Intermed 05
Intermed 05
Intermed 05
5
=
3/
4
2
pizza
b
3
px
/p
2
y
=
1
b
0
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7
cell service (GB)
The dashed lines show the budget frontier if the first 2 GB cost $10 per
GB, and additional GB cost $15 per GB.
2 INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS
Is Bundle A Optimal?
6
5
4
3
2
1 A
b
0
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
4 INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS
6
5
4
3
2
1 A
b
0
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
6
5
4
3
2
1 A
b
0
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
4. INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS — WEEK 5 5
Is Bundle B Optimal?
6
5
4
3 b B
2
C
1 b
0
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
6 INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS
6
5
4
3 b B
2
C
1 b
0
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
Another way of looking at this is that the slope of the indifference curve
through B is higher than the slope of the budget line. This means that
the marginal value of good X in terms of Y, the MRS, is higher than the
its price in terms of Y, px /py . So the consumer can improve by buying
more X and less Y.
4. INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS — WEEK 5 7
Bundle E is Optimal!!
6
5
4
3
E
2 b
1
0
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
8 INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS
Optimality Conditions
6
5
4
3
y∗ 2 b E
1
0
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
x∗
4. INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS — WEEK 5 9
m = px x + py y Budget equation
px
MRS = Optimality equation.
py
Recall that
MUx px MUx
MRS = so = MRS = .
MUy py MUy
10 INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS
MUx px
= = MRS .
MUy py
where the brackets indicate we are giving the units of each expression.
The MU /p terms are the marginal utility per dollar spent for each of
the goods. To maximize utility, we must spend each dollar in a way that
gives us the biggest bang per buck—the biggest marginal utility per
dollar.
Later, in section 4.5.24, we will see that we can easily include the
corner case.
4. INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS — WEEK 5 11
4x + 10y = 40 Budget
y px
= = 2/5. Optimality
x py
Eliminating the common factor of 2 from the first equation and clearing
the denominators of the second, we find
2x + 5y = 20
(1)
5y = 2x.
12 INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS
We solve system (1) to find (x∗, y∗ ). First, let’s repeat (1), emphasizing
the 5y terms.
2x + 5y = 20
(1)
5y = 2x.
2x + 2x = 20 or 4x = 20.
2(5) + 5y = 20 or 5y = 10.
6
5
4
3
(x∗ , y∗ )
2 b
1
0
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
4. INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS — WEEK 5 13
MUx = axa−1yb
MUy = bxa yb−1.
MUx axa−1yb ay
MRS = = a b−1 = .
MUy bx y bx
14 INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS
m = px x + py y Budget equation
ay px
= Optimality equation.
bx py
m = px x + py y
a
py y = px x.
b
4
3 D2
2 D1
1
0 x
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
Perfect Complements
y
MRS = +∞
4
3
2
MRS = 0
1 b
0 x
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8
18 INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS
m = px x + py y Budget equation
ax = by Optimality equation.
so
bm
x∗ = .
bpx + apy
Using y = (a/b)x yields
am
y∗ = .
bpx + apy
4. INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS — WEEK 5 19
7
6
4
3
1 D
0
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 x
bm
apy
Changing preferences (a, b), income (m), or the price of the comple-
mentary good (py ) will shift the demand curve.
20 INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS
a px
= MRS = .
b py
Since a and b are constants that describe preferences, there is only one
relative price where the optimality condition holds. At any other relative
prices, the optimality condition can never be satisfied. We’ll look more
at that in a bit. When optimality holds, the budget line coincides with
the highest indifference curve that touches the budget set. Every point
on the budget frontier is equally good, and maximizes utility.
6
5
4
3
2
1
0 x
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
On the diagram, the budget line is the thick red line and the maximizing
indifference curve is shown as black, superimposed on the budget line.
Any point on the budget line is an optimal point.
4. INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS — WEEK 5 21
6
5
4
3
2
1
0 x
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
22 INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS
6
5
4
3
2
A
1 b
0 x
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
6
5
4
3
2
A
1 b
0 x
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
6
5
4 b (x∗ , y∗)
3
2
1
0 x
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
As you can see on the diagram, the highest indifference curve that
touches the budget line is the one through (x∗, y∗ ) = (0, 4), making it the
optimal choice.
When the relative price is always greater than the MRS, the optimal
consumption bundle will be the vertical intercept of the budget frontier.
This solution at the corner of the budget set is called a corner solution.
4. INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS — WEEK 5 25
6
5
4
3
2
1 (x∗, y∗ )
0 b
x
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
As you can see on the diagram, the highest indifference curve that
touches the budget line is the one through (x∗ , y∗ ) = (10, 0), making it
the optimal choice.
