3.2 Consumer Behaviour - II
3.2 Consumer Behaviour - II
• Monotonicity
• We will typically assume that more goods are better
• If (x1, x2) is a bundle of goods and (y1, y2) is another
bundle of goods with at least as much of one good
and more of the other, then (y1, y2) (x1, x2)
• The assumption of monotonicity implies
• non-satiation (more is always preferred)
• and that indifference curves have a negative slope.
• Convexity
• Mixtures of bundles are (at least weakly)preferred
to the bundles themselves
• e.g., the 50-50 mixture of the bundles x and y is
z = (0.5)x + (0.5)y.
z is at least as preferred as x or y
WELL-BEHAVED PREFERENCES
WELL-BEHAVED PREFERENCES
• Various kinds of preferences.
• Panel A depicts convex preferences
• panel B depicts nonconvex preferences, and
• panel C depicts concave preferences.
x2 x2 x 2 (y , y )
1 2
(y1, y 2) Averaged
(y1, y 2)
bundle
Averaged
bundle
Averaged
(x1, x2) bundle (x1, x 2) (x1, x 2)
x1 x1 x1
A Convex B Nonconvex C Concave
preferences preferences preferences
WELL-BEHAVED PREFERENCES
• Non-convex preferences: Example
• Think of ice cream and tomato ketchup
• I like ice cream and I like ketchup but I don’t like to have them
together
• In considering my consumption in the next hour, I might be
indifferent between consuming 10 ounces of ice cream or 10
ounces of ketchup
• Either one of these bundles would be better than consuming 5
ounces of each (the average bundle)
• We assume that well-behaved preferences are convex because
mostly goods are consumed together
• Non-convex preferences imply that the consumer would
prefer to specialize, at least to some degree, and to consume
only one of the goods.
• However, the normal case is where the consumer would want
to trade some of one good for the other and end up
consuming some of each, rather than specializing in
consuming only one of the two goods.
MARGINAL RATE OF SUBSTITUTION
• The slope of an indifference curve is known as the
marginal rate of substitution (MRS).
• MRS measures the rate at which the consumer is just
willing to substitute one good for the other.
• Suppose that we take a little of good 1, Δx1, away from
the consumer.
• Then we give him Δx2, an amount that is just sufficient to
put him back on his indifference curve, so that he is just as
well off after this substitution of x2 for x1 as he was before.
• We think of the ratio Δx2/Δx1 as being the rate at which the
consumer is willing to substitute good 2 for good 1.
• When we write the ratio Δx2/Δx1, we will always think of
both the numerator and the denominator as being small
numbers
• describing marginal changes from the original
consumption bundle
• Since the MRS is the numerical measure of the slope of an
indifference curve, it will be a negative number
MARGINAL RATE OF SUBSTITUTION
• MRS is the rate at which the consumer is just willing to
exchange commodity 2 for a small amount of commodity 1
• If good 2 represents the consumption of “all other goods,”
measured in dollars that you can spend on these goods, then MRS
measures the marginal willingness to pay (give up dollars) in order
to consume a small amount more of good 1
x2
Indifference curve
x1
MARGINAL RATE OF SUBSTITUTION
• How much you actually end up buying of a good
will depend on
• your preferences for that good and
• the prices that you face
Δx2
Indifference curve
Δx1
Slope = Δx2/Δx1 = MRS = -0.25
x1
UTILITY
• Due to conceptual problems associated with utility
measurement, economists have abandoned the
old-fashioned view of utility as being a measure of
happiness.
x2
Indifference curves
k=3
k=2
k=1
x1
UTILITY FUNCTIONS: EXAMPLES
• Now consider a utility function v(x1, x2) = x12x22
• By the standard rules of algebra we know that
v(x1, x2) = x12x22 = (x1x2)2 = u(x1, x2)2
• Thus the utility function v(x1, x2) is just the square of the utility
function u(x1, x2).
• This means that the utility function v(x1, x2) = x12x22 has to have
exactly the same shaped indifference curves as those of u(x1,
x 2) = x 1x 2
• The labeling of the indifference curves will be different—the
labels that were (k=) 1, 2, 3, will now be (k=) 1, 4, 9.
UTILITY FUNCTIONS: EXAMPLES
• In general, preferences for perfect substitutes can be represented
by a utility function of the form
u(x1, x2) = ax1 + bx2
• Here a and b are some positive numbers that measure the value of
goods 1 and 2 to the consumer.
• When the utility function is linear in one good but (possibly) non-
linear in the other good it is quasilinear (partly linear).
u(x1, x2) = f(x1) + x2 = ln(x1) + x2
u(x1, x2) = f(x1) + x2 = √x1 + x2
UTILITY FUNCTIONS: EXAMPLES
• In case of Quasilinear utility functions the indifference
curves are just vertically “shifted” versions of one
indifference curve.
x2
Indifference curves
x1
UTILITY FUNCTIONS: EXAMPLES
• Another commonly used utility function is the Cobb-Douglas utility function
u(x1, x2) = x1ax2b
• where a and b are positive numbers that describe the preferences of
the consumer
• The preferences represented by the Cobb-Douglas utility function have
the general shape depicted in the following figure.
• In panel A, we have indifference curves for a = 1/2, b = 1/2.
• In panel B, we have indifference curves for a = 1/5, b = 4/5.
• Note how different values of the parameters a and b lead to different
shapes of the indifference curves.
x2 x2
x1 x1