Consumers' Equilibrium
Consumers' Equilibrium
Equilibrium
The consumption decision
◎ Given the assumptions about utility and consumer’s feasible set, the consumer’s problem of
choosing the :most preferred bundle from those available can be formally stated as:
◎ We can derive the conditions which the solution to this problem must satisfy by a diagrammatic
analysis of the two-good case.
◎ The principal behavioral postulate is that a decision-maker chooses its most preferred alternative
from those available to it.
◎ The available choices constitute the choice set.
◎ How is the most preferred bundle in the choice set located/found?
◎ All commodities are assumed to have positive ◎
marginal utility so that bundles on higher
indifference curves are preferred to those on lower
indifference curves. This assumption also means
that the consumer will spend all his income since he
cannot be maximizing u if he can buy more of some
good with positive marginal utility. The consumer
will therefore choose a bundle on his budget line B.
◎ In the figure there is a tangency solution where the
optimal bundle x* is such that the highest attainable
indifference curve 𝐼1 is tangent to the budget line
and the consumer consumes some of both goods.
◎ The slope of the indifference curve is equal to the
slope of the budget line at the optimum:
◎
3
The negative of the slope of the indifference curve ◎ If the consumer spent an extra unit of
is the marginal rate of substitution 𝑀𝑅𝑆21 ; and the money on 𝑥1 he would be able to buy
1
negative of the slope of the budget line is the ratio units of 𝑥1 .
𝑝1
of the prices. Hence the consumer’s equilibrium
condition can be written as ◎ If consumption of 𝑥1 increases by ∆𝑥1 , the
utility of consumer will increase by 𝑢1 ∆𝑥1 .
◎ Thus, for an increase in spending of one
extra unit of money on 𝑥1 , the utility will go
𝑢
up by 1 , at the margin.
𝑝1
◎ Since due to non satiation assumption, we know consumers spend all their income, the
budget constraint will satisfy as equality 𝑝𝑖 𝑥𝑖 = 𝑀. Assuming utility functions and
feasible set are following all standard assumptions, hence consumers consumer a
positive quantity of all goods. Thus the non negativity constraints on consumption levels
are non binding, that is 𝑥𝑖 > 0.
The Lagrange function:
6
◎ Alternatively, the terms can be arranged as
◎ The value of the Lagrange multiplier λ is the rate at which the objective
function increases as the constraint parameter increases. In this case the
objective function is the utility function and the constraint parameter is the
individual’s money income so that λ is the rate at which utility increases as
money income increases.
◎
The Lagrange multiplier can be interpreted as the
marginal utility of money income, since, a we argued
above, ui /pi is the rate
at which utility increases as more money is spent on
good i.
7
Second order condition of utility maximization: (n commodities and one constraint)
8
◎ In this case the unconstrained Lagrange function is maximized with respect to n+1 variables.
Concavity of L requires:
𝜕 𝐿2 𝜕2 𝐿 𝜕2 𝐿
⋯⋯⋯
𝜕𝜆2 𝜕𝜆𝜕𝑥1 𝜕𝜆𝜕𝑥𝑛
𝜕2 𝐿 𝜕2 𝐿 𝜕2 𝐿
◎ 𝜕𝑥1 𝜕𝜆 𝜕𝑥1 2
⋯⋯⋯
𝜕𝑥1 𝜕𝑥𝑛
⋮ ⋮ ⋯⋯ ⋮
𝜕2 𝐿 𝜕2 𝐿 𝜕2 𝐿
𝜕𝑥𝑛 𝜕𝜆 𝜕𝑥𝑛 𝜕𝑥1
⋯⋯ 𝜕𝑥𝑛 2
◎ The sufficiency condition of L to be concave or the maximum
of u(x) subject to the constraint set is found if the bordered
principal minors H1+j should have sign (-1)1+j j=1,2 n-1
such that Hn= H
9
The two commodity case with one constraints
0 p1 p2
◎ H2 = p1 L11 L12 0
p2 L21 L22
2 p1 p2 L12 p12 L22 p22 L11 0
L12 L21 L ij uij
◎ The convexity implies that as we reduce 𝑥2 and increase 𝑥1 indifference curves will become flatter implying
actual slope is higher. That is
◎ 𝑑𝑥2
𝑑𝑥1 𝑥 ′ ,𝑥 ′
>
𝑑𝑥2
𝑑𝑥1 𝑥 ′′ ,𝑥 ′′
where 𝑥1′ > 𝑥1′′ 𝑎𝑛𝑑 𝑥2′ < 𝑥2′′ . Since actual slope is rising, rate of change of slope must
1 2 1 2
be positive.