When the relative price is always less than the MRS, the optimal con-
sumption bundle will be the horizontal intercept of the budget frontier.
26 INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS
px
MRS(m/px , 0) ≥
py
px
MRS(0, m/py ) ≤ ,
py
7
6
4
(a/b)py 3
2
D
1
0
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 x
4. INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS — WEEK 5 29
7
6
(a/b)p′y 5
4
D′
(a/b)py 3
2
D
1
0
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 x
See how demand switches from the one curve to the other when the
price of X reaches the critical level (a/b)py .
Demand again depends on prices, the preference parameters, and
income.
30 INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS
bm
x∗ = .
bpx + apy
Spending on X is
∗ a
px x = m.
a+b
Since this is independent of px , demand is unit elastic. The price elasticity
of demand is −1.
Demand is independent of py , so the cross-price elasticity of demand
is 0.
32 INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS
m dx∗ m
EI = ∗ = × z = +1.
x dm zm
To find the price elasticity of demand, we first take the derivative with
respect to px :
∂x∗ bm
= −b
∂px (bpx + apy )2
−b bm
=
bpx + apy bpx + apy
−b
= x∗ .
bpx + apy
Then
px ∂x∗ bpx
|Ed | = = <1
x∗ ∂px bpx + apy
Demand is always inelastic.
34 INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS
∂x∗ bm
= −a
∂py (bpx + apy )2
−a bm
=
bpx + apy bpx + apy
−a
= x∗ .
bpx + apy
Then
py ∂x∗ −apy
Exy = = < 0.
x∗ ∂py bpx + apy
This is always negative, indicating that X and Y are complements.
Since x∗ is again proportional to m, its income elasticity is again +1.
5. INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS — WEEK 5 35
3
m/py 2
1
0 x
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
m/p′′x m/p′x m/px
The budget set shrinks as the price of X increases, and expands as the
price decreases. Since there are more options available at lower prices,
and fewer at higher prices, we can say that real income (the consumer’s
consumption possibilities) increased as prices fell, and shrank as prices
rose.
When we change the price of X, it doesn’t make sense to think about
income being unchanged. Even when the dollar income is unchanged,
real income still changes. The effect due to changing income is called
the income effect. We will need to take the income effect into account
when analyzing demand.
5. INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS — WEEK 5 37
An Engel Curve
5
quantity demanded
4
3
1
0
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9
income
A positive slope corresponds to a normal good (EI > 0), while a nega-
tive slopes indicates the good is inferior (EI < 0). Straight lines through
the origin indicate the income elasticity EI = 1.
1
Ernst Engel (1821–1896) was a German statistician who was the first to systematically study the
relationship between expenditures and income. He discovered that consumer spend a smaller share of
their on food as income increases. This is known as Engel’s Law.
38 INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS
1
0
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8
income
5. INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS — WEEK 5 39
4
3
1
0
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8
income
40 INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS
6 b
5 b
4 b
3 b
2 b
1 b
x
0
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8
5. INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS — WEEK 5 41
5
4
3
2
1
0 x
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9
42 INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS
6
5
4
3
2
1 u
0 x
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
6
5
4
3
2
1 u
0 x
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
44 INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS
MUx px
MRS(x, y) = = Optimality equation.
MUy py
u = u(x, y) Utility constraint
√ √
The expenditure minimizing point is (x∗ , y∗) = ( 30, 30/3 , which
√ is
approximately
√ √(5.48, 1.83) and the corresponding expenditure is 2 30+
6 30/3 = 4 30 ≈ 21.91.
6
5
4
3
2 b
1 u
0 x
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
5. INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS — WEEK 5 45
e(p′x , p′y , u)
P= .
e(px , py , u)
2
One commonly used price index is the consumer price index (CPI). The CPI was virtually unchanged
in August. However, it’s not a good measure of month-to-month changes because two parts of it, food
and energy prices, are both highly volatile. A better measure for month-to-month changes is the price
of all items except food and energy. The seasonally adjusted version should be slightly better still. That
went up 0.6% in August, for an annual rate of about 7.4%. Inflation works like compound interest, so
the calculation is (1 + 0.6%)12 = (1.006)12 ≈ 1.0744 = 1 + 7.44%.
3
The true cost-of-living index was introduced by Alexander A. Konüs in 1924.
5. INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS — WEEK 5 47
Copyright c 2022 by John H. Boyd III: Department of Economics, Florida International Univer-
sity, Miami, FL 33199