Ocp114 en
Ocp114 en
Ocp114 en
EUROPEAN
ECONOMY
Occasional Papers 114 | August 2012
Economic and
Financial Affairs
Occasional Papers are written by the Staff of the Directorate-General for Economic and
Financial Affairs, or by experts working in association with them. The “Papers” are
intended to increase awareness of the technical work being done by the staff and cover a
wide spectrum of subjects. Views expressed do not necessarily reflect the official views of
the European Commission. Comments and enquiries should be addressed to:
European Commission
Directorate-General for Economic and Financial Affairs
Publications
B-1049 Brussels
Belgium
E-mail: mailto:[email protected]
Legal notice
Neither the European Commission nor any person acting on its behalf may be held
responsible for the use which may be made of the information contained in this
publication, or for any errors which, despite careful preparation and checking, may
appear.
This paper exists in English only and can be downloaded from the website
ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/publications
KC-AH-12-114-EN-N
ISBN 978-92-79-22910-7
doi: 10.2765/23869
This paper has been prepared by Jonas Jensen and Florian Wöhlbier. The opinions expressed in the paper
are the sole responsibility of the authors and do not necessarily represent the views of the European
Commission or DG ECFIN. The authors are grateful for valuable contributions and comments received
from Jannetje Bussink, Frank van Driessche, Helene Michard, Germano Mirabile and Thomas Carroll
(Directorate-General for Taxation and Customs Union) and from Lucio Pench, Gilles Mourre and
George-Marian Isbasoiu (Directorate-General for Economic and Financial Affairs).
2
CONTENTS
Executive summary 5
1. Introduction 7
5. Special topics 31
5.1. Tax amnesties: why are they counterproductive? 31
5.2. VAT evasion 31
5.3. Tax evasion by placing financial wealth in tax havens 33
References 36
Statistical annex 38
LIST OF TABLES
2.1. Size of the shadow economy and undeclared work in the EU 12
3.1. Third-party reporting and tax evasion by type of income in Denmark 25
A.1. Institutional arrangements for tax administration 38
A.2. Sources and uses of third party information on individual income 39
3
LIST OF GRAPHS
1.1. Tax revenue, tax gap and costs of collecting taxes 9
2.1. Size of the shadow economy, the tax-to-GDP ratio (2011) and the effective marginal tax
rate on labour (2010) 13
3.1. The compliance pyramid 16
3.2. Size of the shadow economy and the total staffing of tax authorities 19
3.3. Size of tax administrations (total staffing) and number of local branches 20
3.4. Use of electronic filing for PIT, CIT and VAT in 2009 23
LIST OF BOXES
1.1. Tax evasion, the tax gap, the shadow economy and undeclared work 8
3.1. Policy criterion 1 (condition for success) 16
3.2. Structure of a typical Taxpayer Compliance Programme 17
3.3. Policy criterion 2 (condition for success) 18
3.4. Policy criterion 3 (point to watch) 21
3.5. Policy criterion 4 (condition for success) 22
3.6. Policy criterion 5 (condition for success) 23
3.7. Policy criterion 6 (condition for success) 24
3.8. Policy criterion 7 (condition for success) 26
4.1. Policy criterion 8 (point to watch) 28
4.2. Policy criterion 9 (point to watch) 29
4.3. Policy criterion 10 (condition for success) 30
5.1. Policy criterion 11 (condition for success) 32
5.2. Common forms of VAT fraud 33
5.3. The Savings Directive 34
4
EXECUTIVE SUMMARY
An efficient and effective tax collection is a prerequisite for financing European welfare states.
Particularly at the current conjuncture, at which many Member States face high consolidation challenges,
efforts should be increased to achieve a low tax compliance gap, i.e. a small difference between the taxes
collected and the theoretical tax due. Achieving higher revenues via higher compliance is clearly
preferable to doing so via tax raising measures. While aiming at high compliance, tax administrations also
have to pay due attention to their tax collection costs and the costs businesses and individuals face when
paying taxes.
There are several criteria that characterise efficient tax administrations: They successfully
implement an overall compliance strategy and focus audit efforts on the largest revenue risks. They divide
taxpayers into co-players and opponents and distinguish between providing a service and education to
those who voluntarily comply and control for those who don't. They use third-party information
comprehensively, provide pre-filled tax returns to taxpayers and use IT systems as far as possible to both
make it easy to pay taxes and at the same time limit the taxpayers' ability to evade. As regards their
organisational structure, they often apply a function-based organisational approach. Moreover, it is
important that tax systems are simple and stable and that tax arrears are efficiently collected. All these
measures underpin tax morale and contribute to achieving a high share of voluntary compliance among
taxpayers which allows the tax administration to concentrate its efforts on those taxpayers who try to
evade taxes.
To successfully fight the shadow economy it has proven important to increase the tax morale in a
country and to benefit from electronic means of payments, with tracking possibilities for audit
purposes. On the contrary, the success of deterrence through punishment and the provision of monetary
incentives to declare work are rather limited. Criminalising the purchaser of shadow economy activities
appears to be fruitful.
A few special topics also need particular attention. Tax amnesties should certainly be avoided despite
the temporary and short run increase in revenues. A particular focus should be put on fighting VAT
evasion, both at the national level and EU level, with large amount of revenue being at stake. Tax evasion
by placing financial wealth in tax havens also remains a major concern in the EU.
5
1. INTRODUCTION
An efficient and effective tax collection is a prerequisite for financing European welfare states with a
relatively high level of public service and a redistributive tax and transfer system. It is of particular
importance at the current juncture where Member States face severe consolidation challenges. Tax
avoidance and evasion undermine the revenue raising and redistributive objectives of the tax system. Tax
evasion also leads to redistribution from those who do respect the rules to those who do not. These issues
feature very high on the European policy agenda, as seen in the Commission Communication 'on concrete
ways to reinforce the fight against tax fraud and tax evasion including in relation to third countries (1)
and the Annual Growth Survey 2012. ( 2)
A significant number of Member States face the challenge of improving the efficiency of their tax
collection and of better preventing tax evasion. In order to identify the challenges in the area of the
effectiveness of tax collection several indicators are available. ( 3) All indicate that there are significant
differences in the performance of the tax authorities in different Member States and the challenges they
face.
Undeclared work and other forms of underreporting of income in tax returns are lack of tax
compliance, i.e., tax evasion (see Box 1.1 for definitions). While cheating with the reporting of income
can be detected and prevented administratively through audits, combatting the shadow economy often
requires other methods. Tax compliance can be defined as a "…taxpayer's willingness to comply with tax
laws, declare the correct income, claim the correct deductions, relief and rebates and pay all taxes on
time." (Palil and Mustapha, 2011)
• A genuine behavioural effect, which reduces the tax base, because people and companies reduce
their economic activity. For instance, they choose to work less and enjoy more leisure due to a
taxation of labour income or to consume less of a product on which an excise duty is levied.
• Tax avoidance (legal) in the form of a re-arrangement of income, which is in principle legal but
not the intent of legislation. This includes transformation of income, e.g., remuneration in the form
of dividend income, as this is typically lower taxed than wage income, transformation of expenses into
tax deductible expenses or the placement of savings in assets for which the return is taxed lower.
• Tax evasion (illegal), where income, consumption or production are not (or under) declared for
taxation, despite the fact that they are taxable, e.g., by not reporting the full income to the tax
authorities or by carrying out undeclared work.
Put in a general way, a compliance gap, i.e. a gap between the taxes collected and the theoretical tax
due, can result from the following factors:
• Difficulty to understand the tax code and high costs of declaring income,
7
European Commission
Improving tax governance in EU Member States: Criteria for successful policies
Box 1.1: Tax evasion, the tax gap, the shadow economy and undeclared work
In the literature, different definitions of the terms tax evasion, shadow economy and undeclared work are
used interchangeably. (1) In this note, the following definitions are used.
Tax evasion represents the general concept that individuals and companies underreport taxable activities (and
over-report deductible expenses). Taxpayers illegally conceal or misreport (otherwise legal) economic
activity in an attempt to reduce the amount of taxes they pay. Tax evasion gives rise to a tax gap – the
monetary difference between the revenue that tax authorities would collect if all taxpayers complied with the
tax code and other forms of regulation and the actual revenue that is collected.
The shadow economy can be defined as legitimate productive activities in which a payment or a quid pro quo
barter is taxable but the seller – often in common understanding with the buyer – neglects to pay taxes
(including social security contributions and excise duties). Activity in the shadow economy includes both
undeclared work and underreporting of income of cash-based businesses sale of goods. The shadow economy
measures the value on the black market of the production not reported to the tax authorities; i.e. not the
amount of taxes evaded.
Tax evasion is not always linked to shadow economic activity. It also includes 'pure' tax evasion which is not
linked to any production of goods or services and which does not create an added value. This kind of tax
evasion involves transactions that have the only objective to conceal income or over reporting of deductible
expenses. Examples of this include hiding money in tax shelters, use of manipulated transfer prices and fraud
related to VAT refunds.
(1) See, e.g., Schneider (2011a) and Pedersen (2003) for a discussion and further literature references.
• Ability to cheat/underreport.
The goal for revenue authorities is to collect the full amount of taxes and duties payable in
accordance with the law. From a compliance perspective, tax authorities should aim at reducing the tax
gap while at the same time having low costs of collecting taxes for the government and of paying taxes
for taxpayers (businesses and individuals) (see Graph 1.1). To achieve these objectives, governments may
rely on a variety of tax administration policies.
Tax administration policy can be defined as a set of measures, procedures and tools, which a tax
authority uses to collect the full amount of taxes payable in accordance with the law in the most
effective way and at the lowest administrative costs. This covers policies to facilitate and stimulate
voluntary compliance, to prevent and deter evasion, to detect and combat tax fraud, to enforce
compliance, as well as to effectively collect the taxes due. These policies are interlinked: facilitating
voluntary compliance decreases the need for enforcement, while an effective enforcement policy will
contribute to more voluntary compliance. In general, policies aiming at enhancing voluntary compliance,
e.g. through the provision of high quality taxpayer services, will result in greater trade facilitation, while
enforcement policies will entail a further increase in administrative burdens on businesses. However, a
tax administration policy needs to include both and the challenge is to find a proper balance between the
two elements.
This paper presents operational criteria to assess the adequacy of policy responses in the area of tax
governance, following the approach developed in the EPC's Lisbon Working Group (LIME).( 4) LIME
(4) LIME worked to develop operational criteria to assess the adequacy of policy responses. This was done on the basis of a
literature survey which sought to develop general criteria for successful reforms to make work pay as well as criteria for success
at the level of policy instruments.
8
1. Introduction
Graph 1.1: Tax revenue, tax gap and costs of collecting taxes
Taxes to be paid
Actual tax
revenue
collecting
Costs of
taxes
recommended distinguishing between 'dimensions to watch' for in order to achieve success and
'conditions for success', which are of prescriptive and normative nature. The former requires considering
specific aspects although they do not give concrete recommendations in favour of a predetermined policy
stance. The latter (conditions) recommends a specific and concrete policy design.
