18.1 PP 447 484 The Scope of The SCM Agreement Specific Subsidies
18.1 PP 447 484 The Scope of The SCM Agreement Specific Subsidies
18.1 PP 447 484 The Scope of The SCM Agreement Specific Subsidies
1
Appellate Body Report, US – Softwood Lumber IV, para. 52 (emphasis added); panel
report, US – GOES, para. 7.85.
2
See Article 1.1(a)(1)(iii) of the SCM Agreement and footnote 1 of the SCM Agreement.
3
Recall that export subsidies included in the Illustrative List are prohibited, regardless of
whether they are covered under Article 1 of the SCM Agreement.
4
Panel Report, US – Export Restraints, para. 8.75.
5
Janow and Staiger offer an alternative reasoning on which ground the US claim could be
rejected. Applying the Lerner theorem, they indicate that an export tax is equivalent to an
alternative programme in which an export subsidy of the same magnitude is placed on every
other export good and an import tariff of the same magnitude is placed on each imported
good. On this basis, they argue that an export tax confers a subsidy to production in every
11
Panel Report, US – Export Restraints, para. 8.75. During the Uruguay Round, the United
States proposed to define the term ‘(actionable) subsidy’ as ‘any government action or
combination of actions which confers a benefit on the recipient firm(s)’. See Submission
by the United States, Elements of the Framework for Negotiations (MTN.GNG/NG10/
W/29, 22 November 1989), section II.1(a). See also Appellate Body Report, US –
Softwood Lumber IV, para. 52, n. 35.
12
Panel Report, US – Export Restraints, paras. 8.63–8.72. See above Chapter 3, section 3.1.3.
13
An expansive, effect-based reading would not fit the minimal attention, if any, given by
the negotiators to the inclusion of ‘income or price support’.
14
Appellate Body Report, US – Softwood Lumber IV, para. 52, n. 35.
15
See, e.g., Rubini, above Chapter 3 n. 8, at 160.
16
Appellate Body Report, US – Softwood Lumber IV, para. 52.
17
See also below Chapter 16, section 16.1.1.2.2.
18
On the regulation of export restraints see Mavroidis, above Chapter 4 n. 172, at 16–17,
42–62, 84–5. The US interest in qualifying export restrictions as subsidies was that CVD
action could be undertaken against subsidized downstream imports instead of bringing a
multilateral claim on the basis of the GATT. See MTN.GNG/NG10/W/4, 28 April 1987,
at 26–7.
19
Sykes, above n. 5, at 509–510.
20
See also R. E. Hudec, Essays on the Nature of International Trade Law (London:
Cameron May, 1999), at 263.
21
Appellate Body Report, US – Large Civil Aircraft, para. 811.
adjustments are allowed to level the playing field on either the import or
the export side. Countries predominantly relying on direct taxes, such
as the United States, hold that the economic rationale underpinning this
distinction between direct and indirect taxation is not convincing,
because direct taxes could very well be reflected in the final price.
Again, the criticism holds that the measure’s nature (i.e., indirect versus
direct taxation) rather than its potential effect determines whether it is
covered under the SCM Agreement. What is more, it has been argued
that the application of the relevant benchmark could even generate the
result that measures having the same nature (e.g., direct taxes) and
effect could, nonetheless, be disciplined differently. After all, the
relevant benchmark refers to the domestic fiscal system as relevant
benchmark. The concrete implications thereof are nicely illustrated by
the US defence in the US – FSC case. The United States argued that the
European territorial tax system has the same economic effect as the FSC
exemption from its world-wide tax system, because both tax systems
exempt the foreign-source income of exporters. After all, whereas under
a territorial tax system all foreign-source income is exempted from
taxation, a worldwide tax system in principle taxes all sources of income
and therefore needs an exemption to exclude foreign-source income
of exporters. The United States concluded that the WTO ‘should not
penalize a country using a world-wide system for incorporating
elements of a territorial system in order to obtain comparable tax
treatment for its exports’.22 Yet the EU objected that the United States
was responsible for having chosen a general tax system that puts its
exporters at a disadvantage, and this view was in essence followed by
the panel in US – FSC:
[T]he United States is free to maintain a world wide tax system, a territorial
tax system or any other type of system it sees fit. This is not the business of
the WTO. What it is not free to do is to establish a regime of direct taxation,
provide an exemption from direct taxes specifically related to exports, and
then claim that it is entitled to provide such an export subsidy because it is
necessary to eliminate a disadvantage to exporters created by the US tax
system itself. In our view, this is no different from imposing a corporate
income tax of, say, 75 percent, and then arguing that a special tax rate of 25
percent for exporters is necessary because the generally applicable corporate
tax rate in other Members is only 25 percent.23
22 23
Panel Report, US – FSC, para. 7.121. Ibid., para. 7.122 (original footnotes omitted).
Hudec commented that this ‘your own fault’ response by the panel
begs the following question: why should one government be allowed to
create subsidy-like tax effects in one case but not in another? In partic-
ular, why should the WTO reach a different result regarding a subsidy-
like tax exemption for exporters depending on whether the country also
exempts other foreign-source income?24 After all, the only difference
between both systems is that the territorial tax systems exclude all
foreign-source income, whereas the US FSC exemption merely excludes
foreign-source income of exporters. At first sight, there seems no eco-
nomic logic available to explain this different stance.25,26
Considered at a general theoretical level, however, such a different
outcome is inevitable, given that the benchmark is located in the domes-
tic legal order, which evidently varies among members. The example
given by the panel in US – FSC can serve as an illustration. Member A can
apply a generally applicable corporate tax rate of 75 per cent with an
exemption of 25 per cent for exporters, whereas member B might
provide a generally applicable corporate tax rate of 25 per cent.
