Eco226 History of Economic Development in Nigeria
Eco226 History of Economic Development in Nigeria
Eco226 History of Economic Development in Nigeria
AGO-IWOYE.
Every individual has a need or a potential need for health care in the form of health promotion,
prevention, cure or rehabilitation. This need is not always translated into a demand for health
care particularly in developing countries for various reasons. Health need is transformed into a
health care demand when a patient seeks a medical care and can back it up with money.
Since all needs and wants of society cannot be met at the same time even in richer countries, so
that opportunity cost are incurred by all users of resources, and the scarcer the resources, the
higher the opportunity costs. In the case of health and health services, these costs are incurred
both by producers of health services, through their use of staff, buildings, equipment and
materials supplies, and by consumers, who use transport to health services, buy drugs, etc.
The amount of a particular good that a household will want to buy is a function of the price (P)
of the good. If paracetamol is priced at £1 per pack, you might be prepared to buy more per year
than if it were priced at £10 per pack. For most goods, the higher the price, the less of that good
people will want to buy; the lower the price, the more quantity is demanded.
The amount demanded is also related to the size of a consumer’s income (Y). The higher your
income, the more likely it is that more of a good will be demanded at any given price. Therefore
if your income falls, you might consume less paracetamol per year. The demand for a particular
good is also infl uenced by the relative prices of othergoods (Pc and Ps). For example, if the
price of paracetamol remains fixed at £5 per pack, but the price of a substitute good, say aspirin,
falls, you may now purchase less paracetamol per year than before as it is now relatively less
attractive.
It is important to make a distinction between complementary and substitute goods.
Complementary goods are those bought in conjunction with your product (e.g. a syringe and a
needle). Substitute goods are goods which you can use instead of your good (e.g. if you are
buying paracetamol for a headache then a substitute might be aspirin). If the price of a
complementary good rises then demand for your good may fall. If the price of a substitute good
increases, demand for your good may increase.
The price you are willing to pay for paracetamol is also a function of your tastes or preferences.
If your tastes change (you experience an allergic reaction to paracetamol) then your demand for
it will change and you will be prepared to pay less (or possibly nothing at all) for paracetamol.
Note that your demand for paracetamol is not just a function of your taste for that particular
medicine but also your taste for other goods.
Weather For a number of products, acts of God such as the weather will tend to affect
production. The direction of the effect is obvious: Good weather increases supply.
Or
E p=
Where Δ refers to change in the variable. The price elasticity is always algebraically negative
because an increase in price leads to a decrease in quantity demanded. We derive other
elasticities, such as the income elasticity of demand, similarly.
Or
EY=
Numerical values for price elasticities are often reported in absolute values, eliminating the
minus sign. Absolute values for price elasticities indicate the responsiveness of demand to price
in that the greater the elasticity, the greater the responsiveness. Absolute values greater than 1 are
considered relatively responsive and are called elastic. Elasticities less than 1 in absolute value
are called inelastic. In the limiting cases, zero price elasticity means that the demand curve is
perfectly vertical, while infinite price elasticity means that the demand curve is perfectly flat.
The importance of price elasticity to policy questions can be illustrated with an example
regarding cigarettes, which are clearly a health concern. Suppose that a state added 50 cents per
pack to its tax on cigarettes. Together with supply-and-demand analysis, our elasticity concepts
help us identify the main policy issues. Lawmakers hope that such a tax increase will curb
smoking and bring in tax revenue, but these tend to be contradictory goals. The exact effects will
be difficult to predict unless reliable estimates are available of the cigarette price elasticity. If one
discovered that demand is perfectly inelastic, tax revenue would be at a maximum but with no
effect on smoking or health. Alternative scenarios of increasingly elastic demand create bigger
reductions in smoking but at the cost of decreasing tax revenues. Thus, the more elastic the
response, the greater the effectiveness of an excise tax in inducing people to reduce their levels
of smoking. Lewit and Coate (1982) indicate that teenagers, for example, are more responsive to
cigarette prices than are adults. In such cases, taxes on cigarettes will be relatively more effective
with teenagers.
Market demand elasticities vary by industry and by product. Those goods and services that we
call necessities tend to have elasticities less than 1 in absolute value, while luxuries are more
elastic. Short-run elasticities are generally smaller in absolute value than long-run elasticities.
Further, goods that cost only a tiny fraction of one’s income motivate little or no “shopping
around,” making their demand elasticities very small in absolute value.