PG 13
PG 13
Department of Economics
Game Theory in the Social Sciences
(Econ C110)
Fall 2016
Strategic games II
— Oligopolistic competition.
— Sealed-bid auctions.
The tragedy of the commons
William Forster Lloyd (1833)
— Each additional animal has a positive effect for its herder, but the cost
of the extra animal is shared by all other herders, causing a so-called
“free-rider” problem. Today’s commons include fish stocks, rivers,
oceans, and the atmosphere.
Garrett Hardin (1968)
— This social dilemma was populated by Hardin in his article “The Tragedy
of the Commons,” published in the journal Science. The essay derived
its title from Lloyd (1833) on the over-grazing of common land.
— Hence, the value for each player from the action profile (outcome)
= (1 ) is give by
µ X ¶
( −) = ln() + ln − =1
— To get player ’s best-response function, we write down the first-order
condition of his payoff function:
( −) 1 1
= − P =0
−
=1
and thus
P
− 6=
(−) =
2
The two-player Tragedy of the Commons
— The ‘right way’ to answer this question is using the Pareto princi-
ple (Vilfredo Pareto, 1848-1923) — can we find another action profile
= (1 2) that will make both players better off than in the Nash
equilibrium?
— To this end, assume there are two players, and , choosing two dif-
ferent 6= in equilibrium.
• In the basic example, a single good is produced by two firms (the industry
is a “duopoly”).
Cournot’s oligopoly model (1838) (Antoine Augustin Cournot, an econo-
mist, philosopher and mathematician, 1801-1877).
— The cost for firm = 1 2 for producing units of the good is given
by (“unit cost” is constant equal to 0).
=−
if ≥ and zero otherwise (linear inverse demand function). We
also assume that .
To find the Nash equilibria of the Cournot’s game, we can use the proce-
dures based on the firms’ best response functions.
q '2 q2
q2
A c1 q2 A c1 q'2 Output 1
2 2
To find firm 1’s best response to any given output 2 of firm 2, we need
to study firm 1’s profit as a function of its output 1 for given values of
2.
Using calculus, we set the derivative of firm 1’s profit with respect to 1
equal to zero and solve for 1:
1
1 = ( − 2 − 1)
2
From the figure below, we see that there is exactly one such pair of outputs
Output 2
A c1
BR1 (q2 )
Nash equilibrium
A c2
2
BR2 (q1 )
A c1 A c2 Output 1
2
Nash equilibrium comparative statics
(a decrease in the cost of firm 2)
Output 2
A c1
Nash equilibrium I
A c2
2
BR2 (q1 )
A c1 A c2 Output 1
2
[1] The relation between the firms’ equilibrium profits and the profit they
could make if they act collusively.
[2] The relation between the equilibrium profits and the number of firms.
[1] Collusive outcomes: in the Cournot’s duopoly game, there is a pair of out-
puts at which both firms’ profits exceed their levels in a Nash equilibrium.
[2] Competition: The price at the Nash equilibrium if the two firms have the
same unit cost 1 = 2 = is given by
∗ = − 1∗ − 2∗
1
= ( + 2)
3
which is above the unit cost . But as the number of firm increases, the
equilibrium price deceases, approaching (zero profits).
Cournot’s oligopoly game (many firms)
— Suppose all firms have the same unit cost, i.e. = for all firms .
Firm 1’s payoff (profit) is given by
1 = 1 − 1
= ( − )1 − 1
= ( − 1 − 2 − − )1 − 1
P
= ( − =1 − )1
— To find firm 1’s best response to any given outputs 2 of the
other firms, we need to study firm 1’s profit as a function of its output
1 for given values of 2 .
— Thus firm 1’s best response function is
1
1 = ( − 2 − − − )
2
— The best response functions of every other firm is the same so the
conditions for (1∗ 2∗
∗ ) to be a Nash equilibrium are
1∗ = 1(−1
∗ )
..
∗ = ( ∗ )
1 −
∗ stands for the list of the outputs of all the firms except firm
where −
.
— Let the common value of the firms’ outputs in the (unique symmetric)
Nash equilibrium be ∗. Then each best response function is
1
∗ = ( − ( − 1) ∗ − )
2
Rearranging,
− ( + 1) ∗ − = 0
or
∗ −
=
+1
— The price at this equilibrium is
− ( − )
+1
so as the number of firms increases this price decreases, approaching
as → ∞ (increases without bound).
