who appreciate lower transaction and coordination costs). Thus,
by simultaneously emphasizing efficiency and novelty as design themes, the entrepreneur may be able to
create even more value than through either novelty-centered or efficiency-centered business model design
alone.
14
However, another line of reasoning suggests that attempts by entrepreneurs to design their
business models concurrently for higher efficiency and greater novelty may instead adversely affect their
firm’s performance. Embracing two major design themes in parallel could lead to suboptimal resource
allocation. Given the limited resources available to entrepreneurial firms, entrepreneurs who try to
achieve too much at once may find that they are not getting adequate returns on their design efforts and
investments. This is because a lack of focus may confuse market participants, undermine the venture’s
legitimacy, create technological and organizational problems, and lead to higher costs. Furthermore, it has
been argued that a firm that gets stuck between innovation and imitation – or, analogously, between
novelty and efficiency design themes – may perform poorly because it misses out on the opportunity to
learn to become an even more skillful innovator or imitator (Zott 2003). In summary, there might be
diseconomies of scope in design resulting from bundling novel and efficient design elements.
Sample
we studied the business models of firms that derived all or part of their revenues from transactions
conducted over the Internet. We presume these firms are likely to experiment with, and take advantage of,
the possibilities that advanced information and communication technologies offer for the design of
business models. We examined the business models of firms that had gone public in Europe or in the US
between April 1996 and May 2000. Our sample selection strategy enabled us to create a data set of 362
relatively young, entrepreneurial firms and their business models, from which we randomly sampled 201.
Limited data availability forced us to drop 11 firms from the sample, which left us with a final sample
size of 190. We considered public companies both to ensure the availability of data and because data
collection from initial public offering documents is an acknowledged method for studying entrepreneurial
firms (e.g., Dowling and McGee 1994). Concerns about survival bias (i.e., novelty-centered business
15
model design could be positively correlated with firm performance because novel business models that
did not achieve a particular level of success did not make it to the IPO stage) are mitigated by the fact that
during the sampling period, the threshold for becoming a public company was relatively low, which
resulted in listing very young and immature companies. As a result, many of the firms in our sample still
faced highly uncertain prospects at the time they went public (Lieberman 2005). Indeed, when we
investigated the fate of these firms in June 2004, we found that 107 of our 190 sample firms (56%) had
been delisted: 20 had gone bankrupt, 68 had been acquired, 8 had been merged, and 11 had been taken
private. 2
Data Collection
For each business model design theme, we built composite scales and identified and measured
relevant items in a survey instrument (see Appendix A). The surveying process proceeded in five stages:
(1) development of the survey instrument, (2) development of measurement scales, (3) pre-testing of the
survey, (4) development of an on-line web interface and of a central database, and (5) data collection.
Following the increasing use of panelists in management research (e.g., Iansiti and Clark 1994,
Lee, Smith and Grimm 2003, MacCormack, Verganti and Iansiti 2001), we hired 11 part- or full-time
research assistants (primarily MBA students), and trained them as raters to fill in the survey instrument
2
There are many studies that examine a range of issues which relate to the conduct and performance of e-
commerce firms that became publicly listed corporations during the late 1990s. For example, using event
study methodology, Rajgopal, Venkatachalam and Kotha (2002) investigate the impact of a broad range
of managerial actions on the stock returns of a set of 57 firms engaged in B-to-B e-commerce. They show
that the volatility of stock returns is indeed affected by announcements of managerial actions and thereby
provide insights on important determinants of stock prices for Internet firms. Using a sample of 46 e-
commerce firms during the period 1999-2000, Kotha, Rajgopal and Venkatachalam (2004) investigate the
linkage between customers’ buying experience, and the firm’s competitive advantage as measured by
Tobin’s q. Customers’ confidence in the firm, and relationship services are shown to be positively
associated with Tobin’s q. Kotha, Rindova and Rothaermel (2001) examine a range of firm specific
factors that are associated with a U.S.-based Internet firm’s effort to establish a web site in another
country. Using a sample of 86 publicly traded firms, they establish that the pursuit of internationalization
of these firms is positively related to their reputation and web site traffic as well as to the number of new
product and feature announcements and the number of partnership agreements they announced. Put
together these and related studies provide important insights into the type of firm which we investigate in
this paper. We note that to correct for potential survival bias using Heckman’s econometric technique, we
would need data on the business models of privately held firms in order to estimate in the first stage of
16
for assigned sample companies. We carefully selected our raters from a larger pool of applicants by
interviewing them and asking them to submit an abbreviated test survey on a randomly chosen, sample
company to display their understanding of Internet-based business models. After choosing the most
qualified candidates, we trained them in data collection and data analysis. In addition, raters were
provided with written guidelines on how to properly address survey items. Moreover, each rater was
assigned to one of two project managers, who reviewed completed surveys for internal consistency and
completeness, but not for the accuracy of each individual measurement. On average, it took a rater about
two and a half days to collect data on a given business model, to analyze the model, and to complete the
survey. Data sources included IPO prospectuses, annual reports, investment analysts’ reports, and web
sites. The data were collected from May 2000 to June 2001. During that time period, we were able to take
one measurement of the design themes for each of the 190 business models in our sample. In other words,
different raters (each of whom was assigned to a different project manager), and by conducting a pair-
wise comparison of responses, yielding a Cronbach alpha of 0.81, and a Pearson correlation coefficient of
0.72. Raters were in broad agreement with each other for 82% of the individual items. We repeated the
test periodically for different raters and different business models and found that all indicators of
Independent Variables
We selected two independent variables of business model design: design efficiency and design
novelty. We used 13 items as measures of design efficiency, and 13 items as measures of design novelty.
Given the difficulty of obtaining objective measures of business model design, we deemed the use of
perceptual measures obtained from our raters appropriate (Dess and Robinson 1984). The strength of
each of these items in a given business model was measured using Likert-type scales (see Appendix A for
Heckman’s procedure a Probit model of the probability of being a public company. Data limitations,
however, prevented us from using Heckman’s technique.
17
details) and coded into a standardized score. After coding, we aggregated the item scores for each design
theme into an overall score for the composite scale using equal weights (see Mendelson 2000). This
process yielded distinct quantitative measures of the extent to which each business model in the sample
leveraged efficiency and novelty as design themes. (See Table 2 for summary statistics)
We validated the internal consistency and reliability of our measures using standardized
Cronbach alpha coefficients, which were 0.69 for the design efficiency measure and 0.72 for the design
novelty measure. Hence, our measures sufficiently satisfy Nunnally’s (1978) guidelines, which suggest
0.7 as a benchmark for internal consistency. In order to demonstrate the convergent and discriminant
validity of our measures, we ran a Confirmatory Factor Analysis (CFA). We also employed a Partial
Least Squares (PLS) approach to further strengthen our claim about discriminant validity. The methods
and the results are detailed in Appendix B. Both empirical tests provide support for construct validity of
our measures.
Dependent Variables
A firm’s stock-market value reflects the market’s expectations of future cash flows to
shareholders, and hence can be viewed as a measure of perceived venture performance. This differs from
realized performance, which is typically embodied in historical measures of firm profitability (e.g., ROI,
ROA). Given the level of uncertainty often associated with the true prospects of entrepreneurial firms,
perceived performance operationalized as stock market value is a measure that is particularly suitable for
an entrepreneurship setting (Stuart, Hoang and Hybels 1999). Measures of realized performance such as
ROI, ROA, or Tobin’s q are less appropriate for young, high-growth entrepreneurial firms that often have
negative earnings, few tangible assets, and low (even negative) book values. For instance, 134 firms in
our sample (i.e., 86% of the sample firms for which we had the relevant accounting data) had negative
earnings in Q4 1999. Five firms (i.e., 3% of the sample firms for which we had the relevant data) even
had a negative book value in the same period. These numbers did not change substantially in Q4 2000.
