0% found this document useful (0 votes)
31 views33 pages

ECO101 Week6 ConsumerBehaviour

Uploaded by

Shawn Ma
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
31 views33 pages

ECO101 Week6 ConsumerBehaviour

Uploaded by

Shawn Ma
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 33

Week 6:

Consumer Behaviour
ECO 101: INTRODUCTION TO MICROECONOMICS
This Week’s Class
◦Lecture:
◦ What is Utility?
◦ How do consumers actually choose between consumption bundles they can
afford?
◦ What is “optimal” consumer behaviour?
◦ How can we aggregate individual choices to market demand?
◦Tutorial:
◦ Practice solving for Optimal Choices using Marginal Utilities.
Budget Constraint Example
◦ Recall the budget constraint (BC)
outlines all of the consumption
Food

A E
bundles a household can afford.
◦ Any bundle on the BC is affordable.
◦ Note that A, B, C are all affordable.
Bu
D d ge ◦ But A & C are unlikely to actually be
tC desirable consumption bundles.
on
str
ain B ◦ So how do households actually
t
choose which of these bundles to
purchase and consume?
C
Clothes
Utility
◦ We typically use the economic concept of utility.
◦ Any bundle of goods delivers a certain amount of utility.
◦ For example, 2 units of clothes and 5 units of food might deliver 10
utility (or 10 “utils”).
◦ Consumers like utility and seek to maximize it.
◦ We assume that a consumer’s utility is both:
◦ Complete: any possible combination of goods delivers a utility value.
◦ Ordinal: the absolute value of utility (e.g. 10 utils) has no meaning on its
own, but it is meaningful for comparisons.
◦ If Bundle 1 had higher utility than bundle 2, then Bundle 1 is preferred.
Adding in Utility Values
◦ Suppose that each of these five bundles
A vs B? deliver these utility values.
Food

35 55 ◦ Out of the 5 bundles, which would a


A E consumer prefer to consume?
A vs C?
D ◦ Out of the 5 bundles, which would a
consumer end up consuming?
Bu
37 d ge A vs D? ◦ Typically seeks out the highest utility bundle
tC that they can afford.
on
str ◦ Can always just get higher utility by
ain 45 consuming more, but we are bounded by
t
our resources/income/wealth.
B
◦ Allows us to order all bundles in terms
C
of preference.
35 ◦ (𝐸 ≻ 𝐵 ≻ 𝐷 ≻ 𝐶 ∽ 𝐴)
Clothes
Marginal Utility
◦ Marginal Utility: how much additional utility does an individual
gain from consuming an additional unit of a good.
◦ Economic decision making is often made on the margin.
◦ When deciding between two goods, and individual will choose
whichever delivers the high marginal utility per dollar spent.
◦ Suppose there are two goods (1 & 2):
𝑀𝑈! 𝑀𝑈"
>
𝑝! 𝑝"
Which would the consumer spend their money on?
Diminishing Marginal Utility
Total Utility
◦ We generally assume that

Utility
marginal utility is diminishing
as the quantity of a good
consumed increases.
◦ The added enjoyment from
each successive unit is less.
◦ Examples of goods that
might exhibit this?
Marginal Utility

Quantity
Marginal Utility Example
Good 1 (p1 = $5) Good 2 (p2 = $2.5)
Quantity MU Total Spent Quantity MU Total Spent
1 10 $5 1 7 $2.5
2 9 $10 2 6.5 $5
3 8 $15 3 6 $7.5
4 7 $20 4 5 $10
5 6 $25 5 4 $12.5
6 5 $30 6 3 $15
7 4 $35 7 2 $17.5
8 3 $40 8 0.5 $20
Utility Maximization
◦This implies that an individual is only maximizing their utility
if:
𝑴𝑼𝟏 𝑴𝑼𝟐
=
𝒑𝟏 𝒑𝟐
◦This maximization condition can be rewritten as:
𝑴𝑼𝟏 𝒑𝟏
=
𝑴𝑼𝟐 𝒑𝟐
◦ The ratio of marginal utilities between (any) two goods must be
equal to their ratio of prices.
Diminishing Marginal Utility
◦Suppose that:
MU! MU" MU! MU"
> and we want to go to =
p! p" p! p"
◦Why is the first (left) inefficient?
◦How do they re-arrange spending?
◦ We generally assume that consumers are price takers, so p1 & p2 are
fixed.
◦ Diminishing Marginal Utility tells us how to do this!
◦ Increasing Q1 will decrease MU1 and decreasing Q2 will increase
MU2.
Indifference Curves (IC)
◦Completeness: every possible bundle of goods should
deliver a utility value.
◦All bundles that deliver exactly the same amount of utility
will be on the same Indifference Curve (IC).
◦ An individual IC will exist for each value if utility.
◦ For any given bundle, all of the other points on the same
Indifference Curve deliver the same utility, and therefore a
consumer is indifferent between any of these points.
◦Every bundle is on an Indifference Curve!
Back to Our Utility Example
IC!"#$%'' ◦ Note that A & C both deliver 35 Utils.
IC!"#$%&(
35 ◦ ⇒ same Indifference Curve.
IC!"#$%&' E 55
◦ Likewise, there exists:
A
◦ An IC for Utility = 37, and
Food

D
◦ An IC for Utility = 55.
37 ◦ Every point in this x-y space is on an IC.
55
F ◦ An individual maximizes their utility
45 (subject to their budget) at the highest
B feasible IC (In this case, at point F).
◦ This IC will necessarily be tangent to the BC.
C ◦ This is the highest utility point still within the
35
budget set.
Clothes
Utility Example
◦ Suppose that we are at Point A.
Preferred Set ◦ Can this individual be made better
off?
◦ Certainly! Anywhere above the Indifference
Food

Curve will deliver higher utility (NE).


