Central Banking in Contemporary Capitali1
Central Banking in Contemporary Capitali1
Central Banking in Contemporary Capitali1
net/publication/254449160
CITATIONS READS
5 509
1 author:
Demophanes Papadatos
National and Kapodistrian University of Athens
8 PUBLICATIONS 34 CITATIONS
SEE PROFILE
All content following this page was uploaded by Demophanes Papadatos on 08 February 2019.
Discussion Paper no 5
Demophanes Papadatos
Department of Economics, School of Oriental and African Studies
15 February 2009
RMF invites discussion papers that may be in political economy, heterodox economics, and
economic sociology. We welcome theoretical and empirical analysis without preference for
particular topics. Our aim is to accumulate a body of work that provides insight into the
development of contemporary capitalism. We also welcome literature reviews and critical
analyses of mainstream economics provided they have a bearing on economic and social
development.
Submissions are refereed by a panel of three. Publication in the RMF series does not preclude
submission to journals. However, authors are encouraged independently to check journal policy.
Demophanes Papadatos Address: Department of Economics, Soas, Thornhaugh Street,
Russell Square, London, WC1H 0XG, Britain. Email: [email protected]
Research on Money and Finance is a network of political economists that have a track
record in researching money and finance. It aims to generate analytical work on the
development of the monetary and the financial system in recent years. A further aim is to
produce synthetic work on the transformation of the capitalist economy, the rise of
financialisation and the resulting intensification of crises. RMF carries research on both
developed and developing countries and welcomes contributions that draw on all currents
of political economy.
www.soas.ac.uk/rmf
Demophanes Papadatos ‐ Central Banking in Contemporary Capitalism: Inflation Targeting and Financial Crises 2
Abstract
Demophanes Papadatos ‐ Central Banking in Contemporary Capitalism: Inflation Targeting and Financial Crises 3
1. Introduction
Against this background the financial sector has been entirely transformed through rapid
growth, deregulation, global expansion, introduction of new technology, institutional
change and financial innovation. The weight of the financial sector has grown markedly in
developed countries in terms of employment, profits, size of institutions and markets.
Finance now penetrates every aspect of society in developed countries, and is becoming
increasingly important in the developing world (Lapavitsas, 2009).
However, with the surge in financial flows came a spate of currency and financial crises in
the late 1980s and 1990s. The importance of the central bank has increased as bubbles and
financial crises have become a regular feature of financialised capitalism, particularly since
their nature has varied significantly from the turmoil of the mid‐70s due to the
transformation of the financial system. Nevertheless, much ambiguity and confusion
surrounds the operations of the central bank in the new environment, even as it aims to
preserve the interests and social dominance of the capitalist class.
A first response to these trends by economic policymakers was to strengthen the monopoly
of the central bank over legal tender. The financial system became even more dependent on
using central bank money as obligatory means of payment for the settlement of debts. At
the same time, inflation targeting and central bank independence were also adopted.1 Since
the early 1990s inflation targeting has become the dominant (‘best practice’) monetary
policy paradigm in several high‐ and middle‐income countries.2 In addition to countries
that follow fully‐fledged inflation targeting policies, several dozen countries have adopted it
informally or implicitly, for example, by pursuing ‘inflation caps’ (maximum desired
inflation rates) in the context of IMF programmes. Such ‘caps’ are insufficient to define these
policy regimes as inflation targeting, but they are evidence of a medium‐term move towards
inflation targeting.
1 On how the central banks have strengthened their monopoly of legal tender in the era of financialisation, see Kneeshaw,
J.T. and Van den Bergh 1989.
2The following countries are full‐fledged inflation‐targeters: Australia, Brazil, Canada, Chile, Colombia, Czech Republic,
Hungary, Iceland, Israel, Mexico, New Zealand, Norway, Peru, Philippines, Poland, South Africa, Republic of Korea,
Sweden, Thailand and the United Kingdom (see Carare and Stone 2003 and Stone and Bhundia 2004).
Demophanes Papadatos ‐ Central Banking in Contemporary Capitalism: Inflation Targeting and Financial Crises 4
This paper discusses these developments by adopting a Marxist approach which stresses the
social and political aspects of central banking and their relation to class interests. It is shown
that the current financial crisis has also become a crisis of the monetary policy regime, while
revealing the class dimension of inflation targeting. Essentially, inflation targeting has been
an attempt to preserve financial interests at the expense of the vast majority of society. The
same underlying aims characterise recent mainstream proposals to move central bank policy
beyond inflation targeting. Devised partly in response to the current crisis, these proposals
stress the central bank’s function as lender of last resort and complement it by the novel
function of ‘market‐maker of last resort’. Such policies aim at using the power of the central
bank to socialise financial losses while defending private profits.
The paper first analyses the inflation targeting framework while advancing a political
economy critique of mainstream views of inflationary phenomena. It then analyses the
social relations characteristic of central banking by adopting a Marxist approach.
Specifically, the theory of central banking as “contested terrain” of class and intra‐class
conflict is subjected to critical analysis. Further, capital/labour and finance/industry
relations are examined in light of developments in the era of financialisation under the neo‐
liberal agenda. Finally, financialisation is analysed with regard to financial bubbles,
establishing connections between bubble‐bursting and sudden changes in monetary policy,
while demonstrating the relation of monetary policy changes to social and political interests.
Inflation targeting has been the dominant, ‘best practice’ monetary policy paradigm for
nearly two decades and until the emergence of the subprime mortgage crisis. Things have
now changed and several policymakers and economists argue that central banks must move
beyond inflation targeting.
Early indications of the demise of inflation targeting can also be detected in the previous
period. Thus, until the Asian crisis of 1997‐8, inflation targeting was implemented in its
original form, the primary focus of which was price stability. However, after the financial
crises of the 1990s, financial stability began to be considered as a goal for monetary policy of
equal, if not greater, importance to price stability. This contributed to a gradual weakening
of the exclusive focus towards price stability (Siklos, 2002, p.8). This gradual weakening of
the primary focus on price stability has encouraged a theoretical critique of inflation
targeting, which has supplemented older empirical critiques of its effectiveness.
