David Ricardo contributed the theory of comparative advantage in 1817, which argues that countries benefit from trade even if one country is more efficient in producing all goods. Ricardo used an example of England and Portugal trading cloth and wine. Portugal had lower absolute costs for both goods but a larger comparative advantage in wine over cloth. According to Ricardo, Portugal should specialize in wine and England in cloth. Both countries would gain through trade, even though Portugal had absolute cost advantages in both goods, because each country exports the good where its comparative advantage is largest. Ricardo's theory demonstrates that international trade can benefit all nations.
Copyright:
Attribution Non-Commercial (BY-NC)
Available Formats
Download as DOCX, PDF, TXT or read online from Scribd
David Ricardo contributed the theory of comparative advantage in 1817, which argues that countries benefit from trade even if one country is more efficient in producing all goods. Ricardo used an example of England and Portugal trading cloth and wine. Portugal had lower absolute costs for both goods but a larger comparative advantage in wine over cloth. According to Ricardo, Portugal should specialize in wine and England in cloth. Both countries would gain through trade, even though Portugal had absolute cost advantages in both goods, because each country exports the good where its comparative advantage is largest. Ricardo's theory demonstrates that international trade can benefit all nations.
David Ricardo contributed the theory of comparative advantage in 1817, which argues that countries benefit from trade even if one country is more efficient in producing all goods. Ricardo used an example of England and Portugal trading cloth and wine. Portugal had lower absolute costs for both goods but a larger comparative advantage in wine over cloth. According to Ricardo, Portugal should specialize in wine and England in cloth. Both countries would gain through trade, even though Portugal had absolute cost advantages in both goods, because each country exports the good where its comparative advantage is largest. Ricardo's theory demonstrates that international trade can benefit all nations.
Copyright:
Attribution Non-Commercial (BY-NC)
Available Formats
Download as DOCX, PDF, TXT or read online from Scribd
David Ricardo contributed the theory of comparative advantage in 1817, which argues that countries benefit from trade even if one country is more efficient in producing all goods. Ricardo used an example of England and Portugal trading cloth and wine. Portugal had lower absolute costs for both goods but a larger comparative advantage in wine over cloth. According to Ricardo, Portugal should specialize in wine and England in cloth. Both countries would gain through trade, even though Portugal had absolute cost advantages in both goods, because each country exports the good where its comparative advantage is largest. Ricardo's theory demonstrates that international trade can benefit all nations.
Copyright:
Attribution Non-Commercial (BY-NC)
Available Formats
Download as DOCX, PDF, TXT or read online from Scribd
Download as docx, pdf, or txt
You are on page 1of 5
Comparative Advantage Theory of Ricardo
In 1817, David Ricardo, an English political economist, contributed theory oI comparative
advantage in his book 'Principles of Political Economy and Taxation'. This theory oI comparative advantage, also called comparative cost theory, is regarded as the classical theory oI international trade. According to the classical theory oI international trade, every country will produce their commodities Ior the production oI which it is most suited in terms oI its natural endowments climate quality oI soil, means oI transport, capital, etc. It will produce these commodities in excess oI its own requirement and will exchange the surplus with the imports oI goods Irom other countries Ior the production oI which it is not well suited or which it cannot produce at all. Thus all countries produce and export these commodities in which they have cost advantages and import those commodities in which they have cost disadvantages. Types of Cost Difference in Production Economists speak about three types oI cost diIIerence in production, they are 1. Absolute cost diIIerence, 2. Equal cost diIIerence, and 3. Comparative cost diIIerence. Absolute Cost Differences:- Adam Smith in his book 'ealth of Nation' argued that international trade is advantageous Ior all the participating countries only iI they enjoy absolute diIIerences in the cost oI production oI the commodity which they specialize. As in the case oI individuals where each specializes in the production oI that commodity in which he has an absolutely superiority in terms oI cost, so also each country specializes in production oI goods based on absolute advantage. The principle oI absolute diIIerence in cost can be explained with the help oI table given below. Let us assume that we have 2 countries, I and II specializing in the production oI X and Y.
In country I, one day's labour produces 20x or 10y. The internal exchange rate is 2 : 1. In country II, one day's labour produce 10x or 20y which gives us the domestic exchange rate oI 1 : 2. Country I has the absolute advantage in the production oI X and country II in Y . II these countries enter into trade with the international exchange oI 1 : 1, both countries stand to beneIit. Country I will have 1y Ior 1x as against 1 / 2y Ior 1x within the country. Similarly country II will have 1x Ior 1y as against 1 / 2x Ior 1y within the country. Based on this example, according to Adam Smith, it can be pointed out that international trade to be beneIicial, each country must enjoy absolute diIIerence in cost oI production. Equal Difference in Cost :- Adam Smith, in order to strengthen his argument in Iavour oI absolute diIIerence in cost pointed out that trade is not possible iI countries operate under equal diIIerence in cost instead oI absolute diIIerence.