Moreover, the domestic level is the only appropriate benchmark in the
absence of a level playing field. Indeed, the WTO adjudicating bodies
cannot rely on an agreed international benchmark (e.g., a common
corporate tax rate of 75 per cent), and the WTO itself is not a standard-
setting organization but is essentially a negative integration model. In the
words of the Appellate Body, ‘the SCM Agreement recognizes that WTO
Members are sovereign in determining the structure and rates of their
domestic tax regimes’.27 So the benchmark has to refer to the domestic
legal regime of the member in question. As a consequence, member B’s
tax system will probably fall outside the reach of the SCM disciplines,
whereas the tax exemption provided by member A might constitute a
prohibited (export) subsidy even if the economic effect upon exporters is
largely similar.28 It should be emphasized that the absence of an
24
Caution should be exercised when considering the territorial tax systems as ipso facto
SCM-compatible, given that the WTO did not yet have to decide on this (Panel Report,
US – FSC, para. 7.123).
25
See Hudec, above Chapter 4 n. 88, at 190.
26
A tax exemption confined to exporters might, however, be more trade distortive, because
its bears the risk of shifting resources from non-exporting domestic firms to exporting
firms. This is similar to the trade distortion rationale for the specificity test.
27
See Appellate Body Report, US – Large Civil Aircraft, para. 811.
28
Recall that a general tax cut implemented by a regional government is treated as non-
specific, whereas a similar regional tax cut installed by the national government would
be specific (above Chapter 3, section 3.3.3). Hence members A and B can impose an
identical tax measure but whether this might be disciplined and countervailable depends
on their governance structure.
29
Appellate Body Report, Canada – Renewable Energy / Feed-in Tariff Program, para. 5.188
(emphasis in original).
30
Ibid., paras. 5.228, 5.233, 5.234.
31
Panel Report, Japan – DRAMs (Korea), para. 7.275.
32
Panel Report, Korea – Commercial Vessels, para. 7.28.
This illustrates why the first situation is an extension of the case law on
the benefit concept, while the second situation deviates from the ration-
ale underlying the benefit concept. The case law allowing an alternative
benchmark when market prices are distorted perfectly fits this rationale:
financial contributions should not be excluded from the subsidy defini-
tion if they are so dominant that they distort the market benchmark
itself. In this situation the government is not behaving as a commercial
actor, and an alternative ‘market’ benchmark could still be constructed
to establish subsidization. This alternative benchmark is still a ‘market’
benchmark: it serves to assess whether a financial contribution on
similar terms would be available in the absence of the financial contri-
bution. The analysis focuses on the market of the financial contribution,
which is conceptually the right focus for defining the market benchmark.
In contrast, the Appellate Body’s case law on ‘creating’ markets funda-
mentally departs from this rationale: here, the benefit analysis filters out,
not commercial conduct, but rather government support pursuing cer-
tain legitimate policy objectives that would, by definition, not be pursued
by commercial actors.
To achieve this outcome, the Appellate Body in Canada – Renewable
Energy / Feed-in Tariff Program developed the formalistic argument that
‘where a government creates a market, it cannot be said that the govern-
ment intervention distorts the market, as there would not be a market if
the government had not created it’, and, without any substantive argu-
ment, decided that ‘the creation of markets by government does not in
and of itself give rise to subsidies within the meaning of the SCM
Agreement’.33 Here, the Appellate Body seems to have been guided by
normative considerations (i.e., it wanted to avoid any such financial
contribution being characterized as a subsidy), rather than by legal
reasoning. In the light of the Appellate Body’s reasoning, it appears
that its analysis focuses on the market of the supported good, which is
conceptually not the right focus for distilling the benchmark for the
benefit analysis.34
33
Appellate Body Report, Canada – Renewable Energy / Feed-in Tariff Program, para. 5.188
(emphasis in original).
34
As explained above (section 3.2.1.2), in Canada – Renewable Energy / Feed-in Tariff
Program, no distinction had to be made between the market of the supported good and
the market of the financial contribution, because this financial contribution involved the
purchase of the good. However, the Appellate Body’s reasoning reveals that its focus
seems to be on the market of the supported good.
Had the Appellate Body only been guided by legal reasoning and its
prior case law, it would have shared the dissenting panelist’s argumen-
tation. The dissent found that a subsidy is present if a government
provides financial contributions in order to make an uncompetitive
good (i.e., renewable electricity) competitive with existing goods (i.e.,
non-renewable electricity) on the market. The dissent argued that this
could be demonstrated by comparing the FIT price with the competitive
wholesale market for electricity that could exist in Ontario, but also
accepted that ‘facilitating the entry of certain technologies into the
market that does exist – such as it is – by way of a financial contribution
can itself be considered to confer a benefit’.35 By ‘bringing these high cost
and less efficient electricity producers into the wholesale electricity
market, when they would otherwise not be present’, a subsidy was
considered to be present.36 Thus the difference in production costs
from competing producers on the market (i.e., non-renewable electricity
producers) was considered as evidence of the presence of subsidization.