Problems for inflation targeting appeared already in the early period of its implementation,
when conflicting conclusions came out of efforts empirically to measure its effectiveness.
Several studies identified presumed gains regarding the rate, volatility and inertia of
inflation, improved expectations, faster absorption of adverse shocks, lower sacrifice ratio
(the output cost of reducing inflation), output stabilisation, and convergence of poorly
performing towards well performing countries.3 However, other studies were more critical
of the effectiveness of inflation targeting. They claimed that there is no convincing evidence
that inflation targeting improves economic performance as measured by the behaviour of
3See, for example, Bernanke, B.S. and M. Gertler 1999a , Debelle, G. Masson, P. Savastano, M, Sharma S 1998, Mishkin and
Schmitt‐Hebbel 2001.
Demophanes Papadatos ‐ Central Banking in Contemporary Capitalism: Inflation Targeting and Financial Crises 5
inflation, output or interest rates, and it may even lead to a deterioration of some indicators,
especially unemployment.4
These conflicting conclusions are partly due to the different approaches and econometric
methodologies used in various studies. Yet, the divergence of assessment is also due to
deeper reasons. There are strong indications that the performance of most OECD countries
has improved in terms of inflation, unemployment, output volatility and interest rates
during the last ten to fifteen years. These improvements are evident in both inflation
targeting and non‐inflation targeting countries, which suggests that the underlying cause is
something other than inflation targeting.
In the words of Arestis and Sawyer (2006, p.24): “Both inflation targeting and non‐inflation
targeting countries performed over the inflation targeting period equally well. The average
rate of inflation and its variance have been reduced in both periods. This is true for both
inflation targeting and non‐ inflation targeting countries … We may conclude … by
suggesting that on the basis of the average inflation and GDP growth rates performance,
there is not much difference between inflation targeting and non‐ inflation targeting
countries … Consequently, inflation targeting has been a great deal of fuss about really very
little!”
The degree to which the central bank is formally accountable for meeting this target varies.
In New Zealand, for example, the law links the tenure of the central bank governor to the
inflation target whereas in other countries there are no legal or explicit sanctions. At the
institutional level, inflation targeting is usually associated with changes in the law, which
enhance the independence of the central bank from the elected government.6 Some
economists draw a distinction between goal independence and instrument independence
(Debelle, Guy, and Stanley Fisher, 1996). This distinction may not mean very much in
practice because the two kinds of independence are complementary – enhancing one kind of
independence necessarily implies enhancing the other (Bernanke and Mishkin, 1997, p.102).
Advocates of inflation targeting insist that, at the level of the government, the policy
institutionalises ‘good’ (i.e., orthodox) monetary policies, while increasing the transparency
and accountability of the central bank and providing guidelines for other government
policies. 7 Apparently, inflation targeting also helps to shape private sector expectations,
4See, for example, Agenor 2001, Cecchetti and Ehrmann 1999, Chang and Grabel 2004, pp.183‐4, and Neuman and von Hagen
2002, pp. 149‐153.
5 See Mishkin and Schmidt‐Hebbel, 2001, p.3; Bernanke, Ben S., Thomas Laubach, Adam S. Posen and Frederic S. Mishkin
1999.
6 Bernanke and Mishkin, 1997, p.102; Mishkin and Schmidt‐Hebbel, 2001, p.8.
7 See however, Aybar S and Harris, L (1998, pp. 20‐38) for a critique from a radical political economy perspective.
Demophanes Papadatos ‐ Central Banking in Contemporary Capitalism: Inflation Targeting and Financial Crises 6
thereby reducing uncertainty and the costs associated with the necessary adjustment to the
new, low inflation regime. The implication is that other economic policy objectives – such as
employment generation, economic growth and income distribution – should be
subordinated to inflation targeting. Inflation targeting, therefore, came to dominate all
economic policymaking for nearly two decades. It reinforced the neoliberal view that
government intervention in the economy is either useless or counterproductive, and that
inflation is largely due to fiscal deficits, adverse expectations and lack of policy credibility.
It is worth examining a little more closely the economic model that underpins inflation
targeting. The model is very simple and includes two key parameters: the inflation target
and expectations of inflation. The former is set by the government, while the latter arise
from the private sector. The model also includes one discretionary policy instrument: the
nominal interest rate. In this light, the main objective of the central bank is to eliminate the
difference between the rate of inflation and the inflation target at some point in the future
(the ‘policy horizon’, usually set at between one and three years).
The model presumes that inflation is jointly determined by the inflation expectations of the
private (mainly financial) sector and the output gap, explained below. The rate of
unemployment presumably fluctuates around the NAIRU: when unemployment is below
(above) the NAIRU, it leads to higher (lower) inflation.8 The output gap (expressed as the
difference between the current rate of unemployment and the NAIRU) is determined by the
level of real interest rates. High real interest rates raise the output gap, while low interest
rates stimulate economic activity and reduce the gap. Finally, the real interest rate is, by
definition equal to the nominal interest rate minus inflation expectations. The central bank
attempts to hit the inflation target by manipulating the nominal interest rate in order to
influence expectations and, at a further remove, fine tune the level of aggregate demand.
Thus, the model and its policy implications are based on two underlying claims. First, that
persistent unemployment is essentially voluntary (natural), since involuntary (true)
unemployment is a transitory phenomenon. Second, that attempts to lower unemployment
below its ‘natural’ rate will trigger inflation, and perhaps even create accelerating inflation.
In short, inflation targeting is based on the notion that there is an empirical trade‐off
between inflation and unemployment. Yet, there is little evidence that this is true.
Drawing on empirical evidence, Shaikh (1997) has made three points to the contrary. First,
for much of the post‐war period, the rise in average unemployment levels in OECD
countries was directly associated with a fall in average output growth rates. Second, there is
no general historical trade‐off between unemployment and inflation in OECD countries.
8The NAIRU (non‐accelerating inflation rate of unemployment) derives from the monetarist concept of the ‘natural rate of
unemployment’ (NRU).The NRU is the unemployment rate at which all markets, including the labour market, are in
equilibrium. The NAIRU is defined as the unemployment rate compatible with stable inflation in the long‐run (if the
economy is operating below the NAIRU, inflation will presumably accelerate and vice versa).
