Game Theory
Game Theory
The key pioneers of game theory were mathematician John von Neumann
and economist Oskar Morgenstern in the 1940s.1 Mathematician John
Nash is regarded by many as providing the first significant extension of the
von Neumann and Morgenstern work.
According to game theory, the actions and choices of all the participants
affect the outcome of each. It's assumed players within the game are
rational and will strive to maximize their payoffs in the game.2
The Nash equilibrium is reached over time, in most cases. However, once
the Nash equilibrium is reached, it will not be deviated from. After we learn
how to find the Nash equilibrium, take a look at how a unilateral move
would affect the situation. Does it make any sense? It shouldn't, and that's
why the Nash equilibrium is described as "no regrets." Generally, there
can be more than one equilibrium in a game.
However, this usually occurs in games with more complex elements than
two choices by two players. In simultaneous games that are repeated over
time, one of these multiple equilibria is reached after some trial and error.
This scenario of different choices overtime before reaching equilibrium is
the most often played out in the business world when two firms are
determining prices for highly interchangeable products, such as airfare or
soft drinks.
Ever seen an opposing coach call a timeout right before the other team's
kicker is to attempt a game-winning field goal? Th
Economics
Project Management
When dealing with an internal team, game theory may be less prevalent as
all participants working for the same employer often have a greater shared
interest for success. However, third-party consultants or external parties
assisting with a project may be incentivized by other means separate from
the project's success.
The strategy of Black Friday shopping is at the heart of game theory. The
concept holds that should companies reduce prices, more consumers will
buy more goods. The relationship between a consumer, a good, and the
financial exchange to transfer ownership plays a major part in game theory
as each consumer has a different set of expectations.
Outside from sweeping sales in advance of the holiday season, companies
must utilize game theory when pricing products for launch or in anticipation
of competition from rival goods. The company must balance pricing a good
too low and not reaping profit, yet pricing a good too high may scare
customers away towards a substitute good.
When there is a direct conflict between multiple parties striving for the
same outcome, this type of game is often a zero-sum game. This means
that for every winner, there is a loser. Alternatively, it means that the
collective net benefit received is equal to the collective net benefit lost.
Almost every sporting event is a zero-sum game in which one team wins
and one team loses.
A non-zero-sum game is one in which all participants can win or lose at the
same time. Consider business partnerships that are mutually beneficial
and foster value for both entities. Instead of competing and attempting to
"win", both parties benefit.
Last, game theory can begin and end in a single instance. Like much of
life, the underlying competition starts, progresses, ends, and cannot be
redone. This is often the case with equity traders that must wisely choose
their entry point and exit point as their decision may not easily be undone
or retried.
The expression "tit for tat" has been determined to be the optimal strategy
for optimizing a prisoner's dilemma. Tit for tat was introduced by Anatol
Rapoport, who developed a strategy in which each participant in an
iterated prisoner's dilemma follows a course of action consistent with their
opponent's previous turn. For example, if provoked, a player subsequently
responds with retaliation; if unprovoked, the player cooperates.
The image below depicts the dilemma where the choice of the participant
on the column and the choice of the participant in the row may clash. For
example, both parties may receive the most favorable outcome if both
choose row/column 1. However, each faces the risk of strong adverse
outcomes should the other party not choose the same outcome.
Dictator Game
This is a simple game in which Player A must decide how to split a cash
prize with Player B, who has no input into Player A’s decision. While this is
not a game theory strategy per se, it does provide some interesting
insights into people’s behavior. Experiments reveal about 50% keep all the
money to themselves, 5% split it equally, and the other 45% give the other
participant a smaller share.
Volunteer’s Dilemma
The centipede game concludes as soon as a player takes the stash, with
that player getting the larger portion and the other player getting the
smaller portion. The game has a pre-defined total number of rounds, which
are known to each player in advance.
Game theory exists in almost every facet of life. Because the decisions of
other people around you impact your day, game theory pertains to
personal relationships, shopping habits, media intake, and hobbies.
Maximax Strategy
Maximin Strategy
Dominant Strategy
Pure Strategy
Mixed Strategy
A mixed strategy may seem like random chance, but there is much thought
that must go into devising a plan of mixing elements or actions. Consider
the relationship between a baseball pitcher and batter. The pitcher cannot
throw the same pitch each time; otherwise, the batter could predict what
would come next. Instead, the pitcher must mix its strategy from pitch to
pitch to create a sense of unpredictability in which it hopes to benefit from.
The "games" may involve how two competitor firms will react to price cuts
by the other, whether a firm should acquire another, or how traders in a
stock market may react to price changes. In theoretic terms, these games
may be categorized as prisoner's dilemmas, the dictator game, the hawk-
and-dove, and Bach or Stravinsky.