Muharrami
Muharrami
Muharrami
Access to this document was granted through an Emerald subscription provided by emerald-srm:573577 []
For Authors
If you would like to write for this, or any other Emerald publication, then please use our Emerald for
Authors service information about how to choose which publication to write for and submission guidelines
are available for all. Please visit www.emeraldinsight.com/authors for more information.
About Emerald www.emeraldinsight.com
Emerald is a global publisher linking research and practice to the benefit of society. The company
manages a portfolio of more than 290 journals and over 2,350 books and book series volumes, as well as
providing an extensive range of online products and additional customer resources and services.
Emerald is both COUNTER 4 and TRANSFER compliant. The organization is a partner of the Committee
on Publication Ethics (COPE) and also works with Portico and the LOCKSS initiative for digital archive
preservation.
JES
36,5 The competition and market
structure in the Saudi Arabia
banking
446
Saeed Al-Muharrami
Sultan Qaboos University, Al-Khod, Sultanate of Oman
Received 18 June 2007
Accepted 6 May 2008
Abstract
Purpose – The purpose of this paper is twofold: to investigate the market structure of Saudi Arabia
banking industry; and to evaluate the monopoly power of banks during the years 1993-2006.
Design/methodology/approach – The paper is examining the market structure using the most
frequently applied measures of concentration k-bank concentration ratio (CRk) and
Herfindahl-Hirschman Index (HHI) and it is evaluating the monopoly power of banks using the
Journal of Economic Studies 2009.36:446-460.
1. Introduction
A sound and efficient financial system is the most important prerequisite for savings
and investment decisions and thus economic growth. Economists have long recognised
that financial markets in general, and banks in particular, play a vital role in
the efficient functioning and development of any economy. In developing countries, the
development of the banking and financial system may reflect the extent of importance
given by the country to this vital sector, which can be largely relied upon to
achieve the desired growth in the national economy. The performance of financial
institutions is crucial for the well-being of the whole economy and has attracted the
attention of many researchers. Odedokun (1998) estimated with cross-sectional data
over the 1970s and 1980s for 90 developing countries including Saudi Arabia and the
main finding is that: financial intermediation exerts positive effects on economic
growth in developing countries.
In the early 1970s, many foreign banks had entered the Saudi Arabia banking
system, attracted by the opportunities brought about by the boom in the economy
Journal of Economic Studies
Vol. 36 No. 5, 2009
pp. 446-460 JEL classification – G21, L1, D40
q Emerald Group Publishing Limited
0144-3585
The author is grateful to the anonymous referee and the Editor for helpful comments and
DOI 10.1108/01443580910992375 advice. The author is responsible for all remaining errors.
resulting from the increased oil revenues, especially from 1973 onwards. The strong Competition and
presence of foreign banks, of which there were ten by the mid-1970s, encouraged the market structure
Saudi authorities to introduce a policy encouraging foreign banks to be converted into
publicly traded companies with the participation of Saudi nationals. The legislation
introduced in 1975 aimed to preserve the rights and interests of foreign banks’
positions as partners in the newly incorporated banks. In order to maintain the
performance and stability of the banking sector, foreign banks were allowed to hold up 447
to 50 per cent ownership and include the name of their origins in the bank title (for
example, the Saudi British Bank and the Saudi American Bank). They could also
maintain management responsibilities and were allowed to enjoy treatment equal to
that of national banks (Saudi Arabia Monetary Agency (SAMA) 1998).
Therefore, the significant changes in the Saudi Arabia banking industry raise the
important policy concerns that banks in highly concentrated markets should gain market
power due to being able to charge higher than competitive prices for their products, thus
inflicting welfare costs that could more than offset any presumed benefit associated with
mergers. Other concerns regarding the higher concentration ratio (CR) include such
problems as the limited effectiveness of monetary and credit policy, increased probability
Journal of Economic Studies 2009.36:446-460.