Demophanes Papadatos ‐ Central Banking in Contemporary Capitalism: Inflation Targeting and Financial Crises 7
Such a trade‐off might have existed during 1975‐1991, but the very opposite pattern seems to
hold for the period 1964‐1974. Third, inflation appears to be related to economic growth,
namely lower growth is associated with higher inflation.
Shaikh’s Marxist critique is consistent with the views of other authors within Marxist
political economy.9 Inflationary trends exhibit little homogeneity within capitalist
economies, and are often associated with processes that the state cannot immediately and
effectively control. A fuller understanding of both inflation and inflation targeting from a
Marxist perspective, therefore, requires placing these phenomena within a specific social
and historical context.
The regime of inflation targeting is a product of historical development. After the collapse
of the Bretton Woods system in the early 1970s the ability of the main central banks to
exercise discretionary power over the rate of interest increased greatly. Monetary policy
started to acquire its present historical significance because of the attenuation, or complete
absence, of foreign exchange reserve discipline on the central banks. The rate of interest has
acquired the character of an instrument of public policy, and a multitude of often
contradictory demands has been placed on central banks regarding interest rate
manipulation. Typically these demands have included price stability, a satisfactory level of
economic activity and a balance of payments outlook compatible with high growth and
employment. However, the absence of gold discipline, after the collapse of the Bretton‐
Woods system, only served to emphasise the anarchical nature of the international capitalist
system by encouraging exchange rate instability, price inflation and financial speculation.
The collapse of the Keynesian ideology of full‐employment and the emergence of rapid
inflation in the 1970s gradually made price stability the primary objective of monetary
policy. Thus, Dumenil (2007, p.7) notes that the structural crisis of capitalism, beginning in
the 1970s, created the conditions for the reassertion of the hegemony of finance. The rise of
finance was combined with a broad set of other practices: deregulation, direct confrontation
with the worker movement and unions, a policy favourable to large mergers, and new
methods of corporate governance favourable to the interests of shareholders. For Dumenil,
neoliberalism is a new phase of capitalism, also signalling the return of finance to
hegemony.
The state has played an instrumental role during these transformations. Historically there
have been two primary and one secondary function of the state in relation to capital
accumulation. The primary functions are, first, securing the labour system and, second,
securing the money system. The secondary function is mediating the contradictory interests
of different parts of capital. The primary functions are critical to accumulation but cannot
be guaranteed by capital itself (De Brunfoff, 1976). The necessity of the state to secure the
labour and the money system is due to the very nature of capitalism. On the other hand, the
state’s mediating role derives historically from the anarchy of market‐based interactions.10
10Marx’s first mention of the state in Capital is in relation to the production and distribution of coin, which is “an attribute
proper to the state”. The same point is made in relation to paper currency (Marx 1976, p. 223, 227)
Demophanes Papadatos ‐ Central Banking in Contemporary Capitalism: Inflation Targeting and Financial Crises 8
As a state (or semi‐state) institution, the central bank has varied greatly throughout history
depending on the structure of the financial system, its connections with real accumulation,
the social and political relations mediated by finance, and the past practice of interventions.
The role of the central bank during the Bretton Woods era, for example, was the historical
result of the great depression of the 1930s as well as the emergence of the Keynesian
ideology of full employment. In the period of neoliberalism, which signalled the reassertion
of the power of finance, the major event was the change of monetary policy in 1979,
targeting monetary policy overwhelmingly toward price stability. The Volcker coup in the
USA took place primarily because of the experience of the stagflationary period of the 1970s
(Mayer, 2003), and eventually led to the triumph of inflation targeting.
Since the collapse of the Bretton Woods system, contemporary money has become
overwhelmingly credit money resting on central bank money (banknotes and deposits)
which is in turn backed primarily by state instruments of debt. Central banks have been
freed from the need to guard their gold reserves. Consequently, they have acquired fuller
discretion in making loans, in issuing their own money and, above all, in determining
interest rates. Under these conditions, stability of the value of central bank money has come
to depend on two factors: first, on the central bank’s management of aggregate credit flows
and, second, on central bank money being legal tender for the settlement of commercial and
other debts.
The Marxist approach proposed here has common features with radical post‐Keynesian
treatments of central banking. Post‐Keynesian economics pays particular attention to
conflicting interests and especially to class and intra‐class struggles as determinants of
central banking. Central banking is seen as “contested terrain” in economy and society. 11
Four key factors determine monetary policy, namely the structure of the labour market,
connections between finance and industry, the position of the national economy in the
world economy, and the position of the central bank in the state apparatus.
11 See Epstein and Schor (1986, 1988, 1989, 1990), and Epstein (1992).
Demophanes Papadatos ‐ Central Banking in Contemporary Capitalism: Inflation Targeting and Financial Crises 9
approach sheds necessary light on the various crises during the era of financialisation,
including that of 2007‐9.
To be more specific, with regard to relations between capital and labour, Epstein (1992)
distinguishes between what he calls the “Kaleckian” and the “neo‐Marxian” approach.12 The
latter posits a negative relationship between employment, capacity utilisation and profit
shares. As the economy expands and unemployment falls, workers gain the power to raise
real wages, or to improve working conditions, with the result of lowering productivity. Thus,
as capacity utilisation increases, unit labour costs increase and industrial profit share falls.
In contrast, the “Kaleckian” approach suggests that increased capacity utilisation reduces
competition and gives firms market power, thus allowing firms to increase their mark‐ups.
Consequently, industrial profit share rises as capacity utilisation increases or, at worst,
remains constant. Thus, the “Kaleckian” labour market postulates a non‐negative relation
between employment, capacity utilisation and profit share.
It is notable that neither of these approaches sheds much light on labour markets in the
current regime of financialisation. Ultimately this is because Epstein (1992, p.7) defines the
structural characteristics of labour markets by focusing on a very narrow aspect of the
capital‐labour relationship, namely the effect of changes in capacity utilisation (and thus of
the “reserve army” of the unemployed) on capital’s profit share. But the structure of
contemporary “financialised” labour markets has been determined partly by technological
change, partly by regulatory change, and partly by bouts of unemployment at key junctures
of the period of financialisation.
