Exxon Mobil Merger
Exxon Mobil Merger
Exxon Mobil Merger
J. Fred Weston* The Anderson School at UCLA University of California, Los Angeles [email protected]
Fred Weston is Professor of Finance Emeritus Recalled, the Anderson School at the University of California Los Angeles. Thanks to Matthias Kahl, Samuel C. Weaver, Juan Siu, Brian Johnson, and Kelley Coleman for contributions. The paper also benefited from comments at its presentation to the 1999 Financial Management Association Meetings (Orlando).
ABSTRACT: In response to change pressures, the oil industry has engaged in multiple adjustment processes. The 9 major oil mergers from 1998 to 2001 sought to improve efficiency so that at oil prices as low as $11 to $12 per barrel, investments could earn their cost of capital. The Exxon-Mobil combination is analyzed to provide a general methodology for merger evaluation. The analysis includes: the industry characteristics, the reasons for the merger, the nature of the deal terms, discounted cash flow (DCF) spreadsheet valuation models, DCF formula valuation models, valuation sensitivity analysis, the value consequences of the merger, antitrust and competitive reaction patterns, and the implications of the clinical study for merger theory. JEL classification: G34, G20 Keywords: Mergers; Acquisitions; Alliances
Major horizontal mergers took place during the 1998-2001 period. The BPAmoco merger (announced on 8/11/98) projected $2 billion in savings, stimulating other oil companies to seek improvements in operations. The Exxon-Mobil combination was announced on 12/1/98. In December 1998, the French oil firm Total (founded in 1924 as Compagnie Franaise des Ptroles) announced the acquisition of PetroFina, a large Belgian oil company. On 7/5/99, the new TotalFina began a $43 billion hostile bid for the former state-owned Elf Aquitaine; the deal was completed at a price of $48.8 billion and became the fourth largest world oil company. On 4/1/99, an agreement was reached for BP Amoco to acquire Arco following negotiations initiated by Arcos management. The U.S. Federal Trade Commission (FTC) required that Arco sell its Cushing, Oklahoma operations and its Alaskan crude-oil assets (Phillips Petroleum became the buyer). After rejecting a merger proposal from Chevron in June 1999, Texaco agreed to a takeover announced 10/16/00. In October 1998, DuPont did an equity carve-out of 30% of Conoco; the remaining 70% was spun-off to shareholders in August 1999. On 5/29/01, Conoco purchased Gulf Canada Resources. Phillips Petroleum acquired Tosco, the largest U.S. independent refiner, on 2/4/01. On 11/18/01, Phillips and Conoco agreed on a merger of equals; ConocoPhillips would become the worlds sixth-largest oil and gas company based on reserves. The motives and consequences of these mergers were similar. In this paper, the Exxon-Mobil transaction is analyzed as representative of these major oil merger transactions. As a clinical study, this paper seeks to provide a format for analyzing mergers under eight major topics: (I) industry characteristics, (II) merger motivations, (III) deal terms and event returns, (IV) valuation analysis, (V) sensitivity analysis, (VI)
tests of merger performance, (VII) antitrust considerations, and (VIII) tests of merger theory.
I. Industry Characteristics
The oil industry, like other industries, has been forced to adjust to the massive change forces of technology, globalization, industry transformations, and entrepreneurial innovations. The oil industry has some special characteristics as well. Oil is a global market with 53% of volume internationally traded. It accounts for about 10% of world trade, more than any other commodity. While the oil market is world in scope, oil varies in quality and the requirements for pipelines and other specialized distribution and marketing facilities cause geographic market segmentation.
A. The Impact of OPEC The Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC) has a major influence. Because their production costs are low, OPEC has a substantial influence on oil prices. But the pricing power of OPEC has been constrained. In the early 1970s, OPECs share of the world market was about 55%. The Arab oil embargo in 1973 was associated with more than a three-fold increase in the real price of oil. In response, factories altered production processes away from the use of oil. Consumers increased insulation in their homes, bought smaller cars, and took other energy conservation measures. At higher prices, exploration for oil was stimulated. Wells that had previously been shut down, again became profitable resulting in increased non-OPEC production.
By 1985, the market share of OPEC had dropped to below 30%. This experience demonstrated that the pricing power of OPEC was limited. In their periodic meetings OPEC has sought to balance production quotas against forecasts of demand and of nonOPEC supply changes with the aim of holding OPECs market share to a relatively stable 40%. But recurrent cheating on production quotas has occurred as predicted by economic models of cartel behavior. In addition, economic development requirements in OPEC countries create internal pressures for production increases.
B. Oil Price Instability The interactions of cartel policies and market forces have produced oil price instabilities. In Table 1, crude oil prices for the years 1949 through 2000 are presented in both nominal and real terms. In real terms yearly oil prices declined from $14.71 in 1949 to $10.66 in 1972. The two oil price shocks of the 1970s raised oil prices to almost $51 (real) a barrel by 1981, almost a five-fold increase. Table 1 Saudi Arabia had been the buffer country to absorb the cheating of other members to keep overall OPEC quotas on target. On 11/20/85, the price of West Texas intermediate crude was $31.75 per barrel (nominal). On 12/9/85, Saudi Arabia announced that it would stop performing the buffer role and would seek to recover some of its lost market share. By early 1986, oil prices had dropped to $10 per barrel (nominal), a decline of 68.5%.
C. Early Restructuring Activities in the U.S. Oil Industry In the 1980s, the marginal returns from U.S. oil industry domestic exploration and development (E&D) activities were negative. In this setting, Jensen (1986) formulated his free cash flow theory, arguing that internally generated funds resulted in ill-advised diversification. Oil industry examples included acquisitions in mining such as Cyprus Mines by Amoco, Anaconda Copper by Arco, and Kennecott Copper by Sohio. Exxon produced an electric motor and sought to develop it further by acquiring Reliance Electric. The expertise in information systems analysis developed in exploration activities by Exxon was extended to the office systems and equipment businesses. The purchase by Mobil of Marcor included forest products, container business, and the Montgomery Ward retailing operations. Horizontal oil industry mergers also took place. The largest oil mergers in the eighties are summarized in Table 2. The transactions totaled over $60 billion. The driving force in these mergers was illustrated by the Harvard Business School (HBS) case (Rock, 1988; Ruback, 1992) on the Gulf Oil takeover. The case presented data showing that a firm buying Gulf could avoid a destruction of shareholder value of $50.36 per share by shutting down Gulfs exploration and development (E&D) programs. Adding these savings to the premerger $39 market price of Gulf gives a value of $89.36 per share, justifying the $80 per share paid by Chevron to win the auction contest conducted by Gulf. Table 2 T. Boone Pickens used this logic in making the initial bid in a number of takeovers listed in Table 2. His strategy was to take a toehold position and threaten a tender offer (Shleifer and Vishny, 1986). If the target found other bidders, Pickens sold
out at a profit. For example, through his Mesa Petroleum, in May 1982 he purchased a 5.1% stake in the Cities Service Oil Company at prices estimated to be around $35.50 per share (Ruback, 1983). A multiple bidder contest ensued including Gulf, Mobil, Amerada Hess, and Occidental Petroleum. On 6/17/82 Gulf agreed to purchase Cities Service, but on 8/2/82 the FTC obtained a restraining order. On 8/9/82 Gulf terminated its offer. On 8/23/82 Mobil decided not to bid. Finally, on 8/25/82 Cities accepted an Occidental bid of $55 a share for 45% of Cities Service shares and an exchange of zero coupon notes and preferred stock for the remainder. Some takeover contests resulted in the sale of oil companies to firms outside the industry. Seagram (liquor) initially bid for Conoco on 6/19/81 (Ruback, 1982). The subsequent bidding contest included Mobil and DuPont. On 8/5/81, DuPont announced that it had received tenders for 55% of Conoco stock, ending the contest. (In 1999 DuPont did an equity carve-out and spin-off of Conoco). Mobil also entered the bidding when Marathon Oil had reached a tentative agreement with U.S. Steel in 1981 including a lockup option to buy its prized asset, the Yates Oil Field. Although this lockup option was invalidated by the courts, Mobils bid encountered antitrust obstacles. U.S. Steel won the bidding contest for Marathon Oil. The above examples are sufficient to suggest that no oil company of any significant size was immune to a takeover threat during the early 1980s. Their stock prices were depressed. It was cheaper to buy oil reserves on Wall Street than by E&D outlays. These pressures caused the major oil companies to engage in a wide range of restructuring activities. Programs for cost reduction were developed. Changes in organizational structure and systems sought to increase efficiency, flexibility, and
responsiveness to change. Reductions in capacity and employment took place. Between 1980 and 1992, employment at eight major oil companies was reduced from 800,000 to 300,000, a reduction of 62.5% (Cibin and Grant, 1996). Headquarters staff was reduced from 3,000 to 800 in six major oil companies during the period from 1988-1992. Because of fluctuating oil prices, efforts were made to change cost structures from fixed to variable costs. These efforts included replacing owned assets, such as tankers, with leasing (Cibin and Grant, 1996). Fundamental changes in organization structures were also made. Initially a unitary or functional organization structure was employed representing a relatively high degree of centralization of managerial authority. With diversification, the H form of structure was employed. This involved a holding company with unrelated subsidiary activities. After substantial divestitures, most companies moved toward the M form with multidivisional activities. This form was characterized by a strong central staff, decentralized divisional operations, active communication between divisions, staff support from headquarters, and functional staff groups for related groups of activities (Ollinger, 1994; Roeber, 1994). The M&A activity of the oil industry can be viewed as a response to price instability. Oil firms sought to invest in new technologies to reduce costs. Previous restructuring efforts and improvements in technologies had lowered costs to $16 to $18 per barrel. Oil prices declined to $9 per barrel in late 1998. Thus, the overriding objective for the mergers beginning in 1998 was to further increase efficiencies to lower breakeven levels toward the $11 to $12 per barrel range.