The above table gives us the internal exchange rate 2x : 1y in both countries. Since the exchange ratio between X and Y in both countries is the same; none oI them will beneIit by entering into international trade. Based on this example, according to Adam Smith, Ior international trade to be beneIicial countries must enjoy absolute diIIerence in cost. Trade would not take place when the diIIerence in cost is equal. 3 Comparative Difference in Cost :- David Ricardo agreed that absolute diIIerence in cost gives a clear reason Ior trade to take place. He, however, went Iurther to argue that even that the country has absolute advantage in the production oI both commodities it is beneIicial Ior that country to specialise in the production oI that commodity in which it has a greater comparative advantage. The other country can be leIt to specialise in the production oI that commodity in which it has less comparative advantage. According to Ricardo the essence Ior international trade is not the absolute diIIerence in cost but comparative diIIerence in cost. Ricardo's Theory of Comparative Advantage David Ricardo stated a theory that other things being equal a country tends to specialise in and exports those commodities in the production oI which it has maximum comparative cost advantage or minimum comparative disadvantage. Similarly the country's imports will be oI goods having relatively less comparative cost advantage or greater disadvantage.
Ricardo's Assumptions:-
Ricardo explains his theory with the help oI Iollowing assumptions :- 1. There are two countries and two commodities. 2. There is a perIect competition both in commodity and Iactor market. 3. Cost oI production is expressed in terms oI labour i.e. value oI a commodity is measured in terms oI labour hours/days required to produce it. Commodities are also exchanged on the basis oI labour content oI each good. 4. Labour is the only Iactor oI production other than natural resources. 5. Labour is homogeneous i.e. identical in eIIiciency, in a particular country. 6. Labour is perIectly mobile within a country but perIectly immobile between countries. 7. There is Iree trade i.e. the movement oI goods between countries is not hindered by any restrictions. 8. Production is subject to constant returns to scale. 9. There is no technological change. 10.Trade between two countries takes place on barter system. 11.Full employment exists in both countries. 12.There is no transport cost.
Ricardo's Example :-
On the basis oI above assumptions, Ricardo explained his comparative cost diIIerence theory, by taking an example oI England and Portugal as two countries & Wine and Cloth as two commodities. As pointed out in the assumptions, the cost is measured in terms oI labour hour. The principle of comparative advantage expressed in labour hours by the Iollowing table.
Portugal requires less hours oI labour Ior both wine and cloth. One unit oI wine in Portugal is produced with the help oI 80 labour hours as above 120 labour hours required in England. In the case oI cloth too, Portugal requires less labour hours than England. From this it could be argued that there is no need Ior trade as Portugal produces both commodities at a lower cost. Ricardo however tried to prove that Portugal stands to gain by specialising in the commodity in which it has a greater comparative advantage. Comparative cost advantage oI Portugal can be expressed in terms oI cost ratio.
W Cost ratios of producing Wine and Cloth
Portugal has advantage oI lower cost oI production both in wine and cloth. However the diIIerence in cost, that is the comparative advantage is greater in the production oI wine (1.5 0.66 0.84) than in cloth (1.11 0.9 0.21). Even in the terms oI absolute number oI days oI labour Portugal has a large comparative advantage in wine, that is, 40 labourers less than England as compared to cloth where the diIIerence is only 10, (40 ~ 10). Accordingly Portugal specializes in the production oI wine where its comparative advantage is larger. England specializes in the production oI cloth where its comparative disadvantage is lesser than in wine. W Comparative Cost Benefits Both Participants Let us explain Ricardian contention that comparative cost beneIits both the participants, though one oI them had clear cost advantage in both commodities. To prove it, let us work out the internal exchange ratio.
Let us assume these 2 countries enter into trade at an international exchange rate (Terms oI Trade) 1 : 1. At this rate, England specialising in cloth and exporting one unit oI cloth gets one unit oI wine. At home it is required to give 1.2 units oI cloth Ior one unit oI wine. England thus gains 0.2 oI cloth i.e. wine is cheaper Irom Portugal by 0.2 unit oI cloth. Similarly Portugal gets one unit oI cloth Irom England Ior its one unit oI wine as against 0.89 oI cloth at home thus gaining extra cloth oI 0.11. Here both England and Portugal gain Irom the trade i.e. England gives 0.2 less oI cloth to get one unit oI wine and Portugal gets 0.11 more oI cloth Ior one unit oI wine. In this example, Portugal specializes in wine where it has greater comparative advantage leaving cloth Ior England in which it has less comparative disadvantage. Thus comparative cost theory states that each country produces & exports those goods in which they enjoy cost advantage & imports those goods suIIering cost disadvantage.