In the course of financialisation, as Lapavitsas (2009) notes, there has been a rebalancing of
paid and unpaid labour, while information technology has encouraged the contraction of
private time as well as piece work and putting out practices. These changes have effectively
led to an increase in the working day. Moreover, it is also likely that labour has been
intensified. From the extensive literature on job satisfaction, for instance, it transpires that
work intensification associated with new technology is a key reason for dissatisfaction with
work in developed countries, together with loss of discretion over work choices counting for
a deterioration of their living standards. Finally, the process of work has also been critically
affected by institutional changes in the labour market. This includes casualisation of labour
and entry of women in the labour force which effectively increased the working population.
Thus, the fluidity of labour has increased at the cost of greater insecurity of workers.
12 Neo‐Marxism includes authors such as, Boddy & Crotty 1975; Schor 1985;Goldstein 1986; Schor and Bowles 1987;
Weisskopf 1988; Bowles and Boyer 1989; Bowles, Gordon, and Weisskopf, 1989.
The importance of this point can also be seen in connection with the “contested terrain”
approach. According to that, the primary concern of the central bank is to keep monetary
policy out of the hands of labour. But it is also argued that, when industrial and financial
capitalists are strongly divided, central bank independence often serves to keep monetary
policy out of the hands of industrial capital. In this case, the central bank tends
disproportionately to favour financial, or ‘rentier, interests.14 This means that there is space
for political alliances between labour and the industrial fraction of the capitalist class to
defeat the financial fraction.
It is important to note that Epstein (2002, p.17) has recently argued that: “There seems to be
further evolution in these class interests. Increasingly, in the United States and, probably
Europe, rentier and industrial interests may be merging, but not as in the case of old
German and Japanese financial structures (Zysman, 1984; Pollin, 1995; Grabel, 1997) where
industrial interests dominate finance. Rather, it may increasingly be the case that with the
deregulation of financial markets ‐ that is, with financialisation ‐ industrial enterprises
themselves are beginning to be increasingly guided by rentier motives. In short,
“financialisation” may have changed the structure of class relations between industry and
finance, making their interests much more similar”
In this connection, Marxist work shows that the foundations of the “contested terrain” are
flawed and the analysis has to be reconsidered (Lapavitsas, 1997a, pp. 85‐106). First, it
implies the existence of pure ‘functioning’ capitalists who possess investment projects but
no money. This is an ideally abstract assumption: In practice borrowing capitalists typically
possess some of their own capital plus some that they borrow. Second, revenue in the form
of interest tends also to accrue to industrial and commercial capitalists, and it is not the
exclusive foundation of a separate social group, such as financial capitalists. The separate
and often opposing interests of lending and borrowing capitalists cannot be fully analysed in
terms of the functioning‐industrial section of the capitalist class confronting the financial‐
monied section.
To recap, financial institutions have continued to make profits despite the problems faced
by real accumulation during the period of financialisation. Consequently, the significance of
the financial system has increased enormously, since under such conditions finance has
become a source of profits for the capitalist class as a whole. Meanwhile, capital‐labour
14 See Epstein and Ferguson 1984, pp. 957‐983; Epstein 1992, pp. 1‐30.
Demophanes Papadatos ‐ Central Banking in Contemporary Capitalism: Inflation Targeting and Financial Crises 11
relations have been rebalanced with an eye to keeping central bank “immune” from the
influence of class struggles. The implication is that, in the era of financialisation, the central
bank is not “contested terrain” but the primary defender of financial interests. This is clear
in the context of financial crises, considered below.
4.1 The false belief that low inflation guarantees financial stability
The policy of inflation targeting has been eventually rendered redundant by the emergence
of major financial instability in the course of financialisation. It has taken some time for this
development to become clear, including several episodes of financial instability in the 1990s
and the gigantic crisis of 2007‐9.
The period of rapid inflation in the 1970s and 1980s was followed by nearly two decades of
stability in terms of prices, output volatility and interest rates. The mainstream attributed
these outcomes to monetary policy that focused on inflation targeting (Bernanke 2004). It
did not take long for the false view to emerge that price stability also guaranteed general
financial stability. On this basis, the central bank only had to concern itself with keeping
inflation low, and the financial sector could look after itself.
Schwartz (1988, pp. 33‐62 1998, pp. 34‐41) has been the main advocate of the view that price
stability guarantees financial stability, also shared by Bernanke and Gertler (1999a, pp.
18‐51). Relying on earlier work with Friedman (Friedman and Schwartz 1963), Schwartz
argued that the major threat to financial stability, especially for the banking sector, comes
from unexpected changes in the rate of inflation. Therefore, by promoting price stability, the
central bank “will do more for financial stability than reforming deposit insurance or
reregulating” (Schwartz, 1998, p. 38). If the central bank focused on low inflation, it would
apparently reduce the chances of lending booms (induced by high inflation) and recessions
(induced by unexpected deflation or disinflation). The “Schwartz Hypothesis” has been
tested by mainstream economists, who found a positive “association”, not causation,
between price instability and financial instability (meaning bank panics).15
These views are transparently fallacious, but they rest on ideological and political
considerations. The inflationary crises of the 1970s and 1980s represented failure to defend
the value of credit money. That failure had social and political implications, at the very least
because rapid inflation meant losses for creditors and because wage bargaining was
disrupted as workers attempted to obtain compensating increases in money wages. The
adoption of inflation targeting and central bank independence was a sign of the ability of
the capitalist class to learn from this experience.
Thus, the convenient legal fiction of independent central banking was created, separating
the electoral process from monetary policy. The latter was apparently to be determined by
disinterested and class‐neutral experts on “objective technical grounds”. Financial interests
were assured that inflation – which is deeply damaging to them – would not be tolerated.
