Consumers and Incentives - Part A
Consumers and Incentives - Part A
PART A PART B
❑ Introduction to Consumer Theory Budget Constraints
❑ Consumer Preferences ➢ Change in Income
➢ Change in Prices
➢ Properties of Preferences
Optimum Consumer Choice
Utility and Utility Function
➢ Utility Maximization
Indifference Curves & Utility ➢ Optimality Condition: “Equal
Marginal Utility & Marginal Rate of Bang for the Buck”
Substitution Derivation of the Demand Function
Examples of Utility Function ➢ When Price of A Good Falls
➢ Perfect Substitutes ➢ When Price of A Good Increases
PART A
❑ Introduction to Consumer Theory
❑ Properties of Consumer Preferences
Utility and Utility Function
Indifference Curves & Utility
Marginal Utility & Marginal Rate of Substitution
Examples of Utility Function
❖ Perfect Substitutes
❖ Perfect Complements
Consumer Theory: Introduction
Quantity of Good X
Properties of Consumer Preferences
With completeness in preferences, ALL the possible consumption bundles
in the positive quadrant (shaded region) can be compared and ranked
by the individual:
Y
Each point represents a
consumption bundle with different
quantities of goods X and Y.
X
Properties of Consumer Preferences
Let Point A depicts a consumption bundle with XA units of X and YA units
of Y, i.e. A=(XA, YA), thus:
A
YA
XA X
Properties of Consumer Preferences
Centering on Point A, four regions or quadrants can be delineated as
shown:
IV I
A
YA
III II
XA X
Properties of Consumer Preferences
With non-satiation in preferences, ALL consumption bundles in Region I
have more of either X or Y or both than at Point A and, thus, are
preferred to A
Y
IV I
A
YA
III II
XA X
Properties of Consumer Preferences
For example, at Point B(XB, YB), XB > XA and YB > YA.
Hence, B(XB, YB) ≻ A(XA, YA), i.e. consumption bundle B is preferred to
consumption bundle A. [≻ means “prefers to” and > means “greater
than”.] Y
IV I
B
YB
A
YA
III II
XA XB X
Properties of Consumer Preferences
In contrast, ALL consumption bundles in Region III have less of either X or
Y or both than at Point A and, thus, A is preferred to any point in Region
III.
Y
IV I
B
A
YA
III II
XA X
Properties of Consumer Preferences
For example, at Point C(XC, YC), XC < XA and YC < YA.
Hence, A(XA, YA) ≻ C(XC, YC), or consumption bundle A is preferred to
consumption bundle C.
Y
IV I
B
A
YA
III II
C
YC
XC XA X
Properties of Consumer Preferences
Hence, we have: B(XB, YB) ≻ A(XA, YA) ≻ C(XC, YC)
IV I
B
A
YA
III II
C
XA X
Properties of Consumer Preferences
A line connecting C to B must pass through either quadrant II or IV.
As one moves from an inferior point (C) to a superior one (B), one goes through a
point like D where one is indifferent between the two bundles A and D, as both
give the same satisfaction to the consumer.
Y
IV I
B
A
YA
D
III II
C
XA X
Utility and Utility Function
Somehow, from the millions of things that are available,
each consumer manages to sort out a set of goods and
services to buy. In so doing, he or she makes specific
judgments about the relative worth of things that are
very different.
Economists have constructed a simple theory of consumer
choice based on the hypothesis that each consumer
spends income in the way that yields the greatest
amount of satisfaction, or utility.
Utility and Utility Function
We now define the utility function to represent
preferences, as follows:
Definition:
The utility function U(X,Y) is a function that assigns to
each bundle (X,Y) a utility level for the consumer. It does
so in a way that represents the consumer preferences,
that is, U(X,Y) > U(X’,Y’) if and only if the bundle (X,Y) is
preferred to the bundle (X’,Y’).
Utility and Utility Function
Certain problems are implicit in the concept of utility.
➢ First, it is impossible to measure utility.
➢ Second, it is impossible to compare the utilities of different
people—that is, we cannot say whether person A or person B
derives a higher level of utility from, say, watching a movie.
Despite these problems, however, the idea of utility helps us
better understand the process of choice.
➢ E.g. while we cannot answer the question “How many utils did you
get from the last movie you saw?”, we can probably answer the
question “How many hamburgers would you give up to get that
movie ticket?” Instead of hamburgers, we can consider monetary
units, e.g. S$, as a measure.
Indifference Curves & Utility
With utility function now defined, therefore we can indicate:
U(XB, YB) > U(XA, YA) > U(XC, YC)
U(XA, YA) = U(XD, YD)
Y
D
III II
C
XA X
Indifference Curves & Utility
Points of indifference can be plotted,
… which trace out the Indifference Curve corresponding to each level
of utility, thus:
Y
IV I
B
A
YA
D
III II
C
XA X
Indifference Curves
Indifference Curve:
Good Y
A curve that defines the combinations
of 2 or more goods that give a
consumer the same level of satisfaction.
Good X
Indifference Curves
Numerous indifference curves (IC) for the individual consumer can be
plotted, giving rise to an indifference map:
Indifference Map:
Good Y
Graph containing a set of indifference
curves showing the consumption baskets
among which a consumer is indifferent.
IC4
IC3
IC2
IC1
Good X
Indifference Curves
Bundles of goods X and Y on the same IC provide the consumer the
same satisfaction or utility, as measured by units of utils.
