Caamano-Alegre & Lago-Penas 2013
Caamano-Alegre & Lago-Penas 2013
Caamano-Alegre & Lago-Penas 2013
ABSTRACT The aim of this paper is to shed additional light on the determinants of
budget transparency in local governments. Our work is based on a Likert-type survey
questionnaire specifically designed to measure budget transparency in small municipa-
lities. The questionnaire is based on the IMF’s revised Code of Good Practices on Fiscal
Transparency (2007). Results from 33 Galician municipalities are used to assess its
internal consistency and to test a battery of hypotheses on the determinants of budget
transparency. While several previous findings of the literature are confirmed, some new
results are also obtained.
1. Introduction
Despite a recent upsurge in popularity, concerns regarding budget transparency
have a long tradition. The establishment of representative democracies through-
out the Western world brought with it a resistance to the secrecy that had
previously been the norm in governmental accounting. At the time, budget
transparency was closely linked to notions of executive accountability and
principles of clarity in budgeting.
However, in recent decades the term has been widely adopted by policy
makers and popular media, and its meaning has evolved. Budget transparency
is not just an element of governmental accountability to Parliament, but rather a
tool for facilitating a relationship between public budgeting and market require-
ments, civil society demands and citizen participation.
Table 1. The “three pillars” of the OECD Best Practices for Budget Transparency
standards outlined in the last three pillars of the IMF Code, viewed as an updated
and less detailed version of the OECD Best Practices.
Transparency in public financial management is also receiving increased
attention in public administration, political science and economics research.
Empirical research focuses primarily on testing the benefits of fiscal transpar-
ency. This is the case of the work by Alt and Lassen (2006) focused on the
effects of fiscal transparency on the accumulation of public debt in OECD
countries. When dealing with endogeneity problems of transparency as
regressor, they also find that measures of political competition, presidential
system and common law variables do well in explaining variation in trans-
parency, whereas debt level has no statistically significant effect5.
A more direct analysis of transparency determinants is presented in Alt,
Lassen and Rose (2006). Based on work by Hanssen (2004), the authors
hypothesise that budgeting practices will be more transparent in systems
marked by high political competition. In situations of high political turnover,
incumbents will try to tie the hands of their potential successors (partisan
adversaries) by reinforcing arrangements for transparency. In a similar vein,
political polarisation increases transparency; however, a more polarised polity
could impede a cohesive reform policy and thus become a hindrance to
transparency. To these political but nonpartisan explanations, a partisan
hypothesis is added that Democratic incumbents are more prone than
Republicans to increase transparency, because of the greater transparency
required for directing additional resources toward expand the public sector6.
Along with political variables, the authors also note that financial outcomes
may positively or negatively impact transparency. Incumbents may restrict
access to information in order to avoid blame for poor fiscal performance, or
facilitate information access to get credit for a favourable fiscal record. To test
these theories, the authors construct an annual transparency score for the
years between 1972–2002 using questionnaire data from budget officers in
all 50 U.S. states. The authors then construct the following equation for
estimating fiscal transparency:
The authors find that political competition tends to increase the level of
fiscal transparency, whereas polarisation appears as positively or negatively
related to transparency depending on the regression specifications. A
Democratic legislature is positively associated with transparency when con-
trolling for the effects of debt, fiscal imbalance, and polarisation; the same
occurs when using an Arellano-Bond first-difference GMM estimation of the
main equations rather than fixed effects. Higher levels of debt are associated
with lower transparency, while fiscal imbalance (in the form of higher
surpluses or deficits) appears to contribute to greater transparency.
According the authors, this “conjunction of debt and deficit results suggest
that a deficit motivates reform more where the stock of debt is lower, that
is, where the deficit more resembles a surprise or ‘crisis’” (Alt, Lassen and
Rose 2006, p. 47).
Esteller-Moré and Polo-Otero (2008) combine political competition vari-
ables with tax pressure (proxied by the property tax rate) to explain fiscal
transparency using data from Catalonian municipalities. The study also
includes electoral participation, population size, and percent elderly as control
variables. The resultant fiscal transparency indicator is a measure of municipal
accountability, specifically, the timely submission of the following nine docu-
ments to the region’s Supreme Auditing Institution: (i) opening budget, (ii)
budget liquidation, (iii) budgetary results, (iv) closed years’ budget liquida-
tion, (v) cash flow statement, (vi) cash flow remainder, (vii) balance sheet,
(viii) result statement, and (ix) debt statement. Unfortunately, this indicator
does not account for the accuracy of the documents, and tends to behave
almost as a dichotomous variable, given that the most of municipalities
confront the submission of such documents as an all-or-nothing decision7.