We note the limitations of using stock-market valuation as a dependent variable. The nature of
our sample and the period in which we collected the data could give rise to concerns about bias due to an
18
irrational bubble in the stock market. However, while the rationality of the markets during the 1999-2000
period remains an open question (e.g., Pastor and Veronesi 2004 offer a rational explanation for investors’
behavior and provide empirical evidence against the bubble hypothesis), our paper is not predicated on
the efficiency of capital markets; it rather centers on the differential performance implications of
alternative business model designs; our estimation method exploits their differential valuation by capital
markets. Even if the companies in our sample were systemmatically overvalued, we believe that one
cannot expect the results of our regression analysis to be distorted (i.e., pointing in the wrong direction).
Arguing in favor of our methodology, in addition, is the fact that our dependent variable captures the
sensitivity to market participants’ perceptions of the business cycle, and thus to the level of perceived
resource munificence in the environment; it reflects the factors that market participants value (akin to
Shleifer and Vishny’s (1991) analysis of stock market valuations of conglomerates in the 1960s and
1980s). This was actually beneficial for our analysis as it allowed us to test our contingency hypotheses
about the moderating effect of resource munificence on the relationship between business model design
Since most firms in our sample have relatively low levels of debt, the market value of a firm’s
equity is a good approximation of the market value of the whole firm. We measured the market value of
equity at a given date as the number of shares outstanding multiplied by the firm’s stock price, taken from
the combined CRSP and Datastream databases. We then calculated the logarithm of the market value of
the equity in order to comply with the normality assumption of Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) regression.
Following this transformation, we found that the null hypothesis of normality could not be rejected at the
5% level of significance using a Shapiro-Wilk test. To test our hypotheses, we used measurements of the
dependent variable at various points in time (annual average, average during the fourth quarter (Q4), and
the last day of trading of Q4) and in various time periods (1999, 2000) characterized by different levels of
Most empirical research has hitherto employed industry-type measures of munificence, such as
mean annual industry sales growth (Tushman and Anderson 1986), employment growth in the industry
19
(Dess and Beard 1984), and other indicators of growth at the industry level (McArthur and Nystrom
1991). Because the business model construct spans industry boundaries and many of the sample firms
span multiple industries, we could not define an industry-level variable that captured resource
munificence adequately. We therefore measured the dependent variables in time periods that were
sufficiently distinct in terms of environmental resource munificence yet close to the point in time when
We note that despite the short window, the change in the resource availability for entrepreneurial
firms triggered by the worldwide crash of high-tech stocks in March 2000 was severe. Park and Mezias
(2003), for example, demonstrate the sharp and statistically significant reversal in a number of
munificence measures. Table 1 summarizes the differences between the time periods we considered. The
year 1999 (and Q4 1999 in particular) was a time of relatively high munificence for entrepreneurial firms
in our sample, whereas the year 2000 (and Q4 2000 in particular) was a time of relatively low
dynamism (Dess and Beard 1984), may have changed between the years, perhaps to a lesser extent.3
The use of multiple measures of the dependent variable provided a robustness check for our
results. In our analysis, we contrast the average market value of firms in Q4 1999 with that in Q4 2000,
the market value of firms at the close of Q4 1999 with that at the close of Q4 2000, and the average
Control Variables
We included further factors that might influence the market value of a firm’s equity as control
variables in the analysis because their omission might confound the analysis. Our industry controls were
the level of competitive threat, and estimated market size. Our raters measured competitive threat on a
3
We did not have time-series data on our independent variables; therefore, we could not pool the data,
introduce a year dummy 2000 and test the hypothesized interaction effect directly, for example through a
random effects panel data specification.
20
four-point Likert scale based on information found in annual reports, prospectuses, competitors’ SEC
documents and web sites, Forrester benchmark studies, Hoovers’ database (which lists each focal firm’s
main competitors), and investment analysts’ reports. The information on market size was obtained from
Forrester research reports and from the U.S. Department of Commerce. Consistent with market power
arguments (Porter 1980), and with the theory presented in this paper, the greater level of competition that
a business model is facing (in more competitive or smaller markets), the lower the chances that the
business model will create much total value, and the lower the performance of the focal firm will be.
Our firm-level controls included age of the firm, size, country of origin, and expenditures on
R&D, advertising, and capital. Size was measured as the logarithm of the number of employees. The
variable can be viewed as a proxy for the focal firm’s bargaining power, relative to rival firms and other
business model stakeholders. Ceteris paribus, the larger the focal firm, the greater its potential for value
creation as well as its bargaining power, and, hence, the better its performance. We controlled for country
of origin using a dummy (“1” for firms headquartered in North America, “0” for European firms).
The inclusion of these firm-level variables strengthens the claim that our analysis captures the
influence of distinct business model design characteristics on firm performance as opposed to the effects
of firm characteristics or strategy. For example, investment in R&D has been used in prior research as a
proxy for technology strategy (Dowling and McGee 1994) and also as a proxy for the degree to which a
firm pursues a product differentiation strategy (Mizik and Jacobson 2003). Moreover, advertising
expenditures have been employed as a proxy for a firm’s marketing strategy (Mizik and Jacobson 2003).
Finally, we considered alternative business model design themes, such as complementarities and
lock-in (Amit and Zott 2001), by constructing two latent control variables, using nine indicators for
complementarities (Cronbach alpha = 0.70), and 15 indicators for lock-in (Cronbach alpha = 0.74).
We analyzed the data using multivariate regression techniques. We tested the robustness and
validity of our model specification in several distinct ways. First, we tested for multicollinearity among
independent variables by calculating Variance Inflation Factors (VIF) (see Kleinbaum, Kupper, Muller
21
and Nizam 1998). Second, we performed analyses using different dependent variables. Third, we
discarded influential observations from our data set based on established criteria for identifying influential
points (e.g., leverage, studentized residual, or change in the determinant of the covariance matrix) to see
whether they distorted results. Fourth, we tested for over-fitting of the data.4 Fifth, we considered the
potential bias introduced by sampling on the dependent variable by running a truncated regression model
(Maddala 1986).5 Sixth, we tested for homoskedasticity using White’s test. Seventh, we tested for
potential endogeneity (i.e., the concern that business model design could be a choice variable that is
correlated with unobservables that are relegated to the error term) by running a 2SLS regression with
instrumental variables and by using the Hausmann test (see Appendix C). Eighth, we performed multiple
partial F-tests (Cohen and Cohen 1983) to ensure that adding the design novelty and design efficiency
variables as well as their interaction improved the fit of the model significantly compared to a baseline
None of these tests gave rise to concern. Yet, we observed multicollinearity in those regressions
where the interaction term between design novelty and design efficiency was included. We therefore
mean-centered the interaction variable, as well as the design novelty and design efficiency measures (see
Aiken and West 1991). This significantly reduced the VIF to levels that attenuated the concern about
multicollinearity. In addition, we ensured that the mean-centering approach did not entail a lack of
4
Over-fitting occurs when the fit of the model with the data is due to the idiosyncrasy of a specific data
set, not the fundamental relations among the variables. To see whether this was the case in our study, we
first took a random subsample of 150 firms, with the remaining firms constituting the holdout sample. We
then calibrated the model based on the subsample, and applied the resulting parameter estimates to the
holdout sample, calculating goodness-of-fit, pseudo F-value, and Theil U statistic.
5
To use the truncated regression model, we assume that private entrepreneurial firms have smaller market
values than public entrepreneurial firms. In this case, the sample is truncated and the estimation of the
model using Ordinary Least Squares can lead to biased parameter estimates. The truncated regression
model, however, accounts for the potential sample selection bias by maximizing the log likelihood
function of the model (see Maddala 1986). We applied the truncation regression model to our data using
the truncreg command in Stata. We estimated the parameters for Models 1-4 and for all three dependent
variables. The coefficient estimates from the truncated regression are analogous to the coefficient
estimates from the OLS regression in magnitude, direction (positive or negative), and significance for all
models and all dependent variables. In addition, the Wald test in the truncated regression and the F-
statistic in the OLS regression are both significant at the 5% level for all models and all dependent
22
invariance of regression coefficients, which may arise in equations containing interactions even under
simple linear transformations of the data (Aiken and West 1991). Overall, therefore, we conclude that our
RESULTS
Descriptive Statistics
Table 2, Panel A provides an overview of the data set we assembled. It reveals the entrepreneurial
nature of our sample firms as well as the enormous change that occurred in the environment between Q4
1999 and Q4 2000. Specifically, in 1999 the median age of a sample company was just over 4 years old,
while the mean company was just under 7 years old. The few older firms in the sample are ones that went
through an extensive transformation with entrepreneurial management leading the change. The median
sales of sample companies in 1999 were just under $25 million, while the median book value of equity in
1999 was $57 million. The median sample company employed 269 people (mean 1,067). With respect to
the change in the environment between 1999 and 2000, we note that the median company was worth $349
million at the end of December 1999, but only $49 million at the end of December 2000, representing a
Table 2, Panel B depicts the Pearson Correlations among the right-hand side variables used in the
regression analysis. We note that while some correlations among the explanatory variables are significant,
they do not pose a multicollinearity problem as their Variance Inflation Factors (VIF) are low.