As explained, the Appellate Body took a very different approach by
turning towards supply-side substitutability: the difference in produc-
tion costs rather implied that no subsidy was demonstrated. Differences
in production costs might imply that two goods are not competing in the
same relevant market. If the government provides financial contribu-
tions to make the high-cost product competitive, through, for instance,
purchasing this product, it creates a separate market for this product.
No subsidy is present if the price for this product is not higher than
‘what a market would yield’, taking the creation of this market as a given.
As demonstrated in the Canada – Renewable Energy / Feed-in Tariff
Program case, constructing this benchmark is highly demanding. In
principle, it could consist of prices for these products under older pro-
grammes, prices in other provinces, or even prices in other countries. But
these prices have to be based on a mechanism that ensures a market
outcome, and have to be adapted to the conditions in the country in
question as well as to the government’s current definition of the supply-
side mix. Reading between the lines, it seems that the Appellate Body
suggests that the market would normally yield a price that equals pro-
duction costs plus a reasonable rate of return, although this assumes
competition among suppliers in this newly created market.
35
Panel Report, Canada – Renewable Energy / Feed-in Tariff Program, para. 9.3.
36
Ibid., para. 9.23.
37
Appellate Body Report, Canada – Renewable Energy / Feed-in Tariff Program,
para. 5.199.
market test neglects whether the private benchmark price also equals the
socially optimal price. In the presence of market failures, the market
price does not reflect all benefits (i.e., positive externalities) or costs
(i.e., negative externalities) and the socially optimal price thus deviates
from the market price. Hence a subsidy would be present even if this only
lowers the price to the socially optimal price and thus internalizes a
positive externality. What is more, corrective government interventions
might precisely take the form of a beneficial financial contribution.
Governments playing their complementary role to that of the private
market make financial contributions on terms that are by definition not
available on the private market. In the discussion on export credit
support (see Part II), it was illustrated that governments effectively
fulfilling their complementary role to the private financial market
would precisely offer financial contributions on beneficial terms.
Conversely, a subsidy is not present where the government fails to
internalize negative externalities (i.e., the socially optimal price is higher
than the private market price). On this basis, Stiglitz’s call for CVDs to be
imposed against US products because they do not bear the cost of
environmental pollution seems legally flawed. He argued:
A subsidy means that a firm does not pay the full costs of production. Not
paying the cost of damage to the environment is a subsidy, just as not
paying the full costs of workers would be. In most of the developed
countries of the world today, firms are paying the cost of pollution to
the global environment, in the form of taxes imposed on coal, oil, and gas.
But American firms are being subsidized – and massively so.38
38
J. Stiglitz, ‘A New Agenda for Global Warming’, 3:7 Economists’ Voice (2006), 1–4, at 2.
39
As explained above, the domestic market forms the benchmark for assessing whether
revenue is forgone under a tax system.
40
See also Bhagwati and Mavroidis, above Chapter 4 n. 78, at 302–3; S. Z. Bigdeli, ‘Incentive
Schemes to Promote Renewables and the WTO Law of Subsidies’, in T. Cottier, O. Nartova,
and S. Z. Bigdeli (eds.), International Trade Regulation and the Mitigation of Climate Change
(Cambridge University Press, 2009), 155–99, at 157–76; J. Pauwelyn, ‘US Federal Climate
Policy and Competitiveness Concerns: The Limits and Options of International Trade Law’,
working paper, Duke University, 2007, at 14–15. However, Howse and Eliason agree with
Stiglitz that CVDs could be imposed in response to a lack of undertaking action under the
Kyoto Protocol. They suggest that the allowance for emitting carbon constitutes the
Energy / Feed-in Tariff Program, the case law suggested that the subsidy
definition disregards the question whether government interventions are
corrective rather than distortive in nature.41,42
The Appellate Body in Canada – Renewable Energy / Feed-in Tariff
Program seems to have been concerned about this outcome, particularly
because the SCM Agreement lacks an Article XX GATT type of
defence.43 This seems to have inspired the Appellate Body to take a
different approach to the benefit analysis. But what is the relevance of
the legitimate policy objectives in deciding when recourse to an alter-
native benchmark is allowed? The Appellate Body’s report raises this
question, but fails to give clear guidance on the answer. Overall, its report
suggests that an inquiry into the pursued objective is not needed to
define the relevant market and thus to decide on whether an alternative
benchmark could and should be used.
The Appellate Body firmly states that ‘introducing legitimate policy
considerations into the determination of benefit cannot be reconciled
with Article 1.1(b) of the SCM Agreement’, but subsequently discusses at
length the legitimate policy considerations for providing support to
provision of a good (e.g., a right to emit carbon is given by the government) which confers a
benefit, whereby an adjusted market price in a country that has installed an emissions trading
market (e.g., the EU) is used as benchmark. However, their creative interpretation seems to
be based on an overly broad reading of Articles 1.1(a)(1)(iii) and 14(d) of the SCM
Agreement and of the Appellate Body’s jurisprudence on the use of alternative benchmarks.