𝜕𝑢1 𝜕𝑢1 𝑑𝑥2 𝜕𝑢2 𝜕𝑢2 𝑑𝑥2
𝑢2 + −𝑢1 +
𝑑 2 𝑥2 𝜕𝑥1 𝜕𝑥2 𝑑𝑥1 𝜕𝑥1 𝜕𝑥2 𝑑𝑥1
◎ Taking total differentiation yields
𝑑𝑥12
=−
𝑢22
◎ This implies as we move along a negatively sloped indifference curve, with increasing the level of 𝑥1 and
reducing the level of 𝑥2 the rate of change in the slope increases and the indifference curves become flatter.
Which leads to convex to origin indifference curves along which marginal rate of substitution (𝑀𝑅𝑆21 ) falls.
◎ Thus second order condition actually implies that utility function is quasi concave.
Law of Diminishing MRS and Law of diminishing Marginal Utility:
◎ The law of diminishing marginal rate of substitution (DMRS) implies that indifference curves are
convex to origin or
𝑑 2 𝑥2 𝑢12 𝑢22 +𝑢22 𝑢11 −2𝑢1 𝑢2 𝑢12
◎ = − > 0 implying 2𝑢1 𝑢2 𝑢12 − 𝑢12 𝑢22 − 𝑢22 𝑢11 >0
𝑑𝑥12 𝑢23
◎ Law of diminishing marginal utility (DMU) implies that 𝑢11 and 𝑢22 are negative. Does
diminishing marginal utility leads to diminishing marginal rate of substitution? No, because even
if 𝑢𝑖𝑖 < 0, the sign of 𝑢𝑖𝑗 may be negative to make 2𝑢1 𝑢2 𝑢12 − 𝑢12 𝑢22 − 𝑢22 𝑢11 <0. Thus DMU does
not imply DMRS.
◎ Cardinal utility theory assumes that total utility is additively separable and utility derived form
each commodity is independent follows law of diminishing marginal utility. During the 19th
century and for much of the 20th century, many prominent scholars, including Jeremy Bentham
(1748–1832), thought that utility functions should provide cardinal information about preferences.
According to this view, people are “pleasure machines”—they use consumption goods as inputs
to produce utility as an output. Bentham and others argued that the aim of public policy should be
to maximize the total utility generated through economic activity.
◎ 𝐔 = 𝑵𝒊=𝟏 𝒖𝒊 (𝒙𝒊) , In this case as 𝒖𝒊𝒋=0, the DMU leads to DMRS.
12
◎
◎ Perfect complements:
13
Discrete good
14
Comparative Static Analysis
◎ Solving these n+1 first order conditions we get Marshallian demand function for commodities as a function
of prices and money income and preference pattern of the consumer:
◎ Properties: First, provided that p, M are finite and positive, the optimization problem must have a solution,
since the requirements of the Existence Theorem are satisfied.
◎ Second, the differentiability of the indifference curves and the linearity of the budget constraint imply that
the optimal bundle will vary continuously in response to changes in prices and income, and that the demand
functions are differentiable.
15
Third, the conditions of the Uniqueness
Theorem are satisfied and so the demand relationships are functions rather than
correspondences: a unique bundle is chosen at each (p, M) combination.
Finally, Marshallian demand curves are homogenous of degree zero in prices and income.
In general, a function is called homogeneous of degree k in a variables X, if 𝐹(𝜆𝑥1 , 𝜆𝑥2 ) = 𝜆𝑘 𝐹(𝑥1 , 𝑥2 )
if the particular case where 𝐹(𝜆𝑥1 , 𝜆𝑥2 ) = 𝐹(𝑥1 , 𝑥2 ).
is just the case where k = 0 so this is homogeneity of degree zero.
That is 𝐷𝑖 𝜆𝑝1 , 𝜆𝑝2 … … … . . 𝜆𝑝𝑛 , 𝜆𝑀 = 𝐷𝑖 (𝑝1 , 𝑝2 … … … . . 𝑝𝑛 , 𝑀)
16
Effect of Change in Income
17
Income Effect
For movement from x* to 𝑥 ′ to 𝑥 ′′ , both goods are normal.
If we consider movement from x* to 𝑥 + , commodity 1 is normal but
commodity 2 in inferior.
