Economics Basics Introduction
Economics Basics Introduction
Economics
As an individual, for example, you face the problem of having only limited
resources with which to fulfill your wants and needs, as a result, you must make
certain choices with your money. You'll probably spend part of your money on
rent, electricity and food. Then you might use the rest to go to the movies and/or
buy a new pair of jeans. Economists are interested in the choices you make, and
inquire into why, for instance, you might choose to spend your money on a new
DVD player instead of replacing your old TV. They would want to know whether
you would still buy a carton of cigarettes if prices increased by $2 per pack. The
underlying essence of economics is trying to understand how both individuals
and nations behave in response to certain material constraints.
We can say, therefore, that economics, often referred to as the "dismal science",
is a study of certain aspects of society. Adam Smith (1723 - 1790), the "father of
modern economics" and author of the famous book "An Inquiry into the Nature
and Causes of the Wealth of Nations", spawned the discipline of economics by
trying to understand why some nations prospered while others lagged behind in
poverty. Others after him also explored how a nation's allocation of resources
affects its wealth.
To study these things, economics makes the assumption that human beings will
aim to fulfill their self-interests. It also assumes that individuals are rational in
their efforts to fulfill their unlimited wants and needs. Economics, therefore, is a
social science, which examines people behaving according to their self-interests.
The definition set out at the turn of the twentieth century by Alfred Marshall,
What Is Economics
In order to begin our discussion of economics, we first need to understand (1) the
concept of scarcity and (2) the two branches of study within economics:
microeconomics and macroeconomics.
Scarcity
Because all of our resources are limited in comparison to all of our wants and
needs, individuals and nations have to make decisions regarding what goods and
services they can buy and which ones they must forgo.
So, because of scarcity, people and economies must make decisions over how
to allocate their resources. Economics, in turn, aims to study why we make these
decisions and how we allocate our resources most efficiently.
Macro and microeconomics are the two vantage points from which the economy
is observed. Macroeconomics looks at the total output of a nation and the way
the nation allocates its limited resources of land, labor and capital in an attempt
to maximize production levels and promote trade and growth for future
generations. After observing the society as a whole, Adam Smith noted that there
was an "invisible hand" turning the wheels of the economy: a market force that
keeps the economy functioning.
Microeconomics looks into similar issues, but on the level of the individual people
and firms within the economy. It tends to be more scientific in its approach, and
studies the parts that make up the whole economy. Analyzing certain aspects of
human behavior, microeconomics shows us how individuals and firms respond to
changes in price and why they demand what they do at particular price levels.
Economics Basics: Production Possibility Frontier (PPF), Growth, Opportunity Cost, and Trade
and services and, therefore, allocating its resources in the best way possible. If
the economy is not producing the quantities indicated by the PPF, resources are
being managed inefficiently and the production of society will dwindle.
Let's turn to the chart below. Imagine an economy that can produce only wine
and cotton. According to the PPF, points A, B and C - all appearing on the curve
- represent the most efficient use of resources by the economy. Point X
represents an inefficient use of resources, while point Y represents the goals that
the economy cannot attain with its present levels of resources.
As we can see, in order for this economy to produce more wine, it must give up
some of the resources it uses to produce cotton (point A). If the economy starts
producing more cotton (represented by points B and C), it would have to divert
resources from making wine and, consequently, it will produce less wine than it is
producing at point A. As the chart shows, by moving production from point A to B,
the economy must decrease wine production by a small amount in comparison to
the increase in cotton output.
Point X means that the country's resources are not being used efficiently or,
more specifically, that the country is not producing enough cotton or wine given
the potential of its resources. Point Y, as we mentioned above, represents an
output level that is currently unreachable by this economy.
a change in technology while the level of land, labor and capital remained the
same, the time required to pick cotton and grapes would be reduced. Output
would increase, and the PPF would be pushed outwards.
Opportunity Cost
Opportunity cost is the value of what is foregone in order to have something else.
This value is unique for each individual. You may, for instance, forgo ice cream in
order to have an extra helping of mashed potatoes.
For you, the mashed potatoes have a greater value than dessert. But you can always change
your
mind in the future because there may be some instances when the mashed
potatoes are just not as attractive as the ice cream. The opportunity cost of an
individual's decisions, therefore, is determined by his or her needs, wants, time and resources
(income).