De Cendra, Hufbauer, et al. correctly disagreed that an allowance can be defined as a good
under the SCM Agreement. Regarding the benefit determination, the proposal to use the
price in countries having an emission trading system in place does not fit the Appellate
Body’s jurisprudence on alternative benchmarks (see above Chapter 3, section 3.2.1.1.1.1)
(e.g., their proposed alternative benchmark would also be distorted because governments,
according to their reasoning, are the sole providers of the right to emit carbon, implying that
no market benchmark could be constructed). See R. Howse and A. Eliason, ‘Domestic and
International Strategies to Address Climate Change: An Overview of the WTO Legal Issues’,
in T. Cottier, O. Nartova, and S. Z. Bigdeli (eds.), International Trade Regulation and the
Mitigation of Climate Change (Cambridge University Press, 2009), 48–93, at 73–6; J. de
Cendra, ‘Can Emissions Trading Schemes Be Coupled with Border Tax Adjustments? An
Analysis vis-à-vis WTO Law’, 15:2 Review of European Community and International
Environmental Law (2006), 131–45, at 137; G. C. Hufbauer, S. Charnovitz, and J. Kim,
Global Warming and the World Trading System (Washington, DC: Peterson Institute for
International Economics, 2009), at 61–2.
41
Whether the provision of goods serves a public objective is also irrelevant for the
determination whether it constitutes ‘general infrastructure’, which is excluded from
the subsidy definition (above Chapter 3, section 3.1.1.2).
42
Schwartz and Harper revealed a similar approach under the pre-SCM Agreement period.
W. Schwartz and E. W. Harper, ‘The Regulation of Subsidies Affecting International Trade’,
70:5 Michigan Law Review (1972), 831–58, at 833.
43
See above, section 4.4.2.
44
Appellate Body Report, Canada – Renewable Energy / Feed-in Tariff Program, paras.
5.185–5.189.
45
Ibid., para. 5.189 (emphasis added).
46
Recall that the traditional benchmark should be employed when governments support
certain players ‘in markets that already exist, or to correct market distortions therein’
(ibid., para. 5.188).
Further, the fact that two products created by the government are
similar in the light of the pursued legitimate objective also seems not to
be relevant to deciding whether both products fall within the same
relevant market. For instance, solar and wind electricity are both created
to achieve the same environmental objectives, but were still considered
as part of different markets, because the government had decided to
support both technologies (i.e., part of the supply-side mix that should
be taken as a given) and from the perspective of the supply-side they
were different (i.e., solar generated electricity is much more costly than
wind generated electricity).
Next, the Appellate Body’s jurisprudence implies that in the presence of
positive externalities (e.g., from renewable energy), government support to
make this product competitive to other products (generating no positive, or
even negative, externalities) does not ipso facto amount to subsidization
within the meaning of the SCM Agreement, despite the fact that, from an
economic perspective, this would be a textbook example of what a subsidy is
and when such subsidization is justified. However, it bears noting that the
Appellate Body’s jurisprudence does not ensure that this support is limited
to internalizing the positive externality generated by the environmentally
friendly product. Broadly speaking, such support would not amount to
subsidization as long as the price paid for the environmentally friendly
product is not above production costs plus a reasonable rate of return, even
if this is higher than what the market would be willing to pay plus the value
of the positive externality. This could again be illustrated on the basis of the
difference between wind generated and solar generated electricity: both
types of electricity are arguably similar in terms of positive externalities,
but very unequal in terms of production costs, as solar generated electricity
is much more costly to produce. Still, the price paid for solar generated
electricity could be substantially higher than the price paid for wind gen-
erated, without amounting to subsidization in the meaning of the SCM
Agreement.
Finally, we explained above that governments’ lack of action to inter-
nalize negative externalities should not be regarded as subsidization
within the meaning of the SCM Agreement. This conclusion still holds,
as it is not affected by the Canada – Renewable Energy / Feed-in Tariff
Program case law.
In conclusion, this case law suggests that legitimate policy consider-
ations for government support are neither a necessary nor a sufficient
condition for triggering the application of the alternative benefit bench-
mark. But it is clear that the Appellate Body aimed at excluding some
47
Appellate Body Report, Canada – Renewable Energy / Feed-in Tariff Program, para. 5.175.
48
This is a thorny issue which seems unavoidable under the Appellate Body’s
jurisprudence.
subsidy under the SCM Agreement. If foreign products are kept out of the
market by way of government regulation, the government again cannot
claim that the market does not exist and could be ‘created’ through govern-
ment support. This is not a market that ‘can only come into existence as a
matter of government regulation’, but rather requires less government
regulation regarding imported products. Governments might not be the
reason why markets do not exist, as this would mean that they could pave
the way for the alternative benefit approach. WTO case law is clear that
governments’ own conduct should be discounted in the analysis of whether
two products are substitutable.49
There are other ways to further limit situations where governments
are considered to ‘create’ new markets, resulting in recourse to the
alternative benefit benchmark. First, it is helpful that the alternative
market benchmark seems only available where differences in production
costs are so significant that the uncompetitive product would not have
entered the market at all without government intervention. Second, the
Appellate Body seems to suggest that recourse to the alternative bench-
mark could be limited in time, namely for as long as the differences in
production costs remain significant. Third, it would be helpful if future
panels or the Appellate Body were to confirm that this jurisprudence is
confined to the creation of the supported goods markets, and does not
extend to the creation of the market of any financial contribution (e.g.,
financial market). This would mean that the regular market benchmark
would be applied if the government, in time of a financial crisis, supports
its existing domestic industries with loans unavailable on the private
market. Fourth, and finally, a future panel or the Appellate Body might
be inclined to limit recourse to the alternative benchmark to situations
where the government purchases goods, and thus foreclose this option
for other types of financial contribution (e.g., transfer of funds).