3. Literature review
3.1 Measuring market structure
There are a number of measures of concentration that have been used in banking
studies. Hall and Tideman (1967) suggested a list of six desirable properties for
measures of concentration. These are:
Year 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2006 D 1993-2006
Total 301,607 316,283 356,091 413,394 461,271 540,079 723,838 817,006 þ 171%
Table I. Note: Million Saudi riyal
Total asset Source: Compiled by the author from banks annual reports
Year 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2006 D Branches 1993-2006
Table II. Total 1,106 1,116 1,125 1,168 1,176 1,190 1,211 1,243 12.4%
Branches of banks
in Saudi Arabia Source: Compiled by the author from banks annual reports
(1) a concentration index should be a one-dimensional measure; Competition and
(2) concentration in an industry should be independent of the size of that industry; market structure
(3) concentration should increase if the share of any firm is increased at the
expense of a smaller firm;
(4) if all firms are divided into K equal parts then the concentration index should be
reduced by a proportion 1/K; 449
(5) if all firms are divided into N equal parts then the concentration should be a
decreasing function of N; and
(6) a concentration measure should be between zero and one.
market structure.
3.1.1 The k-bank concentration ratio. Simplicity and limited data requirements
make the k-bank concentration ratio one of the most frequently used measures of
concentration in the empirical literature. Summing only the market shares of the k
largest banks in the market, it takes the form:
X
k
CRk ¼ MSi
i¼1
where MS is the market share of the ith firm and k is number of the biggest firms in the
market.
The index gives equal emphasis to the k leading banks, but neglects the many small
banks in the market. There is no rule for the determination of the value of k, so that the
number of banks included in the concentration index is a somewhat arbitrary decision.
The CR may be considered as one point on the concentration curve, and it is a
one-dimensional measure ranging between zero and unity. The index approaches zero
for an infinite number of equally sized banks (given that the k chosen for the
calculation of the CR is comparatively small when compared to the total number of
banks) and it equals unity if the banks included in the calculation of the CR make up
the entire industry.
3.1.2 The Herfindahl-Hirschman Index. Policy makers in the US Department of
Justice have for many years published formal guidelines that identify structural
changes resulting from mergers that are likely to cause the department to challenge a
merger. Since 1982, the department has based its merger guidelines on the HHI of
concentration. This measure, which is also used by bank regulatory agencies, is
calculated by squaring the market share of each firm competing in a defined
geographic banking market and then summing the squares. The HHI can range from
zero in a market having an infinite number of firms to 10,000 in a market having just
one firm (with a 100 per cent market share).
According to the current screening guidelines in the USA, the banking industry is
regarded to be a competitive market if the HHI is less than 1,000, a somewhat
JES concentrated market if the HHI lies between 1,000 and 1,800, and a very concentrated
36,5 market if HHI is more than 1,800. If the post merger market HHI is lower than 1,800
points, and the increase in the index from the pre-merger situation is less than 200
points, the merger is presumed to have no anticompetitive effects and is approved by
the regulators. Should these threshold values be exceeded, the regulators will check for
the existence of potential mitigating factors. If the mitigating factors are not enough to
450 justify the merger, the regulators may require the divestiture of some branches and
offices, in order to bring the CR to or below the threshold level. If divestiture would not
accomplish this goal, the merger application is denied.
The HHI index was developed independently by the economists A.O. Hirschman
(in 1945) and O.C. Herfindahl (in 1950) (Rhoades, 1993). The HHI is a static measure
and, therefore, gauges market concentration at a single point in time. Algebraically, it
can be depicted as:
X
n
HHI ¼ ðMSi Þ2
i¼1
Journal of Economic Studies 2009.36:446-460.
where MS is the market share of the ith firm and n is number of firms in the market.
The HHI stresses the importance of larger banks by assigning them a greater weight
than smaller banks, and it incorporates each bank individually, so that arbitrary
cut-offs and insensitivity to the share distribution are avoided.