If we move from x* to 𝑥 0 , commodity 2 is normal but commodity 1 in
inferior.
All goods cannot be inferior. If the consumer reduces demand for all
goods when income rises he will be behaving inconsistently.
To show this, let x* be the bundle chosen with an initial money income of 𝑀1
and x′ the bundle chosen when money income rises to 𝑀2 . If x≪x* i.e. if the
demand for all goods is reduced, then x′ must cost less than x* since prices
are held constant. x′ was therefore available when x* was chosen. But when ◎
x′ was chosen x* was still attainable (since money income had increased).
The consumer therefore preferred x* over x′ with a money income of 𝑀1 and
x′ over x* with money income 𝑀2 >𝑀1 . He is therefore inconsistent: his ICC1
behaviour violates the transitivity assumption and our model would have to be
rejected.
18
Engel curve
19
Engel curve for perfect substitute: Income consumption curve (ICC) will be either
horizontal axis or along vertical axis depending on the prices.
20
Perfect complement goods where both goods are mixed at 1:1 ratio.
21
Cobb-Douglas Preferences
◎ For the case of Cobb-Douglas preferences it is easier to look at the algebraic form of the demand functions to see what the graphs
will look like. If
◎ 𝑈 = 𝑥1𝛼 𝑥21−𝛼
◎ 𝑥1 =
𝛼𝑀
𝑝1
◎ For a fixed value of 𝑝1 , this is a linear function of M. Thus, doubling M will double demand, tripling M will triple demand, and so on.
◎ In fact, multiplying M by any positive number t will just multiply demand by the same amount.
22
Quasilinear Preferences
◎ 𝑢 𝑥1 , 𝑥2 = 𝑣 𝑥1 + 𝑥2
◎ If preferences are quasilinear, we sometimes say that there is a “zero income effect” for good 1.
Thus the Engel curve for good 1 is a vertical line—as you change income, the demand for good 1
remains constant.
𝑥1
23
Effects of a Price Change
What happens when a commodity’s price
decreases?
– Substitution effect: the commodity is relatively cheaper, so
consumers substitute it for now relatively more than expensive other
commodities, while holding his real income constant
– Income effect: the consumer’s budget of M can purchase more than
before, as if the consumer’s income rose, with consequent income
effects on quantities demanded.
The income effect, which is the change resulting solely from the change in real
income, with relative prices held constant; and
The own substitution effect, which results solely from the change in p1 with real
income held constant.
Effects of a Price Change
x1
Effects of a Price Change
Consumer’s budget is M.
x2
Lower price for commodity 1
M pivots the constraint outwards.
p2
x1
Effects of a Price Change
x2
x1
Real Income Changes
x2
x1
Real Income Changes
x2
x1
Real Income Changes
x2
x1
Real Income Changes
x2
x1
Real Income Changes
x2
x1
Pure Substitution Effect
x 2’
x 1’ x1
Pure Substitution Effect Only (Slutsky Concept)
x2
x 2’
x 1’ x1
Pure Substitution Effect Only (Slutsky Concept)
x2
x 2’
Constant
Purchasing
power budget
line
x 1’ x1
Pure Substitution Effect Only (Slutsky Concept)
x2
Hypothetical
equilibrium on
Constant
x 2’ Purchasing
power budget
line
x2’’
x 1’ x1’’ x1
Pure Slutsky Substitution Effect Only
x2
x 2’
x2’’
x 1’ x1’’ x1
Pure Substitution Effect Only (Slutsky Concept)
x2 Lower p1 makes good 1 relatively
cheaper and causes a substitution
from good 2 to good 1.
x 2’
x2’’
x 1’ x1’’ x1
Pure Substitution Effect using Slutsky constant Purchasing power budget line Only
x2 Lower p1 makes good 1 relatively
cheaper and causes a substitution
from good 2 to good 1.