However, this is not to be recommended, because it would make the
benefit analysis fundamentally different depending on the type of finan-
cial contribution, and governments could still find their way to the new
benefit approach by converting such financial contributions into direct
or indirect purchases of goods.
In sum, recourse to the alternative benchmark should be confined to
situations where the government ‘creates’ the market of the supported
goods, when and for as long as intrinsic and substantial differences in
49
See, inter alia, Appellate Body Report, Korea – Alcoholic Beverages, paras. 114–122.
50
In the words of Frontier Economics, ‘The public benefit to society from lower emissions
is entirely predicated on there being a private benefit to the producers of energy from
renewable sources.’ ‘FIT for Purpose? A Review of the Economics of a WTO Panel
Ruling on Feed-in Tariffs and Local Content Requirements’, client briefing by Frontier
Economics, March 2013.
51
The only substantive difference is that a violation under the GATT and TRIMs could in
principle still meet the conditions under Article XX of the GATT. But this difference
seems merely theoretical, because such local content measures are in principle not
necessary to achieve a legitimate objective. In Canada – Renewable Energy / Feed-in
Tariff Program, Canada did not even invoke Article XX of the GATT as a defence.
52
See below section 16.1.1.2.2.
57
Hence the EU argued that such subsidies did not affect competition (MTN.GNG/NG4/
W/36, 2 February 1990). This proposition is based on the unlikely assumption that the
subsidy merely affected the location decision of the firm within the subsidizing member.
A. O. Sykes, ‘Second-Best Countervailing Duty Policy: A Critique on the Entitlement
Approach’, 21 Law and Policy in International Business (1990), 699–721, at 717.
58
See G. M. Grossman and P. C. Mavroidis, ‘US – Lead and Bismuth II, United States
Imposition of Countervailing Duties on Certain Hot-Rolled and Bismuth Carbon Steel
Products Originating in the United Kingdom: Here Today, Gone Tomorrow?
Privatization and the Injury Caused by Non-Recurring Subsidies? (WT/DS138; DSR
2000:V, 2595; DSR 2000:VI, 5623)’, in H. Horn and P. Mavroidis (eds.), The American
Law Institute Reporters’ Studies on WTO Case Law – Legal and Economic Analysis
(Cambridge University Press, 2007), 183–213; G. M. Grossman and P. C. Mavroidis,
‘United States – Countervailing Measures Concerning Certain Products from the
European Communities (WTO Doc. WT/DS212/AB/R; DSR 2003:I, 5; DSR 2003:I,
73): Recurring Misunderstanding of Non-Recurring Subsidies’, in H. Horn and
P. Mavroidis (eds.), The American Law Institute Reporters’ Studies on WTO Case
Law – Legal and Economic Analysis (Cambridge University Press, 2007), 381–90; see
also H. Horn and P. C. Mavroidis, ‘United States – Preliminary Determinations with
Respect to Certain Softwood Lumber from Canada (WT/DS236; DSR 2002:XI, 3597):
What is a Subsidy?’, in H. Horn and P. Mavroidis (eds.), The American Law Institute
Reporters’ Studies on WTO Case Law – Legal and Economic Analysis (Cambridge
University Press, 2007), 523–49.
59
See also Sykes, above n. 5, at 510–511.
60
This conclusion is stated from the perspective of positive theory. Grossman and
Mavroidis, ‘Here Today, Gone Tomorrow?’, above n. 58, at 198–9.
of a subsidy must be one that ‘helps to identify policies that inflict such
harm’.61 Accordingly a benefit is conferred, in the view of these authors,
when a competitive advantage is offered to firms vis-à-vis other firms.
Hence the benefit test should not simply look at whether the recipient is
generally better off (e.g., in terms of wealth) than without the financial
contribution. Instead, it should examine whether its competitive position
is improved compared with ‘but for’ the financial contribution. Behind
their alternative approach seems to be the recognition that a precondi-
tion for causing harm to foreign producers is that domestic firms’ output
levels are increased as a result of a financial contribution,62 which in turn
principally assumes, at least in perfectly competitive markets, that it directly
or indirectly lowered their marginal costs.63,64 A profit-maximizing firm in
competitive markets sets output decisions in such a way that marginal costs,
which are a function of production costs, equate marginal revenue. Put
differently, a competitive advantage is present in cases where domestic
firms’ output level (or marginal costs)65 would have been lower (or higher)
‘but for’ the financial contribution.66
Hence the ‘benefit’ approach developed in the case law (and supported
by Diamond67) takes the market value as the benchmark to determine
the existence of subsidization: is a financial contribution made at better-
than-market terms? In contrast, the approach suggested by Mavroidis
61
Ibid., at 199–200.
62
See, e.g., R. Diamond, ‘A Search for Economic and Financial Principles in the
Administration of United States Countervailing Duty Law’, 21 Law and Policy in
International Business (1990), 507–608, at 539.