This is important to the PPF because a country will decide how to best allocate
its resources according to its opportunity cost. Therefore, the previous
wine/cotton example shows that if the country chooses to produce more wine
than cotton, the opportunity cost is equivalent to the cost of giving up the required cotton
production.
For example, assume that an individual has a choice between two telephone services. If he or
she were to buy the most expensive service, that
individual may have to reduce the number of times he or she goes to the movies
each month. Giving up these opportunities to go to the movies may be a cost that
is too high for this person, leading him or her to choose the less expensive service.
Remember that opportunity cost is different for each individual and nation. Thus,
what is valued more than something else will vary among people and countries
when decisions are made about how to allocate resources.
For example, let's look at a hypothetical world that has only two countries
(Country A and Country B) and two products (cars and cotton). Each country can
make cars and/or cotton. Now suppose that Country A has very little fertile land
and an abundance of steel for car production. Country B, on the other hand, has
an abundance of fertile land but very little steel. If Country A were to try to
produce both cars and cotton, it would need to divide up its resources. Because it
requires a lot of effort to produce cotton by irrigating the land, Country A would
have to sacrifice producing cars. The opportunity cost of producing both cars and
cotton is high for Country A, which will have to give up a lot of capital in order to
produce both. Similarly, for Country B, the opportunity cost of producing both
products is high because the effort required to produce cars is greater than that of producing
cotton.
Each country can produce one of the products more efficiently (at a lower cost)
than the other. Country A, which has an abundance of steel, would need to give
up more cars than Country B would to produce the same amount of cotton.
Country B would need to give up more cotton than Country A to produce the
same amount of cars. Therefore, County A has a comparative advantage over
Country B in the production of cars, and Country B has a comparative advantage
over Country A in the production of cotton.
Now let's say that both countries (A and B) specialize in producing the goods with
which they have a comparative advantage. If they trade the goods that they
produce for other goods in which they don't have a comparative advantage, both
countries will be able to enjoy both products at a lower opportunity cost.
the resource for investing and personal finance education.
Furthermore, each country will be exchanging the best product it can make for
another good or service that is the best that the other country can produce.
Specialization and trade also works when several different countries are
involved. For example, if Country C specializes in the production of corn, it can
trade its corn for cars from Country A and cotton from Country B.
Like opportunity cost, specialization and comparative advantage also apply to the
way in which individuals interact within an economy. Absolute Advantage
Country A may have a technological advantage that, with the same amount of
inputs (arable land, steel, labor), enables the country to manufacture more of
both cars and cotton than Country B. A country that can produce more of both
goods is said to have an absolute advantage. Better quality resources can give a
country an absolute advantage as can a higher level of education and overall
technological advancement.
It is not possible, however, for a country to have a comparative advantage in everything that it
produces, so it will always be able to benefit from trade.
Advantage
For example, Country A may have a technological advantage that, with the same amount of
inputs (arable land, steel, labor), enables the country to manufacture more of
both cars and cotton than Country B. A country that can produce more of both
goods is said to have an absolute advantage.
Better quality resources can give a country an absolute advantage as can a higher level of
education and overall
technological advancement. It is not possible, however, for a country to have a
comparative advantage in everything that it produces, so it will always be able to benefit from
trade.
Supply and demand is perhaps one of the most fundamental concepts of economics and it is the
backbone of a market economy. Demand refers to how much (quantity) of a product or service
is desired by buyers.
The quantity demanded is the amount of a product people are willing to buy at a certain price;
the relationship between price and quantity demanded is known as the demand relationship.
Supply represents how much the market can offer. The quantity supplied refers to the amount
of a certain good producers are willing to supply when receiving a certain price.
The correlation between price and how much of a good or service is supplied to the market is
known as the supply relationship. Price, therefore, is a reflection of supply and demand.
The relationship between demand and supply underlie the forces behind the allocation of
resources. In market economy theories, demand and supply theory will allocate resources in the
most efficient way possible. How? Let us take a closer look at the law of demand and the law of
supply.