Nevertheless, the indicator is objective and available for a series of consecu-
tive years and for a substantial number of municipalities. Logistic model
estimation results confirm that electoral competition has a positive impact
on fiscal transparency, whereas per capita debt has a negative impact. Among
the control variables, electoral participation promotes fiscal transparency,
while population negatively affects transparency, but only for the large muni-
cipalities (defined as those with more than 5,000 inhabitants).
3. Empirical analysis
3.1. Questionnaire design and municipal governments surveyed
To measure budget transparency in Galician municipalities, we designed a
survey questionnaire composed of 15 items based on the second, third and
fourth pillars of the IMF’s revised Code of Good Practices on Fiscal
Transparency (2007). Items one through five correspond to the second
pillar (open budget processes), items six through ten to the third (public
availability of information), and items 11 through 15 to the fourth pillar
Budget Transparency in Local Governments 187
MUNICIPAL GOVERNMENT:..............................................................................................................
GOVERNMENT OFFICIAL
(position of the surveyed):.......................................................................................................................
INSTRUCTIONS:
Please indicate your level of agreement with the following statements as they pertain to your
municipality: 5 indicates strong agreement, 4 agreement, 3 neither agree nor disagree, 2 disagreement
and 1 strong disagreement.
Fully disagree Fully agree
Table 2. (Continued ).
MUNICIPAL GOVERNMENT:..............................................................................................................
GOVERNMENT OFFICIAL
(position of the surveyed):.......................................................................................................................
INSTRUCTIONS:
Please indicate your level of agreement with the following statements as they pertain to your
municipality: 5 indicates strong agreement, 4 agreement, 3 neither agree nor disagree, 2 disagreement
and 1 strong disagreement.
Fully disagree Fully agree
Thus, in order to determine whether ITA is optimal, we should begin by using one
of the many factor-analytic techniques currently available to make sure that there are
no large departures from unidimensionality (Cortina 1993, p. 103). Taking into
account the low number of observations, several principal component analysis
tests confirmed that the instrument effectively was mainly unidimensional9.
In a second step, we evaluate internal consistency by examining inter-item
correlations, item-total correlations and Cronbach’s alpha. This classical
approach was used for the following reasons: (i) it is easily computable in
standard statistical packages; (ii) it compensates for the limited sample size by
providing a synthetic measure based on all correlation matrix elements; and (iii)
as multidimensionality would increase the underestimating bias of Cronbach’s α,
a high α is a reliable indicator of internal consistency10.
Prior to inter-item correlation analysis, the Kolgomorov-Smirnov test on normal-
ity of data was performed. According to results, the hypothesis of normal distribu-
tion should not be rejected (p-value < 0.05). Thus, the relationships among items can
be measured through a Pearson correlation coefficient11, as shown in Table 4.
190 J. Caamaño-Alegre et al.
1 A Estrada
2 A Pobra do Caramiñal
3 Ames
4 Baltar
5 Betanzos
6 Bueu
7 Caldas de Reis
8 Calvos de Randín
9 Cambados
10 Cangas
11 Castro Caldelas
12 Cedeira
13 Lugo
14 Marín
15 Moaña
16 Mondariz
17 Monforte de Lemos
18 Mos
19 Oroso
20 Ortigueira
21 Padrón
22 Poio
23 Ponteareas
24 Pontevedra
25 Redondela
26 Ribadavia
27 Riveira
28 Santiago de Compostela
29 Sarria
30 Teo
31 Tui
32 Verín
33 Vilagarcía de Arousa
ITEM 1 ITEM 2 ITEM 3 ITEM 4 ITEM 5 ITEM 6 ITEM 7 ITEM 8 ITEM 9 ITEM 10 ITEM 11 ITEM 12 ITEM 13 ITEM 14
correlated with total and the only ones whose deletion causes an increase in
α. Although these increases are not considerable, the correlation of item 8
with the average of the other items is lower than the normal rule of thumb
cited by Steiner and Norman (1995), of at least 0.20. It suggests that item 8 is
not reflecting only budget transparency but also financial management sophis-
tication. Indeed, we expected a peculiar behavior in this item because most
Galician municipalities have not yet developed a performance management
approach, but other practical considerations led us to maintain the item.