A. Comparable Valuations Comparisons may be made with comparable firms or with comparable transactions. Both employ ratios such as (1) enterprise market value/revenues, (2) enterprise market value/EBITDA, or (3) enterprise market value/free cash flows. The comparables method has wide appeal and broad use. It seeks to measure what has occurred in similar situations in the market place. However in application, it is often difficult to find truly comparable companies or transactions. In the Exxon-Mobil merger, J.P. Morgan, financial advisor to Exxon, reviewed 38 large capitalization stock-for-stock transactions. Their data indicated that a premium of 15% to 25% for Mobil matched market precedent (Joint Proxy to Shareholders, 4/5/99). Goldman Sachs for Mobil used 6 large oil companies judged to be similar to Mobil. The two ratios used were price/earnings and price/cash flows. For 1999, the estimated price/earnings ratio range was 19.3 to 23.8 times. The estimated price/cash flows ratios were 8.5 to 12.5. Both the premium analysis by J.P. Morgan and the ratio ranges of Goldman Sachs result in a relatively wide spread of values. The comparables method in practice fails to arrive at definitive values. This result flows from important conceptual reasons. The companies used in the comparisons are likely to have different track records and opportunities even though they are in similar
10
businesses and comparable in size. They are likely to differ in their prospective (1) growth rates in revenues, (2) growth rates in cash flows, (3) riskiness (beta) of companies, (4) stages in the life cycles of industry and company, (5) competitive pressures, or (6) opportunities for moving into new expansion areas (Weston, Siu and Johnson, 2001).
B. Discounted Cash Flows (DCF) Valuation DCF valuation is basically the capital budgeting net present value (NPV) calculation. The gross returns from an investment (GPV) are netted against investment outlays to obtain free cash flows which are discounted at an appropriate rate to obtain NPV or value. The leading valuation methods differ somewhat with respect to the measurement of returns, investments, and discount factors. The choice of discount factor involves the use of a weighted average cost of capital (WACC) versus an adjusted present value approach (APV). The percentage of sales method measures cash flows with reference to sales, discounting free cash flows by WACC. This method is widely used by consulting firms. The methodology is developed in the successive editions of Copeland et al (2000) and Cornell (1993). Miller and Modigliani (1961, 1963) developed two approaches. The first used the WACC, but keyed on an incremental return on investments and on an investment rate normalized by net operating profit after taxes. The second capitalized future after-tax cash flows by the cost of capital of an unlevered firm to which were added adjustments for tax savings and other benefits. Hence it was called the adjusted present value method (APV). Miller and Modigliani discounted the adjustments with the after-tax cost of debt.
11
In their empirical analysis of valuations, Kaplan and Ruback (1995) discounted the adjustments with the cost of capital for unlevered firms, calling it the Compressed Adjusted Present Value Model (CAPV). Most finance textbooks use a dividend valuation model under alternative assumptions about the patterns of future dividends. These dividend valuation models require modifications for share repurchases (Lamdin, 2000; Randall, 2000). Kaplan and Ruback (KR) (1995) used CAPV to predict the actual transaction values for a sample of 51 highly leveraged transactions. They found that 60% of the forecasts were within 15% of the actual transaction value with an average overall error of about 20%. Gilson, Hotchkiss, and Ruback (2000) applied the CAPV model and the comparable companies methodology to a sample of 63 firms emerging from Chapter 11 reorganization. The error terms were larger than in the earlier KR study, with the DCF valuations more accurate than the comparables method. After reviewing these and other studies, Martin and Petty (2000) conclude that all have large prediction errors, but their use in practice helps firms improve performance. Economic fluctuations and competitive activities cause valuation estimates to be subject to error. However, identification of the key determinants of value (value drivers) can be useful in guiding the firm to timely revisions of policy and practices. We use the WACC and APV percentage of sales methods in the valuation of ExxonMobil. We start with estimates of the costs of capital needed for discounting the cash flows.