Financial bubbles, on the other hand, were seen as irrelevant to central banking, and even
declared unlikely if inflation was kept low. In effect, financial interests were told that the
central bank was not going to intervene in their speculations, while protecting them from
high inflation.
15 See Bordo, Dueker and Wheelock (2000) and Bordo and Wheelock (1998, pp. 41‐62).
Demophanes Papadatos ‐ Central Banking in Contemporary Capitalism: Inflation Targeting and Financial Crises 12
4.2 The significance of bubbles and financial crises
The emergence and burst of financial bubbles in the 1990s has undermined inflation
targeting, while showing the limits of contemporary central banking. Bubbles are
unsustainable, continuous increases in financial asset prices. They result from a climate of
optimism, which is fostered by rises in financial prices and leads to further price rises, thus
creating the phenomenon of asset price inflation. In an asset price bubble, consumers and
enterprises tend to over‐borrow. Rises in asset prices may also lead to a misallocation of
resources through time. There might be excessive capital accumulation in the short term,
for example, followed by an extended period of overcapacity. In this context, it becomes very
difficult for the central bank to set monetary conditions in a way that deals with changing
expectations regarding to the future pace of capital accumulation. As a result, there is
greater risk of policy error.
It is important to note that in all countries that suffered financial bubbles during the last
fifteen years, inflation was either low in absolute terms, or low relative to its earlier history
(King, 1999). In each case, the emergence of an asset price bubble was closely correlated
with apparent success in lowering inflation, an achievement much prized by the advocates
14
12
10
‐2
1980Q1 1983Q1 1986Q1 1989Q1 1992Q1 1995Q1 1998Q1 2001Q12004Q1 2007Q2
US Japan
Source: Bloomberg
Demophanes Papadatos ‐ Central Banking in Contemporary Capitalism: Inflation Targeting and Financial Crises 13
of the so‐called ‘Great Moderation’. This is not to exclude the fact that sometimes low
inflation was only a temporary phenomenon associated with a beneficial external shock, for
instance, in the UK in the late 1980s (King, 1999, 10‐18). Still, bubbles tend to emerge in
conditions in which inflation remains under control.
It is clear from Figure 1, for instance, that Japan’s inflation rate in the 1980s remained at very
low levels. Even when it rose toward the end of the decade, it remained lower than that of
Japan’s competitors. Put another way, for much of the late 1980s, Japan would have easily
met most of the inflation targets currently in use. Very low interest rates in Japan in the
second half of the 1980s went together with low and stable inflation as well as rapid rises in
equity and land prices.
Moreover, when asset prices started to fall, Japanese monetary authorities failed to recognise
the dangers this posed for the economy. Expectations of future growth collapsed, and
industrial enterprises were left with excessive debt levels that prompted a slow move toward
deflation. Yet, the relative stability of inflation at the time gave policymakers an unjustified
level of confidence in the underlying health of Japanese capitalism. The Japanese experience
shows that catastrophic asset price bubbles can be consistent with pursuing low inflation.
The US experience in the late 1990s and more recently is a similarly good example of this
phenomenon. On this basis, it is probable that financial bubbles tend to develop when
inflationary pressures are low and, as a result, central banks feel comfortable with levels of
interest rates that eventually prove too low.
Furthermore, bubbles tend to develop when periods of low inflation are accompanied by
strong expansion of the domestic money supply (see Figures 3, 4, and 5). A temporary
Demophanes Papadatos ‐ Central Banking in Contemporary Capitalism: Inflation Targeting and Financial Crises 14
absence of price pressures allows central banks to tolerate excess money growth for an
extended period of time. A common rationalisation is that monetary expansion is not
problematic, if it reflects financial innovation. Thus, strong growth of money could in
practice lead to rapidly rising asset prices which, in turn, enable borrowers to offer
increasing collateral on loans, apparently lowering risk for lenders.
14
12
10
‐2
1980Q1 1982Q4 1985Q4 1988Q4 1991Q3 1994Q2 1997Q11999Q4 2002Q4 2005Q4
Figure 5 ‐ British M4 Money Supply Year on Year Change (percent), 1983Q3 ‐ 2008Q4
20
16
12
0
1983Q3 1986Q2 1989Q1 1991Q4 1994Q3 1997Q2 2000Q1 2003Q12005Q4 2008Q4
Demophanes Papadatos ‐ Central Banking in Contemporary Capitalism: Inflation Targeting and Financial Crises 15
Figure 4 ‐ German Money Supply (M3) Year on Year Change (percent), 1980Q1 ‐ 2008Q4
16
14
12
10
‐2
1980Q1 1983Q1 1986Q1 1989Q1 1992Q1 1995Q1 1998Q1 2001Q12004Q1 2007Q2
Source: Bloomberg
Finally, it is common for traditional risk assessment and valuation models used by financial
institutions to break down in the course of a bubble. This phenomenon has been particular
pronounced during the US bubble of 2001‐7. Technological progress and financial
innovations made it possible for banks to manage their liabilities more efficiently and
therefore more profitably. Instruments such as derivatives, transactions of securities, money
trust, insurance, as well as a variety of other services related to open markets encouraged
banks to turn toward financial market mediation. Also other activities, such as lending for
mortgages, consumer loans, credit cards and so on, which turn banks toward the personal
revenue of workers, became very prominent (Lapavitsas, 2009). A climate of optimism
fostered a huge asset bubble, contributed to lack of proper risk assessment, and eventually
led to burst. Low inflation offered no protection against the ensuing disaster.
To mitigate the consequences of bubbles bursting, central banks have tended to shift their
focus pragmatically, effecting emergency changes in monetary policy. This practical
response has been prepared by analytical work, such as McGee (2000) and Bean (2003, pp.
787‐807), arguing that price stability offers no guarantee of financial stability. Along similar
lines, Borio and Lowe 2002 have claimed that, if financial imbalances in the economy are
pronounced, there is a strong possibility of financial instability triggered by price stability.
Therefore they proposed the so‐called ‘flexible approach to inflation targeting’. This has
found some support from Mervyn King, the Governor of the Bank of England, arguing that
monetary policy may need to be tightened in response to rising asset prices, even if inflation
is not rising significantly.