Finally, internal consistency of our three subscales was also evaluated by
the alpha coefficient, obtaining the following values: Open Budget Processes
(items 1 to 5), 0.649; Public Availability of Information (items 6 to 10),
0.674; and Assurances of Integrity (items 11 to 15), 0.748. While these
values are lower than the total alpha for all 15 items together, they can be
considered adequate for subscales with a limited number of items. Corrected
item-total correlation and alpha if item deleted were also computed for each
subscale, in order to examine the consistency of each item with the subscale
as a whole. Again, item 8 is the only item whose correlation with the average
of the remaining items of its subscale is lower than 0.2. This result is
consistent with those of an additional PCA/FA on our subscales, according
to which all of the second subscale’s items besides item 8 loaded onto a
single factor.
12
10
8
Frequ en cy
Mean = 2.5778
Std. Dev. = 0.65737
N = 33
0
1.00 2.00 3.00 4.00
MEAN
Figure 1. Survey results distribution.
Insofar as this score is below 3, the average perception resulting from the survey
is like a fail grade in budget transparency. Descriptive statistics by item are
shown in Table 6.
The elements perceived as more transparent are those covered by items 12 and
14. Both items are proxies for the observance of public procurement regulations
and the pre-audit coverage. At the opposite extreme, the less transparent areas are
those represented by items 8, 9, and 3: efficiency analysis prior to approval of
spending programs, citizen participation in budget making, and periodic submis-
sion of spending information. This last result is easily understandable: while the
Spanish Local Finances Act (TRLHL) requires access to information on budget
execution, the definition is left up to each municipal government, leading to a
nearly total negligence of this obligation.
Item 8 has the lowest standard deviation of any item (0.747), suggesting that
municipalities rarely conduct efficiency analysis prior to the approval of
194 J. Caamaño-Alegre et al.
spending programs. The mean item score is 1.39, with a minimum possible score
of 1. The highest standard deviations are those for items 5 (1.444), 7 (1.331), and
1 (1.293), which suggests a certain heterogeneity among municipalities with
regard to the budget liquidation, arrears and non-accounted invoices, timeliness
of budget making and openness to the opposition.
Based on the survey results, a fiscal transparency index is constructed in order
to rank the 33 municipalities with regards to transparency. The index is calcu-
lated by summing the scores recorded for all survey items. So,
X
General Transparency Index ¼ Xi ½2
1 Lugo 62 18 Tui 39
2 Monforte de Lemos 56 19 Oroso 38
3 Rivadavia 52 20 Santiago de Compostela 37
4 Ortigueira 50 21 Moaña 36
5 A Estrada 47 21 Calvos de Randín 36
5 Padrón 47 23 Redondela 35
5 Riveira 47 24 Marín 32
8 Pontevedra 44 25 Baltar 31
8 Cedeira 44 25 Cambados 31
8 Caldas de Reis 44 25 Cangas 31
11 A Pobra do Caramiñal 43 28 Bueu 30
11 Poio 43 29 Mos 27
13 Castro Caldelas 42 30 Betanzos 24
13 Sarria 42 30 Verín 24
13 Teo 42 32 Mondariz 21
16 Ames 40 33 Ponteareas 19
16 Vilagarcía de Arousa 40
● T: Positive. When the tax burden is higher, the taxpayers’ demand for budget
transparency is stronger19.
● PART: Positive. A higher voter turnout would indicate that citizens have a
stronger interest in government activities (La Porte, Demchak and Jong 2002:
428; Esteller-Moré and Polo-Otero 2008)20.
● COAL: Ambiguous. While Alt, Lassen and Rose (2006) argue that coalitions
lead to greater transparency, Lago-Peñas and Lago-Peñas (2010) show that
more political parties corresponds to less electoral control over incumbents.
● LEFT: Positive. Leftist incumbents are more likely to increase revenues to
expand public services, and therefore face the greater transparency require-
ments from the public21.
Budget Transparency in Local Governments 197
● ENPP: Positive. According to Alt, Lassen and Rose (2006), incumbents will
be more likely to increase transparency when leaving office, in order to tie the
hands of their successor.