12
C. Cost of Capital Calculations To obtain the discount factors needed for the DCF valuations, estimates of the cost of equity, of debt and their weighted costs are needed. The Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM) is most widely used to calculate the cost of equity. As a check, the cost of equity should be higher than the before-tax cost of debt by 3 to 5 percentage points. The equation for the CAPM is: ke = rf + ERP (beta) where: ke rf = firms cost of equity = risk free rate measured by the expected yields on 10-year Treasury bonds ERP = equity risk premium measured by the market return less the risk free rate beta = the firms systematic risk the covariance of firms returns with the market returns divided by the market variance
The betas are first discussed. Published sources such as Value Line estimated a beta of 0.85 for Exxon and 0.75 for Mobil. Beta estimates are subject to estimation error. However, there is logic for beta levels below 1 for oil companies. The covariances of oil company stock returns with market returns are reduced by the oil industry special economic characteristics described above. We use a 5.6% yield on 10-year Treasuries as an estimate of the risk-free rate. We next consider the market equity risk premium (ERP). For many years, based on patterns of the long-term relationships between stock and bond returns, the market equity premium appeared to be in the range of 6.5% to 7.5%. By the mid 1990s, a new paradigm for a new economy began to emerge. Academics and practitioners had moved toward using 4% to 5% as the market price of risk (Welch, 2000). But with the stock
13
market adjustments beginning in 2000, the historical range of 6.5 to 7.5% is again reflected in market valuations. Using CAPM, with a risk-free rate of 5.6% and a market equity risk premium of 7%, Exxon with a beta of 0.85 would have an estimated cost of equity capital of 11.55%. Mobil with a beta of 0.75 would have a cost of equity capital of 10.85%. Cost of equity: Exxon: Mobil: ke = rf + ERP(beta) ke = 5.6% + 7%(0.85) = 11.55% ke = 5.6% + 7%(0.75) = 10.85%
For the before-tax cost of debt (kb), we follow the methodology used in the Paramount case by Kaplan (1995) and in Stewart (1991). Bond ratings and yield data have the virtue of being market-based. Exxon had a AAA bond rating, with yields to maturity at about 160 basis points above Treasuries, for an expected before-tax cost of debt for Exxon of about 7.2%. Mobil had a AA bond rating, requiring an additional 30 basis points over the Exxon debt cost, for an expected before-tax cost of debt for Mobil of 7.5%. These pretax cost of debt estimates indicate a risk differential of about three to four percentage points between equity and debt costs, providing further support for our cost of equity estimates. Theory calls for using market values in assigning weights to the cost of equity and the cost of debt to obtain a firms weighted cost of capital. We have studied the leverage policies of the oil companies since 1980. Exxon has had debt-to-total capital (debt plus book equity) ratios as high as 30% to 40%, moving toward 20% in recent years. However, during major acquisition or other major investment programs, these debt-tocapital ratios have been at the higher 40% level. At market values, these ratios would be
14
lower. A similar analysis would apply for Mobil. Plausible target proportions are B/VL equals 30% and S/VL equals 70% where B and S are the market values of debt and equity, respectively, and VL equals the market value of the firm (B+S). We follow the literature and general practice in using target debt-equity proportions for decisions at the margin (Kaplan, 1995; Stewart, 1991; Copeland et al, 2000). This also has the advantage of solving the circularity problem of obtaining leveraged firm valuations (Copeland et al, 2000, p. 204) which depend on the tax benefit of debt. The prospective cash tax rates (T) are 35% for Exxon and 40% for Mobil. Accordingly, the weighted average cost of capital (WACC) for the two companies would be: WACC = (S/VL) ks + (D/VL) kb (1T) Exxon = 0.7 (0.1155) + (0.3)(0.072)(0.65) = 9.49% Mobil = 0.7 (0.1085) + (0.3)(0.075)(0.60) = 8.95% The mix of upstream and downstream activities of the two companies, and the combination of different geographic areas of operations would increase the stability of the combined cash flows. The larger size of the combined companies would enable them to take on larger and riskier investment programs than either could do independently. The critical mass size requirements for research and development efforts in all segments of the oil industry have been increasing, so the combination would be risk-reducing in that dimension as well. Value Line and other sources estimated a beta of 0.80 for the combined firm. Using a risk-free rate of 5.6% and an equity risk premium of 7% gives a cost of equity for ExxonMobil of 11.2%. The combined company has a strengthened AAA rating so Exxons 7.2% debt cost continues to be applicable. With a projected 38%
15
tax rate and a capital structure with 70% equity, the base case WACC is 9.18% for ExxonMobil: Combined WACC = 0.70(0.112) + 0.30(0.072)(0.62) = 9.18%
D. Application of the DCF Percentage of Sales Method to ExxonMobil Projections were developed for the combined company for the years 2001 and beyond as shown in Table 6. The historical patterns provided a foundation for the projections. But these were modified by a business-economic analysis of the future prospects for the oil industry. We studied contemporaneous analyst reports as well as materials from the Energy Information Administration of the U.S. Department of Energy, the Oil & Gas Journal, and consulting firms such as the Energy Economic Newsletter of the WTRG Economics. In Panel A of Table 6, the cash flow inputs are developed. We start with 1999 as the base net revenues of ExxonMobil and use the actual data for 2000. We then project growth rate percentages for net revenues for the years 2001 through 2010 and for the terminal period from 2011 forward. Table 6 The percentage relationships to revenues are developed in Panel B of Table 6. The product of revenues times the net operating margin gives net operating income (NOI). The NOI margin for the combined company increases as synergies are realized; however, this ratio is also dependent on the price of oil. Oil prices fluctuating around $20 per barrel (real) would balance OPEC production targets and non compliance by some producers with the objective of OPEC to maintain a 40% world market share of oil and oil equivalent revenues. Projections of revenue growth reflect the economics of the
16
industry. But oil price volatility makes revenue and operating income estimates in individual years provisional. Continuing in Panel A, the cash tax rates are applied to the NOI to calculate cash income taxes paid which are deducted to obtain net operating profit after taxes (NOPAT). Depreciation is added back since it is a noncash expense. Capital expenditures and changes in working capital are deducted. The disposal of duplicate facilities represents negative outlays shown in the changes in other assets net Line 10 in Panel A. The result is the projected free cash flows for ExxonMobil shown in Table 6, Panel A, Line 11. The patterns of free cash flows projected in Table 6 reflect the economic environment of the oil industry as well as the integration of the two companies. The discount factors calculated in the previous section are applied to the free cash flows in Table 6 to obtain the present values of the free cash flows for 2000-2001 shown in Line 14 of Panel A. These items sum to a total present value of $130,331 million shown in the middle section of Panel C, Line (1). The exit value or terminal value is calculated next. The formula for calculating terminal value with constant growth is the free cash flow in the (n+1) period discounted at the difference between the terminal period WACC and the growth estimate for the terminal period. (In the special case where the terminal period growth is zero, the numerator becomes the n+1 period NOPAT and the denominator becomes the terminal period WACC). The projected continuing growth rate of the free cash flows of 2011 and beyond for ExxonMobil is 3% per year. The estimated terminal value in 2010 is: Terminal Value n = FCFn +1 $27,892 = = $451,327 million WACC g 0.0918 0.03
17
The present value of the terminal value is obtained by discounting the terminal value back to the present using WACC.
$451,327 = $451,327 0.38056 = $171,757 million (1.0918)11 This result is shown in Panel C, Line (2). The sum of (1) the discounted cash flows of the high growth period plus (2) the discounted cash flows of the terminal period plus (3) the initial marketable securities balance gives (4) the total value of the firm of $302,161 million. From total firm value we deduct total interest-bearing debt to obtain the indicated market value of equity. We divide by the total number of shares outstanding to obtain the intrinsic value per share of $81.45 or $40.725 after the 2-for-1 split of 7/19/01. The resulting indicated share price reflects the projections of the key value drivers. Such provisional results are used in a continuing process of reassessing economic and competitive impacts related to the firms operating performance and adjustments. The results reflect the value driver estimates that determine the firms projected intrinsic value. The intrinsic value projections are planning benchmarks to be monitored by the firm. They can provide the basis for setting performance targets and performancebased compensation systems. Sensitivity analysis establishes that small changes in these value drivers can have a substantial impact on estimates of firm values.