The paper is structured as follows: Chapter 2 presents data on tax compliance costs and the costs of tax
collection. Chapter 3 discusses how the efficiency of the tax administration can be improved and Chapter
4 analyses specific ways to combat tax evasion and the shadow economy. Finally, Chapter 5 addresses
three special topics, namely why tax amnesties are counterproductive, which special measures could be
put in place to combat VAT fraud and tax evasion by placing financial wealth in tax havens.
9
2. TAX COMPLIANCE AND COSTS OF TAX COLLECTION:
SOME FIGURES
The size of the shadow economy gives a first idea of the extent of tax non-compliance. Several
researchers have worked on measuring the size of the shadow economy, and on analysing its
consequences for the formal economy. According to Dell’Anno (2003), the shadow economy includes
those economic activities and the income derived thereof that circumvent or avoid government regulation
or taxation. A large share of the shadow economy in official GDP can, therefore, be due to the avoidance
of tax and social security contribution (SSC) payments, but also due to the avoidance of labour protection
legislation and consumer rights protection laws.
By definition, the size of the shadow economy is difficult to ascertain. Reflecting these difficulties,
different studies come to rather different results for some Member States. Therefore, available results
only provide an indication of the magnitude of the problem and the development over time rather than
precise estimates.
Shadow economic activity varies considerably across EU Member States. According to Schneider
(2011a), the size of the shadow economy increased steadily between 2008 and 2010, but dropped again in
2011. In 2011, Bulgaria is estimated to have the largest shadow economy in the EU, equivalent to 32.3%
of its GDP, followed by Romania (29.6%), Lithuania (29.0%), and Estonia (28.8%) (see Table 2.1).
Another important source is the European Employment Observatory, which collected national data in
2004 and 2007 for the share of undeclared work. Depending on availability, these figures are either based
on micro surveys, labour force survey studies, macro studies or a combination or even a guesstimate. The
estimated size of undeclared work is usually significantly lower in the reported national data. The picture
is, nevertheless, rather similar for many Member States. However, it is noticeable that Estonia is
estimated in the latter to have a share of undeclared work well below the European average.
The estimated size of the shadow economy is usually significantly lower in micro surveys than in
macro studies. In micro surveys individuals are asked if they have performed (or acquired) activities in
the shadow economy during the previous year. One reason for the lower results is that micro surveys
usually apply a more narrow definition of the shadow economy, focusing on households' supply of black
labour, whereas the macro studies tend to encompass also other types of tax evasion. Another possible
reason might be biased reporting. Nevertheless, it is likely that the size of the shadow economy is
overestimated, at least for some countries, in macro estimations like Schneider (2011a) and that the truth
lies somewhere between the results from macro studies and micro surveys. Results for the latter are only
available for a few Member States (see right column of Table 2.1 for examples).(5)
Despite cross-country disparities, there seem to be some common characteristics of the prevalence
of undeclared work. Undeclared work is most prevalent among men, singles, people with short or craft
education and workers employed in the construction sector and in the hospitality sector. It is more
common in sparsely populated areas.
Only few studies are available that measure the size of the tax gap. The most well-known study is the
study of the ‘VAT compliance gap’ carried out by Reckon LLP (2009). It aims at measuring the gap
between actual VAT revenues and what they would have been with full compliance. It estimated an
average gap of 11% of liabilities in 2006 for EU as a whole (see also Section 5.2). Apart from this,
mainly studies for single Member States exist. Studies carried out by national tax administrations in many
cases do not get published.
(5) A further discussion of the different methods used to measure the shadow economy is available in Slemrod and Yitzhaki (2002).
11
European Commission
Improving tax governance in EU Member States: Criteria for successful policies
Table 2.1: Size of the shadow economy and undeclared work in the EU
Undeclared work working
S ize of shadow economy (in % of GDP), Schneider (2011a) Undeclared work (share of
hours in % of hours in formal
Country GDP or employment,
economy, Pedersen (2003)/
1995-2006)
2005 2008 2010 2011 RFRU (1997-2004)
AT 10.3 8.1 8.7 8.0 2
BE 20.1 17.5 17.9 17.1 6-10
BG 34.4 32.1 32.9 32.3 22-30
CY 28.1 26.0 26.8 26.0 4.2
CZ 18.5 16.6 17.2 16.4 9-10
DK 16.5 13.9 14.4 13.8 3 3.8
EE 30.2 29.0 29.9 28.6 7-8
FI 16.6 13.8 14.3 13.7 4.2
FR 13.8 11.1 11.7 11.0 4-6.5
DE 15.4 14.2 14.7 13.7 7 4.1
EL 27.6 24.3 25.2 24.3 25
HU 24.5 23.0 23.8 22.8 15-20
IE 14.8 12.2 13.2 12.8 NA
IT 24.4 21.4 22.2 21.2 12
LV 29.5 26.5 27.3 26.5 18
LT 31.1 29.1 30.0 29.0 16-18
LU 9.9 8.5 8.8 8.2 NA
MT 26.9 25.8 26.0 25.8 25
NL 12.0 9.6 10.3 9.8 2
PL 27.1 25.3 26.1 25.0 12-15.
PT 21.2 18.7 19.7 19.4 5
RO 32.2 29.4 30.2 29.6 16-21
SK 17.6 16.0 17.3 16.0 13-15
SI 26.0 24.0 25.0 24.1 17
ES 21.3 18.7 19.8 19.2 12
SE 17.5 14.9 15.6 14.7 5 2.3
UK 12.0 10.1 11.1 11.0 2 1.2
EU-27 17.4 15.1 15.9 15.2 7.2
EA-17 17.6 15.3 16.0 15.1 9.7
Note: The size and development of the shadow economy is calculated with the MIMIC (Multiple Indicators and Multiple Courses) estimation
procedure. The currency demand approach was used for Austria, Germany and Poland. Averages are GDP-weighted.
Source: Schneider (2011a), national data collected by European Employment Observatory, Spring Review 2004 & 2007 (figures for BE, IT and LT
are based on the articles on undeclared work from national SYSDEM correspondents) and Pedersen (2003).
The impact of the tax level on avoidance and evasion is not clear, while the ability to cheat in
combination with tax morale seems to be the crucial factor.( 6) The ability to misreport and the will to
exploit opportunities to do so – the tax morale – appear to be decisive explanatory variables for the size of
the shadow economy and the total amount of tax evasion. This is confirmed by the depiction of the
estimated size of the shadow economy compared to the overall tax-to-GDP ratio or the marginal tax rate
on labour for the EU Member States in Graph 2.1. Increased taxes will increase the value of evading if the
penalty for evading is only dependent on the evaded income. If in contrast, the penalty is directly related
to the evaded tax, the tax rate typically has less or no importance for tax evasion, as the change in the
potential gain and the potential costs nets out. The fact that there is no clear relationship between the level
of taxation and the size of the shadow economy underlines that the tax morale of the inhabitants and the
tax governance of the state is what matters for the size of the shadow economy. The tendency that the size
of the shadow economy is smaller the higher the overall tax-to-GDP ratio could reflect other factors, e.g.
the fact that a high tax-to-GDP ratio is often associated with a high level of economic development,
which is again linked with lower activity in the shadow economy. The share of self-employed and people
employed in small enterprises can have a large impact on the share of taxpayers who is able to cheat and,
therefore, on tax governance. High shares can, e.g., be due to special regulations in sectors which prevent
(6) See, e.g., Alm (2000) for references to estimates of the effect of tax rates on taxpayer compliance. See also Thießen (2010) for
an estimation of factors influencing the size of the shadow economy.
12
2. Tax compliance and costs of tax collection: some figures
Graph 2.1: Size of the shadow economy, the tax-to-GDP ratio (2011) and the effective marginal tax rate on labour (2010)
35 35 35 35
BG BG
y = -0.7365x + 45.653 y = -0.4318x + 36.822
30 RO R² = 0.3753 30 30 EE LT RO R² = 0.367 30
LT EE
LV
LV MT CY
CY
25 PL MT EL 25
25 EL
PL 25 SI
SI
HU
HU
IT
IT
20 PT 20 20 ES PT
20
ES
BE BE
CZ CZ
SK
15 SE 15 15 SK SE 15
DE FI DK FI DE DK
IE IE
UK FR FR
10 NL 10 10 UK
NL 10
LU AT AT
LU
5 5 5 5
0 0 0 0
25 30 35 40 45 50 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65
Tax-to-GDP ratio Effective marginal tax rate (100% AW singe, 2010)
Source: Own calculations based on Schneider (2011b), Eurostat and OECD (2011).
or complicate the market access for bigger companies or employee thresholds for the application of
labour law.
Compliance costs are an important variable often associated with non-compliance. A widely used
indicator for the measurement of tax compliance costs for small and medium-sized enterprises is the
‘paying taxes’ indicator ( 7). It measures the time to prepare, file and pay (or withhold) corporate income
tax, value added or sales tax and labour taxes, including payroll taxes and SSC for a case study company.
In 2011, in particular the Czech Republic and Bulgaria but also Poland, Latvia, Italy, Hungary and
Portugal show high tax compliance costs as compared to the EU average of 189 hours (see Graph 2.2). A
topical case is Italy, which is of particular relevance due to the size of its economy in Europe. Compliance
costs in Italy amount to 285 hours, the second highest amongst euro-area Member States. The high Italian
value is mainly due to compliance with labour tax provisions (214 hours of 285). Overall, compliance
costs have been on a downward trend in the EU in recent years (2005 average: 212 hours).
Moreover, it is important to analyse how costly tax collection is for the revenue administration.
According to OECD (2011), the average costs of tax collection in the EU Member States amounted to 1.1
(costs per 100 units of revenue, see Graph 2.2). No clear trend is discernible for the period 2005-2009.( 8)
In 2009, Poland, Czech Republic, Portugal, Belgium and France were characterised by rather high costs
of tax collection. ( 9) Slovakia had high costs in 2007, the latest year for which data are available.
Expectations for revenue improvements from an augmented fight against the shadow economy
should be cautious. Even if the shadow economy could be completely removed, revenue gains would be
significantly lower than the figures reported in Table 2.1 times the tax rate. Many activities carried out in
the shadow economy would disappear because there would be no demand for such services at formal
market prices. As a rule of thumb based on anecdotal evidence of country examples,( 10) around 1/3 of the
work carried out in the shadow economy could be transferred to the formal economy and thus lead to
additional tax revenues. Other activities wouldn't be demanded any longer or be carried out by the
customers themselves, i.e. move to household production. If the shadow economy amounts to, say, 10%
(7) The indicator is calculated annually by PwC, the World Bank and IFC; see PwC et al. (2011).
(8) The trend in the ‘cost of collection’ ratio is influenced by a series of factors, such as: (i) changes in tax rates over time; (ii)
macro-economic changes; (iii) abnormal expenditure by the tax administrations; and (iv) changes in the scope of taxes. As a
consequence, its value as an indicator of effectiveness is rather limited.