Based on the number of national banks, the researcher expects that the two- and
three-bank deposits and HHI value for testing the market structure will give
indications that Saudi Arabia market could be described as “unconcentrated market”.
for Belgium and Greece at the 95 per cent confidence level. de Bandt and Davis (2000)
investigate banking markets in France, Germany and Italy within groups of large and
small banks. Aiming to assess the effects of Economic and Monetary Union on market
conditions, they obtain estimates of H, which are significantly different from zero and
from unity for large banks in all three countries. The H-statistics estimated for the
sample with small banks indicate monopolistic competition in Italy, and monopoly
power in France and Germany. Bikker and Haaf (2000) consider banks in 23
Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) countries and
investigate small, medium-sized and large banks separately. This P-R analysis finds
monopolistic competition virtually everywhere, although perfect competition cannot be
rejected for some market segments.
Al-Muharrami et al. (2006) evaluate the monopoly power of GCC banks over ten
years period, 1993-2002, using the “H-statistic” by Panzar and Rosse. The results show
that banks in Kuwait, Saudi Arabia and UAE operate under perfect competition; banks
in Bahrain and Qatar operate under conditions of monopolistic competition; and they
were unable to reject monopolistic competition for the banking market in Oman.
Gunalp and Celik (2006) employed the Panzar-Rosse H-statistic to assess the
competitive environment of the Turkish banking industry over the period 1990-2000.
The results indicated that for the period under consideration bank revenues behaved as
if they were earned under conditions of monopolistic competition. Therefore, the
observed high profitability of the Turkish banking sector was not an indication of an
increase in monopoly power. Perera et al. (2006) examines the nature of competition
and structure in South Asian banking markets. The Panzar-Rosse specification tests
show that banks revenues appear to be earned under monopolistic competition during
the period 1995-2003.
Finally, Yildirim (2007) examines the evolution of competitive conditions in the
banking industries of 14 Central and Eastern European (CEE) transition economies for
the period 1993-2000. The results of the competition analysis suggest that the banking
markets of CEE countries cannot be characterized by the bipolar cases of either perfect
JES competition or monopoly over 1993-2000 except for Federal Yugoslavia Republic of
36,5 Macedonia and Slovakia.
Table III summarises the results of those investigations. Most of them are for EC
and indicate that banks earn revenues as if they are under conditions of monopolistic
competition.
Few assumptions need to be made to apply this model in this study. First, one needs
to assume that banks can be treated as single product firms (de Bandt and Davis, 2000);
consistent with the intermediation approach to banking, banks are viewed as
producing intermediation services using labour, physical capital and financial capital
as inputs. Second, one needs to assume that higher input prices are not correlated with
higher quality services that generate higher revenues, because such a correlation could
bias the computed H-statistic. This means, however, that if one rejects the hypothesis
of a contestable/competitive market, this bias cannot be too large (Molyneux et al.,
1996). Third, one needs to be observing banks in long-run equilibrium. Therefore, this
study tries to overcome this problem by using a panel data specification.
The justification for using the log linear form typically to improve the regression’s
goodness of fit and may reduce simultaneity bias (de Bandt and Davis, 2000).
Molyneux et al. (1996) found that a log linear revenue equation gave similar results as a
more flexible translog equation. The revenue equation in the Panzar-Rosse model is
interpreted as a reduced form rather than a structural equation.
In long-run equilibrium, rates of return should be uncorrelated with input prices. To
test if the banking market is in long-run equilibrium the paper also estimates an
auxiliary equation (2), which tests for the equality of risk-adjusted rates of return
across banks:
Journal of Economic Studies 2009.36:446-460.
studies
P-R model results in other
Competition and
Table III.
453
JES LnðROA þ 1Þ ¼b0 þ ðb1 ln PL þ b2 ln PK þ b3 ln PFÞ þ b4 ln RISKAST
ð2Þ
36,5 þ b5 ln ASSET þ b6 ln BR
where:
454 Ln – natural logarithm;
TREV – total revenue to total assets;
ROA – net profits to total assets;
PL – personnel expenses to employees (unit price of labour);
PK – capital expenses to fixed assets (unit price of capital);
PF – ratio of annual interest expenses to own funds (unit price of funds);
RISKAST – provisions to total assets;
Journal of Economic Studies 2009.36:446-460.