63
The suggestion to focus on the effect on the firm’s competitive position somewhat
resembles the plea of proponents of the so-called entitlement rationale in the 1980s
(e.g., Goetz, Granet, Shwartz, and Diamond). These authors advocated that CVDs
should only be imposed to the extent marginal costs are lowered as a result of a subsidy.
An important difference seems to be that Diamond rejects the argument that the
competitive effect could be assessed under the benefit analysis as currently inscribed
in the SCM Agreement (see below Chapter 18, section 18.2). See C. J. Goetz, L. Granet,
and W. F. Schwartz, ‘The Meaning of “Subsidy” and “Injury” in the Countervailing Duty
Law’, 6 International Review of Law and Economics (1986), 17–32; R. Diamond,
‘Economic Foundations of Countervailing Duty Law’, 29 Virginia Journal of
International Law (1989), 767–812. See also Sykes, above Chapter 5 n. 250, at 99.
64
Sykes illustrates that there could be circumstances where marginal costs are not reduced
as a result of subsidization but where output levels have nonetheless increased. Most
cases of higher output levels do result from a reduction in marginal costs.
65
This was the focus of the proponents of the entitlement theory (see above n. 63).
66
Horn and Mavroidis, above n. 58, at 533; Goetz, Granet, and Schwartz, above n. 63, at 23.
67
Diamond holds that there is no interpretative basis for supporting Grossman and
Mavroidis’s suggestion. Diamond, above Chapter 5 n. 249.
Appellate Body decided that such a fair market price does not necessarily
extinguish prior subsidization but only offers a presumption thereof.72
Grossman and Mavroidis have firmly criticized this case law that a fair
market price could extinguish the continued benefit of past non-
recurring subsidies.73 The change in ownership – at a fair market price
or not – simply has no bearing on the question of the continuation of
benefit, at least if the ‘benefit’ concept is understood correctly as an
amelioration of its competitive position and not in terms of economic
‘wealth’ as is understood by the Appellate Body. The price at which a
firm acquires assets should be qualified as a ‘sunk cost’, which does not
affect their future profit-maximizing output decisions inasmuch as mar-
ginal costs are left unaffected.74 The enhanced competitive position
resulting from the firm’s prior subsidization is not affected by the price
paid for the change in ownership and thus leaves the harm caused to
foreign firms untouched.75 In their words, ‘a change in ownership – at
fair market prices or otherwise – has no bearing on competitive con-
ditions in the world market’.76 Grossman and Mavroidis correctly draw a
parallel with non-recurring subsidies paid directly to private firms.77
Ownership shares in private firms frequently transfer in the private
capital market (by definition at a fair market price). Hence would such
common private-to-private sales also extinguish (parts of) the benefit of
the non-recurring subsidy in the Appellate Body’s view, given that the
new owner does not personally benefit (in wealth terms) from the
subsidy? As explained, the Appellate Body in EC – Large Civil Aircraft
was divided on this question: (only) two out of three members consid-
ered that no extinction would take place.78 Observe that one of the
72
Ibid., paras. 122–127.
73
Because the benefit element cannot be interpreted along the lines suggested by
Grossman and Mavroidis, Diamond concurs with the Appellate Body’s reasoning on
the effect of privatization. Diamond, above Chapter 5 n. 249, at 6–8, 21–6.
74
Grossman and Mavroidis, ‘Recurring Misunderstanding of Non-Recurring Subsidies’,
above n. 58, at 386–8; Diamond, above n. 62, at n. 105.
75
In the words of one of the Appellate Body members in EC – Large Civil Aircraft (para.
726), ‘The central point is that a sale of shares, whether or not it conveys control,
transfers rights in the shares to a new owner. The assets of the company, to which the
shares attach, do not change at all.’
76
Grossman and Mavroidis, ‘Here Today, Gone Tomorrow?’, above n. 58, at 201.
77
Palmeter is credited by Grossman and Mavroidis for articulating this parallel.
78
Appellate Body Report, EC – Large Civil Aircraft, para. 726. In my view, this could only be
rejected in a coherent way if the Appellate Body equally reverses its case law on full
privatization, given that the same mechanism and rationale for accepting extinction are at
stake. Hence the view expressed by one of the Appellate Body members (as well as the panel
in EC – Large Civil Aircraft) that the full privatization case law could not simply be
transposed in the case of partial privatization or private-to-private sales is not convincing.
79
The ‘subsidy continues to benefit the recipient, even if the ownership of the recipient’s
shares changes from one day to another’. Appellate Body Report, EC – Large Civil
Aircraft, para. 726(c).
80
Panel Report, US – Large Civil Aircraft, paras. 7.864–7.871.
81
Panel Report, US – Large Civil Aircraft, para. 7.870.
82
Likewise, the current case law opens the door for subsidization of government-owned
enterprises that will be fully privatized.
83
This was articulated by the United States. See Appellate Body Report, US –
Countervailing Measures on Certain EC Products, para. 103.
84
Ibid., para. 103 (original footnotes omitted).