In Table 7 we apply the APV method. Panel A of Table 7 is identical to Panel A of Table 6 down through Line 11, the free cash flows. Instead of discounting by WACC, we discount the free cash flows by the unlevered cost of equity of ExxonMobil. To
18
obtain the unlevered cost of equity, CAPM is used with the unlevered beta calculated by applying the following expression: U = L / [1 + (D/S)(1T)] where: U L D S T = = = = = unlevered beta levered beta market value of debt market value of equity cash tax rate
Table 7
For ExxonMobil, the observed levered beta was 0.80. Since the D/VL ratio is 0.30, the D/S ratio is 0.429. The unlevered beta becomes: U = 0.80 / [1 + (0.429)(10.38)] = 0.632 and the unlevered cost of equity is: kU = rf + ERP(U) = 5.6% + 7% (0.632) = 10.02% The cost of equity unlevered of 10.02% is used in Line 12 of Table 7. This is the discount factor employed to calculate the present values of the free cash flows shown in Line 14. When these yearly present values are summed, they equal the present value of the cash flows over the period 2000-2010 shown in Panel C Line (2) as $124,465 million. The calculation of the terminal value proceeds as before. However, the calculation of the discount factor uses the cost of equity of an unlevered firm instead of WACC. Terminal value =
$27,892 $27,892 = = $397,322 million 0.1002 0.03 0.0702 $397,322 = $397,322 0.34979 = $138,979 million (1.1002)11
19
The present value of the terminal value becomes $138,979 million. The total value of ExxonMobil as an unlevered firm is $263,444 million as shown in Table 7, Panel C, Line (4). We next need to calculate the present value of the tax shield (TS). This is developed in Table 8. This follows the logic in the Modigliani-Miller (1963) tax correction article. We derive the present value of the tax shield as a function of the value of ExxonMobil as an unlevered firm (which we calculated in Table 7 to be $263,444 million), the target leverage ratio, and the actual cash tax rate. The present value of the tax shield is shown to be $33,897 million. In Table 7, we add this amount to the value of the unlevered firm to obtain its value as a levered firm of $297,341 as shown in Panel C, Line (6) . The remaining calculations follow the procedures of Table 6 to obtain approximately the same intrinsic value of $80.08 per share ($40.04 after the split). Table 8
F. DCF Formula Valuation
The formula approach to DCF valuation summarizes the value driver inputs in a compact framework which relates the input variables to broader economic forces. For example, suppose we have a forecast of the growth of the U.S. economy of 5.0% for the next ten years, with 2.5% real and 2.5% inflation. In this overall economic environment, we postulate that revenues in the oil industry grow at 3% a year. We project ExxonMobil to grow at a somewhat higher rate per year for the next ten years. This implies some growth in the firms market share. Some increased competitive pressures will develop. This may influence not only ExxonMobils revenue growth rates, but the magnitudes of other value drivers as well. Individual value drivers may need to be adjusted upward or
20
downward. This establishes the planning relationships between value drivers, performance results, and the resulting projected intrinsic value levels of the firm. This is at the heart of value based management. We can build on the spreadsheet approach to make estimates of the patterns of the value drivers for the initial growth period and for the terminal period in a systematic way. This is illustrated in Panel A of Table 9. Using ExxonMobil for illustration, we present projections of nine value drivers for the growth period and eight value drivers for the terminal period (the number of years is not applicable). The formula projections represent trend patterns for the up and down movements that may occur for individual years in the spreadsheet projections. Table 9 Panel B presents the formulas which are a mathematical summary of the steps in the spreadsheet procedure. The resulting firm values are shown in Panel C. The estimate of intrinsic value per share is about the same as in the spreadsheet calculation. We attach no significance to their equality. The exercise simply illustrates that the spreadsheet valuations and the formula valuations produce similar results.
V. Sensitivity Analysis
Much analysis and many judgments are required in estimating the future behavior of the value drivers. To assess the impact of possible changes in the future behavior of the key value drivers, it is useful to perform sensitivity studies. These can be useful in management planning and control systems and in other forms of enterprise resource planning. The sensitivity analysis can be performed with either the spreadsheet or formula approaches. The formula method is used for simplicity of exposition.
21
In Table 10, we calculate the elasticities of the responses in the ExxonMobil intrinsic value levels to upward and downward changes in each of the value drivers. The analysis changes one value driver, holding constant the levels of the others. The elasticities calculated and shown in the bottom of Table 10 are based on the maximum percent changes calculated. The elasticities are positive for the growth rate in revenues, the net operating income margin, and the duration of the period of competitive advantage. The elasticities are negative for tax rates, cost of capital, and total investment requirements. Table 10 The negative elasticity for investment requirements results from the construction of the sales growth DCF spreadsheet model. In this model when the investment requirements ratios change, the growth rate remains unchanged so the profitability ratio changes in the opposite direction. In other models, such as in the Miller and Modigliani (1961) dividend paper, growth is defined as the product of profitability and investment requirements, so investment could have a positive elasticity. Another dimension of sensitivity is shown in Table 11, in which paired value drivers are analyzed. The top part of the table reflects the critical relationship between the operating margin and the cost of capital. When the spread between the operating margin and the discount rate widens, the impact on valuation is magnified (and conversely). In the lower part of Table 11 the relationship between the growth rates in revenues and in the net operating margin is shown. In some business circumstances a tradeoff between revenue growth and operating margin may be encountered. Hence various combinations of revenue growth and operating margins can be usefully analyzed.
22
Table 11
The sensitivity analysis shown in Tables 10 and 11 enables the decision maker to identify the relative strength of the value drivers on the valuation of the enterprise. Valuations reflect changes in the economy and competitive developments. Valuation estimates are useful because they sensitize decision makers to how the economic and competitive changes affect critical value drivers. In the strategic planning processes of firms, valuations perform an important role in a firms information feedback system. In identifying the impact of value drivers on valuation changes, sensitivity analysis is used in planning processes for improving the performance of the firm and in valuation estimates by outside analysts.
23
2001, Table 13 summarizes value changes (industry adjusted) over a window from 10 days before the announcement date to 10 days after the announcement date. Targets increased in value by $43.8 billion. Acquirers increased in value by $7.8 billion. The combined value increase was $51.6 billion. The acquisition by Total (French) of PetroFina (Belgian) was the sole transaction for which the value change was negative. Analysts were critical of the 54.8% premium offered by Total, while exposing itself to substantial cyclical risks of the petrochemical industry and to PetroFinas low margins on its retail operations. This example also illustrates how the event returns reflect the markets evaluation of the underlying economics of the deal. Table 13 demonstrates that the 9 major oil merger deals during 1998-2001 overall were value increasing for both targets and acquirers. Table 13
24
the remaining 100 firms in the industry have a 0.5% market share each. The H index would be: 400 + 225 + 100 + 25 + 100(0.25) which equals 775. If the smallest two of the top four merged, the H index would become: 400 + 225 + 225 + 100(0.25) which equals 875. This illustrates how horizontal mergers result in higher industry concentration measures. The critical H index specified in the Guidelines is 1,000. Below 1,000, concentration is considered sufficiently low, so that no further investigation is automatically required to determine possible effects on competition. If a post-merger H index is between 1,000 and 1,800 and the index was increased by 100 or more, the merger would be investigated. If the industry H index is more than 1,800 and it was increased by at least 50, the merger is likely to be challenged. Calculations of the H index for the petroleum industry show a relatively stable pattern around 400 for the period 1975 through 1997 (Davies, 2000; U.S, Department of Commerce, 1996; U.S. Energy Information Administration, 1999). For 1997, the H index was 389. The reason that the H index for the petroleum industry did not increase between 1987 and 1997 was that the smallest firms grew faster than the largest (U.S. Energy Information Administration, 1999, p. 69). In Table 14, the effects of recent major mergers on the H index measures are shown. With 9 mergers among the largest petroleum companies during 1998-2001, the HHI for the petroleum industry would rise from 389 points to 583 points, an increase of 194 points. The total HHI for the industry of 583 would still be well short of the 1,000 critical level specified in the regulatory Guidelines. The reason for this is that although individual oil companies are large, they are in an industry that is also large, whether
25
measured by revenues, total assets, or reserves. These are multibillion-dollar companies in a $1,476 billion (1997 revenues) industry. Thus, by the criteria of the U.S. regulatory authorities, the overall industry concentration measures are so far below the H index 1,000 threshold that from an aggregate industry standpoint, antitrust concerns are not raised. Table 14 While the concentration levels are well below the critical 1,000 level for the global exploration and production markets, the refining and distribution markets are segmented. The regulatory authorities have required some divestments of assets in each of the major mergers listed in Table 14. These ranged from wholesale distribution facilities in the case of ExxonMobil to divestitures by BP Amoco of Arcos Alaskan assets. Preoccupation with measurement of concentration ratios misses the dynamics of the new competitive patterns emerging in the oil and energy industries. The improved efficiencies of the megafirms (ExxonMobil, BP, Shell, TotalFinaElf) have enabled them to operate close to breakeven on oil prices as low as $11-$12 per barrel. But the megafirms do not have proprietary control of technology or know how. Oil service
companies make such knowledge available to any industry participant (Davies, 2000). The integrated firms have long been in the traditional areas of oil and gas exploration and production, refining, and marketing. Less generally recognized is their significant penetration into the chemical industry, particularly petrochemicals. Three oil firms occupy the ranks of 3, 11, and 13 in U.S. chemical industry sales. Of the top 25 oil firms, 15 are at least partially state-owned. The state-owned national oil companies (NOCs) are major forces with potentials and interests in
26
expanding their roles. Saudi Arabia began holding discussions in 1998 about developing a gas business. One of the large NOCs, such as Saudi Aramco, could conceivably become a megafirm by purchasing an operating company and broadening its interests. Traditionally, the petroleum industry has been characterized by a varied pattern of relationships among the megafirms, other large integrated firms, specialized firms, oil service firms, and the NOCs. Through alliances and joint ventures, these relationships have been expanded to respond to the new competitive dynamics of the industry.