9
( ) The data given in OECD(2011) for Cyprus appears to signal high costs of tax collection but is currently under revision by the
OECD following a request by the Cypriot authorities.
(10) See, e.g., Schneider (2005) for estimates for Germany and Hvidtfeldt et al. (2010) for Denmark.
13
European Commission
Improving tax governance in EU Member States: Criteria for successful policies
Graph 2.2: Administrative burden of tax systems for a medium-sized company (2011) and administrative cost per net revenue (costs per
100 units of revenue, 2007 to 2009)
7.4
Administrative burden of tax systems for a medium-sized company (2011) 5.0 Administrative cost per net revenue
5.8
2.5 (costs per 100 units of revenue, 2007 to 2009)
600
400
1.5
300
1.0
200
0.5
100
0 0.0
CZ BG PL LV IT HU PT SI SK EL RO DE ES LT AT BE CY DK FR NL SE UK FI EE IE LU EU EA CY SK PL CZ PT BE BG FR IT HU LV UK LU NL IE ES SI FI AT DE RO DK MT EE SE EA- EU-
27 17 17 27
Note: Administrative burden includes total hours to comply across the EU include: corporate income tax time, labour income tax time, and
consumption tax time. Data for Malta are not available. For the administrative cost, no data available for Greece is available. Data for Slovakia are
limited to year 2007. Data for Cyprus is currently under revision by the OECD following a request by the Cypriot authorties.
Source: PwC et al. (2011) and OECD (2011).
of GDP and the average effective marginal tax rate including VAT is 50%, revenue would increase by
1.7% of GDP if the shadow economy could be completely removed.
14
3. POLICIES TO RAISE THE EFFICIENCY OF TAX
ADMINISTRATION
Different policy instruments can be used to increase tax compliance. The effectiveness of each
measure depends on the underlying cause of non-compliance.
Reform priorities to improve tax compliance differ across Member States, reflecting variations in
tax systems, in stages of development, in the administrative capacity, and in the extent and type of
tax evasion. Reforms, therefore, need to be tailored to each Member State's circumstances. The relatively
wider tax gaps and lower revenue productivity of the less developed Member States generally suggest
potential for bigger revenue yields from compliance improvement initiatives. For these countries, getting
the fundamentals of revenue administration in place (especially taxpayer service operations and effective
audit and enforcement) should be the first step.
Developing an overall compliance strategy is critical for the tax authorities' ability to improve
taxpayer compliance and to enhance revenue collection.(11) The purpose of a taxpayer compliance
programme is to identify and respond to the most significant risks in the tax collection system through a
range of measures aimed at the underlying causes of the noncompliant behaviour. Its ultimate objective is
to achieve the widest possible impact on voluntary compliance across the taxpayer population.
A close monitoring of the tax gap or other tax compliance indicators is important in order to be
able to react quickly in case of an increase in the tax gap. As part of a compliance programme tax
administrations should improve revenue analysis capabilities and develop (further) indicators for tax
compliance in the different tax categories. A taxpayer compliance programme should be authorised at a
high level, describe and prioritise resources for the most significant compliance risks and set out the
detailed response by tax administration to those risks. The compliance programme does not cover every
aspect of a revenue agency’s operational activities, but focuses on special areas of high risk and
importance for revenues. Compliance programmes are structured around major taxpayer segments (e.g.,
large businesses, medium-size enterprises, small and micro enterprises, and high income individuals) or
types of taxes with a high risk of fraud (e.g. corporate income tax, vehicle taxation, VAT, deductions for
commuting expenses in personal income taxation) and address compliance risks relevant to these
segments. Box 3.2 lists the features of a typical taxpayer compliance programme.
As an overarching plan, a taxpayer compliance programme should carefully target efforts against
tax evasion. Governments' resources to collect taxes and combat tax evasion are limited. Therefore, it is
essential that the resources are targeted to achieve the best possible outcome.
Taxpayers should be viewed as clients and the tax administration should move from a control to a
service approach. Most taxpayers – whether individuals or businesses – comply voluntarily with the tax
laws and pay their taxes without any intervention from the authorities. Therefore, most revenue agencies
have moved away from administrative assessment systems under which all or most tax returns are
subjected to examination prior to the issue of final tax returns to taxpayers, to a system which relies on
most taxpayers voluntarily complying with their obligations to register, keep proper records, file correct
returns and pay tax on time without the intervention of a tax official. Successful self-assessment systems
are underpinned by an administrative approach which recognizes that voluntary compliance will be
optimized through an appropriate balance of taxpayer education and assistance that help taxpayers and
their advisors understand their obligations and entitlements, simple laws and procedures, and risk-based
(11) See, e.g. Russell (2010a) for a discussion of taxpayer compliance programs.
15
European Commission
Improving tax governance in EU Member States: Criteria for successful policies
Box 3.1: Policy criterion 1 (condition for success) "Developing a Taxpayer Compliance
Programme"
Revenue agencies should draw up an annual Taxpayer Compliance Programme as an overarching strategy
plan focusing on special areas of high risk and importance for revenues. The programme contains an action
plan recording the number and type of different service and control initiatives planned to be undertaken in
the coming year within each major taxpayer segment.
verification programmes (see European Commission, 2010). Tools like one-stop shops and single tax web
portals for all taxes and taxpayers can make it easier for taxpayers to comply with their tax
obligations. ( 12)
Risk-based verification programmes segmenting taxpayers into co-players and opponents have
proved efficient. Segmenting taxpayers improves compliance behaviour by detecting and deterring non-
compliance through the use of risk management approaches. Taxpayers are more likely to comply if they
perceive the likelihood of detection as high and see blatant non-compliers being brought to account. The
compliance level can be shown in the shape of a triangle, the compliance pyramid (see Graph 3.1).
Tax authorities could perform detailed analysis of random audit data to segment individual
taxpayers into co-players and opponents according to the four groups in the compliance pyramid.
The segmentation can then be revised according to the track record of the particular taxpayer. Once the
taxpayers are segmented, the approach towards the taxpayer can be separated between service and
control. The compliance pyramid as a basis for segmentation applies to both individuals and businesses.
The segmenting of taxpayers into the four compliance categories will depend, among other factors, on the
coverage of third-party information. Taxpayers with income and deductions extensively covered by third-
party information will typically be categorised as "compliant". For self-employed and business,
parameters such as size and sector will be influential, but the segmentation may rely more heavily on
track record.
Range of measures:
Complete audit
Partial audit
Assistance
Increased use of
precautionary measures Information
Notifying high-risk taxpayers by letter may increase voluntary compliance. When a taxpayer is
identified as a deliberate defaulter, notifying the taxpayer by letter that he/she will be under close scrutiny
16
3. Policies to raise the efficiency of tax administration
A compliance programme is structured around taxpayer segments. Taxpayers can be grouped in different
ways, from business size (large, medium and small) to economic activity sector (construction, wholesale,
professional) to tax type (direct, indirect). Criteria for segmentation are e.g. level of economic importance,
legal form, compliance level or a combination of these.
For each taxpayer segment, the programme summarizes the economic, revenue and business environment
(e.g., number of taxpayers, nature of entities, total tax contribution, number of persons employed, and
structural features).
The programme addresses the risks in each of the taxes administered in each taxpayer segment.
The programme outlines the headline compliance issues and the specific risks for each taxpayer segment,
and describes how the revenue agency intends to respond to these issues and risks in an action plan.
Headline issues have an impact across more than one taxpayer segment and include, for example, the global
economic crisis, informality, international profit shifting and abuse of tax havens.
The programme records the number and type of different service and control initiatives planned to be
undertaken in the coming year within each taxpayer segment.
Reporting against these commitments ensures that the planned activities are carried out and helps build
community confidence in the administration of the tax system.
may by itself increase compliance and could be a cost-efficient strategy. However, the thread of closer
scrutiny needs to be credible.
Special attention should be paid to the segment of taxpayers who attempt to comply, but fail to
comply fully with their obligations to register, file correct information and pay the correct amount of tax
on time. his segment with information and education, when possible via standard electronic
communication, can increase the number of taxpayers in the fully compliant segment at relatively low
costs and thereby increase the share of revenues that 'enters through the front door'.
Flag systems are an efficient tool and could be based on the segmentation of taxpayers. The four
groups in the compliance pyramid can form the basis of a segmentation-oriented flag system. Flag
systems will typically be more sophisticated and more targeted than the segmentation in the compliance
pyramid.( 13) Available data is used to point out for which tax returns of individuals and businesses it
would be most beneficial to perform closer audits. The tax authorities cannot examine all tax returns and
should, therefore, identify those that can be expected to have the largest deviations. Tax agencies could
apply a computer-based examination of all tax returns that assigns a flag to a tax return if the income
reported seems suspicious, or if the reported type of income is known to often suffer from evasion (e.g.
self-employed income).( 14) A flag would then increase the likelihood of a manual check. The flag system
could build on data about sources of income, size of taxpayers' reported changes to the preliminary
assessment of income, income levels, any mismatch between income and consumption levels, and
perhaps also socio-economic factors.
(13) For instance in Denmark, taxpayers are allocated to the compliant segment unless their record (regarding errors in payment of
taxes ranging from late payment to serious evasion) suggest otherwise. The flag system, on the other hand, is based on detailed
data (in particular on the source of income and the taxpayer's potential ability to cheat) and targeted selection of taxpayers for
auditing.
14
( ) Kleven et al. (2011) found that the presence of types of income difficult to detect (e.g. self-employed income and other income
not reported by a third party) is the most important factor in predicting evasion whereas socio economic characteristics of the
individual have little explanatory power.
17
European Commission
Improving tax governance in EU Member States: Criteria for successful policies
Box 3.3: Policy criterion 2 (condition for success) "Segmentation of taxpayers into co-
players and opponents and exploitation of databases to target audits to the most relevant
taxpayers"
Segmenting taxpayers into the four compliance categories in the compliance pyramid can assist tax
authorities in differentiating the approach towards the taxpayer between service and control.
Building up databases with information on taxpayers' income and assets can make the investigations of tax
authorities better targeted, e.g. by means of a flag system, where a flag significantly increases the audit
probability. The flag system should build on data on the sources of income of each taxpayer, the taxpayer's
income level and the difference between the taxpayer's tax return and the preliminary assessment of income
as well as the track record for previous years. This data may help to segment a given taxpayer into one of the
four compliance categories.
A preferable treatment of self-employed as compared to employed people in the tax system should
be avoided. As pointed out in the above (and discussed in more detail in Section 3.6), self-employed are
much more likely to evade taxes than employees. This can lead to significant revenue losses and a higher
workload for the tax administration due to a higher need for manual controls in the case of self-employed.
Moreover, such incentives are also debatable from a general tax policy point of view as a tax system
should not discriminate between different forms of employment.
Controls should complement the flag system in specific cases. Even if control costs on average
outweigh the revenue gain for some categories of taxpayers (e.g. self-employed), they are important for
the fairness of the tax system and thus tax morale. Moreover, controls should increase an audited
taxpayer's compliance in the future and this need to be taken into account in the cost-benefit analysis
when deciding on the level of audits.