Stackelberg’s duopoly model (1934)
How do the conclusions of the Cournot’s duopoly game change when the
firms move sequentially? Is a firm better off moving before or after the
other firm?
Suppose that 1 = 2 = and that firm 1 moves at the start of the game.
We may use backward induction to find the subgame perfect equilibrium.
We found that under the assumptions of the Cournot’s duopoly game Firm
2 has a unique best response to each output 1 of firm 1, given by
1
2 = ( − 1 − )
2
(Recall that 1 = 2 = ).
Firm 1
Profit 1
1
1 q1 ( A q1 c)
2
A c1 Ac Output 1
2
We conclude that Stackelberg’s duopoly game has a unique subgame per-
fect equilibrium, in which firm 1’s strategy is the output
∗ 1
1 = ( − )
2
and firm 2’s output is
1
2∗ = ( − 1∗ − )
2
1 1
= ( − ( − ) − )
2 2
1
= ( − )
4
By contrast, in the unique Nash equilibrium of the Cournot’s duopoly game
1
under the same assumptions (1 = 2 = ), each firm produces ( − ).
3
The subgame perfect equilibrium of Stackelberg's duopoly game
Output 2
Ac Output 1
Ac Ac
3 2
Bertrand’s oligopoly model (1883)
In Cournot’s game, each firm chooses an output, and the price is deter-
mined by the market demand in relation to the total output produced.
=⇒ As we shell see, some of the answers it gives are different from the answers
of Cournot.
Suppose again that there are two firms (the industry is a “duopoly”) and
that the cost for firm = 1 2 for producing units of the good is given
by (equal constant “unit cost”).
Assume that the demand function (rather than the inverse demand function
as we did for the Cournot’s game) is
() = −
for ≥ and zero otherwise, and that (the demand function in
PR 12.3 is different).
Because the cost of producing each until is the same, equal to , firm
makes the profit of − on every unit it sells. Thus its profit is
⎧
⎪
⎪ ( − )( − ) if
⎪
⎨ 1
= ( − )( − ) if =
⎪
⎪ 2
⎪
⎩ 0 if
where is the other firm.
In Bertrand’s game we can easily argue as follows: (1 2) = ( ) is the
unique Nash equilibrium.
Using intuition,
— If one firm charges the price , then the other firm can do no better
than charge the price .
If you are in a situation satisfying the following assumptions, then you will
end up in a Bertrand trap (zero profits):
Sequential / simultaneous
— English (or oral) — the seller actively solicits progressively higher bids
and the item is soled to the highest bidder.
— Dutch — the seller begins by offering units at a “high” price and reduces
it until all units are soled.
— Sealed-bid — all bids are made simultaneously, and the item is sold to
the highest bidder.
First-price / second-price
The price paid may be the highest bid or some other price:
— First-price — the bidder who submits the highest bid wins and pay a
price equal to her bid.
— Second-prices — the bidder who submits the highest bid wins and pay
a price equal to the second highest bid.
To define the game precisely, denote by the value that bidder attaches
to the object. If she obtains the object at price then her payoff is − .
Assume that bidders’ valuations are all different and all positive. Number
the bidders 1 through in such a way that
1 2 · · · 0
Each bidder submits a (sealed) bid . If bidder obtains the object, she
receives a payoff − . Otherwise, her payoff is zero.
Tie-breaking — if two or more bidders are in a tie for the highest bid, the
winner is the bidder with the highest valuation.
In summary, a first-price sealed-bid auction with perfect information is the
following strategic game:
It is easy to verify that all these profiles are Nash equilibria. It is harder
to show that there are no other equilibria. We can easily argue, however,
that there is no equilibrium in which player 1 does not obtain the object.
=⇒ The first-price sealed-bid auction is socially efficient, but does not neces-
sarily raise the most revenues.
Second-price auction (with perfect information)
The winning bidder is likely to be the bidder with the largest positive error
(the largest overestimate).
In this case, the winner has fallen prey to the so-called the winner’s curse.
Auctions where the winner’s curse is significant are oil fields, spectrum
auctions, pay per click, and more.
First-price auction class experiment
.25
.2.15
Fraction
.1
.05
0
5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100
Bid
Second-price auction class experiment
.25
.2.15
Fraction
.1
.05
0
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100
Bid