Hypotheses Tested
Table 3 depicts the OLS regression results. Panels A and B (“full sample”) show the results for
regressions in which the dependent variable is the logarithm of market value averaged over the fourth
quarter of 1999 (Panel A), and 2000 (Panel B). Panel C summarizes the main regression results for each
variables. Hence, there are no noticeable differences between the results of the truncated regression and
23
of the three dependent variables we considered. Panel D (“restricted sample”) depicts the results of the
same regressions reported in Panels A and B on a restricted sample of firms that were present in both
1999 and 2000. In other words, in the regressions reported in Panel D we control for entry to and exit
analysis. As depicted by Table 3 (Panels A-D), the coefficient on the design novelty variable is positive,
and in most cases it is significant both during a period of environmental munificence and during a period
of resource scarcity. The observed effect was thus relatively robust to changes in the environment. Our
results suggest that even in times of resource scarcity and less uncertainty about the viability of business
model designs, innovative business model designs were associated with higher levels of performance.
Comparing Panels A and B (full sample) with panel D (restricted sample), we note that the
coefficient on the design novelty variable is significant at the 1% level in the restricted sample for all four
models (see Panel D), while it is significant at the 10% level in the full sample for three of the four
models we ran (see Panels A & B). This might suggest a weakening of the design novelty effect due to
entry dynamics. We explored these apparent differences by running a separate set of regressions using
only those 30 firms that entered our sample in 20006. We observed that in most models the coefficients
for novelty-centered business model design were not significant for this small set of 30 firms. That is, the
novelty-centered business model design of the firms that entered our sample in 2000 did not significantly
explain the variance in the dependent variable. Furthermore, according to the t-test suggested by Cohen
and Cohen (1983, p. 111) the coefficient on design novelty in the sample of the 30 entering firms was
24
This analysis highlights the potential role of entry dynamics for the hypothesized contingent
effect of munificence on the relationship between business model design and firm performance.
Specifically, under conditions of low resource munificence, capital markets may be less receptive to new
public offerings of firms that center their value proposition on novel business models. Overall, however,
Hypothesis 2 about the changing strength of the design novelty coefficient in different environments
receives little support from our data. Following Gatignon (2003), we examined the moderating role of
environmental munificence by conducting a Chow test for the equality of the coefficients in the overall
model between the 1999 and 2000 regressions. The test provided significant results (see Table 4). This led
us to further examine whether the coefficient on design novelty caused the observed structural break,
which is suggested by Table 3 Panel C. The table shows that the regression coefficients on the design
novelty variable were highly significant in 1999, and less significant in 2000. We attempted to confirm
whether this effect was statistically significant by conducting a series of pooled regression runs (for all
models and all dependent variables) (a) on a completely unrestricted model, in which we included a year
dummy (0 for 1999, 1 for 2000) which we interacted with all variables, (b) on a partially restricted model,
in which the only difference with the model in (a) was that the coefficient on novelty-centered business
model design was restricted to be the same for 1999 and 2000. Then, we proceeded to do F-tests to test
the null hypothesis of homogeneity of the coefficient on design novelty in models (a) and (b). Following
Gatignon (2003:74) the test statistic we used was [(PRSS - CUSS)/(DF_PR - DF_CU)] / [CUSS /
DF_CU], where PRSS was the sum of squared residuals from the partially restricted model, CUSS was
the sum of squared residuals from the completely unrestricted model, DF_PR was the number of degrees
of freedom of the partially restricted model, and DF_CU was the number of degrees of freedom of the
completely unrestricted model. As a result of these tests, we could not reject the null.
Hypothesis 3 (regarding efficiency-centered business model design) receives mixed support from
our data. The results in Table 3 indicate that Hypothesis 3 is supported by the Q4 2000 results in the full
sample (Panel B: Models 1-4). The results are robust across all dependent variables (see Panel C). In our
25
full sample, during a period of resource scarcity, entrepreneurial firms performed better if their business
model design, and hence value proposition to their customers, partners, and suppliers, included efficiency
enhancements that reduced their transaction costs, simplified transactions, and sped up processes.
However, we find that Hypothesis 3 is not supported by the data pertaining to Q4 1999. Table 3 Panel A,
which depicts the regression results during a period of environmental munificence (1999), shows that
while the coefficient of the mean-centered design efficiency variable is positive, it is not significant. That
is, during this period of abundant resources, efficiency-centered business model design did not serve to
We also note the lack of support that this hypothesis receives from the regressions done on the
restricted sample (see Table 3 Panel D). The coefficient on design efficiency is insignificant in the
restricted sample for each of the models we ran, yet, as noted above, it is significant in the full sample for
Q4 2000. What accounts for the difference? Again, we probed deeper into the underlying reasons by
running a separate set of regressions using only those 30 firms that entered the sample in 2000. We
observed that these firms have significant positive coefficients for efficiency-centered business model
design in 2000, which were also significantly different from the respective coefficients in the restricted
sample in 1999 (according to the t-test suggested by Cohen and Cohen (1983, p. 111)). This may have
Regarding the hypothesized contingent effect of environmental munificence, the above analysis
highlights the role of entry dynamics. Specifically, under low resource munificence, capital markets may
be more receptive to new public offerings of firms that promise lower transaction costs. This in turn may
favor the IPOs of firms that have more efficiency-centered business model designs. Overall, however, we
find that Hypothesis 4 receives little support from our empirical analysis. While the Chow Test suggests a
structural break in the overall model parameters between 1999 and 2000 (see Table 4), and while Table 3
Panel C suggests a strengthening of the design efficiency effect from 1999 to 2000, a series of pooled
26
regression analyses with dummy variables (see also Gatignon 2003, p. 74) did not allow us to reject the
null hypothesis that the coefficient on design efficiency was identical in 1999 and 2000.7
Hypothesis 5 regarding the interaction effect among the design themes of business models
received no support from the empirical analysis: none of our regressions revealed a significant positive
interaction. Indeed, the coefficient of the variable capturing the interaction between design novelty and
design efficiency had a negative sign in all the regressions we ran, yet in most cases it was not statistically
significant (see Table 3, Panels A, B, and D). That coefficient, however, was significant at the 10% level
in Model 4 for the full sample when we used as dependent variables the logarithm of the market value of
firms at the close of Q4 2000, and the logarithm of the average market value of firms in 2000. For these
models we performed post-hoc analysis using plotting techniques suggested by Aiken and West (1991).
The plots of design efficiency on the respective dependent variable for different values of design novelty
revealed that for higher values of design novelty, the slope of the plotted regression line was smaller, but
remained positive. In other words, the plot was consistent with Hypothesis 6, and yielded the additional
insight that while diseconomies of scope in design might exist, they do not override the positive effects of
results. In other words, our data seem to suggest, yet do not convincingly prove, that there appear to be
diseconomies of scope in design. That is, attempting to emphasize both efficiency and novelty in the
design of a business model may be costly; it could adversely affect performance. Our analysis provides
The central thesis anchoring our study is the notion that organizational design should extend
beyond internal design (Nystrom and Starbuck 1981) to include a focus on the architecture of the
7
Note that these results also do not support the idea that capital markets valued novelty versus efficiency-
centered business model designs differentially before and after the stock market crash on NASDAQ in
April 2000 due to irrational assumptions. (That is, before April 2000 market participants might have
assumed that the basic laws of business had changed, and any novel business model could perform well.