H#0 Monopoly equilibrium: each bank operates independently as under monopoly profit
maximisation conditions (H is a decreasing function of the perceived demand elasticity)
or perfect cartel
0 , H , 1 Monopolistic competitions free entry equilibrium (H is an increasing function of the
perceived demand elasticity)
H¼1 Perfect competition. Free entry equilibrium with full efficient capacity utilisation
Equilibrium test
H,0 Disequilibrium
H¼0 Equilibrium
Table IV.
Discriminatory power Sources: Rosse and Panzar (1997); Panzar and Rosse (1982, 1987); Shaffer (1982, 1983) ; Nathan and
of H Neave (1989)
4.3 The data Competition and
In a competitive conditions analysis, production units are expected to be relatively market structure
homogenous, providing similar services and using similar resources. Commercial
banks operating in Saudi Arabia are depository institutions that cannot take part in the
leasing and trading real goods for commercial purposes. In contrast, development and
investment banks can engage in such activities, but they cannot accept deposits. These
non-depository institutions also do not extend small commercial and individual loans, 455
which require a substantial amount of investment in a brick-and-mortar branching
network, work force and red tape, etc. In fact, they are mostly single branch banks that
finance large long-term projects, such as those financed by funds borrowed from the
World Bank, International Monetary Fund or other international organizations, which
provides substantial savings on overhead, monitoring and control costs. Because of
their small market share in the sector as well as quite different technology, structure
and goal, this study excludes development and investment banks and instead
concentrates on commercial banks.
The data are obtained from financial statements of banks, on their web pages on the
internet, annual central bank reports, and from the Fitch-IBCA Ltd Bankscope CD
Journal of Economic Studies 2009.36:446-460.
Rom. This study covers ten banks privately held and domestically owned that are fully
licensed commercial. These are: The National Commercial Bank, Samba Financial
Group, Riyad Bank, The Saudi British Bank, Arab National Bank, Banque Saudi
Fransi, Saudi Hollandi Bank, The Saudi Investment Bank, Al-Jazera Bank and Al-Rajhi
Bank[1]. The period sample covers is from 1993 to 2006. The final sample consists of
panel of 140 bank-year observations. The sample of 140 observations is very similar to
or more than the sample size used in previous studies of banking. For example, Nathan
and Neave (1989) used samples of 39 observations on Canadian trust companies and 33
observations on mortgage companies; Shaffer (1993) used 25 observations on Canadian
banks; and Shaffer and DiSalvo (1994) used samples of 36 and 44 observations on
duopoly banks in alternate specifications.
5. The results
5.1 Market structure
Table V presents the trends of the HHI and CRk for the period 1993-2006 where the
total deposits and total loans have been taken as the measure of bank size. In general,
the CR shows the decreasing trend. CR in deposit market implies a concentrated
market with CR2, CR3 recording 38 and 55 per cent and HHI 1,455 in the 1993. However,
in 2006, CR fell down with CR2, CR3 recording 34 and 46 per cent and HHI 1,226 due to
the decrease of the market share of the bigger banks and the increase of the market
share of the smaller banks. According to the current screening guidelines in the USA,
this market could be described as an “unconcentrated market”. The CR in the loan
market shows similar trend with that in the deposit market.
time. The paper uses the fixed effects estimators, correcting for the effect of any
combination of time-invariant variables that have been omitted, knowingly or not,
from the regression model.
The equilibrium test and the competitive position tests for the pooled data are
reported in Table VI. For both models, this study performed a variety of tests to check
for serial correlation, normality of the residuals and heteroscedasticity and for the
functional form. All tests confirm the good fit of the models. Most of the estimated
coefficients are statistically significant, while there is no evidence of multicollinearity
among the independent variables. All tests confirm the good fit of the models.
The estimated regression equations explained 47 per cent of the variability in the ROA
and 97 per cent in the TREV equation.