◦ This is the preferred set for this Indifference
A Pre Curve.
Af fer
fo re
rd d
◦ But can the individual afford to be
ab &
le made better off?
◦ Still yes, but in a more limited set of points.
◦ Anywhere in the preferred set that is also
on or below the budget constraint is
affordable and preferred.
◦ Optimization occurs at the tangency!
Clothes
Marginal Rate of Substitution (MRS)
◦ Can move along the IC by giving up some
amount of X and receiving an amount of Y.
◦ Marginal Rate of Substitution (MRS): The
rate at which you can trade off X for Y and
Food (Y)

stay just as well off.


𝑴𝑼𝑿
𝑴𝑹𝑺 = −
𝑴𝑼𝒀
◦ The MRS is shown on the graph as the
slope of the Indifference Curve.
◦ Note that this ratio of Marginal Utilities
decreases as you move SE on the IC. Why?
IC!"#$%'' ◦ Diminishing Marginal Utility gives
individuals a preference for variety.
Clothes (X) ◦ This is why (typically) curved inwardly.
Indifference Curves Cannot Cross
IC* ◦ Indifference Curves cannot cross.
IC)
◦ Why not? Suppose they do.
◦ The argument is centered around the
B
“preferred set”.
Food

A
◦ Recall that anything NE of an Indifference
Curve is (strictly) preferred to anything on the
curve.
◦ Note that B ≻ A and also C ≻ D.
C ◦ But also that B & D and C & A are on the
same ICs, so we must be indifferent
D between them.
◦ This would imply: B ≻ A ∼ C ≻ D.
◦ Which gives us: B ≻ D (which cannot be)
Clothes
Substitutability of Products
◦ As products become close substitutes,
the IC will get straighter.
◦ E.g. blackboards versus whiteboards.
◦ Perfect Substitutes: Constant MRS.
Food

◦ Manifests as a linear line.


◦ The Utility tradeoff remains constant.
◦ Perfect Complements: Zero MRS, then
infinity.
◦ Manifests as an L-Shape.
◦ No tradeoff – must be consumed in fixed
proportions to deliver utility.
◦ How do we optimize on either of these?
Clothes
Utility: As A (Useful) Concept?
◦ The general framework for economic choice theory involves:
◦ Consumers choosing their optimal consumption bundles that maximize
their own personal utility functions, subject to:
◦ Their own resource constraints and market prices (budget constraint)
◦ How plausible is this? Is it convincing?
◦ People do not know their own utility functions.
◦ Precisely inaccurate – but predictions bear out.
◦ Generally plausible in the sense that people think critically and try to do their best
with the resources and information available to them.
◦ People are generally “boundedly rational”, but almost surely not “perfectly rational”.
◦ This weeks podcast thinks about how much we really do optimize in our lives.
10-minute Break
The Effect of an Income Increase
◦ Suppose that somebody is utility maximizing and income
increases:
MU" MU#
We start from =
p" p#
◦ How should a utility-maximizing consumer react?
◦ Still price-taking, but just have more money to spend.
◦ As you spend money on each good, their MU will drop (Dim MU)
◦ Therefore, you need to spend money on all goods such that all
their marginal utilities drop and maintain this equality.
The Income Effect
◦We call the demand effects of an increase in consumer
income the income effect.
◦How a consumer’s demand for a good changes with
increased income holding the relevant prices of all good
constant.
◦Normal goods: demand increases when income increases.
◦Inferior goods: demand decreases when income increases.
◦ Examples of inferior goods: McDonalds, bus tickets, potatoes.
The Income Effect Graphically
◦ An Increase in Income manifests in a
parallel shift outwards in the budget
constraint.
◦ The new point of tangency moves us
Food

from point A → point B.


◦ Notice that Income has increased,
B and so has demand for both goods.
◦ Assuming both are Norma Goods.
A
◦ This demand increase for these
goods is the income effect.