But then the basic laws of business were perceived to be working again, and design novelty might have
been differentially hurt.) We would like to thank one reviewer for pointing out this insight.
27
transactions that a focal firm engineers with its partners, suppliers, and customers. Consistent with Foss
(2002), we suggest the need to pay greater attention to the structuring of firm boundaries and, in
particular, to the structuring of a firm’s exchanges with external stakeholders. Specifically, we develop a
theory of business model design that explains how value is created at the business model level of analysis
and how it is captured at the focal firm level of analysis. No prior theory explicitly centered on this issue
has existed. Our theoretical contribution is the model that links business model design to performance of
Although the design of the business model has been raised as an important issue for research on
new organizational forms and boundary-spanning organizational designs (Foss, 2002; Rindova and
Kotha, 2001), it has not been explored in detail. Perhaps this is because, until now, we lacked a
methodology for conceptualizing and measuring business model design with a high degree of granularity.
Our methodological contribution is that we provide a way to think about, and measure business model
design themes. By moving beyond generic typologies of business models (which are often only applicable
to e-commerce firms), we offer a greater level of abstraction and higher degree of granularity in the
description and measurement of business model designs. This allows us to outline the design elements of
business models that are relevant for wealth creation, and it also allows us to provide measures that can be
Our research is particularly relevant to the study of new organizational forms, innovation, and
entrepreneurship. It adds to an emerging body of research on business models (e.g., Amit and Zott 2001,
Chesbrough and Rosenbloom 2002, Hargadorn and Douglas 2001, Mendelson 2000). We operationalize
and measure the business model construct, and show empirically that it has impact on wealth creation. To
the best of our knowledge, this is the first rigorous empirical large-sample study of business model design
themes. While there are promising empirical studies in this domain (e.g., Rajgopal et al. 2003), there
exists no systematic, large-scale, empirical analysis of the performance implications of business model
28
By providing common definitions for new organizational forms, particularly boundary-spanning
designs, our study can enable comparisons among different designs. It can also help bridge the increasing
chasm between the reality of organization design and organization theory that some scholars have
asserted (e.g., Daft and Lewin 1993, Ilinitch et al. 1996). Indeed, while organization scholars have
identified and investigated intriguing, yet largely isolated cases of new organizational forms, such as the
dynamic network form (Miles and Snow 1986), the virtual corporation (Davidow and Malone 1992), or
hypertext organizations (Nonaka and Takeuchi 1995), research on these designs could be unified and
advanced through common frameworks, concepts, and theories (Daft and Lewin 1993, Foss 2002). Our
study, for example, shows that capturing configuration as variables helps us characterize and measure
business model designs, which should facilitate further research in that domain.
This paper not only articulates essential features and properties of boundary-spanning
organizational designs, but it also addresses their performance implications. Our strongest and most
robust finding relates to the novelty theme of business model design. That theme centers on innovation,
which is “the specific instrument of entrepreneurship. It is the act that endows resources with a new
capacity to create wealth” (Drucker 1985, p. 30). Such wealth-creating innovation may be achieved
through a recombination of existing resources (Schumpeter 1934) in new designs. Our study shows that
firms are not only able to innovate by recombining the resources they control, but also by harnessing
those of the partners, suppliers, and customers who participate in their business model. In this way, our
study contributes to the entrepreneurship literature. We highlight business model design as a crucial task
for entrepreneurs, and as a source of innovation. We also find that environmental munificence does not
moderate the positive relationship between business model design innovation and focal firm performance.
This counterintuitive finding is noteworthy. It attests to the remarkable temporal stability of that
relationship, thus emphasizing the business model as an important and enduring locus of innovation and
wealth creation.
By framing business model design as an entrepreneurial task and by identifying business model
innovation as a source of wealth creation for firms, our work informs research at the intersection of
29
organization theory, entrepreneurship, and strategy (Hitt, Ireland, Camp, and Sexton 2001, Langlois
2005). Business model-specific effects may explain some hitherto unexplained variance in the
performance of firms; in this sense, they complement, but do not replace, firm-specific and industry-
specific effects on firm performance (Rumelt 1991, Hawawini, Subramanian and Verdin 2003, McGahan
and Porter 2002). We corroborate the premise that in a highly interconnected world, entrepreneurs should
consider looking beyond firm and industry boundaries in order to create and capture business
opportunities. They can create wealth by introducing innovative boundary-spanning organization designs.
We acknowledge several limitations of this study. Some empirical results could be affected by
measurement problems. For example, our measurement of business model design themes may not have
captured all lines of a firm’s business that have revenue potential; hence, it might not explain all the
variation in the dependent variable due to business model design themes. Another problem could be that
bad management corrupts inherently good designs. Unfortunately, our data do not allow us to control for
the quality of management. As well, data limitations do not allow us to engage in a dynamic analysis of
business-model evolution or to measure value creation at the business-model level directly. Lastly, the
scope of the theory presented in this paper, as well as the data set used to test it do not allow us to draw
generalizeable conclusions about the role of business model designs in the broader population of firms.
Viewed through an entrepreneurial lens, however, the limitations of this study could present
interesting opportunities for future research. For example, do our results apply to more mature and
established organizations? Our study also raises questions such as what are the factors that give rise to
and shape business model designs? How do regulations, customer preferences, and competition influence
the emergence and evolution of these designs? What are the dynamics of business model design change,
and how stable are business model designs across time? How reliable is the impact on performance of
various business model design themes, and do efficiency-centered business models have higher reliability
of performance than novelty-centered ones (Sorensen 2002, Sorenson and Sorensen 2001)? Of specific
interest to organization scholars might be the questions of how the firm’s architecture of boundary-
spanning transactions is linked to its internal organization and how the interaction of the two affects firm
30
performance. Strategy scholars, meanwhile, could be interested in the questions of whether and how
business model design contributes to the competitive advantage of firms, and whether and how it interacts
It is our hope that the ideas presented in this paper inspire and enable further research on these
intriguing issues. We believe that the perspective of the business model, its design elements, and the
concepts developed in this paper for describing and measuring business model design themes are a step
31
REFERENCES
Aiken, L.S., S.G. West. 1991 (Paperback 1996). Multiple Regression: Testing and Interpreting
Interactions. Sage, Thousand Oaks, CA.
Aldrich, H.E. 1979. Organizations and Environments. Prentice Hall, Englewood Cliffs, NJ.
Amit, R., C. Zott. 2001. Value creation in e-business. Strategic Management J. 22 493-520.
Bhide, A. 2000. The Origin and Evolution of New Businesses. Oxford University Press, New York.
Brandenburger, A.M., B.J. Nalebuff. 1995. The right game: Use game theory to shape strategy. Harvard
Bus. Rev. 73 57-71.
Brandenburger, A.M., H. Stuart. 1996. Value-based business strategy. J. Econom. & Management
Strategy 5 5-25.
Bresnahan, T., E. Brynjolfsson, L. Hitt. 2002. Information technology, workplace organization, and the
demand for skilled labor: Firm-level evidence. Quart. J. Econom. 117 339-376.
Brynjolfsson, E., L. Hitt. 2004. Intangible assets and the economic impact of computers. W. Dutton, B.
Kahin, R. O’Callaghan, A. Wyckoff, eds. Transforming Enterprise. MIT Press, Boston, MA, pp. 27-48.
Campa, J. M., S. Keida. 2002. Explaining the diversification discount. Journal of Finance LVII 1731-
1762.
Chesbrough, H., R. Rosenbloom. 2002. The role of the business model in capturing value from
innovation: Evidence from Xerox Corporation’s technology spinoff companies. Indust. and Corporate
Change 11 529-555.
Christensen, C.M. 2001. The past and future of competitive advantage. MIT Sloan Management Rev. 42
105-109.
Clemons, E.K., M.C. Row. 1992. Information technology and industrial cooperation: The changing
economics of coordination and ownership. J. Management Inform. Systems 9 9-28.
Coff, R.L. 1999. When competitive advantage doesn't lead to performance: The resource-based view and
stakeholder bargaining power. Organ. Sci. 10 119-133.