5.3 Implications
Even though, from mid-1975, no new foreign bank entities have been allowed to enter
the Saudi banking system, it does not appear that concentration has increased in the
Saudi Arabia banking industry. In fact, concentration measures reported here indicate
that declines in concentration over the 1993-2006. On the basis of these findings, it is
safe to conclude that Saudi Arabia banking industry is not highly concentrated and the
concentration in general should not cause a big concern since the concentration indices
indicate a decline in concentration over the ten years. However, the results suggest that
JES SAMA should be very cautious in granting mergers among banks, in particular among
36,5 large “core” banks. Moreover, the results indicate that Saudi Arabia is not over
branched. So, there is a span for more branches within a country. Therefore, Saudi
Arabia Monetary Authority can grant Saudi banks to open more branches within the
country.
monopoly is rejected leading us to conclude that banks earned their revenues in the
condition of monopolistic competition.
Note
1. Al-Rajhi Bank is an Islamic Bank.
References
Al-Jarrah, I.M. (2002), “Efficiency in Arabian banking”, PhD dissertation, University of Wales,
Bangor.
Al-Muharrami, S., Matthews, K. and Karbhari, Y. (2006), “Market structure and competitive
conditions in the Arab GCC banking system”, Journal of Banking & Finance, Vol. 30,
pp. 3487-501.
Al-Sahlawi, K. (1997), “The role of industrial development banks in financing and promoting
technological change: the case of the Saudi Industrial Development Fund”, PhD thesis,
University of Wales, Bangor.
Bikker, J.A. and Groeneveld, J.M. (2000), “Competition and concentration in the EU banking
industry”, Kredit und Kapital, Vol. 33, pp. 62-98.
Bikker, J.A. and Haaf, K. (2000), “Competition, concentration and their relationship: an empirical
analysis of the banking industry”, Research Series Supervision, No. 30, De Nederlandsche
Bank, Amsterdam.
Bikker, J.A. and Haaf, K. (2002), “Competition, concentration and their relationship: an empirical
analysis of the banking industry”, Journal of Banking & Finance, Vol. 26, pp. 2191-214.
Claessens, S. and Laeven, L. (2004), “What drives bank competition? Some international
evidence”, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 36 No. 3, pp. 563-83 (Part 2).
Coccorese, P. (1998), “Assessing the competitive conditions in the Italian banking system: some
empirical evidence”, BNL Quarterly Review, Vol. 205, pp. 171-91.
Coccorese, P. (2004), “Banking competition and macroeconomic conditions: a disaggregate
analysis”, Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions & Money, Vol. 14,
pp. 203-19.
de Bandt, O. and Davis, E.P. (2000), “Competition, contestability and market structure in Competition and
European banking sectors on the eve of EMU”, Journal of Banking & Finance, Vol. 24,
pp. 1045-66. market structure
Gunalp, B. and Celik, T. (2006), “Competition in the Turkish banking industry”, Applied
Economics, Vol. 38, pp. 1335-42.
Hall, M. and Tideman, N. (1967), “Measures of concentration”, Journal of the American Statistical
Association, Vol. 62, pp. 162-8. 459
Hempell, H.S. (2002), “Testing for competition among German banks”, Deutsche Bundesbank,
Economic Research Centre, Frankfurt on the Main, Discussion Paper 04/02.
Hondroyiannis, G., Lolos, S. and Papetrou, E. (1999), “Assessing competitive conditions in the
Greek banking system”, Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions and
Money, Vol. 9, pp. 377-91.
Lloyd-Williams, D.M., Molyneux, P. and Thornton, J. (1991), “Market structure and performance
in Spanish banking”, Journal of Banking & Finance, Vol. 18, pp. 433-43.
Molyneux, P., Lloyd-Williams, D.M. and Thornton, J. (1994), “Competitive conditions in
European banking”, Journal of Banking Finance, Vol. 18, pp. 445-59.
Journal of Economic Studies 2009.36:446-460.
Molyneux, P., Thornton, J. and Lloyd-Williams, D.M. (1996), “Competition and market
contestability in Japanese commercial banks”, Journal of Economics and Business, Vol. 48,
pp. 33-45.