The Appellate Body’s reasoning qualifies, but certainly does not refute,
the core of the argument articulated by Grossman and Mavroidis. First of
all, the core thesis that the artificially enhanced competitiveness gener-
ated by prior non-recurring subsidies will not be eliminated by a fair
market price is not addressed at all by the Appellate Body’s argumenta-
tion.85 The Appellate Body’s response simply shows that an additional
subsidy would be generated when privatization is done at below market
prices.86 The claim that the level of the sales price has no bearing what-
soever on subsequent, profit-maximizing behaviour might indeed be too
rigid, as a below the market price could improve the firm’s financial
position and thus generate a reduction in its cost of raising capital, which
could affect future investment decisions. To be sure, this reasoning is
based on the premise that the firm in question is constrained in its access
to capital. If not, an increase in cash flow resulting from this extra
subsidy (i.e., the sale below market price) would not affect this firm’s
investment behaviour and would thus not generate extra investments.87
In conclusion, under the present case law, there is a presumption that
privatization at a fair market price extinguishes the continued benefit of
prior non-recurring subsidies.88,89 This case law could be criticized, since
a change of ownership – regardless of the actual price – does not affect
the artificially generated competitive advantage. Privatization could
only generate an additional subsidy if made at below market terms
85
As illustrated above, the Appellate Body simply rejects this argument because the benefit
analysis looks at the market price.
86
The United States seemed to share this view as well: ‘the fact that the private owner pays
full market price for the enterprise indicates only that the private owner is not receiving a
new subsidy’. Appellate Body Report, US – Countervailing Measures on Certain EC
Products, para. 99 (emphasis in original).
87
As explained in US – Large Civil Aircraft, the Modigliani–Miller theorem implies that it
could be assumed that firms invest at optimal levels when they are unconstrained as to
capital. In that case, a subsidy would be passed on in its entirety to shareholders
(dividends) instead of higher investments. See Panel Report, US – Large Civil Aircraft,
paras. 2 and 8 of Appendix VI.F.2.
88
In order to implement the DSB’s recommendations in US – Countervailing Measures on
Certain EC Products, the United States has drafted a new privatization methodology (see
Panel Report, US – Countervailing Measures on Certain EC Products (Article 21.5 – EC),
n. 313). This new methodology was not as such challenged before the compliance panel
(ibid., n. 206 and para. 7.89).
89
The panel in US – Countervailing Measures on Certain EC Products (Article 21.5 – EC)
decided that the CVD administration has to determine in a sunset review whether
privatization has occurred at arm’s length and for fair market value, and cannot simply
assume that this has been the case. See Panel Report, US – Countervailing Measures on
Certain EC Products (Article 21.5 – EC), paras. 7.198–7.217.
90
This also seemed to be the view of the panel in EC – Large Civil Aircraft, para. 7.243.
91
Grossman and Mavroidis first articulated their viewpoint in a case note on US – Lead
and Bismuth II. See Grossman and Mavroidis, ‘Here Today, Gone Tomorrow?’,
above n. 58.
92
Appellate Body Report, US – Countervailing Measures on Certain EC Products, para. 102
(emphasis in the original).
93
Contextual support could be found in Article 14 of the SCM Agreement. See also
Diamond, above Chapter 5 n. 249.
94
The benefit test ‘should focus on the relevant market benchmark at the time the financial
contribution is granted to the recipient’ and this is ‘an ex ante analysis that does not depend
on how the particular financial contribution actually performed after it was granted’.
Appellate Body Report, EC – Large Civil Aircraft, para. 706 (emphasis in the original).
95
Appellate Body Report, EC – Large Civil Aircraft, para. 709; see also Panel Report, EC –
Large Civil Aircraft, paras. 7.218, 7.221.
96
Appellate Body Report, EC – Large Civil Aircraft, para. 710 (emphasis in original).
97
See above Chapter 4, section 4.2.3.1.
the fact that ‘the owners’ investment in the privatized company will be
recouped through the privatized company providing its owners a market
return on the full amount of their investment’ suggests that the ‘benefit’
conferred by prior financial contributions is ultimately not in fact ‘paid
for’ by the new owner.100
this subsidy, regardless of whether it is still the old owner or a new one
who collects this benefit over this period. Hence the products continue to
be subsidized as required by the obligation to limit CVDs to the ad
valorem subsidy level.
Thus the extinction theory of privatization should not be endorsed
under the existing SCM provisions even if the benefit concept is –
correctly – understood as an improvement in wealth terms that disre-
gards the competitive effect. First, considering the implications of the
Appellate Body in EC – Large Civil Aircraft, the effect of a prior subsi-
dization in wealth terms remains untouched after privatization, even if
one supports the view that the benefit has been extinguished. Such
benefit extinction does not preclude a positive adverse effect test under
Article 5 of the SCM Agreement as a ‘continued benefit’ should not be
shown. Alternatively, it could be argued that the products remain sub-
sidized even after privatization and that a continued benefit is thus
present. This would align the current obligations on the imposition of
CVDs with the economic logic that privatization does not affect the
firm’s competitive position. In the next section we return to the broader
question whether the SCM Agreement disciplines only those subsidies
effectively improving the competitive position of the firm.
subsidy as well as the nature of the market affects this trade effect test.103
For instance, showing adverse trade effects in the case of subsidies tied to
production (and certainly when tied to exports) is certainly easier than
showing such effects from untied subsidies.104 Further, showing adverse
effects on competitors in a duopolistic market (e.g., the Boeing and
Airbus disputes) seems easier than showing them in competitive markets
(e.g., US – Upland Cotton case), because of the direct substitution effect
as well as the presence of market power (giving the ability and incentive
to use subsidies to ameliorate its competitive position) in the case of a
duopoly. The particularities of the duopolistic market also seems to
explain why a quantitative analysis was not a strict prerequisite. In
competitive markets, a quantitative analysis has to model the adverse
trade effect caused by subsidization.