Cohen, J., P. Cohen. 1983. Applied Multiple Regression: Correlation Analysis for the Behavioral
Sciences, 2nd ed. Lawrence Erlbaum Associates, Hillsdale, NJ.
Daft, R.L., A.Y. Lewin. 1993. Where are the theories for the “new” organizational forms? An editorial
essay. Organ. Sci. 4 i – vi.
Daft, R.L. 2004. Organization Theory and Design. 8th ed. Thomson South-Western, Mason, OH.
Davidow, W.H., M.S. Malone. 1992. The Virtual Corporation: Structuring and Revitalizing the
Corporation for the 21st Century. HarperBusiness, New York.
32
Deephouse, D.L. 1999. To be different, or to be the same? It’s a question (and theory) of strategic
balance. Strategic Management J. 20 147-166.
Dess, G.G., D.W. Beard. 1984. Dimensions of organizational task environments. Admin. Sci. Quart. 29
52-74.
Dess, G.G., R. Robinson. 1984. Measuring organizational performance in the absence of objective
measures. Strategic Management J. 5 265-73.
Dowling, M.J., J.E. McGee. 1994. Business and technology strategies and new venture performance: A
study of the telecommunications equipment industry. Management Sci. 40 1663-1677.
Drucker, P. 1985. Innovation and Entrepreneurship. Harper & Row, New York.
Filson, D. 2004. The impact of e-commerce strategies on firm value: Lessons from Amazon.com and its
early competitors. J. Bus. 77 135-154.
Fornell, C., D.F. Larcker. 1981. Evaluating structural equation models with unobservable variables and
management error. J. Marketing Res. 18 39-50.
Foss, N.J. 2002. Introduction: New organizational forms – critical perspectives. Internat. J. the Econom.
of Bus. 9 1-8.
Gatignon, H. 2003. Statistical Analysis of Management Data. Kluwer Academic Publishers, Boston, MA.
Gatignon, H., M. Tushman, W. Smith, P. Anderson. 2002. A structural approach to assessing innovation:
Construct development of innovation locus, type and characteristics. Management Sci. 48 1103-1122.
Hargadorn, A.B., Y. Douglas. 2001. When innovations meet institutions: Edison and the design of the
electric light. Admin. Sci. Quart. 46 476-501.
Hite, J M., W.S. Hesterly. 2001. The evolution of firm networks: From emergence to early growth of the
firm. Strategic Management J. 22 275-286.
Hitt, M.A., R.D. Ireland, S.M. Camp, D.L. Sexton. 2001. Strategic entrepreneurship: Entrepreneurial
strategies for wealth creation. Strategic Management J. 22 479-491.
Hulland, J. 1999. Use of partial least squares (PLS) in strategic management research: A review of four
recent studies. Strategic Management J. 20 195-204.
Iansiti, M., K.B. Clark. 1994 Integration and dynamic capability: Evidence from product development in
automobiles and mainframe computers. Indust. and Corporate Change 3 557-605.
Ichniowski, C., T.A. Kochan, D. Levine, C. Olson, G. Strauss. 1996. What works at work: Overview and
assessment. Indust. Relations 35 299-333.
Ilinitch, A.Y., R.A. D’Aveni, A.Y. Lewin. 1996. New organizational forms and strategies for managing in
hypercompetitive environments. Organ. Sci. 7 211-220.
33
Ireland, R.D., M.A. Hitt, M. Camp, D.L. Sexton. 2001. Integrating entrepreneurship and strategic
management actions to create firm wealth. Acad. of Management Executive 15 49-63.
Kaplan, S. N., B.A. Sensoy, P. Stromberg. 2005. What are firms? Evolution from birth to public
companies. Working Paper, University of Chicago, Chicago, IL.
Kleinbaum, D.G., L.L. Kupper, K.E. Muller, A. Nizam. 1998. Applied Regression Analysis and Other
Multivariable Methods, 3rd ed. Duxberry Press, Pacific Grove, CA.
Kotha, S., S. Rajgopal, M.Venkatchalam. 2004. The role of online buying experience as a competitive
advantage: Evidence from third party ratings from e-commerce firms. J. Bus. 77 109-133.
Kotha, S., V. Rindova, F. Rothaermel. 2001. Assets and actions: Firm-specific factors in the
internationalization of US Internet firms. J. Internat. Bus. Stud. 32 769-791.
Langlois, R.N. 1992. Transaction costs in real time. Industrial And Corp. Change 1 99-127.
Langlois, R.N. 2005. The entrepreneurial theory of the firm and the theory of the entrepreneurial firm.
Working paper, University of Connecticut (Department of Economics, 2005-27).
Langlois, R.N., P.R. Robertson. 1995. Firms, Markets, and Economic Change: A Dynamic Theory of
Business Institutions. Routledge, London.
Lieberman, M. 2005. Did first-mover advantage survive the dot-com crash? Working paper, UCLA, Los
Angeles, CA.
Lee, H., K.G. Smith, C.G. Grimm. 2003. The effect of new product radicality and scope on the extent and
speed of innovation diffusion. J. Management 29 753-768.
Lewin, A.Y., H. Volbverda. 1999. Prolegomena on coevolution: A framework for research on strategy
and new organizational forms. Organ. Sci. 10 519-534.
Lounsbury, M., M. Glynn. 2001. Cultural entrepreneurship: Stories, legitimacy, and the acquisition of
resources. Strategic Management J. 22 545-564.
MacCormack, A., R. Verganti, M. Iansiti. 2001. Developing products on “Internet time”: The anatomy of
a flexible development process. Management Sci. 47 133-150.
Marquis, C. 2003. The pressure of the past: Network imprinting in intercorporate communities. Admin.
Sci. Quart. 48 655-689.
McArthur, A.W., P.C. Nystrom. 1991. Environmental dynamism, complexity and munificence as
moderators of strategy-performance relationships. J. Bus. Res. 23 349-361.
McGahan, A., M. Porter. 2002. What do we know about variance in accounting profitability?
Management Sci. 48 834-851.
McGrath, R., I. MacMillan. 2000. The Entrepreneurial Mindset. Harvard Business School Press, Boston,
MA.
34
Mendelson, H. 2000. Organizational architecture and success in the information technology industry.
Management Sci. 46 513-529.
Meyer, A.D., A.S. Tsui, C.R. Hinings. 1993. Guest co-editors’ introduction: Configurational approaches
to organizational analysis. Acad. of Management J. 36 1175-1195.
Miles, R.E., C.C. Snow. 1978. Organization Structure, Strategy, and Process. McGraw-Hill, New York.
Miles, R.E., C.C. Snow. 1986. Organizations: New concepts for new forms. California Management Rev.
28 62-73.
Milgrom, P.R., J. Roberts. 1992. Econom., organ. and management. Prentice-Hall, Upper Saddle River,
NJ.
Mizik, N., R. Jacobson. 2003. Trading off between value creation and value appropriation: The financial
implications of shifts in strategic emphasis. J. Marketing 67 63-76.
Nonaka, I., H. Takeuchi. 1995. The Knowledge-Creating Company. Oxford University Press, New York.
Nystrom, P.C., W. H. Starbuck. 1981. Handbook of Organizational Design. Oxford University Press,
London.
Park, N.K., J. Mezias. 2005. Before and after the technology sector crash: Stock market response to
alliances of e-commerce firms. Strategic Management J. Forthcoming.
Pastor, L., P. Veronesi. 2004. Was there a NASDAQ bubble in the late 1990s? Working paper, University
of Chicago, Chicago, IL.
Pfeffer, J., G.R.Salancik. 1978. The External Control of Organizations. Harper & Row, New York.
Poppo, L., T. Zenger. 1998. Testing alternative theories of the firm: Transaction cost, knowledge-based,
and measurement explanations for make-or-buy decisions in information services. Strategic Management
J. 19 853-877.
Porter, M.E. 1980. Competitive strategy: Techniques for analyzing industries and competitors. Free
Press/Macmillan, New York.
Rajgopal, S., M. Venkatachalam, S. Kohta. 2002. Managerial actions, stock returns, and earnings : The
case of business-to-business Internet firms. J. Accounting Res. 40 529-556.