The problem is that in a capitalist economy it is very hard to distinguish at an early stage
between a bubble and a period of lasting improvements in productivity performance.
Demophanes Papadatos ‐ Central Banking in Contemporary Capitalism: Inflation Targeting and Financial Crises 16
Moreover, technological revolutions are often used to justify extended gains in asset prices.
It is historically documented that technological revolutions often give rise to bubbles.16 This
means that an initial expansion in economic activity based on productivity growth can give
way to unsustainable bubbles as money supply begins to increase and asset prices rise to
exceptionally high levels.
A case in point is the response of the Federal Reserve under Alan Greenspan to the so‐called
New Economy stock market bubble and the subsequent housing bubble in the USA.
Greenspan chose to restrain neither the former nor the latter. He declared himself right not
prick the equity bubble of the 1990s, allowing it to burst by itself and then ‘mopping up’ the
mess through lower interest rates. Greenspan justified his action on the grounds that one
can never be sure that what looks like a bubble really is a bubble. Apparently, he could not
use interest rates to ‘prick’ the bubble, because interest rates affect the economy more like a
sledgehammer than a scalpel. A modest rise in interest rates would be unlikely to halt rising
prices, but an increase sufficient to pop the bubble would slow the whole economy and
could even cause a recession. On this basis Greenspan concluded that it was safer to wait for
a bubble to burst by itself and then to ease monetary policy to soften the downturn.
In practice, Greenspan allowed financial interests to make enormous profits during the
bubble in the hope that the costs of the burst would not be unmanageable. It was taken for
granted, of course, that these costs would be passed on to society as a whole. Thus, inflation
targeting has gradually come to acquire the aspect of protecting private profits in a bubble,
while socialising losses during the burst. This approach led to disaster in 2007‐9.
The crisis of 2007‐9 has thrown inflation targeting in turmoil. As was previously explained,
the policy can be characterised as the epitome of sophisticated monetarism, which emerged
primarily because of the experience of the stagflation of the 1970s (Mayer, 2003). The policy
limits the central bank to pursuing a low inflation target subject to broad rules, while
downplaying the traditional function of lender of last resort.
Imposing the rule of targeting inflation rule can be quite restraining on the central bank.17
Since the capitalist economy develops dynamically, any rule which limits discretion by the
central bank is necessarily static. The recent crisis has shown that the dynamic evolution of
finance in the era of financialisation has undermined what was considered the greatest
achievement of inflation targeting regimes, namely central bank credibility. Thus,
mainstream economists are at present advocating renewed emphasis on the function of
lender of last resort (De Grauwe, 2007, pp. 159‐161). Others have proposed complementing
that with market making of last resort (Buiter and Sibert, 2007).
The crisis of 2007‐9 has manifested itself primarily as turmoil in financial markets.
Uncertainty and fear, which easily extended to panic, meant that little or no trade occurred
in certain classes of financial instruments. Subprime‐backed Collateralised Debt
Obligations, for instance, were often impossible to trade as there was no market maker
capable of valuing the necessary funds credibly to establish buying and selling prices. Such
market failures occurred in different ways across financial assets, including exchange‐traded
17Even when it is perceived as ‘constrained discretion’, as in the USA, which allows for stabilisation of output and
employment subject to a declared target range for inflation. See Bernanke, 2003.
Demophanes Papadatos ‐ Central Banking in Contemporary Capitalism: Inflation Targeting and Financial Crises 17
and over‐the‐counter instruments. But a common solution has been suggested: the central
bank should be the market maker of last resort. The function of market maker of last resort,
could involve, first, outright purchases and sales of a wide range of private‐sector securities
and, second, acceptance of a wide range of private‐sector securities as collateral (Buiter and
Siebert, 2007, p. 171‐172).
But extending the function of the lender of last resort and complementing it with the
function of the market‐maker of last resort would be far from easy. First, severe moral
hazard problems could arise as central banks substituted public credit for bankrupt private
credit. On this basis, Vives (2008, p.99) has even argued that the outbreak of crises might be
desirable to maintain investment discipline. It is even postulated that some barely solvent
institutions should not be rescued.18 Second, it is possible that as central banks acquire
problematic private securities, their own solvency might become problematic (Buiter 2008).
Thus, it is proposed that the state (as national fiscal authority) should provide ultimate
support for the central bank acting as lender and market maker of last resort. One way of
doing this would be for the state explicitly to underwrite the balance sheet of the central
bank.
From the Marxist perspective adopted in this paper, the proposals are evidence of the
central bank being used to socialise losses in order to protect private profits. Central bank
independence and inflation targeting have allowed repeated bubbles to emerge, partly
because of low inflation rates. The ensuing disaster has led to renewed emphasis on lender
of last resort supplemented with the novel function of market maker of last resort.
Financialisation has turned central banks into the main agent protecting financial interests
at the expense of society as a whole.
4. Conclusion
Inflation targeting and central bank independence have aimed at promoting capitalist
accumulation at the expense of working people by “immunising” central bank from the
effects of class struggle. Inflation targeting and central bank independence have facilitated
extraction of private profits at the cost of increased financial instability with enormous
ensuing losses for society. Capitalist states now recognise that central banking must go
beyond inflation targeting to protect the capitalist system from itself, without however
18 From a different perspective Dickens (1990, pp. 1‐23 1999, pp. 379‐398) argued that financial instability is a problem
created by the dynamics of the capitalist market reflecting the contradictions of capitalist accumulation. Financial crises
are primarily due to political decisions and are political in nature.
Demophanes Papadatos ‐ Central Banking in Contemporary Capitalism: Inflation Targeting and Financial Crises 18
abandoning the neo‐liberal agenda. This has meant renewed emphasis on the function of
lender of last resort supplemented with the newly‐fangled function of market maker of last
resort. In practice this amounts to socialising financial losses in an effort to preserve private
financial profits. Nonetheless, the crisis of 2007‐9 has shown that there are limits to what
central banks can do to stabilise finance.