The law of demand states that, if all other factors remain equal, the higher the
price of a good, the less people will demand that good. In other words, the higher
the price, the lower the quantity demanded.
The amount of a good that buyers purchase at a higher price is less because as the price of a
good goes up, so
does the opportunity cost of buying that good. As a result, people will naturally
avoid buying a product that will force them to forgo the consumption of something
else they value more. The chart below shows that the curve is a downward slope.
A, B and C are points on the demand curve. Each point on the curve reflects a
direct correlation between quantity demanded (Q) and price (P). So, at point A,
the quantity demanded will be Q1 and the price will be P1, and so on. The
demand relationship curve illustrates the negative relationship between price and
quantity demanded.
The higher the price of a good the lower the quantity demanded (A), and the lower the price,
the more the good will be in demand (C).
Like the law of demand, the law of supply demonstrates the quantities that will be
sold at a certain price. But unlike the law of demand, the supply relationship
shows an upward slope. This means that the higher the price, the higher the
quantity supplied.
Producers supply more at a higher price because selling a higher quantity at a higher price
increases revenue.
A, B and C are points on the supply curve. Each point on the curve reflects a
direct correlation between quantity supplied (Q) and price (P). At point B, the
quantity supplied will be Q2 and the price will be P2, and so on.
So it is important to try and determine whether a price change that is caused by demand will
be temporary or permanent.
Let's say there's a sudden increase in the demand and price for umbrellas in an
unexpected rainy season; suppliers may simply accommodate demand by using
their production equipment more intensively.
If, however, there is a climate change, and the population will need umbrellas year-round, the
change in
demand and price will be expected to be long term; suppliers will have to change
their equipment and production facilities in order to meet the long-term levels of demand.
Now that we know the laws of supply and demand, let's turn to an example to
show how supply and demand affect price.
Imagine that a special edition CD of your favorite band is released for $20.
Because the record company's previous analysis showed that consumers will not
demand CDs at a price higher than $20, only ten CDs were released because
the opportunity cost is too high for suppliers to produce more. If, however, the ten
CDs are demanded by 20 people, the price will subsequently rise because,nvestopedia.com – the
resource for investing and personal finance education.
according to the demand relationship, as demand increases, so does the price.
Consequently, the rise in price should prompt more CDs to be supplied as the
supply relationship shows that the higher the price, the higher the quantity supplied.
If, however, there are 30 CDs produced and demand is still at 20, the price will
not be pushed up because the supply more than accommodates demand. In fact
after the 20 consumers have been satisfied with their CD purchases, the price of
the justifyover CDs may drop as CD producers attempt to sell the remaining ten
CDs. The lower price will then make the CD more available to people who had
previously decided that the opportunity cost of buying the CD at $20 was too high.
Equilibrium
When supply and demand are equal (i.e. when the supply function and demand
function intersect) the economy is said to be at equilibrium. At this point, the
allocation of goods is at its most efficient because the amount of goods being
supplied is exactly the same as the amount of goods being demanded.
Thus, everyone (individuals, firms, or countries) is satisfied with the current economic
condition. At the given price, suppliers are selling all the goods that they have
produced and consumers are getting all the goods that they are demanding.
As you can see on the chart, equilibrium occurs at the intersection of the demand
and supply curve, which indicates no allocative inefficiency. At this point, the
price of the goods will be P* and the quantity will be Q*. These figures are
referred to as equilibrium price and quantity.
In the real market place equilibrium can only ever be reached in theory, so the
prices of goods and services are constantly changing in relation to fluctuations in
demand and supply.
Disequilibrium
1. Excess Supply
If price is set too high, excess supply will be created within the economy,
and there will be allocative inefficiency.
indicated by Q2. At P1, however, the quantity that the consumers want to
consume is at Q1, a quantity much less than Q2. Because Q2 is greater
than Q1, too much is being produced and too little is being consumed. The
suppliers are trying to produce more goods, which they hope to sell in
hope of increasing profits, but those consuming the goods will purchase
less because the price is too high, making the product less attractive.
3. Excess Demand
Excess demand is created when price is set below the equilibrium price. Because
the price is so low, too many consumers want the good while producers are not
making enough of it.
However, as consumers have to compete with one other to buy the good at this price, the
demand will push the price up, making
suppliers want to supply more and bringing the price closer to its
equilibrium.