Rajgopal, S., M. Venkatachalam, S. Kotha. 2003. The value relevance of network advantages: The case of
e-commerce firms. J. Accounting Res. 41 135-162.
Randolph, W.A., G.G. Dess. 1984. The congruence perspective of organization design: A conceptual
model and multivariate research approach. Acad. of Management Rev. 9 114-128.
Reinartz, W., M. Krafft, W. Hoyer. 2004. The CRM process: Its measurement and performance. J.
Marketing Res. 41 293-305.
35
Rindova, V., S. Kotha. 2001. Continuous “morphing”: Competing through dynamic capabilities, form,
and function. Acad. of Management J. 44 1263-1280.
Romanelli, E. 1991. The evolution of new organizational forms. Annual Rev. of Sociology 17 79-103.
Romme, A.G.L. 2003. Making a difference: Organization as design. Organ. Sci. 14 558-573.
Rumelt, R. 1987. Theory, strategy, and entrepreneurship. D.J. Teece, ed. The Competitive Challenge.
Ballinger Publishing Company, Cambridge, MA, 137-158.
Rumelt, R. 1991. How much does industry matter? Strategic Management J. 12 167-185.
Schumpeter, J. A. 1934 (Reprint 1996). The Theory of Economic Development: An Inquiry into Profits,
Capital, Credit, Interest, and the Business Cycle. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA.
Shleifer, A., R.W. Vishny. 1991. Takeovers in the 60s and the 80s: Evidence and implications. Strategic
Management J. 12 51-61.
Silverman, B. 2001. Organizational economics. J.A.C. Baum, ed. Blackwell Companion to Organizations,
Blackwell Publishers, London, 465-493.
Sorensen, J. 2002. The strength of corporate culture and the reliability of firm performance. Admin. Sci.
Quart. 47 70-91.
Sorenson, O., J. Sorensen. 2001. Finding the right mix: Franchising, organizational learning, and chain
performance. Strategic Management J. 22 713-724.
Stinchcombe, A. 1965. Social structure and organizations. J.G. March, ed. Handbook of Organizations.
Rand McNally, Chicago, IL, 142-193.
Stuart, T.E., H. Hoang, R.C. Hybels. 1999. Interorganizational endorsements and the performance of
entrepreneurial ventures. Admin. Sci. Quart. 44 315-349.
Van de Ven, A., D. Hudson, M. Schroeder. 1984. Designing new business startups: Entrepreneurial,
organizational, and ecological considerations. J. Management 10 87-107.
Von Hippel, E., R. Katz. 2002. Shifting innovation to users via toolkits. Management Sci. 48 821-833.
Williamson, O.E. 1975. Markets and Hierarchies -- Analysis and Antitrust Implications. The Free Press,
New York.
Williamson, O.E. 1983. Organizational innovation: The transaction cost approach. J. Ronen, ed.
Entrepreneurship. Lexington Books, Lexington, MA. 101-133.
Zimmerman, M. A., G. J. Zeitz. 2002. Beyond survival: Achieving new venture growth by building
legitimacy. Acad. of Management Rev. 27 414-431.
36
Zott, C. 2003. Dynamic capabilities and the emergence of intra-industry differential firm performance:
Insights from a simulation study. Strategic Management J. 24 97-125.
Zott, C., R. Amit. 2006. Exploring the fit between business strategy and business model: Implications for
firm performance. Working paper, INSEAD, Fontainebleau, France.
Zott, C., Q. Huy. 2006. How entrepreneurs use symbolic management to acquire resources. Working
paper, INSEAD, Fontainebleau, France.
37
APPENDIX A: Survey Items
APPENDIX B
Convergent and Discriminant Validity
We first ran a confirmatory factor analysis (CFA) on a measurement model with two factors, where the
design efficiency traits loaded onto the design efficiency factor, and the design novelty traits loaded onto
the design novelty factor. In this model, the correlation between the design efficiency and the design
novelty index was estimated. We then ran a CFA on a measurement model with only one factor, where
the correlation between the design efficiency and the design novelty variable was constrained to be one. If
the model where the correlation is not equal to one improves the fit significantly compared to the
constrained model, the two constructs (i.e., design novelty and design efficiency) are distinct from each
other, although they can be significantly correlated (Gatignon et al 2002, Gatignon 2003).
38
We also used CFA to establish the convergent validity of the constructs, by comparing a measurement
model where the correlation between the two constructs was estimated with a model where the correlation
was constrained to be equal to zero. “A significant improvement in fit indicates that the two constructs are
indeed related, which confirms convergent validity” (Gatignon et al. 2002, p. 1109).
We used LISREL to implement the CFA, following the routines described in Gatignon (2003, p. 178-
220). The results from the CFA are displayed in the table below:
The results from the CFA demonstrate that efficiency-centered design and novelty-centered design are
two distinct dimensions of business models, although they are positively correlated (estimated correlation
= 0.14). This is confirmed by a significantly (at the 0.01 level) improved confirmatory factor analytic
model when the correlation is estimated, compared to a measurement model where the correlation is
constrained to 1 (chi-squared = 761.9 – 733.4 = 28.5, degrees of freedom = 320 – 319 = 1). Furthermore,
the results from the CFA demonstrate that efficiency-centered design and novelty-centered design are
independent dimensions of business models. The confirmatory factor analytic model when the correlation
is estimated, compared to a measurement model where the correlation is constrained to 0 is not
significantly improved (chi-squared = 735.1 – 733.4 = 1.7, degrees of freedom = 320 – 319 = 1). This is
akin to Gatignon et. al’s (2002) result that some dimensions of innovation (e.g., competence-
enhancing/destroying) are independent of others (e.g., radicalness), yet all measure important, distinct
aspects of innovation.
In addition to CFA, the literature suggests partial least squares (PLS) as another method for assessing
discriminant validity. Using PLS, one can determine whether a construct shares more variance with its
measures than it shares with other constructs in the model (Hulland 1999, Reinartz, et al. 2004). This is
achieved by (1) calculating the square roots of the Average Variance Extracted (AVE) values, which
measure the average variance shared between a construct and its measures, and by (2) calculating the
correlations between different constructs. A matrix can then be constructed where the square root of AVE
is in the diagonal, and the correlations between the constructs are in the off-diagonal. For adequate
discriminant validity, the diagonal elements should be greater than the off-diagonal elements in the
corresponding rows and columns (Fornell and Larcker 1981). In our case, we obtained the following
matrix as a result of the PLS analysis. The results further strengthen the discriminant validity of our
constructs.
Note: (1) The square root of AVE is displayed in the diagonal, and the correlations between the constructs
are displayed in the off-diagonal. (2) According to Fornell and Larcker (1981), if the factor variance is set
to 1, then the average variance extracted is defined as: AVE = Σλi2 / {Σλi2 + Σ(1-λi2)}.
39
APPENDIX C
Testing for Endogeneity
Endogeneity refers to the fact that an independent variable included in the model is potentially a choice
variable, correlated with unobservables relegated to the error term. To the extent that endogeneity is
indeed present in OLS regressions, the standard procedure for dealing with it is to use the Instrumental
Variables (IV) technique (a.k.a. two-stage least squares) in cases where the variables that may potentially
be endogenous –i.e., in our case DESIGN_NOVELTY & DESIGN_EFFICIENCY– are continuous (see
Greene 2003, pp.398ff). The standard test for endogeneity is the Hausmann Test (see Greene 2003,
pp.80ff). The main idea of this test is to see if the estimates of coefficients from OLS are different from
the ones obtained by estimating the model using the IV technique. To the extent that we cannot reject the
test’s null hypothesis of no endogeneity, then there should be less concern about the OLS estimates. If,
however, the Haussman test indicates that endogeneity is present, then, for each time period, 1999 and
2000, we must rely on the appropriate estimation method (e.g., 2SLS) to obtain the coefficients. In what
follows, we explain the steps that we took in order to run the Hausmann Test.
First, we needed to identify and collect additional data on suitable instrumental variables that satisfied the
statistical requirements and were theoretically justifiable. Concretely, we needed variables that could have
affected business model design, but not the focal firms’ performance in 1999 or 2000. Following the idea
that the environment can have an important imprinting effect on organizations (Stinchcombe 1965), our
choice was to use munificence variables.8 In our study we argue that all firms were subject to the same
degree of (high) munificence in 1999 and then subject to the same degree of (low) munificence in 2000.