X
n X
m X
p
PTIji ¼ αj þ βhj Xhji þ δhj Whji þ γhj Zhji þ εji ðwith j ¼ 1; 2; 3Þ
h¼1 h¼1 h¼1
½4
(4)
Independent variable (1) (2) (3) (dy/dx)
Notes: Robust t-statistics (columns 1 and 2) or z-statistics (column 3) are in parentheses, below the
coefficients. In column (4) dy/dx is the marginal effect computed with all variables held at their mean
values (QMLE coefficients). R2 is the coefficient of determination.***p < 0.01, **p < 0.05, *p < 0.1.
3.4.2. Econometric methods and results. Equations [3] and [4] are estimated
using Ordinary Least Squares. Given that several tests (White, Breusch-Pagan-
Godfrey, Cook-Weisberg) detected the presence of heteroskedasticity, standard
errors are replaced by White robust errors in the case of specification [3] and
clustered errors by municipality in the case of specification [4]. Multicollinearity
is not a serious concern according to the so-called “Klein’s rule”.
In both cases, the Ramsey’s RESET test is computed23. Specification errors
may be discarded at usual significance levels in all cases. Goodness of fit
significantly increases when moving form specification [3] (R2 = 0.549) to
specification [4] (R2 = 0.959). Results are not reported. Normality of residuals
was also confirmed performing the Jarque-Bera test.
We also tested the endogeneity of some of the right-hand variables using a
graphical display of the cumulative sum (CUSUM) of the recursive residuals
associated with a specific ordering of cross-sectional data (de Luna and
Budget Transparency in Local Governments 199
Notes: Robust t-statistics (column 1) or z-statistics (column 2) are in parentheses, below the
coefficients. In column (3) dy/dx is the marginal effect computed with all variables held at their
mean values (QMLE coefficients). R2 is the coefficient of determination.***p < 0.01, **p < 0.05,
*p < 0.1.
200 J. Caamaño-Alegre et al.
15
10
–5
–10
–15
12 14 16 18 20 22 24 26 28 30 32
CUSUM 5% Significance
15
10
–5
–10
–15
12 14 16 18 20 22 24 26 28 30 32
CUSUM 5% Significance
15
10
–5
–10
–15
12 14 16 18 20 22 24 26 28 30 32
CUSUM 5% Significance
and the third partial indexes. Finally, ENPP is only relevant in the case
of PTI1.
Using the marginal effects computed with QMLE for the global index, we can
compare the relative quantitative relevance of the most significant variables. The
effect of LEFT is strong: leftist governments tend to enjoy transparency levels
12.46 points higher than more conservative governments. Coalition incumbents
reduce its transparency by 8.75 points. The unemployment rate reduces global
transparency by 2.91 points. An unitary increase in the effective number of
political parties increases the global index by 6.51, but the standard deviation
of this variable is low (0.55). Finally, the marginal effect of BAL is very small but
the standard deviation is large (more than three times the mean). Hence, its effect
is also important in some cases.
4. Concluding remarks
From a methodological standpoint, our first conclusion is that relying on
subjectivity-laden data from internal sources does not necessarily suppose
an overoptimistic bias in transparency scores. Second, results made clear
the necessity of a more in-depth examination of the survey questionnaires’
dimensionality and internal consistency. Certain features of the budgetary
Budget Transparency in Local Governments 203
process may be attributes of more than one latent variable, rather than
reflecting only budget transparency.
Finally, while some of our empirical results on the determinants of budget
transparency confirm previous findings, others point to new relationships. This is
the case for the statistical significance of unemployment, the negative relation-
ship between coalitions and transparency, and the positive impact of debt on the
first partial transparency index. This last result stands in contrast to the negative
effect reported by Alt, Lassen and Rose (2006) and Esteller-Moré and Polo-Otero
(2008), and the negative influence of deficit on transparency. This contrast could,
however, have a suitable explanation. While debt may have been accumulated
during past fiscal stresses and not to be attributable to the current or previous
government, deficit supposes a recent and even ongoing fiscal stress. Thus, our
results may be suggesting that governments are more prone to enhance transpar-
ency when inheriting a heavy fiscal burden (high debt) and enacting sound
spending policies (low deficit).
Acknowledgements
We are grateful to Philip Whiteman and one anonymous referee for their
insightful comments. The usual disclaimer applies. The research was financially
supported by the Spanish Ministry of Science and Innovation (ECO2010-
15553).