The communication strategy of tax authorities could improve voluntary compliance. As part of the
compliance strategy, tax authorities should consider using strategic communication of results. Strategic
communication about results of control actions and detection of evaders can contribute to increasing the
perceived detection probability and underpin tax morale at a low cost. Non-monetary sanctions such as
"name and shame" methods which include the publication of the names and relevant information of
delinquent taxpayers can be used to increase the cost of non-compliance in cases where monetary
sanctions are not adequate to discourage taxpayers from non-compliance.
Simple and stable tax laws and procedures make it easier and less expensive for taxpayers to
comply with their obligations and access their entitlements. Taxpayers are less likely to voluntarily
comply if the tax system itself makes it too difficult or very expensive for them to meet their obligations.
Furthermore, rate differentiations, exemptions and deductions complicate the system and create scope for
avoidance. As a general rule, tax bases should, therefore, be broad and allow only limited possibility for
deductions and exemptions and tax systems should tax substitutable types of income in a similar way.
Taxpayers are entitled to have up-to-date information on the operation of the tax system and the
way in which their tax is assessed. They are also entitled to be informed of their rights, including their
rights of appeal. All taxpayers can expect that the information provided to them reflects the complexity of
the tax situation, thereby enabling them to understand better their tax affairs. The authorities may use a
variety of means to fulfil this obligation: information leaflets, taxpayers’ charters, telephone
announcements, video guides, etc. The right of appeal against any decision of the tax authorities applies
to all taxpayers, and to almost all decisions taken by the tax authorities, whether they concern the
18
3. Policies to raise the efficiency of tax administration
application of the law or of administrative rulings and penalties, provided the taxpayer is directly
concerned.
Taxpayers also have a right to a high degree of predictability as to the tax consequences of their
actions. Firstly, this calls for a stable tax system over the years. Of course, certainty is not always
possible. For example, taxpayers may not always know in advance the effect of rules that are dependent
on the facts and circumstances in a particular case. However, it is clearly a goal that taxpayers should be
able to anticipate the consequences of their ordinary personal and business affairs. Achieving this goal is
often difficult because modern tax systems are complex and evolving. However, tax authorities may not
be obligated to provide the taxpayer with certainty in relation to the application of anti-abuse provisions
aimed at taxpayers seeking to circumvent the intent of the legislation.
A simple and stable tax system is also preferable from the tax administration viewpoint. It is easier
to administer and can be applied better and at lower costs.
There are vast differences in the size and organisation of tax administrations in EU Member States.
Some of these differences can be attributed to the differences in organisation of the administration of
SSC, customs, excises etc., which could be (or not) part of the tax agency. Overall, the total staffing of
tax authorities appears rather low in Italy, Spain and Estonia. In the Netherlands and Latvia, total staffing
on the other hand appears relatively high.
Tax administrations with more resources do not perform better than tax administrations with
fewer resources. When total staffing of tax administrations per 1 million inhabitants is compared with
the size of the shadow economy, only a very weak relationship emerges (see Graph 3.2). However, a
cross country comparison does not take into account the wealth of other possible explanations. One
important aspect is that the causality could be from the size of the shadow economy and the level of tax
evasion to total staffing rather than the other way around, as there is a rationale for employing more staff
to combat tax evasion if the shadow economy and tax evasion in other areas are large.
Graph 3.2: Size of the shadow economy and the total staffing of tax authorities
35 35
BG
30 RO 30
EE LT
MT CY LV
25 PL 25
SI
HU
IT ES y = -0.0027x + 22.703
20 PT R² = 0.0163 20
BE CZ
SK
15 SE DE 15
FI DK
IE
UK FR
10 NL 10
AT
5 5
0 0
400 600 800 1000 1200 1400 1600 1800 2000
Total staffing per 1 mio. inhabitants
19
European Commission
Improving tax governance in EU Member States: Criteria for successful policies
Some country examples suggest that a limited amount of resources could be associated with
efficient tax administration and small shadow economy. Looking at Member States like Finland,
Austria, Sweden and the United Kingdom, it appears to be possible to run an efficient tax administration
with a staffing of slightly above 1,000 per 1 million inhabitants (see Graph 3.3). The number of local and
regional tax offices or branches also varies largely between Member States from 35 in the UK to 3,271 in
France and 1,421 in Belgium. A relatively low number of local tax offices (below 10 per 1 million
inhabitants) could support professional competency, ensure quality of the service and improve
administrative cost effectiveness.
Not only the headcount but also the quality of human resources in the tax authority is essential.
Adequate education and training of the staff must be ensured. Practices should be in place to build and
maintain the required professional skills and ethical standards of the personnel. Furthermore, staff in tax
authorities needs to be amply equipped with efficient IT tools.
Graph 3.3: Size of tax administrations (total staffing) and number of local branches
2000 40
50.8 132.1
1500 30
1000 20
500 10
0 0
IT ES EE AT MT PT BG FI SK CY SE FR LT UK RO SI DE IE BE DK CZ HU PL NL LV EU EA
27 17
Total staffing per 1m inhabitants (left axis) Regional and local offices per 1m inhabitants (right axis)
To ensure cost efficiency and the specialisation of the officials, field offices should not be too widely
dispersed geographically. A large country might also choose to organize its field offices into a smaller
number of regions. In smaller Member States, local tax centres might not contain all different functions.
Some specialised functions like corporate income tax, large corporations, frontier taxpayers (taxpayers
who derive income in one Member State but reside in another), property taxation, and vehicle taxation
etc. may be concentrated in one physical address.
Operation of an integrated tax and social security contribution collection agency could improve
efficiency and effectiveness, and reduce the compliance burden for businesses. SSCs are the largest
single source of government revenue in most Member States. However, in 14 Member States the
collection of SSCs is administered through a separate social security agency, rather than by the main tax
revenue body (see Annex 1). The majority of the revenue bodies are set up as unified semi-autonomous
bodies responsible for both direct and indirect tax administration. Customs administration is most often
administered by a separate entity, although some Member States have merged tax and customs
administration. Twenty Member States have separate bodies for tax and customs administration; of these,
nine have allocated the excise administration to the customs body and not to the revenue body. Running
separate entities for similar tasks implies a duplication of fixed costs and means that taxpayers have to
deal with several collection bodies.
20
3. Policies to raise the efficiency of tax administration
Box 3.4: Policy criterion 3 (point to watch) "Basic organisation of revenue collection"
The optimal size of tax authorities in terms of total number of employees depends on the scale of the
challenges with tax evasion in the Member State. Member States with less than 1,000 employees per 1
million inhabitants might investigate whether increasing full-time equivalents would be worthwhile.
A high number of local tax offices (above 10-15 per 1 million inhabitants) appears not recommendable.
Professional competency and administrative cost effectiveness could increase by reducing the number of local
offices.
Member States could possibly lower administration costs by integrating the collection of SSC, excise duties
and customs into the tax agency.
There is a new trend towards integrating the collection of social security contributions with tax
collection operations. The Czech Republic, Slovakia and Portugal (as part of the Memorandum of
Understanding) consider integrating the collection of taxes and SSCs over the next few years. Tax
administrations can be organised as a department within the Ministry of Finance, as a separate department
of government or as is the case in some countries, an autonomous agency. The Minister of Finance
usually has direction or oversight of the tax administration.
A function based approach gives tax authorities a better picture of overall taxpayer compliance. It
is also able to better leverage a number of synergies from the standardization of common work in the
same unit.
The organizational structure of tax administrations should be based on a strong head office. The
head office should be assigned with policy direction and monitoring, organized by key tax administration
functions and separate from operational tasks. The headquarter develops strategies and priorities,
develops and maintains the IT infrastructure, allocates operational results, sets goals and targets, measures
the results and adjusts approaches as a consequence of those results.
The responsibility for the tax assessment, dispute resolution and for recovery tax arrears should be
strictly separated between two different parts of the tax agency. If the tax official responsible for
regulating the tax to be paid is the same as the official recovering tax arrears, this could give rise to
suspicion of possible corruption. Likewise, the system for resolving disputes between taxpayers and tax
authorities should be strictly separated to ensure independency and objectivity.
(15) See Kidd (2010) for a more detailed analysis of functionally organised tax administrations.
21
European Commission
Improving tax governance in EU Member States: Criteria for successful policies
Box 3.5: Policy criterion 4 (condition for success) "Function-based organisation of revenue
collection"
A function-based organization for the tax administration, organised in logical groupings of core functions that
encompass all taxes, rather than separate units to deal with each different tax, is the most effective
organisation to collect revenues, minimise the tax gap and service taxpayers.
However, setting up a large taxpayer office within the revenue headquarters or as a 'special branch' could
improve tax governance, because large corporate taxpayers pose the biggest risk as they account for a large
share of revenues and the tax assessment of large taxpayer's require specific skills. Tax authorities should
also investigate whether to set-up special entities for High Wealth Individuals and High Income Self-
Employed.
Field offices are usually structured in a similar manner to the functions established at
headquarters. In this way, communication lines with headquarters are clearer, services are properly set
up for taxpayers and staff efficiency can be maximized.
The organization of the tax administration should also recognize that both the needs and
compliance challenges of large, medium and small taxpayers and other specific groups of taxpayers
are quite different and tailor its programmes accordingly. Many administrations have created large
taxpayer offices (LTOs) and sometimes even medium taxpayer offices as key components of their field
network. Large corporate taxpayers pose a particular risk in terms of the tax gap as a limited number of
companies account for a large share of revenues. Furthermore, a large taxpayer's tax assessment is often
relatively complicated and involves transnational issues (e.g. transfer pricing and thin capitalization).
Other groups of taxpayers that could justify the setting-up of special entities or units are High Wealth
Individuals and High Income Self-Employed.( 16)
Pre-filling appears a successful formula to improve the efficiency of tax collection for the personal
income tax. Pre-populated tax returns were first introduced by Denmark in 1988. Since then, pre-filling
has evolved to become a significant (and for some, transformational) component of e-services and the e-
government strategy by revenue bodies in many countries.
Pre-filling entails the use by revenue bodies of information already held by them (e.g. taxpayer
identity information, elements of taxpayer history, and third-party reports of income and deductions etc.)
to populate fields within tax returns etc. that are made available to taxpayers for examination. Depending
on the degree of sophistication of the service (and the legislative framework in place), fully or partially-
completed tax returns can be made available to taxpayers in electronic and/or as hardcopy form. In their
most advanced form, tax return preparation has been fully automated for the vast majority of the taxpayer
population. In the Nordic countries, tax administrations generate at the year-end a fully completed
personal income tax return in electronic and/or hardcopy form for the majority of taxpayers required to
file tax returns (Denmark: 84%, Finland: 94% and Sweden 60%), with the remaining share of taxpayers
(16) For an analysis of organisation responses to dealing with High Net Worth Individuals and examples of Member States that have
set-up special units to deal with this group of taxpayers, see OECD (2009).