In those two years, then, the degree of munificence could not have affected entrepreneurs’ choice of
business model designs systematically because all firms faced the same environment. (Yet, munificence
interacting with business model design may have well affected investors’ perceptions of firm
performance, as we argue). Therefore, our challenge was to find suitable munificence measures that
could have systematically affected entrepreneurs’ choice of business model designs, but not investors’
perceptions of performance in 1999 and 2000.
A good instrumental variable possesses two characteristics: (1) It influences the independent variable,
and (2) is uncorrelated with the residuals of the regression).9 We therefore chose to use time-lagged
munificence measures. As there is no prior theory on the determinants of business model designs, we
decided to experiment with different time lags:
These choices were based on the following conceptual arguments. The environmental conditions that
possibly affected the entrepreneur’s early choice of business model design are likely to have an important
organizational imprinting effect (see Marquis (2003) for a recent study on how social technologies
available at founding continued to influence network structures). If that choice was affected by
environmental munificence then one should expect a causal relationship between munificence and
8
We would like to thank an anonymous referee for this suggestion.
9
This requirement for zero or low correlation is difficult to prove empirically. That is part of the reason for why
there is no commonly agreed upon scientific method for establishing a good instrument.
40
business model design. That is why we decided to use the level of munificence in the firm’s founding
year as our first time-lagged munificence variable (see a).
Some firms in our study, however, are older than the average 7 years for our sample and it might be a
stretch to assume that their business models have not changed since they were founded. Thus, at some
stage the business model design may have changed, and once again the environmental munificence
prevailing at that point in time may have influenced the new design. A recent analysis by Kaplan, Sensoy,
and Stromberg (2005) suggests that entrepreneurial firms are surprisingly stable over time. For example,
firm business lines remain remarkably stable from business plan through public company, which is a
period that, on average, lasted 6 years in the Kaplan et al. (2005) study. Hence, our second choice of a
time lag was 6 years prior to the IPO, or the company’s birth year, whichever date was greater (i.e., more
recent) (see b).
Moreover, all our sample companies had an IPO between 1996 and 2000, and we wanted to acknowledge
the possibility that business model designs were less stable than implied by our other two choices.
Therefore, our third choice of a time lag was 3 years prior to the IPO, or the company’s birth year,
whichever date was greater (see c).
The underlying idea behind all these time lags is that the entrepreneur’s choice of business model may
have indeed been affected by environmental munificence at some point in time prior to the time period of
our study. Past munificence measures are less likely to be correlated with residuals from regressions
involving as dependent variable firm performance in 1999 or 2000, because investors’ perceptions in
1999 or 2000 were probably affected by the prevailing, not past munificence. Hence, these variables
conceptually fulfilled the requirements of useful instruments.
Because there were two different variables that we needed to test for endogeneity,
DESIGN_EFFICIENCY and DESIGN_NOVELTY, we needed to find two variables--IV1 and IV2--that
could have affected business model design. Following Park and Mezias (2005) we have collected
additional data from CRSP on the following 22 munificence measures:
Annual level, relative and absolute annual change in the NASDAQ Index, with
pre 1971 data representing the over-the-counter market: 3 variables
Annual level, relative and absolute annual change in the number of IPOs on
NASDAQ, AMEX and NYSE: 9 variables
Annual level, relative and absolute annual change in the number of firms listed
on NASDAQ, Amex, and NYSE that filed for bankruptcy: 9 variables
Annual US GDP growth: 1 variable
While we have tried to collect data on all these variables for the period 1954 to 2000, we have some
missing observations for some of the variables in the early time period in this new dataset.
Second, we needed to choose instrumental variables from the above list and the control variables in order
to perform the first stage of the 2SLS regression. There is no commonly agreed upon and empirically
rigorous method for choosing instrumental variables; their choice is often given by theoretical
considerations, as well as empirical usefulness (e.g., the IV should meaningfully explain the independent
variables); for a recent example of an application of the IV method to control for endogeneity see Campa
and Keida (2002).
Given that the choice of suitable instruments for the 2SLS regression is more art than science, we decided
to adopt several ways of making this choice.
41
(a) We selected some munificence variables opportunistically, based on the availability of data
(i.e., we preferred variables without any missing observations).
(b) We performed OLS regressions (of the munificence variables on DESIGN_EFFICIENCY
and DESIGN_NOVELTY) with stepwise selection of independent variables (using the REG
procedure from SAS) and used the retained variables as instruments.
(c) We used all variables retained from (b) as well as all control variables as instruments.
We then estimated the first stage in the 2SLS using the IV form the above lists as follows:
In many cases, the coefficients, m1 and m2, were statistically significant, so the instruments indeed
explained part of the variation in the business model design themes. The R-squared from the first stage
regressions was highest under option (c), for which we found it to be between 0.24 and 0.38.
In the second stage of the 2SLS procedure, we took the estimated variables from the first stage and
plugged them into the main OLS equation, replacing the DESIGN_EFFICIENCY and
DESIGN_NOVELTY variables.10 We did this for each of our six dependent variables -- the average
market value of firms in Q4 1999 and in Q4 2000, the market value of firms at the close of Q4 1999 and
at the close of Q4 2000, and the average market value of firms in 1999 and in 2000. Together with the
permutations explained in steps 1 and 2 above, we thus ran 3 (different time lags) * 3 (different sets of
IVs) * 6 (different dependent variables) = 54 2SLS regressions, and for each regression we also ran the
Hausmann test.11 Since this test was never statistically significant (even at the 10% level), our analyses do
not appear to suffer from endogeneity bias.
10
Technically speaking, we used the MODEL procedure in SAS with the HAUSMAN option to run the OLS and
2SLS regressions with our chosen instruments and to carry out the Hausmann test.
11
It was actually not necessary to run all these different permutations, because when one uses different instruments
(with different R-squares) and one does not find endogeneity with the instrument that has the highest R-squared,
then, by definition, one should not find endogeneity when using an instrument that has a lower R-squared. We ran
all these regressions anyway, just in order to be on the safe side.
42
TABLE 1: Indicators of resource munificence 1999 and 2000
1999 2000
Indicators • Median quarterly sales growth of sample • Median sales growth of sample
of companies: 30% (Q2’99), 29% (Q3’99), companies: 18% (Q1 ’00), 15% (Q2’00),
Resource 33% (Q4 ’99) 8% (Q3’00), 6% (Q4 ’00)
Munifi- • Number of Internet-related IPOs in US: • Number of Internet-related IPOs in US:
cence 193 (Q4: 62) 122 (Q4: 0) [2]
• Public market Internet IPO financings in % • Public market Internet IPO financings in
of total IPO financings: 67% % of total IPO financings: 36% [2]
• VC funding for B2C e-commerce • VC funding for e-commerce companies
companies: $4.5 billion (+1000% from dropped from $843 million (Q1) to $69
1998) [1] million (Q4) [3]
No.
Std.