As the burden of financial instability has become greater for the vast majority of society, the
need for central banks to be subject to democratic control has become clearer. Through
social control, central banks should be made to reflect the broader interests of workers and
others, rather than primarily those of banks and finance. Central banking is often called an
art, but it should certainly not be an art for the benefit of the few.
Demophanes Papadatos ‐ Central Banking in Contemporary Capitalism: Inflation Targeting and Financial Crises 19
References
Agenor P.R 2001, ‘Monetary Policy under Flexible Exchange Rates: An Introduction to
Inflation Targeting’, working papers, Central Bank of Chile 124.
Aybar Sedat and Harris, L 1998, How credible are credibility models of central banking? in P.
Arestis and M.Sawyer (eds), The Political Economy of Central Banking, Edward Elgar.
Bagehot Walter. 1978 [1873], ‘Lombard Street’, in vol. 9 of The Collected Works of Walter
Bagehot, St John‐Stevas, N. (ed), London: The economist.
Ball L. and Sheridan, N 2003, ‘Does Inflation Targeting Matter?’, IMF Working Paper 03/129.
Bean C. 2003, ‘Asset prices, financial imbalances and monetary policy: Are inflation targets
enough?’ Revue d’ Economie Politique, 110, 6: 787‐807.
Bernanke Ben S, and Frederic S. Mishkin 1997, ‘Inflation targeting: a new framework for
monetary policy?’ Journal of Economic Perspectives 11, 2: 97‐116.
Bernanke B.S. and M. Gertler 1999a, ‘Monetary policy and asset price volatility’, Federal
Reserve Bank of Kansas City Economic Review, 4: 18‐51.
Bernanke Ben S., Thomas Laubach, Adam S. Posen and Frederic S. Mishkin 1999, Inflation
Targeting: Lessons from the International Experience. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University
Press.
Bernanke Ben.S. 2003, ”Constrained Discretion” and Monetary Policy, Remarks by Governor
Ben.S.Bernanke before the Money Marketeers of New York University, available in
www.federareserve.gov/Boarddocs/2003/20030203/default.htm.
Bernanke Ben.S. 2004, ‘The Great Moderation’, Remarks by Governor Ben.S.Bernanke at the
meetings of the Eastern Economic Association, Washington, DC February 20, available in
www.federareserve.gov/Boarddocs/2004
Bordo M.D. and D.C.Wheelock 1998, ‘Price stability and financial stability: The historical
record’. FRBSL Review, 80, 4:41‐62.
Bordo M.D, M. J.Dueker, and D.C.Wheelock 2000, ‘Aggregate price shocks and financial
instability: A historical analysis’. The Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, working paper
2000‐005B.
Borio C.E.V. and P Lowe, 2002, ‘Asset prices, financial and monetary stability: Exploring the
nexus’, Bank of International Settlements, working paper 114.
Boddy Radford and James Crotty 1975, ‘Class Conflict and Macro Policy: The Political
Business Cycle’, Review of Radical Political Economics 7, 1: 1‐19.
Demophanes Papadatos ‐ Central Banking in Contemporary Capitalism: Inflation Targeting and Financial Crises
20
Bowles Samuel and Robert Boyer 1989, ‘Labour Discipline and Aggregate Demand’, American
Economic Review 78, 2: 395‐400
Bowles Samuel, David M. Gordon and Thomas Weisskopf, 1989, ‘Business ascendancy and
Economic Impasse: A Structural Retrospective of Conservative Economics, 1979 ‐1987’, Journal
of Economic Perspectives 3, 1: 107‐134.
Buiter Willem and Sibert Anne 2007, The central bank as the market‐maker of last resort:
from lender of last resort to market‐maker of last resort, in Τhe First Global Financial Crisis
of the 21st Century, (eds) Andrew Felton and Carmen Reinhart, A VoxEU.org Publication,
Center for Economic Policy Research (CERP)
Buiter Willem 2008, ‘Can Central Banks Go Broke?’, Policy Insight, no.24, Center for
Economic Policy Research (CERP)
Carare A. and Stone M. 2003, ‘Inflation Targeting Regimes’, IMF Working paper, 03/9
Cecchetti S.G. and Ehrmann M. 1999, ‘Does Inflation Targeting Increase Output Variability?
An International Comparison of Policymakers preferences and Outcomes’, NBER Working
Paper No.7426.
Chang H.‐J. and Grabel I 2004, Reclaiming Development: An Alternative Economic Policy
Manual. London: Zed Books.
Debelle Guy, and Stanley Fisher 1996, ‘How independent should a central bank be?’, In
Goals, Guidelines, and Constraints Facing Monetary Policy makers, ed. Jeffrey Fuhrer: FRB of
Boston Conference Series 38.
De Grauwe Paul 2007, ‘There is more to central banking than inflation targeting’, in Τhe
First Global Financial Crisis of the 21st Century, (eds) Andrew Felton and Carmen Reinhart, A
VoxEU.org Publication, Center for Economic Policy Research (CERP)
Dickens E, 1990, ‘Financial Crises, innovations and federal reserve control of the stock of
money’, Contributions to Political Economy, 9:1‐23.
De Brunhoff S 1976, The State, Capital and Economic Policy, London: Pluto Press
Dos Santos Paulo 2008, ‘On the content and Contradictions of Financialised Commercial
Banking’, mimeo
Dumenil G 2007, ‘Neo‐liberalism under US Hegemony: The Crisis of the late 2000s’, Paper
presented in the conference, ‘A Crisis of Financialisation?’ SOAS, 30 May 2008, available at
www.soas.ac.uk/events/event43769
Demophanes Papadatos ‐ Central Banking in Contemporary Capitalism: Inflation Targeting and Financial Crises 21
Epstein G 1992, ‘Political Economy and Comparative Central Banking’, Review of Radical
Political Economics’, 24:1‐30.
Epstein G 2002, ‘Financialisation, Rentier Interests and Central Bank Policy’, Paper prepared
for PERI conference on ‘Financialization of the World Economy’, December 7‐8, 2001,
University of Massachusets, Amherst.
Epstein G and Ferguson T 1984, ‘Monetary Policy, Loan Liquidation and Industrial conflict:
The Federal Reserve and the open market operations of 1932’, Journal of Economic History,
44:957‐983.