22
3. Policies to raise the efficiency of tax administration
Box 3.6: Policy criterion 5 (condition for success) "Comprehensive use of electronic pre-
filling "
The use of electronic pre-filled tax returns lowers compliance costs, lowers costs of tax administration and
increases compliance. Tax authorities should pre-file tax returns based on third-party reports of labour and
savings income.
receiving a partly pre-filled tax return (see OECD, 2011). Substantial use of pre-filling to fully or partially
complete tax returns for a significant share of taxpayers also takes place in Belgium, Estonia, France,
Lithuania, the Netherlands, Portugal, Slovenia and Spain.
Tax authorities can pre-fill tax returns based on third-party reports of labour and savings income.
This concerns wage data from employers, positive and negative interest income, dividends and return to
shares and financial instruments as well as acquisition prices for shares and bonds etc. from financial
institutions and deductible expense such as union fees from unions (see Section 3.6 for further details on
third-party information). Other than third-party information, a pre-filled return may contain additional
hard information that the tax agency possesses such as an estimated commuting allowance based on
knowledge of the taxpayer's residence and work address. Where no third-party information exists, tax
authorities could use the information of the previous year as a starting point. Upon receiving the pre-filled
return, taxpayers have the option of making adjustments and of submitting a new return. The taxpayers'
access to making adjustments to the final tax return should be limited (by locking fields on the tax return)
to those types of income and deductions for which the tax authorities do not possess hard and reliable
information from third parties.
Pre-filled tax returns with third-party information make it easy for the taxpayer to comply and pay
taxes. However, third-party information cannot cover all taxpayers and all income types. In particular,
companies and self-employed will to a large extend have to assess their own income and deductible
expenses. For these taxpayers, it should be as easy as possible to fill in and file the tax return. While it
cannot be avoided that the tax rules in some cases are complicated, the filing process should be made easy
by appropriate IT solutions. As can be seen in Graph 3.4, the use of electronic filing varies widely across
Member States.
Graph 3.4: Use of electronic filing for PIT, CIT and VAT in 2009
100 100
90 90
80 80
70 70
60 60
50 50
40 40
30 30
20 20
10 10
0 0
AT BE CZ DK EE FI FR DE EL HU IE IT LU NL PO PT SK SL ES SE UK BG CY LV LT MT RO EA EU
Personal income tax Corporate profits/income tax Value added tax 17 27
Pre-filled tax returns make it easy for tax authorities to select taxpayers for audit. This is
particularly the case when taxpayers make significant downward adjustments to the pre-filled return.
23
European Commission
Improving tax governance in EU Member States: Criteria for successful policies
Box 3.7: Policy criterion 6 (condition for success) "Comprehensive use of third-party
reporting"
The coverage of third-party information available to tax authorities is crucial for limiting a normal taxpayer's
possibilities of under declaring income. Third-party information should be introduced wherever possible and
Member States should set up IT systems to handle the third-party data and use it systematically when
examining each taxpayer's situation. Member States should introduce requirements for employers to report
taxable remuneration for employees on an individual basis. This should also include fringe benefits.
Furthermore, Member States could require that financial institutions report interests and dividends as well as
purchase and selling prices of financial assets in order to automatically compute capital gains.
The whole process of handling the tax returns should be made electronic to the mutual benefit of
the taxpayer and the tax agency. For example, the administration of tax returns in Denmark is
completely automated since 2008 and taxpayers can access online their tax return information and the
related notice of assessment. Neither pre-filled tax returns nor a final tax assessment is sent to the
taxpayer on paper unless requested.
A preliminary and pre-filled tax return should be sent to the taxpayers and their workplace before
the beginning of the tax year. A preliminary and pre-filled tax return before the tax year ensures that a
taxpayer pays the taxes on a continuous monthly basis while the income is earned. The preliminary tax
return will vastly be based on information from the previous tax year.
Third-party reporting makes tax evasion considerably more difficult. There is a clear negative
correlation between the share of an income type reported by third parties, and the proportion of tax
evasion for the income type. Tax evasion varies widely across different income types, as the possibilities
to evade differ. This is primarily due to the feasibility of using third-party information for different
income types. In a detailed study on Danish data, Kleven et al. (2011) found that while only 2% of all
individuals who receive personal earnings (wages, transfers, etc.) reported too low incomes, and just over
4% of those with deductions do the same, tax evasion was discovered for almost 40% of individuals with
self-employment income. This reflects the coverage of third-party information, as seen from Table 3.1.
Over 90% of all personal income (wages, transfers, etc.) are reported via third parties. For self-employed
taxpayers, the share of income reported by third parties, however, is only just under 10 per cent. The
authors conclude that the extensive use of third-party information in Denmark makes Danes unable to
cheat, and that this is very important for tax compliance. The negative correlation between third-party
reporting and tax evasion is also identified in studies for the U.S. While there was a tax evasion on 1% of
the required tax payments for wages reported by third parties for the tax year 2001, the same share was
57% for self-employed business income that cannot be verified using third-party reporting.( 17)
24
3. Policies to raise the efficiency of tax administration
Ten Member States already use third party information to pre-fill tax returns. An overview of the
use of Third Party Information in the European Union by the Fiscalis Risk Management Platform
(European Commission, 2012), shows that Third Party Information regarding individual income is widely
available and include information received from other countries (within the EU, the Savings taxation
Directive – see Box 5.3 - provides for automatic exchange of information on interest payments made in
one Member State to any individual who is resident in another Member State). Ten Member States
(Belgium, Denmark, Finland, Lithuania, Malta, Netherlands, Portugal, Romania, Spain, Sweden) use the
information to pre-fill tax returns. Many Member States also use the information for audit or control and
for assessment. The majority of countries uses the information for risk analysis. It is also often used as a
source for debt collection. Details on sources and uses of third party information are included in
Appendix 2.
In most Member States, employers are obliged to report to the tax authorities the taxable wages
and royalties they pay their employees. Some Member States have expanded the obligation to conduct
third-party reporting to financial institutions regarding each account holder's interest payments (positive
and negative), dividends and yields on bonds, as well as the purchase and selling prices of shares and
bonds, whereby large parts of the taxpayer's capital income including capital gains can be automatically
calculated by the tax authorities.( 18)
Table 3.1: Third-party reporting and tax evasion by type of income in Denmark
Total 98 93 9
Note: Each person may have more types of income at the same time.
Source: Kleven et al. (2011) and Danish Economic Council (2011).
The better the coverage of third-party information, the more resources are freed up that can be
targeted, e.g., to areas reliant on self-reporting and to combating the shadow economy. For third-party
reporting to work, tax agencies need to be operating a certain level of IT-systems to handle the data and to
feed it into the taxpayer's final tax return. It should, however, be kept in mind that in small companies
with only a few employees, it could be relatively easy for the employee and employer to collaborate on
under declaring, and thus third-party reporting conducted by small businesses should not be totally
excluded from scrutiny.
For an effectively functioning tax administration it is essential to have a credible procedural justice
system in place. The main objective of such a functioning legal system – as the last step of the
(18) Some Member States also get information about non-monetary payments or benefits and withholding tax. And information on
tax allowable deductions e.g. kindergarten fees, charities and upgrading to environmentally friendly equipment.
25
European Commission
Improving tax governance in EU Member States: Criteria for successful policies
Box 3.8: Policy criterion 7 (condition for success) "Efficient procedural justice increasing
voluntary compliance"
Efficient procedural justice is important as the last stage of the compliance management chain. An
administrative complaint and tax dispute resolution system can often swiftly and fairly settle disputes
between tax authorities and taxpayers. Sufficiently high interest payments for deferred payments are a strong
incentive to achieve high rates of voluntary compliance.
compliance management process system – is to build trust in the tax system and encourage voluntary
compliance.
Tax legislation should provide procedural justice to the individual taxpayer. Tax authorities should
always inform taxpayers about their right to file a complaint about a decision, and they should reply and
settle any case within an acceptable time span and always provide taxpayers with an explanation for their
decision.
Most Member States have set up specialised National Tax Courts for adjudicating disputes over
direct and indirect taxes. This helps ensure that tax disputes are dealt with by highly qualified
professionals. Moreover, tax courts give an independent and objective ruling on tax disputes. They need
to be sufficiently staffed and have proper IT systems in place to avoid unnecessary backlogs that hamper
the enforcement of tax debts and reduce the credibility of the whole tax system in the citizens' eyes.
Any deferred payment of disputed taxes must be subject to interest payments of a sufficient level
and taxpayers could be charged a fee for submitting complaints. The charging of interests on any
deferred tax payment is necessary to avoid that appeal mechanisms and the legal system are exploited for
deference of tax payments. To avoid that in particular companies have an incentive to use outstanding tax
payments as a means of financing their business, the interest rate should be set at a sufficient level, i.e.
above the market rate. On the other hand, the interest rate should not be so high that it gives an incentive
to use too high tax payments as a savings account. Where a fee for submitting a complaint exists, it could
be recoverable in case the taxpayer wins the dispute.
To avoid too high a burden for the jurisdiction, it is important to have a mandatory administrative
appeal phase within the tax authority. This should lead to a resolution of many cases while recovering
the revenues required or releasing the undue amounts of tax in a timely manner. However, individual tax
authority officials should not have discretionary power to decide the correct amount of taxes from the
taxpayers they audit.
Finally, it is important to ensure that court decisions are effectively enforced. As far as possible,
automated systems should be used to collect those tax debts once a final court decision has been taken
against which no further appeal is possible. Moreover, to ensure payment the tax authorities should be
allowed to ask for sufficient collateral from taxpayers that go to court.
26
4. SPECIFIC MEASURES TO COMBAT THE SHADOW
ECONOMY
Raising the efficiency of tax administration will not be enough to combat the shadow economy. In
most Member States, undeclared work constitutes the vast majority of the shadow economy, while
undeclared or under declared sale of goods and services constitutes a minor part. Unlike for
underreporting of income or "over reporting" of tax deductions, it is difficult for tax authorities to detect
undeclared work in the process of audits of annual tax returns, as it is not possible to obtain third-party
reports of income from moonlighting and the activity is typically concealed both by the person
performing the work and the costumer. This means that detecting undeclared work through administrative
actions can be costly.
Undeclared work involves a welfare loss. The lack of taxation makes the after-tax return of
moonlighting disproportionately larger than comparable activities carried out in the formal economy. This
implies that too many economic resources and skills are allocated to the black sector, while the
productivity of undeclared work can be expected to be lower.(19) On the other hand, moonlighting
reduces the distortions caused by taxation in the form of reduced labour supply and income
transformation, as the tax wedge implies that some activities would not be carried out in the formal
economy, if not performed in the shadow. Furthermore, undeclared work represents an undesirable
redistribution from those who do not cheat, for people who cheat. The existence of undeclared work is
thus in conflict with the horizontal equity principle, which dictates that people with equal incomes should
be taxed equally. More commonly occurring moonlighting may make it more accepted in other people's
eyes, which can induce them to supply or demand moonlighting themselves. Therefore, another cost of
undeclared work is that it increases tax evasion in the future through deterioration of other taxpayers' tax
morale.