Variable Name (Acronym) Mean Median Min Max Observa-
Deviation
tions
Market Value at Close of Q4 1999 USD
$1,506 $349 $3,184 $2 $25,942 159
million (MVQtr4Close_99)
Market Value at Close of Q4 2000 USD
$387 $49 $1,101 $0.7 $8,885 173
million (MVQtr4Close_00)
Design Efficiency 0.702 0.712 0.112 0.404 0.92 190
Design Novelty 0.366 0.359 0.133 0.077 0.795 190
Complementarity 0.617 0.639 0.174 0.000 0.972 190
Lock-In 0.454 0.463 0.140 0.167 0.763 190
Age of firm 7.0 4.3 7.8 0.4 45.8 190
Ln number of Employees 5.723 5.593 1.336 2.833 10.342 190
Country (1=US, 0=European Country) 0.88 1.00 0.32 0.00 1.00 190
R&D Expense USD 00 (million) $2.7 $0.5 $6.4 $0.0 $67.3 190
Advertising expense USD 00 (million) $4.7 $1.0 $9.3 $0.0 $52.8 190
Capital Expense USD 00 (million) $42.7 $3.7 $415.9 $0.0 $5,733.1 190
Book Value of Equity 99 (million) $163.7 $57.3 $416.6 $-68.6 $4,601.2 188
Book Value of Equity 00 (million) $272.8 $71.2 $685.2 $-967.3 $5,752.2 160
Sales Net USD 99 (million) $263.3 $24.9 $1,575.4 $0.0 $20,111.8 177
Sales Net USD 00 (million) $331.7 $52.9 $1,643.0 $0.0 $20,609.0 177
Number of Employees 1,067 269 3,557 17 31,000 190
Market Size USD 00 (million) $20,477 $5,400 $65,640 $120 $744,000 190
43
TABLE 2, Panel B: Pearson Correlation
Centered Design
Log (employees)
Capital Ex. 00
(market size)
Competition
Adv. EX 00
R&D EX 00
Mentarities
Interaction
Variable Name
Efficiency
Centered
Comple-
Country
(Acronym)
Lock-In
Novelty
Log
Age
Independent
variables
Centered design
1.000
efficiency
Centered design
0.175* 1.000
novelty
Interaction between
centered design
efficiency & -0.057 -0.041 1.000
centered design
novelty
Control variables
Complementarity 0.349** 0.349** -0.001 1.000
Lock-In 0.316** 0.413** -0.173* 0.373** 1.000
Competition -0.006 -0.322** -0.147* -0.128* -0.121g 1.000
ln Market Size -0.039 0.016 0.022 0.112 -0.062 0.097 1.000
Age of firm -0.112 -0.131g 0.118 0.026* -0.152* 0.048 0.214** 1.000
Ln number of -
0.004 -0.038 0.027 0.040 -0.028 0.338** 0.452** 1.000
Employees 0.076
Country -0.074 0.168* 0.123g 0.107 0.159* 0.097 0.462** 0.107 0.110 1.000
-
R&D Expense 00 0.066 0.220** 0.049 0.088 0.140g 0.022 -0.027 0.281** 0.123g 1.000
0.011
Advertising
-0.088 0.020 0.037 0.042 0.002 0.027 0.199** 0.223** 0.493** 0.178* 0.434** 1.000
expense 00
Capital Expense 00 0.004 0.018 -0.004 0.147* 0.075 0.055 0.066 0.355** 0.271** 0.036 0.001* 0.414** 1.000
** p <0.01, * 0.01<=p<0.05, g 0.05<=p<0.1
44
TABLE 3, Panel B : Mean centered OLS regression results (full sample)
Dependent variable Ln (Market Value Quarter 4 Avg 00)
RHS Variables Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4
Estimate (std.
Estimate (std. error) Estimate (std. error) Estimate (std. error)
error)
Constant 18.42*** 16.36*** 18.44*** 16.64***
Design Efficiency 2.21† (1.18) 2.44* (1.01) 2.16† (1.10) 2.51* (1.01)
Design Novelty 1.72† (1.01) 1.54† (0.93) 1.70† (1.01) 1.47 (0.93)
Interaction Between Design Efficiency and
Design Novelty -8.24 (8.45) -10.25 (6.83)
Complementarities -0.71 -0.67
Lock-In -0.30 -0.57
Competition 0.88† -1.04*
Log (market size) 0.04 0.04
Age -0.01 -0.01
Log (employees) 0.66*** 0.65***
Country -1.12** -1.01**
R&D expenditures 2000 0.05** 0.05**
Advertising exp. 2000 0.02 0.02
Capital exp. 2000 0.00 0.00
R-squared 0.04 0.47 0.05 0.48
Adjusted R-squared 0.03 0.44 0.03 0.44
F 3.84* 12.59*** 2.88* 11.88***
N 180 180 180 180
***p<0.001, ** p <0.01, * 0.01<=p<0.05, g 0.05<=p<0.1
TABLE 3, Panel C: Summary of main regression results for different dependent variables
INDEPENDENT VARIABLE DEPENDENT VARIABLE MODEL 1 MODEL 2 MODEL 3 MODEL 4
1999 Design Efficiency Market Value Quarter 4 Close 1.70 1.35 1.70 1.44
Market Value Quarter 4 Average 1.23 0.93 1.23 1.01
Market Value Annual Average 1.25 0.89 1.25 0.96
2000 Design Efficiency Market Value Quarter 4 Close 2.76* 3.16** 2.70* 3.26**
Market Value Quarter 4 Average 2.19† 2.44* 2.14† 2.51*
Market Value Annual Average 1.96* 1.82* 1.88† 1.87*
1999 Design Novelty Market Value Quarter 4 Close 3.44*** 2.61** 3.34*** 2.49**
Market Value Quarter 4 Average 3.25*** 2.29** 3.14*** 2.17*
Market Value Annual Average 2.70** 2.00* 2.62** 1.89*
2000 Design Novelty Market Value Quarter 4 Close 1.28 1.77† 1.23 1.66
Market Value Quarter 4 Average 1.69 †
1.54† 1.67† 1.47
Market Value Annual Average 2.33** 1.93* 2.30** 1.85*
***p<0.001, ** p <0.01, * 0.01<=p<0.05, g 0.05<=p<0.1
45
TABLE 3, Panel D: Mean centered OLS regression results (restricted sample)
Dependent variable Ln (Market Value Quarter 4 Avg 99)
RHS Variables Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4
Estimate (std. err.) Estimate (std. err.) Estimate (std. err.) Estimate (std. err.)
Constant 19.79*** 17.25*** 19.81*** 17.50***
Design Efficiency 0.89 (1.12) 0.57 (0.93) 0.91 (1.12) 0.68 (0.93)
Design Novelty 3.56*** (0.97) 2.51** (0.87) 3.46*** (0.97) 2.40** (0.87)
Design Efficiency * Design Novelty -6.34 (7.78) -7.59 (6.18)
Complementarities -0.35 -0.34
Lock-In 0.37 0.13
Competition -0.03 -0.15
Log (market size) -0.18* -0.18*
Age -0.05*** -0.05**
Log (employees) 0.69*** 0.68***
Country 0.21 0.28
R&D expenditures 1999 0.08** 0.08**
Advertising exp. 1999 0.02 0.02
Capital exp. 1999 0.00 0.00
R-squared 0.11 0.54 0.11 0.55
Adjusted R-squared 0.09 0.5 0.09 0.5
F 8.25*** 12.70*** 5.71*** 11.89***
N 142 142 142 142
Dependent variable Ln (Market Value Quarter 4 Avg 00)
RHS Variables Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4
Constant 18.42*** 15.95*** 18.43*** 16.16***
Design Efficiency 1.36 (1.32) 1.57 (1.09) 1.37 (1.32) 1.67 (1.09)
Design Novelty 2.97** (1.13) 2.83** (1.02) 2.93* (1.13) 2.74** (1.02)
Design Efficiency * Design Novelty -2.39 (9.13) -6.8 (7.17)
Complementarities 0.37 0.38
Lock-In -2.04† -2.25*
Competition -0.51 -0.61
Log (market size) -0.03 -0.04
Age -0.01 -0.01
Log (employees) 0.69*** 0.68***
Country -0.43 -0.36
R&D expenditures 2000 0.06** 0.06**
Advertising exp. 2000 0.02 0.02
Capital exp. 2000 0.00 0.00
R-squared 0.07 0.52 0.07 0.53
Adjusted R-squared 0.05 0.48 0.05 0.48
F 4.88** 11.74*** 3.25** 10.90***
N 142 142 142 142
***p<0.001, ** p <0.01, * 0.01<=p<0.05, g 0.05<=p<0.1
TABLE 4: Chow test for structural break between 1999 and 2000
DEPENDENT VARIABLE MODEL 1 MODEL 2 MODEL 3 MODEL 4
Market Value Quarter 4 Close 34.1** 14.92** 25.69** 14.06**
Market Value Quarter 4 Average 18.3** 9.1** 13.81** 8.6**
g
Market Value Annual Average 2.48 1.93* 1.95 1.87*
Table entries are F Statistics. ** p <0.01, * 0.01<=p<0.05, g 0.05<=p<0.1
46