Shifts vs Movement
For economics, the “movements” and “shifts” in relation to the supply and demand curves
represent very different market phenomena:
1. Movements –
Like a movement along the demand curve, a movement along the supply
curve means that the supply relationship remains consistent. Therefore, a
movement along the supply curve will occur when the price of the good
changes and the quantity supplied changes in accordance to the original
supply relationship.
Shifts in the demand curve imply that the original demand relationship has changed, meaning
that quantity demand is
affected by a factor other than price. A shift in the demand relationship
would occur if, for instance, beer were all of a sudden the only type of
alcohol available for consumption.
Conversely, if the price for a bottle of beer were $2 and the quantity
supplied decreased from Q2 to Q1, then there would be a shift in the
supply of beer. Like a shift in the demand curve, a shift in the supply curve
implies that the original supply relationship has changed, meaning that
quantity supplied is affected by a factor other than price.
A shift in the supply curve would occur, if, for instance, a natural disaster caused a
mass shortage of hops: beer manufacturers would therefore be forced to
supply less beer for the same price.
The degree to which a demand or supply curve reacts to a change in price is the
curve's elasticity. Elasticity varies among products because some products may
be more essential to the consumer.
Products that are necessities are more insensitive to price changes because consumers would
continue buying these
products despite price increases. Conversely, a price increase of a good or
service that is considered less of a necessity will deter more consumers because
the opportunity cost of buying the product will become too high.
kinds of products are readily available in the market and a person may not
necessarily need them in his or her daily life.
On the other hand, an inelastic good or service is one in which changes in price witness only
modest changes in
the quantity demanded or supplied, if any at all. These goods tend to be things
that are more of a necessity to the consumer in his or her daily life.
To determine the elasticity of the supply or demand curves, we can use this
simple equation:
There are three main factors that influence a demand’s price elasticity:
For example, if the price of a cup of coffee went up by $0.25, consumers could replace their
morning caffeine with a cup of
tea. This means that coffee is an elastic good because a raise in price will cause
a large decrease in demand as consumers start buying more tea instead of coffee.
Most people are not willing to give up their morning cup of caffeine no matter what the price.
We would, therefore, say that caffeine is an
inelastic product because of its lack of substitutes. Thus, while a product within
an industry is elastic due to the availability of substitutes, the industry itself tends
to be inelastic.
Thus, if the price of a can of Coke goes up from $0.50 to $1 and income stays the same, the
income that is available to spend on Coke, which is $2, is
now enough for only two rather than four cans of Coke. In other words, the
consumer is forced to reduce his or her demand of Coke.
Thus if there is an increase in price and no change in the amount of income available to spend
on the good, there will be an elastic reaction in demand: demand will be sensitive to
a change in price if there is no change in income.
Time
This means that tobacco is inelastic because the change in the quantity demand will have been
minor with a change in price.
However, if that smoker finds that he or she cannot afford to spend the extra $2
per day and begins to kick the habit over a period of time, the price elasticity of
In the second factor outlined above, we saw that if price increases while income
stays the same, demand will decrease. It follows, then, that if there is an increase
in income, demand tends to increase as well.
The degree to which an increase in income will cause an increase in demand is called income
elasticity of demand,
which can be expressed in the following equation:
If EDy is greater than one, demand for the item is considered to have a
high income elasticity. If however EDy is less than one, demand is considered to
be income inelastic. Luxury items usually have higher income elasticity because
when people have a higher income, they don't have to forfeit as much to buy
these luxury items.
Income elasticity of demand for Bob’s air travel is seven - highly elastic.
With some goods and services, we may actually notice a decrease in demand as
income increases.
These are considered goods and services of inferior quality that will be dropped by a consumer
who receives a salary increase.
An example may be the increase in the demand of DVDs as opposed to video cassettes, which
are generally considered to be of lower quality. Products for which the
demand decreases as income increases have an income elasticity of less than zero.
Products that witness no change in demand despite a change in income usually have an income
elasticity of zero - these goods and services are considered necessities.
We have already seen that the focus of economics is to understand the problem
of scarcity: the problem of fulfilling the unlimited wants of humankind with limited
and/or scarce resources.