Notes
1. In this article, the word “scale” usually refers to “an instrument made up of multiple
items that have a relationship to each other as well as to the concept of interest
[budget transparency, in our case]” (Colton and Covert 2007, p. 249). A Likert scale
is a scale composed of Likert-type items, as we explain in subsection 3.1. Although
there are precedents for using Likert-type items in measuring budget transparency at
the national level (Lavielle, Pérez and Hofbauer 2003, Pérez 2005), leading studies
on determinants of budget transparency have tended to rely on the above-mentioned
kinds of data.
2. According to Colton and Covert (2007, p. 68), content validity is the degree to which
an instrument is representative of the topic and process being investigated.
3. For instance: (i) inclusion of comparative and non-financial information, (ii) explana-
tion of deviations, (iii) consistency in format between the budget and the final report,
(iv) issuing of monthly reports within four weeks, and (v) audit and issuing of the
year-end report within of six months.
4. The second pillar also requires “clear mechanisms for the coordination and manage-
ment of budgetary and extra-budgetary activities within the overall fiscal policy
framework”. The third and fourth pillars incorporate innovative provisions such as:
i) publication of a periodic report on long-term public finances;
ii) openness in purchase and sale of public assets;
iii) mechanisms to monitor follow-up actions recommended by the national auditor;
iv) assessment of the fiscal forecasts, the macroeconomic forecasts, and their under-
lying assumptions by independent experts; and
v) institutional independence of the national statistical body.
204 J. Caamaño-Alegre et al.
5. See also Jarmuzek (2006). Although he does not detail the effects of his instrumental
variables on fiscal transparency, the variables used in the model include a political
competition index (i.e. past turnover), the rule of law, and the media freedom index
compiled by the Freedom House.
6. The authors base this hypothesis on model implications from Ferejohn’s (1999).
7. As Islam (2006, p. 154) acknowledges, transparency indicators “could be strength-
ened by considering not just the frequency and availability of data but also the quality
of the data produced by governments.”
8. Although we are well aware of the threats that public corporations and other entities
depending on a municipality may pose to fiscal transparency, these issues have been
considered beyond the scope of the more restricted notion of budget transparency
adopted in our empirical research. All in all, revenues and expenditures of the
autonomous bodies or agencies depending on a municipality are included in the
consolidated budget of local governments. Regarding public corporations, only three
of the municipalities under study have any of them.
9. Plotting the magnitude of the successive eigenvalues and applying the Cattell’s
(1966) Scree test, a sharp drop in eigenvalues from component one is observed.
10. Within a hierarchical factor model framework, Zinbarg et al. (2005) demonstrate that α
underestimates reliability in the first three of four theoretical scenarios: (1) unidimen-
sional scales with unequal general factor loadings, (2) multidimensional scales with
equal general factor loadings, and (3) multidimensional scales with unequal general
factor loadings. Only in the fourth case, unidimensional scales with equal general factor
loadings – i.e., essential tau equivalence – is α as appropriate as ω to measure
reliability. Vehkalahti, Puntanen and Tarkkonen (2006, p. 2) also use alpha’s under-
estimating bias to justify the search for and proposal of a new estimator suggesting that
this estimator, called Tarkkonen’s rho, provides a better alternative for Cronbach’s α.
11. According Revelle (2010, p. 216), the correlations associated with an ordinal scale are
not Pearson’s but Spearman’s. However, Garson (2008) explains that ordinality in
Likert scales refers only to an ordinal relationship of values within a single item:
Likert response values are ordinal within any given item but sets of Likert items are not
necessarily ordinal with respect to each other, and they can be used to form indexes.
12. When calculated from the correlation matrix (Table 4), a standardised alpha of 0.849 is
obtained – the same could be calculated from the covariance matrix by standardizing and
summing all items in the scale. In our case, the raw alpha provided by SPSS (0.850) is
practically equal to the standardised alpha. In Table 5, raw alphas from SPSS are reported.
13. Although the widely-accepted social science criterion is that alpha should be 0.70 or higher
for a set of items to be considered a scale, and even a lenient cut-off of 0.60 is common in
exploratory research, many researchers require a score of 0.80 for a “good scale” (Garson
2008, 2010). On the other hand, a high alpha may also suggest a high level of item
redundancy, wherein essentially the same item is rephrased in several different ways (Boyle
1991). Thus, for example, Fitzpatrick et al. (1998, p. 23) consider that alpha values should
not be higher than 0.9 for scales which are used as research tools to compare groups. A very
high α suggests that there is some redundancy among items, and the possibility that the
items together are addressing a rather narrow aspect of an attribute.