A variety of measures is applied in different Member States to combat the shadow economy. These
measures can be either of a deterrence nature or provide incentives to carry out the activities in the formal
economy. Moreover, electronic payments can help reduce the shadow economy, while the tax morale
deserves constant focus.
Several ways to deter people from using the shadow economy exist, but often prove to be costly and
difficult to implement. These measures have in common that they aim at making the use of shadow
economic activity riskier.
In principle, high penalties for undeclared work or other activity in the shadow economy could be a
successful way to combat the shadow economy as they would have a deterrent effect. However,
according to the principle of proportionality, there must be a reasonable relationship between the
severance of a crime and the penalty. Therefore, this is in general not an effective and sufficient way
forward.
A complimentary policy instrument to deter the shadow economy could be increased monitoring
and auditing. Increasing the probability that working in the shadow economy will be discovered also
reduces the expected gains from informality as would higher penalties. However, simply increasing
control efforts in terms of full-time equivalents could prove relatively costly compared to the direct
revenue gains.
(19) Moonlighting enables less efficient producers to offer services at a lower price and displaces more efficient (and taxpaying)
producers, and thus it leads to a poor allocation of resources (see, e.g., Palda, 1998).
27
European Commission
Improving tax governance in EU Member States: Criteria for successful policies
One promising way to fight the shadow economy is to punish buyers if the seller does not pay the
appropriate tax on the transaction, unless the buyer pays by electronic means.
A potentially powerful option would be to criminalize the purchase of undeclared work. Some
studies have shown that the buyer of undeclared work reap a large part of the evaded taxes through a
lower price.( 20) Thus, there is currently a lack of proportionality between the buyers' gain and their
potential punishment. Therefore, the current penalty for the supply of undeclared work is complemented
with an additional penalty placed on the buyer of moonlighting, which is not the case in most Member
States today. It should, however, be taken into account that it could be difficult for the buyer of a service
to ensure that the seller pays the statutory taxes. In Italy, purchase of undeclared work is illegal, but it is
sufficient for the buyer to show a receipt for the work performed, to avoid criminal liability. This also
applies to individuals purchasing services from private individuals. This system, however, creates an
administrative cost for the buyer, who must keep track of receipts. An alternative solution is to require the
purchaser to pay with electronic means in order to avoid criminal liability for purchases of undeclared
services (such a system has, e.g., been implemented in Norway and is foreseen in Denmark) or to keep
invoices for works carried out for them for some time (e.g. two years in Germany).
Introducing tax deductions for certain activities and sectors with a high prevalence of undeclared
work, i.e. monetary incentives, could be effective but very costly at the same time. This route is likely
to be very costly as it involves a high deadweight loss and implies an undermining of the vertical fairness
of the tax system.
Several countries (e.g. Belgium, Denmark, Germany and Sweden) have introduced or experimented
with tax deductions or subsidies for the purchaser of household services (such as cleaning,
babysitting, and construction work on the taxpayers' home) in recent years with rather disappointing
results. The argument used for such deductions is that they increase the formal market in specific sectors
with a high prevalence of shadow economy and home production. To benefit from the tax deductions, the
supply of the service normally has to be registered and in some cases the payment has to take place
through a specific electronic system registering the purchase. Although such tax credits and subsidies
may have a positive impact on employment in the formal economy, they tend to be expensive in terms of
forgone revenue and the experienced results in terms of reduction of the shadow economy have not been
convincing, in particular when compared to the cost of the measure.( 21) Moreover, these measures tend to
introduce a 'trap' which might lock in people in this kind of household jobs.
A commonly used measure in the fight against the shadow economy is the use of mandatory
electronic payments for purchases over a certain threshold. Such an obligation to pay purchases over
a certain amount by electronic means exists, e.g., in Italy (€ 2,500) and Greece (€ 1,500). Electronic
payments leave a trace that the tax authorities could possibly use for audits, which should have a deterrent
effect on potential tax evaders. Of course, this requires that tax authorities have sufficient legal provisions
28
4. Specific measures to combat the shadow economy
Box 4.2: Policy criterion 9 (point to watch) "Obligations to pay amounts above a certain
threshold by electronic means"
When subject to the obligation to pay purchases of relatively large amount electronically, purchasers would
leave a trace that could possibly be used for audits.
To further build on this, matching of taxpayers declared income with their life style and consumption
patterns monitored through use of bank cards etc. may effectively facilitate the detection of incomes.
to access data of individuals' electronic payments or bank accounts. This is currently not the case in all
Member States.
A related measure is to exploit data of an individual's electronic transactions and to compare them
with the declared income of the individual to detect tax evaders. If individuals have low reported
income and at the same time an elevated level of private consumption, it could be an indication that the
taxpayer is worth a closer audit. Italy pursues this strategy rather systematically with the so-called
'income meter', a procedure by which a computed level of income based on expenses made by the
taxpayer is compared with declared income to detect tax evaders. Also Denmark and Sweden are
exploiting data on electronic purchases for audits of taxpayers.
Tax morale is considered a key factor and encompasses several dimensions. In the conventional view
of economic models of taxpayer behaviour, taxpayers comply with tax laws if the expected penalty in
case evasion is detected exceeds the tax to be paid. However, a host of other factors such as social values,
public morality, and people’s perception about the public sector also matter in shaping attitudes to tax
laws. Dell'Anno (2009) argues that aggregate tax evasion may be largely explained by the taxpayers'
moral considerations and that tax morale is dependent on the taxpayers’ intrinsic attitudes to honesty and
social stigma. These attitudes are influenced by the taxpayers’ perceptions of the size of tax evasion, that
is how much everyone else evades, as well as by their perceptions of the policy maker's effectiveness and
ability to act in the interests of citizens. According to Slemrod (2007), taxpayers' adherence to the law
regarding tax payments depends on the taxpayers' perception about the fairness of the tax system and
whether the governments spends tax revenues in a satisfactory way. The extent of tax evasion can thus be
expected to decrease if the tax system is deemed to a greater extent as fair and just and if taxpayers
believe that the government provides a good service for the taxes paid.
Low tax morale can be contagious. If the individual justifies his evasion by the fact that everyone else
does it, existing tax evasion motivates further cheating. Therefore, it is important that governments
protect and nurse the tax morale of the population. This can be done by highlighting the risk of being
detected and securing. In combination with high actual detection probabilities, an active communication
strategy about successful control actions and detection of evaders can contribute to this. Using strategic
communication of successful detection and persecution of severe tax evasion could prove a cost effective
way to both underpin tax morale and increase the perceived detection probability.
The importance of tax morale means that tax compliance may also be strengthened by influencing
the taxpayers' attitudes and norms. This could be done through attitude campaigns, e.g. explaining why
one should comply and why it is unfair not to pay the required taxes. Attitude campaigns appeal to the
conciseness of taxpayers and explain how costly moonlighting is to society by making examples of what
could be achieved in terms of tax cuts or increased public spending for the revenue that would accrue in
absence of moonlighting. This will remind the campaigned taxpayer, that it is unbeneficial to him and the
29
European Commission
Improving tax governance in EU Member States: Criteria for successful policies
Box 4.3: Policy criterion 10 (condition for success) "Attitude campaigns improve tax
morale"
Tax authorities may strengthen the taxpayers' tax morale through attitude campaigns explaining why one
should pay the amount of taxes required and why it is unfair for other taxpayers if one does not pay the
required taxes. Attitude campaigns may be targeted towards younger taxpayers, who generally have lower
tax morale. Civic lessons at school could also help found a better tax morale.
society that other taxpayers evade, and, therefore, make him aware that he should not evade himself.
Especially young taxpayers are an important target group, as their tax morale is generally lower than for
all taxpayers as a whole.
Attitude campaigns have been used extensively in several Member States recently, e.g. the "Tænk
hvis alle arbejdede sort" in Denmark and the "Se tutti pagano le tasse, le tasse ripagano tutti" in Italy.
However, as Slemrod (2007) points out, the effectiveness of such campaigns has not been compellingly
demonstrated empirically.
30
5. SPECIAL TOPICS
Tax amnesties remain popular as an instrument aimed at raising revenue and increasing tax
compliance. The common inducement offered in exchange for voluntary disclosure of past untaxed
income is a significant but temporary reduction in tax liabilities including penalties. The argument for
instituting tax amnesty programmes is usually to forgo the tax revenue that has proven to be difficult to
enforce with the objective to secure a short term increase in tax revenue from that category of taxpayers.
In theory the costs of tax amnesty programmes are likely to exceed their benefits.(22) The
effectiveness of a tax amnesty would require (i) that the amnesty is a one-off and does not create
expectations of repeated amnesties in the future and (ii) the existence of a real and credible threat of
detection and punishment. These requirements are generally not fulfilled, and if (ii) is so, there might not
be a need for a tax amnesty. Even with these requirements fulfilled, there are important costs of initiating
a tax amnesty programme: (i) tax amnesties lead to vertical inequality as dishonest taxpayers are favoured
over honest taxpayers, (ii) the reduction in perceived fairness of the system may adversely affect the
compliance rates of otherwise honest taxpayers and (iii) initiation of a tax amnesty programme and
especially repetitions thereof are likely to create expectations of future programmes. This leads to a
perception among taxpayers that tax evasion could prove profitable.
The experience of tax amnesty programmes at country level is not encouraging. Several studies have
provided evidence that additional tax amnesties are likely to produce decreasing yields and discourage
future compliance (see Luitel and Sobel, 2007). Such programmes have, e.g., been implemented in Italy,
Greece and Germany. Most evidence suggests that tax amnesties generate little additional tax revenues
and also seem to have relatively little effects on post-amnesty compliance (see Alm, 2000). Furthermore,
the positive effects of past tax amnesties are likely to have been overestimated. Figures for received
amounts in a tax amnesty programme would invariably include amounts that might otherwise have been
collected in the normal course of tax enforcement. Moreover, the long term effects of deteriorating the tax
morale are never included.
VAT is widely recognised as an effective way of raising tax revenue. But like any other tax, VAT is
vulnerable to evasion and fraud. This is especially so in the EU, where the abolition of internal frontiers at
the end of 1992 opened up new areas of vulnerability.
The VAT compliance gap is large. As discussed in Chapter 2, it is estimated at an average of 12% of
liabilities in 2006 for the EU as a whole (see Reckon LLP, 2009).( 23) The bulk of VAT evasion can be
attributed to transactions in the shadow economy that are not reported, followed by underreporting of
taxable sales or exaggerating claims for refunds of VAT paid on business inputs. Contrived insolvency
fraud and carrousel fraud are particularly severe forms of VAT evasion, where few evaders can cause a
significant revenue loss. Organised carrousel fraud becomes more attractive the higher is the VAT rate,
whereas it is unlikely that shadow economy fraud will be reduced by applying lower rates to the
transactions that are not reported, because it remains attractive to evade the associated income tax.