Because of scarcity, economies need to allocate their resources efficiently. Underlying the laws
Usually, the more the person consumes, the larger his or her total utility will be. Marginal
utility is the additional satisfaction, or
amount of utility, gained from each extra unit of consumption.
Take, for example, a chocolate bar. Let's say that after eating one chocolate bar
your sweet tooth has been satisfied. Your marginal utility (and total utility) after
eating one chocolate bar will be quite high. But if you eat more chocolate bars,
the pleasure of each additional chocolate bar will be less than the pleasure you
received from eating the one before - probably because you are starting to feel
full or you have had too many sweets for one day.
This table shows that total utility will increase at a much slower rate as marginal
utility diminishes with each additional bar. Notice how the first chocolate bar
gives a total utility of 70 but the next three chocolate bars together increase total
The law of diminishing marginal utility helps economists understand the law of
demand and the negative sloping demand curve. The less of something you
have, the more satisfaction you gain from each additional unit you consume; the
marginal utility you gain from that product is therefore higher, giving you a higher
willingness to pay more for it.
Prices are lower at a higher quantity demanded because your additional satisfaction diminishes
as you demand more.
In order to determine what a consumer's utility and total utility are, economists turn to
consumer demand theory, which studies consumer behavior and
satisfaction. Economists assume the consumer is rational and will thus maximize
his or her total utility by purchasing a combination of different products rather
than more of one particular product.
Thus, instead of spending all of your money on three chocolate bars, which has a total utility of
85, you should instead
purchase the one chocolate bar, which has a utility of 70, and perhaps a glass of
milk, which has a utility of 50. This combination will give you a maximized total
utility of 120 but at the same cost as the three chocolate bars.
Economists assume that there are a number of different buyers and sellers in the
marketplace. This means that we have competition in the market, which allows
price to change in response to changes in supply and demand. Furthermore, for
almost every product there are substitutes, so if one product becomes too
expensive, a buyer can choose a cheaper substitute instead. In a market with
many buyers and sellers, both the consumer and the supplier have equal ability
to influence price.
maximize his or her total utility and has have very little influence over the price of goods.
For instance, a government can create a monopoly over an industry that it wants to control,
such as electricity. Another reason for
the barriers against entry into a monopolistic industry is that oftentimes, one
entity has the exclusive rights to a natural resource. For example, in Saudi Arabia
the government has sole control over the oil industry. A monopoly may also form
when a company has a copyright or patent that prevents others from entering the
market. Pfizer, for instance, had a patent on Viagra.
In an oligopoly, there are only a few firms that make up an industry. This select
group of firms has control over the price and, like a monopoly, an oligopoly has
high barriers to entry. The products that the oligopolistic firms produce are
often nearly identical and, therefore, the companies, which are competing for
market share, are interdependent as a result of market forces.
Assume, for example, that an economy needs only 100 widgets. Company X produces 50
widgets and its competitor, Company Y, produces the other 50. The prices of the
two brands will be interdependent and, therefore, similar. So, if Company X starts
selling the widgets at a lower price, it will get a greater market share, thereby forcing Company
Y to lower its prices as well.
There are two extreme forms of market structure: monopoly and, its
opposite, perfect competition. Perfect competition is characterized by many
buyers and sellers, many products that are similar in nature and, as a
result, many substitutes.
Perfect competition means there are few, if any, barriers to entry for new companies, and
prices are determined by supply and demand.
Thus, producers in a perfectly competitive market are subject to the prices
determined by the market and do not have any leverage. For example, in a
perfectly competitive market, should a single firm decide to increase its selling
price of a good, the consumers can just turn to the nearest competitor for a better
price, causing any firm that increases its prices to lose market share and profits.
We hope that this has given you some insight to the market and, in turn, your
investment strategies. Let's recap what we've learned in this tutorial:
Demand and supply refer to the relationship price has with the quantity
consumers demand and the quantity supplied by producers. As price
increases, quantity demanded decreases and quantity supplied increases.
Market economies are assumed to have many buyers and sellers, high
Oligopolies are industries with a few interdependent companies. Perfect competition represents
an economy with many businesses competing with one another for consumer interest and
profits.