14. In particular, we detected a high correlation between aging, population size, munici-
pal public expenditure over municipal GDP, and per capita GDP. Youth migrate from
backward municipalities in terms of GDP, bringing about both the ageing and
reduction of total population. Insofar as local expenditure is partially financed by
equalisation grants, the public expenditure/GDP ratio tends to be higher in the
backward municipalities. Dropping per capita GDP and ageing from the specification
substantially reduced multicollinearity among the independent variables.
15. Alt, Lassen and Rose (2006) find a non-significant effect. Esteller-Moré and Polo-Otero
(2008) obtain a negative effect, but only for municipalities with over 5,000 inhabitants.
Budget Transparency in Local Governments 205
16. LaFaive (2009) detects a negative relationship between unemployment and the
transparency of a Michigan’s program for economic development. However,
Peixoto (2010) finds no correlation between the US states’ levels of unemployment
and the transparency of their recovery websites. Moreover, Andersen and Nielsen
(2010, p. 28) suggest that the extremely damaging nature of procyclical fiscal policies
during recessions may trigger reforms that increase the degree of fiscal transparency.
Other studies on transparency also consider unemployment (Alt, Lassen and Skilling
2001, Rosendorff and Vreeland 2009), but not as a determinant of transparency.
17. In Alt, Lassen and Rose’s (2006) empirical analysis, the resulting sign is positive for
imbalance (both surplus and deficit), implying that a greater deficit leads to greater
fiscal transparency.
18. La Porte, Demchak and Jong (2002) fail to obtain empirical support for their hypothe-
sised positive effect of government size on openness, although in some of their tests
the “government size” variable does not remain after removing accounting for obvious
collinearity. Bastida and Benito (2007, p. 690–691) observe that the relative size of
central government presents a low significant (p-value = 0.079) negative relationship
(–0.260) with budget transparency. According to the authors, although the study
shows that larger central governments are linked to lower levels of transparency, the
low significance prevents using the evidence to draw a strong conclusion.
19. Alt, Lassen and Rose (2006) find that per capita general revenues are not significant
in most estimates. In Esteller-Moré and Polo-Otero (2008) taxes are only significant
at 10% in a cluster model, with the expected positive sign.
20. Although La Porte, Demchak and Jong (2002) find no empirical support for the hypothe-
sized impact of democracy on web site openness, they appear not include the “voting”
variable in testing. Esteller-Moré and Polo-Otero (2008), however, confirm a positive
relationship between electoral participation and fiscal transparency, and Rosendorff and
Vreeland (2009) do the same for democracy and transparency. Finally, Bastida and
Benito (2007, p. 690) find no significant correlations between their democratic-level
variables and budget transparency, although they suggest that the direction of the
relationships supports the notion that greater levels of political and civil liberty corre-
spond to higher fulfilment of the OECD Best Practices for Budget Transparency.
21. As pointed out in the above mentioned section, Alt, Lassen and Rose’s (2006)
econometric analysis corroborates this positive relationship when controlling for the
effects of debt, fiscal imbalance, and polarisation, as well as when using an Arellano-
Bond GMM first-difference estimation of their main equations. By contrast, Esteller-
Moré and Polo-Otero (2008) find the variable is not significant, and Bastida and Benito
(2007, p. 692) do not find any relationship between ideology and budget transparency.
22. Variables defined as those with a t-statistic below unity (in absolute value) in the first
step: 4 variables in the case of equation [3] and up to 13 variables in the case of [4].
A Wald test on the joint significance of those variables clearly failed to reject the null
hypothesis in both cases (p-values = 0.73 and 0.42, respectively)
23. RESET is a general test for the following types of specification errors: Omitted variables,
incorrect functional form, and correlation between the exogenous variables and the random
term which may be caused by measurement error or simultaneity, among other things.
24. Following a referee’s suggestion, we also included the rate of female aldermen in the
council as explanatory variable in specification [3], but it was not statistically
significant (p-value > 0.50). In this sense, it is interesting to note that Piotrowski
and Van Ryzin (2007) find that this variable is relevant to explain the demand for
safety transparency, but not to explain differences in fiscal transparency.