Turning to the CVD context, the competitive effect would in theory
equally be singled out, since only specific subsidies causing injury to the
domestic industry should be countervailable. However, as explained above,
the effect of subsidization on production levels could be largely neglected in
CVD investigations because the case law only mandates the establishment of
a causal link between subsidized imports and injury instead of between
subsidies and injury.105 Hence CVD investigations do not detect only
those subsidies affecting a firm’s competitive position. This forms a defi-
ciency in the standard set for demonstrating the causal relationship require-
ment, rather than one in the standard set for the subsidy determination.
Further, as mentioned before, the risk that this would result in large CVDs
offsetting insignificant subsidization is tempered by the obligation that
CVDs are not to be imposed above the subsidy level. Yet it does not
neutralize the risk that large CVDs are imposed offsetting significant sub-
sidization that does not de facto cause injury.
103
See above Chapter 4, sections 4.2.3.5.3; 4.2.4.
104
The Appellate Body in US – Large Civil Aircraft (paras. 1336, 1348) accepted the
proposition that subsidies that are not directly contingent on production or sale can
still cause serious prejudice. However, even cumulation of their effect on other subsidies
for which adverse effects have been shown is not easily demonstrated. As explained,
such cumulation only requires demonstration of a ‘genuine’ (and not a ‘substantial’)
causal connection to the same adverse effects. Cumulation was not accepted regarding
those untied subsidies that were not somehow linked to the relevant sales campaign
(e.g., relocation subsidies). In US – Upland Cotton, the panel declined aggregation of
non-price subsidies to price contingent subsidies for its price suppression analysis. See
above Chapter 4, sections 4.2.3.5.4; 4.2.4.2.
105
See above Chapter 5, section 5.2.2.3.
106
See World Trade Report 2006, above Chapter 1, n. 4, at 51, 198; see also Jackson, above
Chapter 2 n. 57, at 296–7.
107
Sykes, above n. 5, at 512; Jackson, above Chapter 2 n. 57, at 297; see also Hufbauer and
Shelton Erb, above Chapter 2 n. 12, at 55 (in the context of general tax measures);
Benitah, above Chapter 6 n. 108, at 258–60; Luengo, above Chapter 3 n. 135, at 129–30.
108
Sykes, above n. 5, at 512 (in the context of general tax measures); Trebilcock and
Fishbein, above Chapter 3 n. 367, at 22; Trebilcock and Howse also doubt that the
exchange rate adjustment assumption holds in a world where exchange rates are
increasingly determined by capital flows rather than trade flows. Trebilcock and
Howse, above Chapter 5 n. 1, at 289.
109
See also Mavroidis, Messerlin, and Wauters, above General introduction n. 3, at 350–1.
110
Anderson and Husisian, above Chapter 2 n. 80, at 331. EU state aid disciplines also only
targeted aid favouring ‘certain undertakings’. See Evtimov, above Chapter 3 n. 434, at
456; Luengo, above Chapter 3 n. 135, at 330.
111
See SCM/M/48, 21 December 1990, paras. 74, 76.
112
See also Jackson, above Chapter 2 n. 57, at 298.
113
Jackson, above Chapter 2 n. 57, at 297. See also D. Palmeter, ‘Safeguard, Anti-dumping,
and Countervailing Duty Disputes in the Transatlantic Partnership: How to Control
“Contingency Protection” More Effectively,’ in E.-U. Petersmann and M. A. Pollack
(eds.), Transatlantic Economic Disputes: The EU, the US, and the WTO (Oxford
University Press, 2003), 141–73, at 155; A. O. Sykes, ‘International Trade: Trade
Remedies’, in A. T. Guzman and A. O. Sykes (eds.), Research Handbook in
International Economic Law (Cheltenham, Edward Elgar, 2007), 62–112, at 103.
114
As Sykes observes, ‘basic expenditures on publication education and road construction,
for example, can have profound effects on costs’. Sykes, above n. 511, at 31–2.
115
Sykes, above n. 113, at 103. 116 Ibid., at 101; Sykes, above n. 5, at 513–514.
117
As Green explains, ‘not all subsidies that promote environmental concerns may be specific
but some valuable ones are targeted’. Green, above Chapter 4 n. 448, at 400–1, 405.
118
See Article 8.1(b) of the SCM Agreement.
119
See also Sykes, above n. 54, at 100; see also Trebilcock and Howse, above Chapter 5
n. 1, at 289.
120
Further, the fact that subsidies such as agricultural subsidies are widely available does
not imply that they are non-specific. See above Chapter 3, section 3.3.2.
121
Panel Report, US – Softwood Lumber IV, para. 7.116.
122
Panel Report, US – Large Civil Aircraft, para. 7.763 (emphasis in original).
123
Ibid., paras. 7.765–7.766; Panel Report, US – Upland Cotton, para. 7.1142.
124
Chapter 3, section 3.3.2.3.
125
Likewise, Green gives the example of subsidies aimed at providing energy efficiency or
emission reduction payments across all sectors. These would be de facto specific if the
de facto subsidy test is read in isolation. Green, above Chapter 4 n. 448, at 405.
126
Chapter 3, section 3.3.2.1.