(x1’,x2’) (x1’’,x2’’) is the
x 2’
pure substitution effect.
x2’’
x 1’ x1’’ x1
And Now The Income Effect
x2
x 2’ (x1’’’,x2’’’)
x2’’
x 1’ x1’’ x1
And Now The Income Effect
x2 The income effect is
(x1’’,x2’’) (x1’’’,x2’’’).
x 2’ (x1’’’,x2’’’)
x2’’
x 1’ x1’’ x1
The Overall Change in Demand (Slutsky Concept)
x2 The change to demand due to
lower p1 is the sum of the
income and substitution effects,
(x1’,x2’) (x1’’’,x2’’’).
x 2’ (x1’’’,x2’’’)
x2’’
x 1’ x1’’ x1
Price effect using Hicksian compensated budget line
x2
x 2’
Hypothetical
budget line that
allows
consumer to
enjoy initial
level of utility
x 1’ x1
Pure Substitution Effect Only (Hicksian Concept)
x2 Hypothetical
equilibrium on
budget line that
allows
consumer to
enjoy initial
x 2’ utility level
x2’’
x 1’ x1’’ x1
Pure Hicksian Substitution Effect Only
x2
x 2’
x 2’
x 1’ x1’’ x1
Pure Substitution Effect Only (Hicksian Concept)
x2 Lower p1 makes good 1 relatively
cheaper and causes a substitution
from good 2 to good 1.
x 2’
x2’’
x 1’ x1’’ x1
Pure Substitution Effect using Hicksian constant utility budget line Only
x2 Lower p1 makes good 1 relatively
cheaper and causes a substitution
from good 2 to good 1.
(x1’,x2’) (x1’’,x2’’) is the
x 2’
pure substitution effect.
x2’’
x 1’ x1’’ x1
And Now The Income Effect
x2
x 2’ (x1’’’,x2’’’)
x2’’
x 1’ x1’’ x1
And Now The Income Effect
x2 The income effect is
(x1’’,x2’’) (x1’’’,x2’’’).
x 2’ (x1’’’,x2’’’)
x2’’
x 1’ x1’’ x1
The Overall Change in Demand ( Hicksian Concept)
x2 The change to demand due to
lower p1 is the sum of the
income and substitution effects,
(x1’,x2’) (x1’’’,x2’’’).
x 2’ (x1’’’,x2’’’)
x2’’
x 1’ x1’’ x1
Slutsky’s Effects for Normal Goods= Substitution effect+Income effect
x 2’ (x1’’’,x2’’’)
x2’’
x 1’ x1’’ x1
Slutsky’s Effects for Normal Goods
x 1’ x1’’ x1
Slutsky’s Effects for Normal Goods
x2
x 2’
x 1’ x1
Slutsky’s Effects for Income-Inferior Goods
x2
x 2’
x 1’ x1
Slutsky’s Effects for Income-Inferior Goods
x2
Slutsky
compensated
constant purchasing
x 2’ power
x 1’ x1
Slutsky’s Effects for Income-Inferior Goods
x2
x 2’
x2’’
x 1’ x1’’ x1
Slutsky’s Effects for Income-Inferior Goods
x2
The pure substitution effect is as for
a normal good. But, ….
x 2’
x2’’
x 1’ x1’’ x1
Slutsky’s Effects for Income-Inferior Goods
x2’’
x 1’ x1’’ x1
Slutsky’s Effects for Income-Inferior Goods
x 1’ x1’’ x1
Slutsky’s Effects for Income-Inferior Goods
x2
The overall changes to demand are
the sums of the substitution and
(x ’’’,x ’’’) income effects.
1 2
x 2’
x2’’
x 1’ x1’’ x1
Giffen Goods
x2 A decrease in p1 causes
quantity demanded of
good 1 to fall.
x 2’
x1’ x1
Slutsky’s Effects for Giffen Goods
x2 A decrease in p1 causes
quantity demanded of
good 1 to fall.
x2’’’
x 2’
x1’’’x1’ x1
Slutsky’s Effects for Giffen Goods
x2 A decrease in p1 causes
quantity demanded of
good 1 to fall.
x2’’’
x 2’
x2’’
x1’’’x1’ x1’’ x1
Substitution effect
Income effect
Slutsky’s Effects for Giffen Goods
𝑥1
Perfect Substitutes
76
Perfect Complements
◎
◎ The case of perfect
complements—the right and
left shoes example—is
◎ depicted in Figure . We know
that whatever the prices are, a
consumer will demand the
same amount of goods 1 and
2. Thus his offer curve will be
a diagonal line as depicted in
Figure
77
Demand Curves
78
The Marshallian constant money income demand curve
DD shows the effect of
◎ changes in p1 with M (and p2) held constant. It plots the
information contained in the price consumption curve. For
example, a fall in p1 from p″1 to p′1 with M constant
causes the consumer to shift from bundle x* to x′ and his
demand for x1 to rise from x*1 to x′1 .
79