References
Alesina, A. and Angeletos, G.M., 2005. Corruption, inequality and fairness. Journal of
Monetary Economics, 52 (7), 1227–1244.
206 J. Caamaño-Alegre et al.
Alt, J.E. and Lassen, D.D., 2006. Fiscal transparency, political parties, and debt in OECD
countries. European Economic Review, 50, 1403–1439.
Alt, J.E., Lassen, D.D., and Rose, S., 2006. The causes of fiscal transparency: evidence
from the U.S. states. IMF Staff Papers, 53, 30–57.
Alt, J.E., Lassen, D.D., and Skilling, D., 2001. Fiscal transparency, gubernatorial popu-
larity, and the scale of government: evidence from the States. EPRU Working Paper
Series, 16. Copenhagen: Economic Policy Research Unit, University of Copenhagen.
Andersen, A.L. and Nielsen, L.H.W., 2010. Fiscal transparency and procyclical fiscal
policy. EPRU Working Paper Series, 1. Copenhagen: Economic Policy Research Unit,
University of Copenhagen.
Bastida, F. and Benito, B., 2007. Central government budget practices and transparency:
an international comparison. Public Administration, 85 (3), 667–716.
Blöndal, J.R., 2006. Budget transparency: experiences from OECD countries. Meeting of
Senior Budget Officials from Latin American Countries, Santiago de Chile, 25 January.
Boyle, G.J., 1991. Does item homogeneity indicate internal consistency or item redundancy
in psychometric scales? Personality and Individual Differences, 12 (3), 291–294.
Caixanova, 2008. Atlas socioeconómico de Galicia 2008. Vigo: Caixanova.
Cattell, R.B., 1966. The scree test for the number of factors. Multivariate Behavioral
Research, 1 (2), 245–276.
Colton, D. and Covert, R.W., 2007. Designing and constructing instruments for social
research and evaluation. San Francisco: Jossey-Bass.
Cortina, J.M., 1993. What is coefficient alpha? An examination of theory and applications.
Journal of Applied Psychology, 78 (1), 98–104.
Cronbach, L., 1951. Coefficient alpha and the internal structure of tests. Psychometrika,
16 (3), 297–333.
DeCoster, J., 2004. Data Analysis in SPSS. Available from http://www.stat-help.com/spss.pdf
De Luna, X. and Johansson, P., 2008. Graphical diagnostics of endogeneity. In: D.
Millimet, J.A. Smith, and E. Vytlacil eds. Advances in econometrics 21 (modelling
and evaluating treatment effects in econometrics. Amsterdam: Elsevier, 147–166.
Esteller-Moré, A. and Polo-Otero, J., 2008. Analysis of the causes of fiscal transparency:
Evidence from Catalonian municipalities. Unpublished paper.
Ferejohn, J., 1999. Accountability and authority: toward a theory of political account-
ability. In: A. Przeworski, S.C. Stokes and B. Manin, eds. Democracy, accountability
and representation, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 131–153.
Fitzpatrick, R., et al., 1998. Evaluating patient-based outcome measures for use in clinical
trials. Health Technology Assessment, 2 (14), i–74.
Garson, G.D., 2008. Scales and standard measures [online]. Available from: http://faculty.
chass.ncsu.edu/garson/PA765/standard.htm [Accessed 22 April 2010].
Garson, G.D., 2010. Reliability analysis. Available from: http://faculty.chass.ncsu.edu/
garson/PA765/reliab.htm
Hanssen, F.A., 2004. Is there a politically optimal degree of judicial independence?
American Economic Review, 94, 712–729.
Heald, D., 2003. Fiscal transparency: concepts, measurement and UK practice. Public
administration, 81 (4), 723–759.
Heald, D., 2006. Varieties of transparency. In: C. Hood and D. Heald, eds. Transparency:
the key to better governance? Oxford: Oxford University Press, 25–43.
Hood, C., 2006. Transparency in Historical perspective. In: C. Hood and D. Heald, eds.
Transparency: the key to better governance? Oxford: Oxford University Press, 3–23.
IMF, 2007a. Code of good practices on fiscal transparency (2007) [online]. Washington,
DC: International Monetary Fund. Available from: http://www.imf.org/external/np/pp/
2007/eng/051507c.pdf [Accessed 1 October 2009].