VAT rate differentiation creates scope for misclassification fraud where the VAT liability is reduced
by exaggerating the proportion of sales in the lower-taxed categories. Moreover, sufficiently large rate
31
European Commission
Improving tax governance in EU Member States: Criteria for successful policies
Box 5.1: Policy criterion 11 (condition for success) "Avoiding tax amnesties"
Tax amnesties should be avoided despite the immediate revenue gains. They lower tax liabilities and the full
exposure of taxpayers to the risk of tax evasion. The consequent moral hazard leads to higher tax arrears in
the future and possibly a higher likelihood of another tax amnesty.
differentials can also give rise to refund entitlements for some traders (those using inputs taxed at a high
rate to produce outputs subject to a low VAT rate), which creates opportunities for abuse and extends the
scope of the refund problem beyond exports. Furthermore, reduced VAT rates are an inferior instrument
for distributional considerations compared to progressive income taxes and direct subsidies (see European
Commission, 2011). This points towards the application of a uniform VAT rate with exemptions only
based on the technical unfeasibility of taxation (for financial services for instance).
Abusive use of VAT refunding is difficult to control in real time. VAT is a tax on all commodity sales,
whether to consumers or to other businesses. However, registered businesses are able to credit the VAT
charged on their purchases (“input VAT”) against the VAT due on their sales (“output VAT”). Any
excess credits this creates are refunded to the taxpayer. According to the VAT Directive, commodities are
taxed by the jurisdiction in which they are consumed by zero-rating exports and intra-community supplies
and charging VAT on imports and intra-community acquisitions. Under the “invoice-credit” form,
registered businesses charge tax on their sales and issue corresponding invoices to their customers, who,
if they are also VAT registered businesses, can use these invoices to establish a right to credit or refund
against their own output VAT liability. These features of the VAT system are a crucial prerequisite for
the functioning of the internal market. However, they also leave the VAT system exposed to economic
crime. See Box 5.2 for a short description of some common types of VAT fraud.(24)
As VAT is a harmonized tax and a large part of problems with fraud is cross-border, work is being
done at EU level to combat fraud and evasion, notably through the use of administrative cooperation
provisions financed by the Fiscalis Programme.(25) Furthermore, the EU VAT Information Exchange
System (VIES) that enables traders to verify that their customer in another Member State is registered for
VAT is used to track transactions and thus can signal possible fraud.
The scope for VAT fraud partly depends on the speed with which VAT refunds are paid, compared
to VAT collections. Fraud that involves false refund claims by firms which subsequently disappear is
more attractive when VAT is refunded rapidly, because this gives the authorities less time to detect and
fight the fraud. However, traders should be able to rely on the right to obtain VAT refunds within a
certain period of time in order not to transform VAT into a tax on production, and on exports in
particular, rather than a tax on consumption. Whenever a new business is registered for VAT and
immediately claims large VAT refunds over a certain level, the business should routinely be checked by
the tax authorities to establish whether the business is genuine and its activities are legal. Alternatively, a
requirement could be introduced for some transactions and risky VAT refund reclaims for a third-party
processor to act as a clearer if a bank does not wish to perform this role.
Member States also use the reverse charge mechanism, placing VAT liability on the buyer rather
than the seller (with the amount thus paid fully creditable against the purchaser’s liability on any
subsequent sales), for business-to-business transactions in some sectors, to prevent VAT fraud (e.g. for
mobile phones, computer chips, and other particular goods that have proved popular instruments for
(24) See, e.g., Keen and Smith (2007) for a more detailed description of VAT fraud and possible measures to combat it.
(25) http://ec.europa.eu/taxation_customs/taxation/tax_cooperation/fiscalis_programme/index_en.htm
32
5. Special topics
“Acquisition fraud” (also called “contrived insolvency fraud” or “missing-trader fraud”) is a type of fraud in
which the zero-rating of intra-community supplies is combined with the “deferred payment” mechanism for
collecting VAT on acquired goods is exploited for economic crime by illegal claims of VAT refunds: A
company (B) buys goods from a company (A) in another Member State (which export the goods without
VAT) and sells the goods to a third company (C) (situated in the same Member State as company B) at a
price including VAT. However, company B disappears before paying the liable VAT. In other types of fraud,
a fake company simply claims VAT refunds based on fake invoices and then disappears. These types of fraud
are typically carried out by organized criminals, moving between Member States to perpetrate the fraud.
“Carousel fraud” is another important type of fraud that exploits the zero-rating of intra-community supplies
combined with the deferred payment of VAT on acquired goods: A company (B) buys goods from a company
(A) in another Member State (which supplies the goods without VAT). Suppose the VAT-free unit price at
which the good is sold is € 1000. Company (B) sells the goods to a buffer company (C) at a price shown as
including VAT, say € 1080 (€ 900 + € 180 VAT) if the VAT rate is 20%. However, company (B) disappears
before paying the liable VAT. The third company (C), which may be complying and know nothing of the
fraud, is used to conceal the fraud. Company (C) sells the goods to a fourth company (D), say at a price of
€ 1140 (€ 950 + € 190 VAT), and pays the VAT of € 10 (output VAT €190 – input VAT € 180). The fourth
company (D) pays this price including VAT on the purchase from the buffer company (C) and then supplies
(ICS) the goods back to the original company (A) in the other Member State at a price of € 980 (VAT
exempt) and claims a refund for VAT on exported goods of € 190; in effect it reclaims the VAT not paid by
the disappeared company (B) (i.e. € 190 – € 10 = € 180 which is 20% of the price company (B) had to pay on
its sale to company (C). In this example, all participants have a profit from the carousel arrangement. Every
member of the chain, although some might not be aware of the fact that they take part in a chain of fraud, gets
an advantage (namely the VAT is not paid to the government, but shared between the parties).
carousel fraud). However, reverse charging entails significant disadvantages. It de-facto converts VAT
into a general sales tax, with the possible problem of cascading, a higher risk for revenues as no tax is
collected if the final seller fails to pay VAT due and impediments for the free movement of goods and
services.
The EU ‘Anti-Fraud Strategy’ launched in 2006(26) resulted in a short term action plan presented by
the Commission in December 2008. (27) Since then the Commission has tabled all the legislative
proposals announced in this action plan and the Council adopted almost all of them. The result is a range
of new measures such as the creation of Eurofisc (28) and more automated exchanges of information
which are about to enter into force or did so only recently. Furthermore, the Commission is elaborating on
new ways of tackling fraud, i.e. the introduction of a quick reaction mechanism, strategies for improving
voluntary tax compliance, measures for improving the administrative cooperation with third countries and
studies on new tax collection systems. (29)
Negotiating the adoption of measures equivalent to those applied within the EU regarding
information exchange with non-EU countries with strong banking secrecy laws is a high priority of
the EU (see COM(2012) 351 final). The return to financial wealth in form of interests and dividends are
taxable in the home country of the owner of the assets and in a few Member States the wealth itself is
subject to a wealth tax. However, the existence of tax havens implies that wealth can be kept hidden from
33
European Commission
Improving tax governance in EU Member States: Criteria for successful policies
The EU Savings Directive (2003/48/EC) states that Member States must exchange information about
interest income earned on their respective territories on accounts held by individuals who are resident in
other EU countries. The aim of the Savings Directive is to enable effective taxation of the foreign interest
income of EU resident individuals in accordance with the rules of their Member State of residence. Initially,
it covered 25 EU Member States and, through agreements for the same or equivalent measures, 15 non-EU
jurisdictions of which 5 were fully independent countries (i.e. Switzerland, Andorra, Liechtenstein, Monaco
and San Marino) and 10 were dependent territories (i.e. Anguilla, Aruba, British Virgin Islands, Cayman
Islands, Guernsey, Isle of Man, Jersey, Montserrat, Netherlands Antilles and the Turks and Caicos Islands).
Negotiations with the 15 non-EU jurisdictions were concluded towards the end of 2004 and the Savings
Directive took effect simultaneously in all participating jurisdictions on 1 July 2005. The EU enlargement on
1 January 2007 brought the number of participating jurisdictions to 42.
The Savings Directive is based on automatic information exchange but also provides, on a transitional basis,
an alternative regime of international cooperation consisting in the levying of withholding taxes. The first
regime requires banks and other financial institutions to report interest income earned by foreign EU
residents to their local tax authorities who periodically and automatically convey this information to the tax
authorities of the residence country. The second regime requires banks to levy a withholding tax on the
interest income of foreign EU residents. The rate was gradually increased from 15% in 2005 to 20% in 2008
and 35% in 2011. Importantly, banks remit the revenues to domestic authorities with no information about
the identity of the taxpayers who thus remain anonymous. Since the withholding tax in the source country
effectively anticipates final taxation in the residence country, 75% of the revenue from the tax is transferred
to the residence country, leaving an incentive for the destination country to enforce the agreement. While
most EU countries adopted the information exchange regime, Austria, Belgium and Luxembourg as well as
11 of the non-EU jurisdictions including Switzerland (but excluding Anguilla, Aruba, the Cayman Islands
and Montserrat) opted for the withholding tax regime. However, in any jurisdiction where the withholding
tax regime is the default, individuals may avoid the withholding tax by accepting that information on interest
income is automatically transmitted to their country of residence. This implies that the withholding tax
effectively targets tax evaders unwilling to disclose tax relevant banking information.
Since 2010, some participant jurisdictions having originally opted for the withholding tax regime have
voluntarily switched to automatic information exchange (Belgium, Ile of Man, Guernsey, British Virgin
Islands, Turks and Caicos and part of the Netherlands Antilles).
the domestic tax authorities. The deregulation of international capital movement and technological
progress has significantly reduced the cost of moving capital across national borders. With an increasing
number of individuals now owning foreign financial assets, it becomes more difficult for domestic tax
authorities to keep track of their residences' tax base.
The Savings Directive (2003/48/EC) aims to ensure that a Member State can raise residence-based
taxes on its citizens' interest income in accordance with its domestic tax laws. The Savings Directive,
however, only covers interest income and does not ensure information sharing regarding the size of
deposits.(30) Furthermore, coordination through the EU and OECD has led to the conclusion of a number
of bilateral tax treaties with a scope for information exchange upon request. The incompleteness of treaty
networks and the existence of non-cooperating offshore jurisdictions imply that tax evaders generally
have the possibility to place assets in a jurisdiction that has no tax treaty with their country of residence
and thereby also avoid the taxation of the interest income. See Box 1 for further details on the Savings
Directive.
(30) For the majority of Member States which share information on individuals' interest income, the value of deposits can be
approximated by applying an imputed return. For the remaining countries (Luxembourg, Austria and non-EU countries) which
are not sharing individual information, but opting for a withholding tax instead, it is more difficult to assess the value of bank
deposits concerned and to ensure that final taxation of a given individual is correct.
34
5. Special topics
The Savings Directive has a limited scope and tax evaders may circumvent its provisions in a
number of ways. Firstly, geographical coverage is partial; hence moving assets to a non-participating
jurisdiction is a simple and effective evasion strategy. Secondly, transferring the formal ownership of
assets to a trust in a non-participating jurisdiction suffices to fall outside its scope. Thirdly, since the
currently applicable Savings Directive does not include a so called substance-over-form test(31),investors
may engage in a type of income shifting whereby interest bearing assets are replaced with structured
products with returns linked to leading interest rates. Although in substance such derivatives are identical
to debt claims, their returns are not formally interest payments and are therefore not subject to the
provisions of the Savings Directive.