27
Hubris may be reflected in overpaying for the target. Exxon paid a premium of $15.5 billion. The equity market cap of the combined firm increased from $234 billion to actual values of $280 billion by the end of 1999 and to $301 billion by the end of 2000. Thus the capitalized value of the synergies was $46 to $67 billion. In his news release of 8/1/00, Chairman Raymond stated that an improvement of at least 3 points above the historic Exxon level of return on capital employed (ROCE) was being achieved. These results are inconsistent with agency problems. Other motives for mergers discussed in the literature include tax savings, monopoly, and redistribution. Tax aspects were not a major factor. Regulatory agencies found no antitrust problems in the upstream activities (exploration and development). However, divestitures were required in downstream activities (distribution and marketing). Redistribution from bondholders did not occur. Redistribution from labor took place in the sense that employment reshuffling and reductions were made. In their review of merger activity, Holmstrom and Kaplan (2001) described the positive influence of a number of developments in the 1990s. These included an increase in equity-based compensation, an increased emphasis on shareholder value, a rise of shareholder activism, improved and more active boards of directors, increased CEO turnover, and an increased role of capital markets. The efforts for efficiency improvements sought in the Exxon-Mobil merger reflected these general developments. In their companion review, Andrade, Mitchell, and Stafford (2001) further developed the earlier Mitchell and Mulherin (1996) emphasis on the role of shocks in causing mergers. Their analysis is applicable to the oil industry mergers. But the pressures have been more than periodic shocks. Price instability has been a continuing
28
problem for oil firms. Large price changes in both downward and upward directions have been destabilizing. Price drops reduce profit margins and investment returns. Price rises increase margins and returns, but stimulate production expansion and new entrants. Hence, price uncertainty created strong continuing pressures for improved efficiency to reduce oil finding and production costs. Another oil industry characteristic is high sensitivity to changes in overall economic activity. The East Asian financial problems in 1997-98 reduced demand resulting in a decline in world oil prices to below $10 per barrel in late 1998. The decline in growth in the U.S. economy beginning in 2000 contributed to the drop in oil prices from $37 to under $20 per barrel during 2001. The rise of 15 government-connected national oil companies created increased competitive pressures. The increased application of technological advances in exploration, production, refining methods, and transportation logistics created new competitive opportunities and threats. Price instabilities (like persistent overcapacity in the steel, auto, and chemical industries) cause continuing pressures for M&A activities to reduce costs and increase revenues. In addition, the $2 billion synergy in the BP acquisition of Amoco stimulated competitive responses resulting in other mergers, alliances, and joint ventures. The oil industry M&A activities during 1998-2001 are consistent with the industry shocks theory, an industry structural problems theory, and a theory of competitive responses.
IX. Reprise
The Exxon-Mobil combination is an archetype of a successful merger. Fundamentally, the reasons, structures, and implementation of the transaction reflected 29
the characteristics of the oil and gas industry. The industry increasingly utilizes advanced technology in exploration, production, refining, and in the logistics of its operations. It is international in scope. World demand is sensitive to economic conditions. The weakness in the Asian economies pushed prices below $10 per barrel at the end of 1998. The U.S. recession which began in March 2001 helped push oil prices from $32 a barrel to $17 a barrel by November 2001. Critics of merger activities have argued that the likelihood of successful mergers is small. Prevailing market prices of the equity of firms embody some probability of a takeover. In addition, they argue that purchase prices include substantial premiums requiring increases in values of acquired firms not likely to be achieved. The ExxonMobil combination provides counter evidence. Synergies include improvements in the performance of all the parties in the transaction. Premiums are usually expressed as a percentage of the premerger market cap of the target. These percentages can run high. However, more relevant is the amount of the premium in relation to the size of the combined firm. The $15.5 billion premium to Mobil was 26.4% of its market cap, but represented only 6.6% of the combined premerger market cap. The $2.8 billion premerger synergy estimate ($7 billion postmerger) required only a modest valuation multiple to recover the $15.5 billion premium. More generally, Table 13 demonstrates that in total the 9 major oil transactions were value increasing for acquirers as well as targets. This paper develops a framework for an analysis of how M&As can perform a positive role in aiding firms adjust to changing environments. We emphasize a multiple approach. Critical are: the economics of the industry, the business logic of the
30
combination within the framework of the industry and the economy, the behavior of the value drivers in the financial analysis of the merger, regulatory factors, and competitive interactions.
31
References
Andrade, Gregor, Mark Mitchell, and Erik Stafford, 2001, New Evidence and Perspectives on Mergers, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 15 (No. 2, Spring), 103-120. Berkovitch, Elazar and M. P. Narayanan, 1993, Motives for Takeovers: An Empirical Investigation, Journal of Financial & Quantitative Analysis, 28 (No. 3, September), 347-362. Cibin, Renato and Robert M. Grant, 1996, Restructuring Among the Worlds Leading Oil Companies, 1980-92, British Journal of Management, 7 (No. 4, December), 283307. Copeland, Tom, Tim Koller, and Jack Murrin, 2000, Valuation: Measuring and Managing the Values of Companies, 3rd ed., New York, NY, John Wiley & Sons. Cornell, Bradford, 1993, Corporate Valuation: Tools for Effective Appraisal and Decision Making, New York, NY, Irwin Professional Publishing. Davies, Peter, 2000, The Changing World Petroleum Industry Bigger Fish in a Larger Pond, The CEPMLP Internet Journal, 6 (No. 14, June 19). ExxonMobil, 1999, Joint Proxy to Shareholders, April 5, 1999. Gilson, Stuart C., Edith S. Hotchkiss, and Richard S. Ruback, 2000, Valuation of Bankrupt Firms, Review of Financial Studies, 13 (No. 1, Spring), 43-74. Healy, Paul M., Krishna G. Palepu and Richard S. Ruback, 1992, Does Corporate Performance Improve After Mergers? Journal of Financial Economics, 31 (2, April), 135-175. Holmstrom, Bengt and Steven N. Kaplan, 2001, Corporate Governance and Merger Activity in the United States: Making Sense of the 1980s and 1990s, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 15 (No. 2, Spring), 121-144. Jacoby, Neil H., 1974, Multinational Oil, New York, NY, Macmillan Publishing Co., Inc. Jensen, Michael C., 1986, Agency Costs Of Free Cash Flow, Corporate Finance, and Takeovers, American Economic Review, 76 (No. 2, May), 323-329. Kaplan, Steven N., 1995, Case Teaching Package for: Paramount1993, CaseNet South Western College Publishing. Kaplan, Steven N. and Richard S. Ruback, 1995, The Valuation of Cash Flow Forecasts: An Empirical Analysis, Journal of Finance, 50 (No. 4, September), 1059-1093. 32
Lamdin, Douglas J., 2000, Valuation with the Discounted Dividend Model when Corporations Repurchase, Financial Practice and Education, 10 (No. 1, Spring/Summer), 252-255. Landes, William M. and Richard A. Posner, 1981, Market Power in Antitrust Cases, Harvard Law Review, 94 (No. 5, March), 937-996. Martin, John D. and J. William Petty, 2000, Valued Based Management: The Corporate Response to the Shareholder Revolution, Boston, MA, Harvard Business School Press. Miller, Merton H. and Franco Modigliani, 1961, Dividend Policy, Growth, and the Valuation of Shares, Journal of Business, 34 (October), 411-433. Mitchell, Mark L. and J. Harold Mulherin, 1996, The Impact of Industry Shocks on Takeover and Restructuring Activity, Journal of Financial Economics, 41 (No. 2, June), 193-229. Modigliani, Franco and Merton Miller, 1963, Corporate Income Taxes and the Cost of Capital: A Correction, American Economic Review, 53 (No. 3), 433-442. Ollinger, Michael, 1994, The Limits of Growth of the Multidivisional Firm: A Case Study of the U.S. Oil Industry from 1930-90, Strategic Management Journal, 15 (No. 7, September), 503-520. Randall, Maury R., 2000, Share Repurchases: The Impact on Stock Valuation, Financial Practice and Education, 10 (No. 1, Spring/Summer), 256-263. Roeber, Joe, 1994, Oil Industry Structure and Evolving Markets, The Energy Journal, 15 (Special Issue), 253-276. Rock, Kevin, 1988, Gulf Oil Corp. Takeover, Harvard Business School Case No. 9285-053, (December 8). Ruback, Richard S., 1982, The Conoco Takeover and Stockholder Returns, Sloan Management Review, 23 (No. 2, Winter), 13-33. _______________, 1983, The Cities Service Takeover: A Case Study, Journal of Finance, 38 (No. 2, May), 319-330. _______________, 1992, Gulf Oil Corporation Takeover, Harvard Business School Teaching Note No. 5-292-071, (January 27). Shleifer, Andrei and Robert W. Vishny, 1986, Large Shareholders and Corporate Control, Journal of Political Economy, 94 (3, June, Part I), 461-488.