IMF, 2007b. Manual on fiscal transparency (2007) [online]. Washington DC: International
Monetary Fund. Available from: http://www.imf.org/external/np/pp/2007/eng/101907m.pdf
[Accessed 1 October 2009].
Budget Transparency in Local Governments 207
Islam, R., 2006. Does more transparency go along with better governance? Economics
and Politics, 18 (2): 121–167.
Jarmuzek, M., 2006. Does fiscal transparency matter? The evidence from transition
economies [online]. Available from: http://www.cerge.cuni.cz/pdf/gdn/RRCV_77_
paper_03.pdf [Accessed 31 July 2009].
Kopits, G. and Craig, J., 1998. Transparency in government operations. IMF Occasional
Papers, 158. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.
Laakso, M. and Taagepera, R., 1979. Efective number of parties: a measure with applica-
tion to Western Europe. Comparative Political Studies, 13, 3–27.
LaFaive, M.D., 2009. MEGA, the MEDC and the loss of sunshine. Policy Brief 5,
Midland, MI: Mackinac Center for Public Policy.
Lago-Peñas, I. and Lago-Peñas, S., 2010. Decentralization and electoral accountability.
Environment and Planning C: Government and Policy, 28, 318–334.
La Porte, T.M., Demchak, C.C. and Jong, M. de, 2002. Democracy and bureaucracy in the
age of the web: empirical findings and theoretical speculations. Administration &
Society, 34 (4), 411–446.
Lavielle, B., Pérez, M., and Hofbauer, H. (coords), 2003. The Latin American index of
budget transparency 2003: a comparison of 10 countries [online]. Lima, Peru: Fundar.
Available from: http://www.internationalbudget.org/themes/BudTrans/English.pdf
[Accessed 30 July 2010].
Likert, R., 1932. A technique for the measurement of attitudes. Archives of Psychology,
140, 1–55.
Nunnaly, J., 1978. Psychometric theory. New York: McGraw-Hill.
OECD (Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development), 2001. OECD best
practices for budget transparency [online]. Paris: OECD. Available from: http://www.
oecd.org/dataoecd/33/13/1905258.pdf [Accessed 30 July 2010].
Papke, L.E. and Wooldridge, J. M., 1996. Econometric methods for fractional response
variables with an application to 401(k) plan participation rates. Journal of Applied
Econometrics, 11, 619–632.
Peixoto, T., 2010. Transparency on the web: a democrat(ic) virtue? [online]. Personal
Democracy Forum. TechPresident. Available from: http://techpresident.com/blog-entry/
transparency-web-democrat-virtue [Accessed 30 July 2010].
Pérez, M. (coord.), 2005. Latin American index of budget transparency 2005: a compar-
ison of 8 countries [online]. Managua, Nicaragua: CISAS. Available from: http://www.
fundar.org.mx/indice2005/docs/Regional%20Transparency%20Report%202005.pdf.
[Accessed 30 July 2010].
Piotrowski, S.J. and Van Ryzin, G.G., 2007. Citizen attitudes toward transparency in local
government. The American Review of Public Administration, 37 (3), 306–323.
Revelle, W., 2010. An introduction to psychometric theory with applications in R [online].
Available from: http://personality-project.org/r/book/ [Accessed 22 May 2010].
Rosendorff, B.P. and Vreeland, J.R., 2009. Electoral accountability and data dissemina-
tion: the effect of democracy on transparency [online]. Available from: https://files.nyu.
edu/bpr1/public/papers/BPRJRV.pdf [Accessed 30 July 2010].
Streiner, D.L. and Norman, G.R., 1995. Health measurement scales: a practical guide to
their development and use, 2nd ed. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Vehkalahti, K., Puntanen, S., and Tarkkonen, L., 2006. Estimation of reliability: a better
alternative for Cronbach’s alpha [online]. Reports on Mathematics 430, Department of
Mathematics and Statistics, University of Helsinki, Helsinki, Finland. Available from:
http://mathstat.helsinki.fi/reports/Preprint430.pdf [Accessed 23 April 2010].
Zinbarg, R., et al., 2005. Cronbach’s α, Revelle’s β, and McDonald’s ωh: their relations with each
other and two alternative conceptualizations of reliability. Psychometrika, 70 (1), 123–133.
Copyright of Local Government Studies is the property of Routledge and its content may not be copied or
emailed to multiple sites or posted to a listserv without the copyright holder's express written permission.
However, users may print, download, or email articles for individual use.