On 13 November 2008, the Commission adopted an amending proposal to the Savings Taxation
Directive(32) with a view to closing existing loopholes and better preventing tax evasion.(33)
Exchange of information provides tax administrations with invaluable information on income received
and assets owned by their taxpayers. The information can also be particularly useful for risk analysis
purposes and can serve as an incentive to voluntary compliance. The use of automatic exchange of
information should be promoted where it is the most useful. The Commission has developed
computerised formats for savings income and is currently developing new formats for income covered by
Directive 2011/16 in order to implement secure and enhanced automatic exchange of information within
the EU. The EU has a key role to play in promoting its standard of automatic exchange of information so
as to give support to developing international standards of transparency and exchange of information in
tax matters.
(31) The substance-over-form principle is an accounting concept used to ensure that the economic impact and not the legal form is
used as basis for determining tax liability etc.
(32) Council Directive 2003/48/EC of 3 June 2003 on taxation of savings income in the form of interest payments (OJ L 157 of
26.6.2003, p.38).
(33) The content of the Amending Proposal is not yet fully agreed by Member States.
35
REFERENCES
Alm, J. (2000), Tax Compliance and Administration, in: Handbook of Taxation, Jildreth, W. B. and J.A.
Richardson (eds.), New York, Marcel Dekker, pp. 741-768.
Baer, K. and E. Le Borgne (2008), Tax Amnesties: Theory, Trends, and Some Alternatives, International
Monetary Fund.
Brondolo, J. (2009), Collecting Taxes During an Economic Crisis: Challenges and Policy Options, IMF
Staff Position Note, SPN/09/17.
Dell’Anno, R. (2003), Estimating the Shadow Economy in Italy: a Structural Equation Approach.
Working Paper 2003-7, Department. of Economics, University of Aarhus, Denmark.
Dell'Anno, R. (2009), Tax evasion, tax morale and policy maker's effectiveness. Journal of Socio-
Economics, 38 (6), pp. 988-997.
European Commission (2010), Compliance risk management guide for tax administrations, Fiscalis Risk
Management Platform, DG TAXUD.
European Commission (2011), Tax reforms in EU Member States 2011 – Tax policy challenges for
economic growth and fiscal sustainability, European Economy 5/2011.
European Commission (2012), An Overview of the use of Third Party Information in the European
Union, Fiscalis Risk Management Platform, DG TAXUD.
Hvidtfeldt, C., Jensen, B., and C. Larsen (2010), Danskerne og det sorte arbejde (Undeclared work and
the Danes), University Press of Southern Denmark, 2010.
Keen, M. and S. Smith (2007), VAT Fraud and Evasion: What Do We Know, and What Can be Done?,
IMF Working Paper 07/31.
Kidd, M. (2010), Revenue Administration: Functionally Organized Tax Administration, IMF, Fiscal
Affairs Department, June 2010.
Kleven, H.J., Knudsen, M.B., Kreiner, C.T., Pedersen, S., and E. Saez (2011), Unwilling or Unable to
Cheat? Evidence from a Tax Audit Experiment in Denmark. Econometrica, 79, pp. 651-692.
Luitel, H.S. and R.S. Sobel (2007), The Revenue Impact of Repeated Tax Amnesties, Public Budgeting
and Finance/Fall 2007, Volume 27, No. 3, pp. 29-30.
OECD (2009), Engaging with High Net Worth Individuals on Tax Compliance, OECD Publishing.
OECD (2010), Forum on tax administration: Small /Medium Enterprise (SME), Compliance Subgroup,
Information Note, November 2010.
36
References
OECD (2011), Forum on tax administration – tax administration in OECD and selected non-OECD
countries: comparative information series, OECD Publishing.
Palda, F. (1998), Evasive Ability and the Efficiency Cost of the Underground Economy. The Canadian
Journal of Economics, 31 (5), pp. 1118-1138.
Palil, M. R. and A.F. Mustapha (2011), The Evolution and Concept of Tax Compliance in Asia and
Europe, Australian Journal of Basic and Applied Sciences, Vol. 5 (11), pp. 557-563.
Pedersen, S. (2003), The Shadow Economy in Germany, Great Britain and Scandinavia. A measurement
based on questionnaire surveys, Rockwool Foundation Research Unit, Study No. 10, 2003.
PwC, World Bank and IFC (2011), Paying Taxes 2012 – The Global Picture.
Reckon LLP (2009), Study to quantify and analyse the VAT gap in the EU-25 member states, Report for
DG Taxation and Customs Union, September 2009.
Russell, B. (2010b), Revenue Administration: Managing the Shadow Economy, Technical Notes and
Manuals.
Schneider, F. (2005), Shadow Economies Around the World: What Do We Really Know?, European
Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 21/3, pp. 598-642.
Schneider, F. (2011a), Size and Development of the shadow economy of 31 European and 5 other OECD
Countries from 2003 to 2011, September 2011.
Schneider, F. (2011b), The Shadow Economy in Europe, 2011: Using electronic payment systems to
combat the shadow economy, study.
Slemrod, J. (2007), Cheating Ourselves: The Economics of Tax Evasion, Journal of Economic
Perspectives, 21 (1), pp. 25-48.
Slemrod, J. and S. Yitzhaki (2002), Tax Avoidance, Evasion and Administration, Handbook of Public
Economics, in: A.J. Auerbach and M. Feldstein (eds.), Handbook of Public Economics, Edition 1,
Volume 3, Chapter 22, pp. 1423-1470.
Thießen, U. (2010), The Shadow Economy in International Comparison: Options for Economic Policy
Derived from an OECD Panel Analysis, DIW Discussion Papers, 1031.
Williams, C.C. (2008), Tackling undeclared work in the European Union, Selected Works, Policy Studies
Organization.
37
Statistical annex
Major tax types administered by the national revenue body/ multiple directorates/2
Nature of
Country Real Estate Wealth Motor
body (*)/1 PIT CIT VAT Excises SSCs
estate taxes taxes vehicles
Austria SDMOF ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✗ ✗ ✗ ✓ ✗
Belgium MDMOF/1 ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓/2 ✗ ✗ ✗ ✓ ✗
Bulgaria USBB ✓ ✓ ✓ ✗ ✗ ✗ ✗ ✗ ✓
Cyprus MDMOF/1 ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✗ ✗ ✗ ✗
Czech
SDMOF ✓ ✓ ✓ ✗ ✓ ✓ ✗ ✓ ✗
Republic
Denmark USB/1 ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✗ ✓ ✗
Estonia SDMOF ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✗ ✗ ✓/2 ✓
Finland USBB ✓ ✓ ✓ ✗/2 ✓ ✓ ✗ ✗/2 ✓
France SDMOF ✓ ✓ ✓ ✗ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✗
Germany MDMOF/1 ✓ ✓ ✓ ✗ ✓/2 ✓ ✗ ✓/2 ✗
Greece MDMOF ✗ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✗
Hungary USB ✓ ✓ ✓ ✗ ✗ ✓ ✓ ✗ ✓
Ireland USB ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✗ ✓ ✗ ✓ ✓
Italy Other /1 ✓ ✓ ✓ ✗ ✓ ✓ ✗ ✗ ✓
Latvia USB ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✗ ✗ ✓ ✓
Lithuania SDMOF ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✗ ✗ ✗
Luxembourg MDMOF/1 ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✗ ✓ ✓ ✗ ✗
Malta MDMOF/1 ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✗ ✓ ✗ ✗ ✓
Netherlands SDMOF ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✗/2* ✓ ✗/2** ✓ ✓
Poland MDMOF/1 ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✗ ✓ ✓ ✗ ✗
Portugal MDMOF ✓ ✓ ✓ ✗ ✓ ✓ ✗ ✓ ✗
Romania USB ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✗ ✗ ✗ ✗ ✓
Slovak
USB ✓ ✓ ✓ ✗ ✗/2 ✗ ✗ ✓ ✗
Republic
Slovenia USB ✓ ✓ ✓ ✗ ✓ ✓ ✗ ✓ ✓
Spain USB ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✗ ✗ ✓/2 ✓/2 ✗
Sweden USBB/1 ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✗ ✗ ✓ ✓
UK USBB ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✗ ✗ ✓/2
(*) USB - Unified semi-autonomous body; USBB - Unified semi-autonomous body with formal board or advisory group comprised of external
officials; SDMOF - Single directorate in MOF; MDMOF - Multiple directorates in MOF
* Municipalities tax real property; Tax and Customs Administration taxes acquisition.
**Wealth tax since 2001 incorporated in PIT;
Table notes: /1. Belgium- The Federal Public Service Finances is now comprised of six general administrations: 1) taxation; 2) collection and recovery
of taxes; 3) serious tax fraud; 4) customs and excise; 5) patrimonial documentation; and 6) treasury; Cyprus, Luxembourg, Malta- There are separate
directorates for Direct Taxes, Indirect Taxes, and/or Customs and Excise; Denmark- As of March 2010, the Danish Tax Administration has merged
with the Danish Ministry of Taxation to form a single unified and autonomous tax administration with a corporate structure, headed by a single
(internal) board chaired by the Permanent Secretary of the Ministry of Taxation; this integrated Danish revenue body is now officially referred to as
the "Danish Ministry of Taxation"(Skatteministeriet); Germany- Major taxes are administered separately by 16 State (Länder) MOFs, and subject to
co-ordination and supervision by the Federal MOF; additionally, a Federal Central Tax Office, subordinated to the Federal MOF, performs certain
central functions; Italy- Tax administration functions are carried out by a number of separate government and partly government-owned bodies: 1)
Revenue Agency (Agenzia Entrate) , main stream operations), 2) Guardia di Finanza (tax fraud), 3) Customs Agency (excise and VAT on imports), 4)
Equitalia Spa (tax debt collection), and 5) SOGEI (information processing); Poland- With common head, Secretary of State; Sweden- Swedish Tax
Agency with advisory council;
/2. Belgium- Specific general administration of customs and excises; Estonia-Heavy goods vehicle tax; Finland- Excise and motor vehicle taxes
administered by separate state bodies; Germany- Revenue bodies determine property values for real property tax collected by municipalities; the motor
vehicle tax will be administered by the Länder tax administrations by means of the official delegation of powers to them until 30 June 2014;
Netherlands- * Municipalities tax real property; Tax and Customs Administration taxes acquisition. **Wealth tax since 2001 incorporated in PIT;
Spain- Revenue body collaborates only in some aspects; wealth tax was abolished.
Source: OECD (2011): Tax Administration in OECD and selected non-OECD countries. Comparative Information Series (2010).
38
Statistical annex
Table A.2: Sources and uses of third party information on individual income
Source: European Commission (2012), An Overview of the use of Third Party Information in the European Union, Fiscalis Risk Management
Platform Group, DG TAXUD.
39
KC-AH-12-114-EN-N