Clothes
The Effect of a Price Increase
◦ Suppose that somebody is utility maximizing and p1 increases:
MU" MU# MU" MU#
We go from = to <
p" p# p" p#
◦ How should a utility-maximizing consumer react?
◦ Should adjust consumption to re-establish this equality.
◦ To re-reach equality, we need MU2 ↓ and MU1 ↑.
◦ Therefore, an increase in p1 should lead to:
◦ A decrease in the demand for good 1 (MU1 ↑), and
◦ An increase in the demand for good 2 (MU2 ↓).
The Substitution Effect
◦Changes in prices actually have two effects:
◦ The Income Effect: If the price of a good increases, it reduces the set
of goods you can afford.
◦ The Substitution Effect: changes in the demand for a good when its
price changes, holding income constant.
◦The substitution is the pure effect of the change in relative
prices, if you could maintain a consumer’s purchasing power.
◦ This is a theoretical idea.
Income Versus Substitution Effects
◦ How demand reacts to price changes depends on the net impact of
both the income and substitution effects.
◦ Suppose that the price of Good A decreases. Which way do the
effects go?
◦ If Good A is a Normal Good:
◦ Income has increased ⇒ Income↑ leads to Quantity demanded ↑
◦ Good A is also relatively cheaper ⇒ Quantity demanded ↑
◦ Both income and substitution effects go in the same direction.
◦ If Good A is an Inferior Good:
◦ Income has increased ⇒ Income↑ leads to Quantity demanded ↓
◦ Good A is also relatively cheaper ⇒ Quantity demanded ↑
◦ The income and substitution effects work against each other.
The Substitution Effect Graphically
In this case, for clothes, ◦ A decrease in the price of clothes manifests in a
which effect dominates? pivoting in the budget constraint.
◦ The new point of tangency moves us from point
A → point C.
Food

◦ Note that:
◦ The increase in clothes is large.
◦ The increase in food is very slight, but positive.
C ◦ Note that there are both effects here for both
goods:
A 1. The Income Effect (Income increases for both)
2. The Substitution Effect (↑ clothes, ↓ food)
◦ For Clothes, they both move together (↑).
◦ For Food, they move against each other.
Clothes
Price Changes: Income & Sub. Effects
◦ This is an example where pX has dropped.
◦ The substitution effect shows how we
Food (Y)

would change consumption choices if we


held purchasing power constant.
◦ Note here that we are just richer.
◦ The way we do this is to say suppose that
we are not made better off by this price
A change.
C ◦ We should remain on the same IC then.
◦ Where would be the point of tangency be
B on IC1 with the new prices.
𝑴𝑼𝑿 𝒑𝑿
𝑴𝑹𝑺 = − =−
𝑴𝑼𝒀 𝒑𝒀
Clothes (X)
Price Changes: Income & Sub. Effects
◦ A → B is now the pure substitution effect.
◦ pX ↓ and QX ↑ (Sub effect).
Food (Y)

◦ pY ↑ and QY ↓ (Sub effect).


◦ Then B → C is the income effect.
◦ Gotten richer and QX ↑ (Income effect).
◦ Gotten richer and QY ↑ (Income effect).
A ◦ Note here: this picture is depicting positive income
C
effects for X & Y, so both normal goods.
◦ This (theoretical) decomposition lets us
B think about the impacts of these two
forces.
◦ In reality: we only ever observe A & C.
Clothes (X)
Demand Curves for Ordinary Goods
◦ We can show why Demand is (typically) downward sloping using Indifference Curves.
P
A
Food

B
A
B
C C

Clothes D1
Q
Ordinary & Giffen Goods
◦ Ordinary Goods: Demand P
decreases as price increases.
◦ Giffen Goods: The demand for a
good increases as its price
increases.
◦ (Flawed) observations of increases in
price and quantity in 19th Century C.E.
◦ May not actually exist.
◦ Luxury Goods: The demand for a
good increases as it gets more
expensive.
◦ Similar to the idea of Giffen Goods.
Q
Individual to Market Demand
◦We have spent a lot of time on individual demand.
◦When we start thinking about firms, we care about the total
demand in the market.
◦Therefore, the market demand is the sum of all individual
demands for a single product.
◦Therefore, demand can increase through two means:
◦ Intensive Margin: Individual existing consumers buying more.
◦ Extensive Margin: New (more) consumers entering the market.
Market Demand Example: Identical Demands
◦Suppose that we have 3 P
individuals with Demand: 12.5
◦ QD = 25 – 2p
◦If price = $10, how many
will we sell?

◦So we get the market


demand here:
◦ QDM = 3QD = 3(25-2p)
◦ QDM = 75 – 6p Q
25 75
Market Demand Example: Different Demands
◦Suppose that we have 2 P 60 − 2𝑝 𝑖𝑓 𝑝 < 25
𝑄+, = '35 − 𝑝 𝑖𝑓 ( 𝑝 ≥ 25 𝑎𝑛𝑑 𝑝 ≤ 35 )
different Demand: 0 𝑖𝑓 𝑝 > 35
◦ QD1 = 25 – p 35
◦ QD2 = 35 – p
◦Here, we need to divide 25
market demand into 2 parts
◦ Will produce a kink in demand.
◦ Will need to define market demand
on either side of this kink.
10 25 35 60 Q
Conclusion
◦Utility is a theoretical tool used to measure consumer
preferences.
◦Consumers maximize their utility by setting their
Indifference Curves tangent to their Budget
Constraints.
◦Consumers react to price and income changes with
substitution effects and income effects.

You might also like