33
Stewart, G. Bennett, III, 1991, The Quest for Value, New York, NY, HarperBusiness,. U.S. Department of Commerce, 1996, 1992 Census of Manufacturers: Concentration Ratios in Manufacturing, Report MC92-S-2, Washington, D.C., GPO. U.S. Energy Information Administration, January 1999, January 2000, January 2001, Performance Profiles of Major Energy Producers, Washington, D.C., GPO. Welch, Ivo, 2000, Views Of Financial Economists on the Equity Premium and on Professional Controversies, Journal of Business, 73 (No. 4, October), 501-537. Weston, J. Fred, Juan A. Siu and Brian A. Johnson, 2001, Takeovers, Restructuring, & Corporate Governance, Upper Saddle River, NJ, Prentice-Hall. Yergin, Daniel, 1993, The Prize, New York, NY, Simon & Schuster.
34
Table 1 Crude Oil Prices at the Wellhead (First Purchase Prices) U.S. Yearly Average (Dollars per Barrel)
Year 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 Nominal $2.54 2.51 2.53 2.53 2.68 2.78 2.77 2.79 3.09 3.01 2.90 2.88 2.89 2.90 2.89 2.88 2.86 2.88 2.92 2.94 3.09 3.18 3.39 3.39 3.89 6.87 7.67 8.19 8.57 9.00 12.64 21.59 31.77 28.52 26.19 25.88 24.09 12.51 15.40 12.58 15.86 20.03 16.54 15.99 14.25 13.19 14.62 18.46 17.23 10.87 15.56 26.73 GDP Deflator 17.265 17.411 18.595 18.983 19.238 19.448 19.735 20.413 21.127 21.642 21.878 22.186 22.433 22.739 22.992 23.336 23.773 24.450 25.207 26.290 27.586 29.051 30.516 31.812 33.596 36.603 40.027 42.293 45.015 48.224 52.242 57.053 62.367 66.256 68.873 71.438 73.695 75.324 77.575 80.215 83.271 86.527 89.661 91.846 94.053 96.006 98.103 100.000 101.947 103.225 104.772 106.985 Real $14.71 14.42 13.61 13.33 13.93 14.29 14.04 13.67 14.63 13.91 13.26 12.98 12.88 12.75 12.57 12.34 12.03 11.78 11.58 11.18 11.20 10.95 11.11 10.66 11.58 18.77 19.16 19.36 19.04 18.66 24.20 37.84 50.94 43.05 38.03 36.23 32.69 16.61 19.85 15.68 19.05 23.15 18.45 17.41 15.15 13.74 14.90 18.46 16.90 10.53 14.85 24.98
35
Year Chevron Corp. E.I. DuPont de Nemours & Co. U.S. Steel Corp. Mobil Corp. Societe Nationale Elf Aquitaine-France Amoco Corp. Exxon Corp. Occidental Petroleum Corp. U.S. Steel Corp. Shell Oil Co. Occidental Petroleum Corp. Gulf Corp. Conoco Inc. Marathon Oil Corp. Superior Oil Co. Texasgulf Inc. Dome Petroleum Ltd.-Canada Texaco Canada Inc.-Canada Cities Service Co. Texas Oil & Gas Corp. Belridge Oil Co. MidCon Corp.
Acquirer
Acquired
Purchase Price (millions) $13, 205.5 8, 039.8 6,618.5 5,725.8 4,293.7 4,180.0 4,149.6 4,115.6 4,094.4 3,653.0 3,085.6 $61,161.5
1984 1981 1981 1984 1981 1987 1989 1982 1985 1979 1985
Total
36
Exxon $175.0 $43.7 4.0 $7,410 23.6 $74.2 $15.5 26.4% $55.2 290.5%
Share Price (2) Shares Outstanding (million) Total Market Value (billion) Exchange Terms Post-Merger Number of Shares (million)
(1)
$233.7
74.9%
25.1%
2,431
1,030
3,461
70.2%
29.8%
(1) Share Prices as or 11/20/98, a few days before runup in stock prices; announced 12/01/98 (2) Shares Outstanding are as of 1998 3Q 10Qs
37
Date XON 72.88 71.44 70.56 70.69 69.88 72.00 72.06 72.69 72.69 74.38 75.00 71.63 71.25 70.56 71.50 73.00 73.19 73.94 73.75 74.63 74.44 74.00 -1.107% -2.053% 0.292% 0.122% 2.503% 3.750% 2.109% 6.696% 16.424% 16.424% 13.808% 14.331% 14.702% 16.477% 18.076% 18.720% 19.075% 19.075% 19.783% 20.346% 19.297% -0.549% -0.557% 1.569% 2.186% 2.850% 3.805% 2.699% 7.361% 13.155% 14.468% 14.831% 17.127% 18.370% 19.543% 20.394% 19.843% 18.860% 19.105% 20.254% 20.960% 20.617% -1.972% -1.225% 0.177% -1.150% 3.041% 0.086% 0.869% 0.000% 2.321% 0.840% -4.500% -0.524% -0.966% 1.329% 2.098% 0.258% 1.025% -0.254% 1.186% -0.251% -0.588% -0.558% -0.938% 0.219% -0.787% 1.717% 0.291% -0.535% -0.076% 3.935% -1.313% -2.980% -1.772% -0.873% 0.602% 0.749% 1.195% 1.338% -0.245% -0.441% -0.143% -0.705% -0.558% -1.496% -1.277% -2.064% -0.347% -0.056% -0.590% -0.666% 3.270% 1.956% -1.023% -2.796% -3.669% -3.067% -2.318% -1.123% 0.215% -0.030% -0.471% -0.614% -1.319% 73.44 72.63 71.94 73.63 73.50 75.25 76.19 74.94 78.38 86.00 86.00 83.75 84.19 84.50 86.00 87.38 87.94 88.25 88.25 88.88 89.38 88.44 -1.107% -0.946% 2.345% -0.170% 2.381% 1.247% -1.641% 4.586% 9.729% 0.000% -2.616% 0.523% 0.371% 1.775% 1.599% 0.644% 0.355% 0.000% 0.708% 0.563% -1.048%
Dow Jones Returns on DJWDOIL DJWDOIL Index Index MOB MOB Returns XON Returns -1.972% -3.197% -3.020% -4.170% -1.129% -1.042% -0.174% -0.174% 2.147% 2.987% -1.513% -2.036% -3.002% -1.672% 0.426% 0.683% 1.708% 1.454% 2.640% 2.389% 1.801%
Cumulative Cumulative Actual Adjusted Returns Returns -1.414% -1.701% -1.743% -2.106% -0.782% -0.987% 0.416% 0.492% -1.122% 1.031% -0.489% 0.759% 0.667% 1.394% 2.743% 1.806% 1.493% 1.484% 3.111% 3.004% 3.120%
11/13/1998 11/16/1998 11/17/1998 11/18/1998 11/19/1998 11/20/1998 11/23/1998 11/24/1998 11/25/1998 11/27/1998 11/30/1998 12/1/1998 12/2/1998 12/3/1998 12/4/1998 12/7/1998 12/8/1998 12/9/1998 12/10/1998 12/11/1998 12/14/1998 12/15/1998
216.62 215.41 213.39 213.86 212.18 215.82 216.45 215.29 215.13 223.59 220.66 214.08 210.29 208.45 209.71 211.28 213.80 216.66 216.13 215.18 214.87 213.36
38
Table 6 DCF Spreadsheet Valuation of ExxonMobil (Dollar Amounts in Millions Except per Share)
2000 2001E 2002E 2003E 2004E 2005E 2006E 2007E 2008E 2009E 2010E 2011E On
1.