Epstein G and Schor. J 1986, The Political Economy of Central Banking, Harvard Institute for
Economic Research, Discussion Paper No.1281.
Epstein G and Schor. J 1988, ‘The Determinants of Central Bank Policy in Open Economies’,
In Monetary Theory and Central Banking, Bruno Jossa and Carlo Panico (eds.). pp. 225‐264,
Naples, Italy:Liguori Press
Epstein G and Schor. J 1989, ‘The Divorse of the Banca D’ Italia and the Italian Treasury: A
case Study of Central Bank Independence’. In State, Market and Social Regulation: New
Perspectives on the Italian Case. Peter Lange and Marino Regini (eds.). New York Cambridge
University Press.
Epstein G and Schor. J 1990, ‘Macropolicy and the rise and Fall of the Golden Age’, In, The
Golden Age of Capitalism: Reinterpreting the Postwar experience, Stephen Marglin and Juliet
Schor (eds.). New York: Oxford University Press.
Friedman Milton and Schwartz, Anna 1963, A Marxist History of the United States 1867‐1960,
Princeton N.J. Princeton University Press.
Goldstein John 1986, ‘Mark‐up variability and flexibility: Theory and Empirical Evidence’,
Journal of Business 59: 599‐621.
Grahl John 1998, ‘Emergency Changes In Monetary Policy’, in P.Arestis, S.Daniel and J.Grahl
(eds) ‘Adjustment, Convergence and Economic Policy: Essays in macroeconomics in honor of
Bernard Corry and Maurice Peston’, Edward Elgar.
Kindleberger. P. C (1989) Manias, Panics, and Crashes: A History of Financial Crises, Revised
Edition, Basic Books, New York.
King Stephen (1999) ‘Bubble Trouble: The US bubble and how it will burst, HSBC Economics
& Investment Strategy.
Kneeshaw J.T. and Van den Bergh 1989, ‘Changes in Central Bank money market operating
procedures in the 1980s’, BIS Economic Papers, no.23.
Lapavitsas C & Itoh M 1999, Political Economy of Money and Finance, Macmillan: London.
Lapavitsas C 1991, ‘The Theory of Credit Money: A Structural Analysis’, Science & Society, 55,
3: 291‐322.
Demophanes Papadatos ‐ Central Banking in Contemporary Capitalism: Inflation Targeting and Financial Crises
22
Lapavitsas C. (1997a), ‘Two Approaches to the Concept of Interest‐Bearing Capital’,
International Journal of Political Economy, 27:85‐106.
Lapavitsas C. 1997b, ‘The Political Economy of Central Banks: Agents of stability or Sources of
Instability?’, International Papers in Political Economy.
McGee R. 2000, ‘What Should a Central Bank Do?’ , Department of Economics, Florida State
University, mimeo.
Meyer Thomas 2003, ‘The Monetarist Policy Debate: An informal Survey’, Department of
Economics, University of California, Davis, working paper, 03‐9.
Mishkin Frederic S 1999, ‘Inflation Experiences with Different Monetary Policy Regimes’,
Journal of Monetary Economics 43:579‐605.
Mishkin Frederic S. and Claus Schmidt‐Hebbel 2001, ‘One decade of Inflation Targeting in the
World: What do We Know and What do we need to Know?’ NBER Working paper, 8397
Neumann M.J.M. and von Hagen, J 2002, ‘Does Inflation Targeting Matter?’, Federal Reserve
Bank of St. Louis Review 84:149‐153.
Painceira Juan Pablo 2008, ‘Developing countries in the Era of Financialisation: From Deficit
Accumulation to Reserve Accumulation’, mimeo.
Saad‐Filho, A 2000, ‘Inflation Theory: A Critical Literature Review and a New Research
Agenda’ in Paul Zarembka (ed) Value, Capitalist Dynamics and Money, Vol.18, pp.335‐362.
Saad‐Filho, A and Mollo, M.L.2002, ‘Inflation and stabilisation in Brazil: a political economy
analysis, 34, pp.109‐135.
Shaikh Anwar 1997, ‘The Challenge of Marxian Economics to Neoliberal Economic Theory’,
Paper presented at the Conference on Contemporary Economic Theory: Critical
Perspectives, Athens University of Economics and Business, October 6‐7.
Schwartz A.J. 1988, ‘Financial stability and the safety net’, In Haraf, W.S. and R.M.
Kushmeider (eds) Restructuring Banking and Financial Services In America, 34‐62.
Washington, D.C.: American Enterprise Institute For Public Policy and Research.
Schwartz A.J 1998, ‘Why financial stability depends on price stability’, In Wood G. (ed.)
Money, Prices and the Real Economy, 34‐41. Northampton: Edward Elgar.
Demophanes Papadatos ‐ Central Banking in Contemporary Capitalism: Inflation Targeting and Financial Crises
23
Schor Juliet 1985, ‘Wage Flexibility, Social Wage Expenditures and Monetary
Restrictiveness’, In Money and Macro Policy. Mark Jarsulic (ed.). pp. 135‐154. Boston: Kluwer‐
Nijhoff.
Schor Juliet and Samuel Bowles 1987, ‘Employment Rents and the Incidence of Strikes’,
Review of Economics and Statistics 59: 584‐592.
Siklos, L.P. 2002, The Changing Face of Central Banking: Evolutionary Trends since World
War II, Cambridge University Press, U.K.
Stone, M. and Bhundia, P. 2004, ‘A new taxonomy of monetary regimes’, IMF Working paper,
04/191
Vives, Xavier 2008, ‘Bagehot, central banking and the financial crisis’, in ‘Τhe First Global
Financial Crisis of the 21st Century’, (eds) Andrew Felton and Carmen Reinhart, A VoxEU.org
Publication, Center for Economic Policy Research (CERP)
Weisskopf, Thomas 1988, ‘The analysis of a Neo‐Marxian Crisis Theory’. The Economic
Review 39:193‐208.
Demophanes Papadatos ‐ Central Banking in Contemporary Capitalism: Inflation Targeting and Financial Crises
24