Nathan, A. and Neave, E.H. (1989), “Competition and contestability in Canada’s financial system:
empirical results”, Canada Journal of Economics, Vol. 22 No. 3, pp. 576-94.
Odedokun, M.O. (1998), “Financial intermediation and economic growth in developing
countries”, Journal of Economic Studies, Vol. 25 No. 3, pp. 203-24.
Panzar, J.C. and Rosse, J.N. (1982), “Structure, conduct and comparative statistics”, Bell
Laboratories Economic Discussion Paper No. 248.
Panzar, J.C. and Rosse, J.N. (1987), “Testing for monopoly equilibrium”, Journal of Industrial
Economics, Vol. 35, pp. 443-56.
Perera, S., Skully, M. and Wickramanayake, J. (2006), “Competition and structure of South Asian
banking: a revenue behaviour approach”, Applied Financial Economics, Vol. 16,
pp. 789-801.
Rhoades, S. (1993), “The Herfindahl-Hirschman index”, Federal Reserve Bulletin, Vol. 79,
pp. 188-9.
Rime, B. (1999), “Mesure de degré de concurrence dans le système bancaire Suisse à l’aide du
modèle de Panzar et Rosse”, Revue Suisse d’Economie Politique et de Statistique, Vol. 135,
pp. 21-40.
Rosse, J.N. and Panzar, J.C. (1977), “Chamberlain vs Robinson: an empirical study of monopoly
rents”, Bell Laboratories Economic Discussion Paper, No. 90.
SAMA (1998), Annual Report, Kingdom of Saudi Arabia, Saudi Arabia Monetary Agency,
Riyadh.
Shaffer, S. (1982), “A non-structural tests for competition in financial markets”, Bank Structure
and Competition, Conference Proceedings, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, Chicago, IL,
pp. 225-43.
Shaffer, S. (1983), “Non-structural measures of competition”, Economic Letters, Vol. 12, pp. 349-53.
Shaffer, S. (1985), “Competition, economies of scale, and diversity of firm sizes”, Applied
Economics, Vol. 17, pp. 467-76.
JES Shaffer, S. (1993), “Can megamergers improve bank efficiency?”, Journal of Banking and Finance,
Vol. 17, pp. 423-36.
36,5 Shaffer, S. and DiSalvo, J. (1994), “Conduct in a banking duopoly”, Journal of Banking and
Finance, Vol. 18 No. 6, pp. 1063-82.
Utrero-Gonzalez, N. (2004), “Banking competition in UK and Spain: is there a Euro effect?”, paper
presented at FMA European Conference, University of Zurich, Zurich, 3-4 June.
460 Vesala, J. (1995), “Testing for competition in banking: behavioural evidence from Finland”, Bank
of Finland Studies, E: 1.
Yildirim, H. (2007), “Competition and contestability in Central and Eastern European banking
markets”, Managerial Finance, Vol. 33 No. 3, pp. 195-209.
Further reading
Al-Suhaimi, J. (2001), “Consolidation, competition, foreign presence and systematic stability in
the Saudi banking industry”, BIS papers, 4 August.
Capital Intelligence (2006), Bankscope CD Rom Databases.
Journal of Economic Studies 2009.36:446-460.
Corresponding author
Saeed Al-Muharrami can be contacted at: [email protected]
1. Munacinga Simatele. 2015. Market Structure and Competition in the South African Banking Sector.
Procedia Economics and Finance 30, 825-835. [CrossRef]
2. Fadzlan SufianInstitute of Islamic Banking and Finance, International Islamic University Malaysia, Kuala
Lumpur, Malaysia Muzafar Shah HabibullahEconomics Department, Universiti Putra Malaysia, Serdang,
Malaysia. 2013. Financial sector consolidation and competition in Malaysia. Journal of Economic Studies
40:3, 390-410. [Abstract] [Full Text] [PDF]
Journal of Economic Studies 2009.36:446-460.