For example, depending on the functional form
Good Y for preferences,
• each bundle on IC3 provides, say, 30 utils of
satisfaction, while
• each bundle on IC2 provides, say, 20 utils of
satisfaction, lower than that on IC3
• and so on.
IC3
IC2
IC1
Good X
Indifference Curves
One plausible utility function which satisfies the 3 properties of
preferences is 𝑈 = 𝑋. 𝑌, which plots the indifference curves as shown:
160
140
120
Note that only 3 indifference curves
100 with their corresponding utility
values are shown for illustration.
Good Y
80
𝑼 = 𝟓𝟎
60
40 𝑼 = 𝟑𝟎
20
𝑼 = 𝟏𝟎
0
0 20 40 60 80 100 120 140
Good X
Indifference Curves
Completeness – Consumer is capable of expressing preferences (or
indifference) between all possible bundles. (“I don’t know” is NOT an
option!) For example:
Good Y If the only bundles available to a consumer
are A, B, and C, then the consumer
▪ is indifferent between A and C, i.e. A ~ C
(since they are on the same IC).
▪ will prefer B to A, i.e. B ≻ A.
▪ will prefer B to C, i.e. B ≻ C.
A B IC3
C
IC2
IC1
Good X
Indifference Curves
Non-Satiation or “More is Better” – Bundles that have at least as much
of every good and more of some good are preferred to other bundles.
For example:
Increasing utility
Good Y or satisfaction ▪ Bundle B ≻ A, ∵ XB > XA
even if YB = YA.
▪ Bundle B ≻ C, ∵ YB > YC
even if XB = XA.
▪ More generally, bundles on
an IC further in the north-
easterly direction provide
A B IC3 greater satisfaction or utility
YA = YB
C
IC2
YC
IC1
XA XC = XB Good X
Indifference Curves
Transitivity – ensures consistency in consumer choice. For the three
bundles A, B, and D, the transitivity property implies that if D ≻ B and B
≻ A, then D ≻ A.
Good Y
D
A B IC3
IC2
IC1
Good X
Indifference Curves
Non-satiation and transitivity in preferences ensure that the individuals
are consistent and rational, such that an individual’s indifference curves
do not cross.
Good Y
IC1
Good X
Indifference Curves
If this were not so, we would obtain the following inconsistent results:
P~R
R~Q
Good Y
P~Q
But R lies northeast of Q with
R more of both good X and
Q good Y, and hence:
R≻Q
P Inconsistent!!!
IC1
Good X
Indifference Curves
Non-satiation in preferences also implies that indifference curves do not
bend backwards…
… as “more is better” => A ≻ B NOT A ~ B
Good Y
C ≻ D NOT C ~ D
A
C IC
Good X
Marginal Rate of Substitution (MRS)
IC
Good X
Marginal Rate of Substitution (MRS)
1 2 3 4 Good X
Marginal Rate of Substitution & Marginal Utility
Definition:
The marginal utility of good X, MUx, is the marginal
increase in the utility generated by a marginal increase
in the consumption of X.
Marginal Utility & Marginal Rate of Substitution
ΔU
ΔX
∆𝑼 ∆𝑼
ΔU 𝑴𝑼𝑿 = at X1 > 𝑴𝑼𝑿 = at X2
∆𝒙 ∆𝒙
ΔX
Note: The symbol ∆ means “change”.
ΔU
ΔX
∆𝑼 ∆𝑼
ΔU 𝑴𝑼𝑿 = at X1 > 𝑴𝑼𝑿 = at X2
∆𝒙 ∆𝒙
ΔX
Note: The symbol ∆ means “change”.
∆𝐘
|Slope|= = MRSXY
∆𝐗
A Note: |Z|– the two vertical lines means
∆Y
to take the non-negative value of Z.
IC
∆X
X
Marginal Utility & Marginal Rate of Substitution
IC
∆X
X
Marginal Utility & Marginal Rate of Substitution
∆𝐘 𝐌𝐔𝑿
∆Y
A MRSXY = =
∆𝐗 𝐌𝐔𝒀
IC
∆X
X
Marginal Utility & Marginal Rate of Substitution
A
=> MRSXY ↓
IC
Decreasing Y
Diminishing MRSXY
Increasing X
X
Examples of Utility Function – Special Case #1
X
Examples of Utility Function – Special Case #2
“Steep” IC “Flat” IC
Owners of Ford Mustang coupes (a) The opposite is true for owners of
are willing to give up considerable Ford Explorers. They prefer interior
interior space for additional space to acceleration (b).
acceleration.
Diagrams for In-Video Quiz
IC3
IC3
IC2
IC2
IC1
IC1
Good X Good X
Connecting-the-Dots
Giffen Goods:
➢ WSJ - Economists’ Hunt for a Giffen Good Might Have Ended, 16
July 2007
Veblen Goods:
➢ Economist - Luxury - Exclusively for everybody, 13 Sep 2014
➢ WSJ - Soaring Luxury-Goods Prices Test Wealthy's Will to Pay, 02
Mar 2014
➢ WSJ - New iPhone X Tests Economic Theory, 18 Sep 2017
Substitutes and Complements:
➢ Economist - Taxis v Uber - Substitutes or complements, 10 Aug
2015
➢ ST - Pricey food court fare irks diners, 27 Dec 2010
End of Session
• We have come to the end of this session.
• Please complete & submit the in-video quizzes.
• Hope you have learned something useful.
• Thank you!