Panel A Inputs for Present Value Calculations $206,083 $185,475 $191,039 $198,680 $208,615 $224,261 $238,838 $253,168 $265,826 $276,459 $284,753 $293,296 28.1% -10.0% 3.0% 4.0% 5.0% 7.5% 6.5% 6.0% 5.0% 4.0% 3.0% 3.0%
3.
4.
5.
6.
7.
8.
9.
10.
11.
12.
13.
14.
NOI Cash tax rate Income taxes NOPAT + Depreciation Change in working capital Capital expenditures Change in other assets net Free cash flows WACC Discount factor Present values Panel B Operating Relationships (As a % of Revenues) 12.2% 7.3% 3.9% 2.7% 4.1% 0.3% 4.3% 12.0% 7.4% 4.0% 1.5% 4.5% -1.25% 6.7% 15.0% 9.3% 4.0% 1.5% 4.0% -1.25% 9.1% 16.0% 9.9% 4.0% 1.5% 4.0% -1.25% 9.7% 16.5% 10.2% 4.0% 1.5% 4.0% -1.25% 10.0% 18.0% 11.2% 4.0% 1.5% 4.5% -1.25% 10.4% 17.0% 10.5% 4.0% 1.5% 4.5% -1.25% 9.8% 17.0% 10.5% 4.0% 1.5% 4.5% -1.25% 9.8% 17.0% 10.5% 4.0% 1.5% 4.5% -1.25% 9.8%
$ 25,179 39.9% 10,056 $ 15,123 8,130 5,463 8,446 583 $ 8,761 9.18% 0.91592 $ 8,025
$ 22,257 38.0% 8,458 $ 13,799 7,419 2,782 8,346 (2,318) $ 12,408 9.18% 0.83891 $ 10,409
$ 28,656 38.0% 10,889 $ 17,767 7,642 2,866 7,642 (2,388) $ 17,289 9.18% 0.76837 $ 13,284
$ 31,789 38.0% 12,080 $ 19,709 7,947 2,980 7,947 (2,484) $ 19,212 9.18% 0.70376 $ 13,521
$ 34,421 38.0% 13,080 $ 21,341 8,345 3,129 8,345 (2,608) $ 20,820 9.18% 0.64459 $ 13,420
$ 40,367 38.0% 15,339 $ 25,027 8,970 3,364 10,092 (2,803) $ 23,346 9.18% 0.59039 $ 13,783
$ 40,602 38.0% 15,429 $ 25,173 9,554 3,583 10,748 (2,985) $ 23,382 9.18% 0.54075 $ 12,644
$ 43,039 38.0% 16,355 $ 26,684 10,127 3,798 11,393 (3,165) $ 24,785 9.18% 0.49529 $ 12,276
$ 45,190 38.0% 17,172 $ 28,018 10,633 3,987 11,962 (3,323) $ 26,024 9.18% 0.45364 $ 11,806
$ 45,616 38.0% 17,334 $ 28,282 11,058 4,147 12,441 (3,456) $ 26,208 9.18% 0.41550 $ 10,890
$ 46,984 $ 45,461 38.0% 38.0% 17,854 17,275 $ 29,130 $ 28,186 11,390 11,732 4,271 4,399 12,814 7,332 (3,559) 293 $ 26,995 $ 27,892 9.18% 9.18% 0.38056 $ 10,273
NOI NOPAT Depreciation Change in working capital Capital expenditures Change in other assets net Free cash flow
Risk-free rate Beta Equity risk premium Cost of equity Cost of debt (before-tax) Cost of debt (after-tax) Capital structure, % equity Base WACC
Total value of the firm Value of debt Value of equity Shares outstanding Intrinsic share price
* Net revenues exclude excise taxes and earnings from equity interests. End-of-year revenues for 1999 were $160,883 million.
39
Table 7 DCF Spreadsheet Valuation of ExxonMobil Using APV (Dollar Amounts in Millions Except per Share)
2000 Panel A Inputs for Present Value Calculations $206,083 $185,475 $191,039 $198,680 $208,615 $224,261 $238,838 $253,168 $265,826 $276,459 $284,753 $293,296 28.1% -10.0% 3.0% 4.0% 5.0% 7.5% 6.5% 6.0% 5.0% 4.0% 3.0% 3.0% 2001E 2002E 2003E 2004E 2005E 2006E 2007E 2008E 2009E 2010E 2011E On
1.
2.
3.
4.
5.
6.
7.
8.
9.
10.
11.
12.
13.
14.
NOI Cash tax rate Income taxes NOPAT + Depreciation Change in working capital Capital expenditures Change in other assets net Free cash flows Cost of Equity Unlevered Discount factor Present values Panel B Operating Relationships (As a % of Revenues) 12.2% 7.3% 3.9% 2.7% 4.1% 0.3% 4.3% 12.0% 7.4% 4.0% 1.5% 4.5% -1.25% 6.7% 15.0% 9.3% 4.0% 1.5% 4.0% -1.25% 9.1% 16.0% 9.9% 4.0% 1.5% 4.0% -1.25% 9.7% 16.5% 10.2% 4.0% 1.5% 4.0% -1.25% 10.0% 18.0% 11.2% 4.0% 1.5% 4.5% -1.25% 10.4% 17.0% 10.5% 4.0% 1.5% 4.5% -1.25% 9.8% 17.0% 10.5% 4.0% 1.5% 4.5% -1.25% 9.8% 17.0% 10.5% 4.0% 1.5% 4.5% -1.25% 9.8%
$ 25,179 39.9% 10,056 $ 15,123 8,130 5,463 8,446 583 $ 8,761 10.02% 0.90893 $ 7,963
$ 22,257 38.0% 8,458 $ 13,799 7,419 2,782 8,346 (2,318) $ 12,408 10.02% 0.82615 $ 10,251
$ 28,656 38.0% 10,889 $ 17,767 7,642 2,866 7,642 (2,388) $ 17,289 10.02% 0.75091 $ 12,982
$ 31,789 38.0% 12,080 $ 19,709 7,947 2,980 7,947 (2,484) $ 19,212 10.02% 0.68252 $ 13,113
$ 34,421 38.0% 13,080 $ 21,341 8,345 3,129 8,345 (2,608) $ 20,820 10.02% 0.62036 $ 12,916
$ 40,367 38.0% 15,339 $ 25,027 8,970 3,364 10,092 (2,803) $ 23,346 10.02% 0.56386 $ 13,164
$ 40,602 38.0% 15,429 $ 25,173 9,554 3,583 10,748 (2,985) $ 23,382 10.02% 0.51251 $ 11,984
$ 43,039 38.0% 16,355 $ 26,684 10,127 3,798 11,393 (3,165) $ 24,785 10.02% 0.46583 $ 11,546
$ 45,190 38.0% 17,172 $ 28,018 10,633 3,987 11,962 (3,323) $ 26,024 10.02% 0.42340 $ 11,019
$ 45,616 38.0% 17,334 $ 28,282 11,058 4,147 12,441 (3,456) $ 26,208 10.02% 0.38484 $ 10,086
$ 46,984 $ 45,461 38.0% 38.0% 17,854 17,275 $ 29,130 $ 28,186 11,390 11,732 4,271 4,399 12,814 7,332 (3,559) 293 $ 26,995 $ 27,892 10.02% 10.02% 0.34979 $ 9,443
NOI NOPAT Depreciation Change in working capital Capital expenditures Change in other assets net Free cash flow
Risk-free rate Beta levered Equity risk premium Debt ratio (D/VL)
$397,322 $124,465 138,979 $263,444 33,897 $297,341 73 $297,414 Total value of the firm Value of debt Value of equity Shares outstanding Intrinsic share price $297,414 18,972 $278,442 3,477 $ 80.08
Debt-equity ratio (D/S) Tax rate Beta unlevered Cost of equity unlevered Terminal period growth rate
* Net revenues exclude excise taxes and earnings from equity interests. End-of-year revenues for 1999 were $160,883 million.
