Price Elasticity of Supply: Example
Price Elasticity of Supply: Example
The price elasticity of supply is defined in an analogous way to that of demand. We define
percentage change in supply
E=
percentage change in price
This time, however, there is no need to fiddle the sign. An increase in price leads to an increase
in supply, so E is automatically positive. In symbols,
P ∆Q
E= ×
Q ∆P
If (Q1, P1) and (Q2, P2) denote two points on the supply curve then arc elasticity is obtained, as
before, by setting
∆P = P2 − P1
∆Q = Q2 − Q1
P = 1/2(P1 + P2)
Q = 1/2(Q1 + Q2)
The corresponding formula for point elasticity is
P dQ
E= ×
Q dP
Example
Solution
(a) We are given that
Q1 = 100, Q2 = 105
so that
P1 = 10 + 100 = 20 and P2 = 10 + 105 = 20.247
Hence
∆P = 20.247 − 20 = 0.247, ∆Q = 105 − 100 = 5
1 1
P = (20 + 20.247) = 20.123, Q = (100 + 105) = 102.5
2 2
The formula for arc elasticity gives
P ∆Q 20.123 5
E= × = × = 3.97
Q ∆P 102.5 0.247
MFE_C04e.qxd 16/12/2005 11:15 Page 292
292 Differentiation
dQ
(b) To evaluate the elasticity at the point Q = 100, we need to find the derivative, . The supply equation
dP
P = 10 + Q1/ 2
differentiates to give
dP 1 −1/ 2 1
= Q =
dQ 2 2 Q
so that
dQ
=2 Q
dP
At the point Q = 100, we get
dQ
= 2 100 = 20
dP
The formula for point elasticity gives
P dQ 20
E= × = × 20 = 4
Q dP 100
Notice that, as expected, the answers to parts (a) and (b) are nearly the same.
Practice Problem
Advice
The concept of elasticity can be applied to more general functions and we consider some
of these in the next chapter. For the moment we investigate the theoretical properties of
demand elasticity. The following material is more difficult to understand than the fore-
going, so you may prefer just to concentrate on the conclusions and skip the intermediate
derivations.
We begin by analysing the relationship between elasticity and marginal revenue. Marginal
revenue, MR, is given by
d(TR)
MR =
dQ
MFE_C04e.qxd 16/12/2005 11:15 Page 293
Now TR is equal to the product PQ, so we can apply the product rule to differentiate it. If
u = P and v=Q
then
du dP dv dQ
= and = =1
dQ dQ dQ dQ
By the product rule
dv du
MR = u +v
dQ dQ
dP
=P+Q×
dQ
A Q dP D
= PC1 + ×
P dQ F
Now
P dQ
− × =E
Q dP
so
Q dP 1
× =−
P dQ E
294 Differentiation
Hence
dQ 1
=
dP a
The formula for elasticity of demand is
P dQ
E=− ×
Q dP
so replacing Q by (1/a)(P − b) and dQ/dP by 1/a gives
−P 1
E= ×
(1/a)(P − b) a
−P
=
P−b
P
=
b−P
Notice that this formula involves P and b but not a. Elasticity is therefore independent of the
slope of linear demand curves. In particular, this shows that, corresponding to any price P, the
elasticities of the two demand functions sketched in Figure 4.20 are identical. This is perhaps a
rather surprising result. We might have expected demand to be more elastic at point A than at
point B, since A is on the steeper curve. However, the mathematics shows that this is not the
case. (Can you explain, in economic terms, why this is so?)
Another interesting feature of the result
P
E=
b−P
is the fact that b occurs in the denominator of this fraction, so that corresponding to any price,
P, the larger the value of the intercept, b, the smaller the elasticity. In Figure 4.21, elasticity at
C is smaller than that at D because C lies on the curve with the larger intercept.
The dependence of E on P is also worthy of note. It shows that elasticity varies along a
linear demand curve. This is illustrated in Figure 4.22. At the left-hand end, P = b, so
Figure 4.20
MFE_C04e.qxd 16/12/2005 11:15 Page 295
Figure 4.21
Figure 4.22
b b
E= = =∞
b−b 0
At the right-hand end, P = 0, so
0 0
E= = =0
b−0 b
As you move down the demand curve, the elasticity decreases from ∞ to 0, taking all pos-
sible values. Demand is unit elastic when E = 1 and the price at which this occurs can be found
by solving
P
= 1 for P
b−P
MFE_C04e.qxd 16/12/2005 11:15 Page 296
296 Differentiation
Key Terms
Practice Problems