40
Definitions: VU = Value of unlevered firm VL = Value of levered firm TS = Present value of tax shield D = Value of debt D/VL = Debt ratio T = Tax rate kd = Cost of debt
TS = PV(tax shield) =
kd D T = D T kd
(assume perpetuity)
VU = VL DT D = V L 1 T V L VU VL = 1 ( D VL ) T The present value of the tax shield can then be expressed as: TS = DT = VL ( D V L ) T = = VU ( D VL ) T 1 ( D VL ) T $263,444 0.30 0.38 = $33,897 million 1 0.30(0.38)
41
Table 9 DCF Formula Valuation of ExxonMobil (Dollar Amounts in Millions Except Per Share)
Panel A Value Drivers R0 = Base year revenues (EOY 1999)* Initial growth period ms = Net operating income margin Ts = Tax rate gs = Growth rate ds = Depreciation Iws = Working capital requirements Ifs = Capital expenditures Ios = Change in other assets net ks = Cost of capital n = Number of growth years Terminal period mc = Net operating income margin Tc = Tax rate gc = Growth rate dc = Depreciation Iwc = Working capital requirements Ifc = Capital expenditures Ioc = Change in other assets net kc = Cost of capital 1 + h = calculation relationship = (1+gs)/(1+ks) Panel B Formula $160,883 16.5% 38.0% 5.1% 4.0% 1.5% 4.5% -1.25% 9.18% 11
V 0 = R 0 [ m s (1 T s ) + d s I ws I fs I os ]
t =1
n (1 + g s ) t R 0 (1 + g s ) (1 + g c )[m c (1 T c ) + d c I wc I fc I oc ] + (1 + k s ) t ( k c g c )(1 + k s ) n
V0 =
R1 [ m s (1 T s ) + d s I ws I fs I os ] (1 + h ) n 1 R 0 (1 + g s ) n (1 + g c )[m c (1 Tc ) + d c I wc I fc I oc ] + h 1 + ks ( k c g c )(1 + k s ) n
Panel C Calculating Firm Value Present value of initial growth period cash flows Present value of terminal value Enterprise operating value Add: Marketable securities Total value of the firm Less: Total interest-bearing debt Equity value Number of shares Value per share
42
% Change -20%
gs 5.10% 4.08%
-14%
4.39%
-10%
4.59%
-6%
4.79%
-4%
4.90%
-2%
5.00%
0%
5.10%
2%
5.20%
4%
5.30%
6%
5.41%
10%
5.61%
14%
5.81%
20%
6.12%
Elasticities 0.466 0.427 0.512 -0.314 0.512 -0.314 -0.704 -0.847 -0.238 -0.238 0.129 0.139
+20%
-20%
The table shows that for the value drivers with positive elasticities, the profit margin (ms) and the growth rate in revenues (gs) have the greatest influence. The cost of capital (k) has the greatest negative relationship with value. These numerical relationships are specific to the magnitudes of the value drivers in Table 9, Panel A. The signs of the relationships will always hold. More general expressions for the elasticities can be obtained by taking the derivative of value with respect to (wrt) each of the value drivers in the formula shown in Table 9, Panel B.
43
Equity Value ($ billions) Net Operating Income Margin, ms $ 283.29 7.50% 8.00% Discount Rate, ks 8.50% 9.00% 9.18% 9.50% 10.00% 10.50% 11.00% 10.5% $269.3 $257.0 $245.4 $234.4 $230.5 $223.9 $213.9 $204.5 $195.5 12.5% $288.5 $275.7 $263.6 $252.1 $248.1 $241.2 $230.8 $220.9 $211.5 16.5% $326.9 $313.1 $300.1 $287.6 $283.3 $275.8 $264.5 $253.8 $243.6 18.5% $346.1 $331.8 $318.3 $305.4 $300.9 $293.1 $281.4 $270.3 $259.7 20.5% $365.3 $350.6 $336.5 $323.1 $318.5 $310.4 $298.3 $286.7 $275.7
Equity Value ($ billions) Revenues Growth Rate, gs ####### 13.0% Net Operating Margin, ms 14.0% 15.0% 16.0% 16.5% 17.0% 18.0% 19.0% 20.0% 3.00% $208.2 $216.1 $223.9 $231.8 $235.7 $239.7 $247.5 $255.4 $263.3 4.00% $228.3 $236.6 $244.9 $253.2 $257.3 $261.5 $269.8 $278.0 $286.3 5.10% $252.5 $261.3 $270.1 $278.9 $283.3 $287.7 $296.5 $305.3 $314.1 6.00% $274.1 $283.4 $292.6 $301.8 $306.4 $311.1 $320.3 $329.5 $338.7 7.00% $300.2 $310.0 $319.7 $329.4 $334.3 $339.2 $348.9 $358.7 $368.4
44
Exxon Mobil Total Postmerger Combined Value Paid to Mobil Remainder Exxon Premerger Gain from Merger Portion to Exxon 70% Portion to Mobil 30% Plus Premium to Mobil Mobil Total Gain
45
Table 13 Value Changes in 9 Major Oil Industry Mergers, 1998-2001 (in $ Billions)
Announcement Date 8/11/1998 12/1/1998 12/1/1998 4/1/1999 7/5/1999 10/16/2000 2/4/2001 5/29/2001 11/18/2001 Market Cap, -10 days Target Acquirer Combined 38.7 8.1 56.7 20.8 41.6 29.4 5.0 3.0 15.5 218.8 79.7 29.6 173.7 161.5 46.2 56.6 14.0 19.2 20.6 601.1 118.4 37.7 230.3 182.3 87.8 86.0 19.1 22.2 36.1 819.9 Value Changes (-10,+10) Target Acquirer Combined 10.6 2.5 11.7 4.7 5.9 3.8 1.2 1.1 2.3 43.8 1.9 (4.7) 5.4 7.9 (3.2) (1.1) (0.2) (0.3) 2.1 7.8 12.5 (2.2) 17.1 12.6 2.7 2.7 1.0 0.7 4.5 51.6
Target Amoco PetroFina Mobil Arco Texaco Tosco Gulf Canada Conoco
Market capitalizations are calculated 10 days before the merger announcement date. The value changes are calculated from 10 days before the announcement date to 10 days after. The measurement of the value changes adjust for market changes using the Dow Jones Major World Oil Companies Index (DJWDOIL).
46
Combined Revenues (millions) Original H Index BP/Amoco Total/PetroFina Exxon/Mobil BP Amoco/ARCO TotalFina/Elf Aquitaine Chevron/Texaco Phillips/Tosco Conoco/Gulf Canada Phillips/Conoco
Sum of Initial Hs
New H Index
Change in H Index
Cumulative Levels of the Oil Industry H Index 389.35 418.53 424.66 507.72 529.64 551.64 569.62 573.98 574.22 583.34
..................................................................................... 123,871 53,133 203,148 143,143 98,220 88,617 43,870 22,622 66,492 41.27 6.84 106.43 72.16 22.30 18.08 4.48 2.11 11.19 70.45 12.96 189.49 94.08 44.30 36.06 8.84 2.35 20.30 29.18 6.12 83.06 21.92 22.00 17.98 4.36 0.24 9.11
47