ECO101 Week6 ConsumerBehaviour
ECO101 Week6 ConsumerBehaviour
Consumer Behaviour
ECO 101: INTRODUCTION TO MICROECONOMICS
This Week’s Class
◦Lecture:
◦ What is Utility?
◦ How do consumers actually choose between consumption bundles they can
afford?
◦ What is “optimal” consumer behaviour?
◦ How can we aggregate individual choices to market demand?
◦Tutorial:
◦ Practice solving for Optimal Choices using Marginal Utilities.
Budget Constraint Example
◦ Recall the budget constraint (BC)
outlines all of the consumption
Food
A E
bundles a household can afford.
◦ Any bundle on the BC is affordable.
◦ Note that A, B, C are all affordable.
Bu
D d ge ◦ But A & C are unlikely to actually be
tC desirable consumption bundles.
on
str
ain B ◦ So how do households actually
t
choose which of these bundles to
purchase and consume?
C
Clothes
Utility
◦ We typically use the economic concept of utility.
◦ Any bundle of goods delivers a certain amount of utility.
◦ For example, 2 units of clothes and 5 units of food might deliver 10
utility (or 10 “utils”).
◦ Consumers like utility and seek to maximize it.
◦ We assume that a consumer’s utility is both:
◦ Complete: any possible combination of goods delivers a utility value.
◦ Ordinal: the absolute value of utility (e.g. 10 utils) has no meaning on its
own, but it is meaningful for comparisons.
◦ If Bundle 1 had higher utility than bundle 2, then Bundle 1 is preferred.
Adding in Utility Values
◦ Suppose that each of these five bundles
A vs B? deliver these utility values.
Food
Utility
marginal utility is diminishing
as the quantity of a good
consumed increases.
◦ The added enjoyment from
each successive unit is less.
◦ Examples of goods that
might exhibit this?
Marginal Utility
Quantity
Marginal Utility Example
Good 1 (p1 = $5) Good 2 (p2 = $2.5)
Quantity MU Total Spent Quantity MU Total Spent
1 10 $5 1 7 $2.5
2 9 $10 2 6.5 $5
3 8 $15 3 6 $7.5
4 7 $20 4 5 $10
5 6 $25 5 4 $12.5
6 5 $30 6 3 $15
7 4 $35 7 2 $17.5
8 3 $40 8 0.5 $20
Utility Maximization
◦This implies that an individual is only maximizing their utility
if:
𝑴𝑼𝟏 𝑴𝑼𝟐
=
𝒑𝟏 𝒑𝟐
◦This maximization condition can be rewritten as:
𝑴𝑼𝟏 𝒑𝟏
=
𝑴𝑼𝟐 𝒑𝟐
◦ The ratio of marginal utilities between (any) two goods must be
equal to their ratio of prices.
Diminishing Marginal Utility
◦Suppose that:
MU! MU" MU! MU"
> and we want to go to =
p! p" p! p"
◦Why is the first (left) inefficient?
◦How do they re-arrange spending?
◦ We generally assume that consumers are price takers, so p1 & p2 are
fixed.
◦ Diminishing Marginal Utility tells us how to do this!
◦ Increasing Q1 will decrease MU1 and decreasing Q2 will increase
MU2.
Indifference Curves (IC)
◦Completeness: every possible bundle of goods should
deliver a utility value.
◦All bundles that deliver exactly the same amount of utility
will be on the same Indifference Curve (IC).
◦ An individual IC will exist for each value if utility.
◦ For any given bundle, all of the other points on the same
Indifference Curve deliver the same utility, and therefore a
consumer is indifferent between any of these points.
◦Every bundle is on an Indifference Curve!
Back to Our Utility Example
IC!"#$%'' ◦ Note that A & C both deliver 35 Utils.
IC!"#$%&(
35 ◦ ⇒ same Indifference Curve.
IC!"#$%&' E 55
◦ Likewise, there exists:
A
◦ An IC for Utility = 37, and
Food
D
◦ An IC for Utility = 55.
37 ◦ Every point in this x-y space is on an IC.
55
F ◦ An individual maximizes their utility
45 (subject to their budget) at the highest
B feasible IC (In this case, at point F).
◦ This IC will necessarily be tangent to the BC.
C ◦ This is the highest utility point still within the
35
budget set.
Clothes
Utility Example
◦ Suppose that we are at Point A.
Preferred Set ◦ Can this individual be made better
off?
◦ Certainly! Anywhere above the Indifference
Food
A
◦ Recall that anything NE of an Indifference
Curve is (strictly) preferred to anything on the
curve.
◦ Note that B ≻ A and also C ≻ D.
C ◦ But also that B & D and C & A are on the
same ICs, so we must be indifferent
D between them.
◦ This would imply: B ≻ A ∼ C ≻ D.
◦ Which gives us: B ≻ D (which cannot be)
Clothes
Substitutability of Products
◦ As products become close substitutes,
the IC will get straighter.
◦ E.g. blackboards versus whiteboards.
◦ Perfect Substitutes: Constant MRS.
Food
Clothes
The Effect of a Price Increase
◦ Suppose that somebody is utility maximizing and p1 increases:
MU" MU# MU" MU#
We go from = to <
p" p# p" p#
◦ How should a utility-maximizing consumer react?
◦ Should adjust consumption to re-establish this equality.
◦ To re-reach equality, we need MU2 ↓ and MU1 ↑.
◦ Therefore, an increase in p1 should lead to:
◦ A decrease in the demand for good 1 (MU1 ↑), and
◦ An increase in the demand for good 2 (MU2 ↓).
The Substitution Effect
◦Changes in prices actually have two effects:
◦ The Income Effect: If the price of a good increases, it reduces the set
of goods you can afford.
◦ The Substitution Effect: changes in the demand for a good when its
price changes, holding income constant.
◦The substitution is the pure effect of the change in relative
prices, if you could maintain a consumer’s purchasing power.
◦ This is a theoretical idea.
Income Versus Substitution Effects
◦ How demand reacts to price changes depends on the net impact of
both the income and substitution effects.
◦ Suppose that the price of Good A decreases. Which way do the
effects go?
◦ If Good A is a Normal Good:
◦ Income has increased ⇒ Income↑ leads to Quantity demanded ↑
◦ Good A is also relatively cheaper ⇒ Quantity demanded ↑
◦ Both income and substitution effects go in the same direction.
◦ If Good A is an Inferior Good:
◦ Income has increased ⇒ Income↑ leads to Quantity demanded ↓
◦ Good A is also relatively cheaper ⇒ Quantity demanded ↑
◦ The income and substitution effects work against each other.
The Substitution Effect Graphically
In this case, for clothes, ◦ A decrease in the price of clothes manifests in a
which effect dominates? pivoting in the budget constraint.
◦ The new point of tangency moves us from point
A → point C.
Food
◦ Note that:
◦ The increase in clothes is large.
◦ The increase in food is very slight, but positive.
C ◦ Note that there are both effects here for both
goods:
A 1. The Income Effect (Income increases for both)
2. The Substitution Effect (↑ clothes, ↓ food)
◦ For Clothes, they both move together (↑).
◦ For Food, they move against each other.
Clothes
Price Changes: Income & Sub. Effects
◦ This is an example where pX has dropped.
◦ The substitution effect shows how we
Food (Y)
B
A
B
C C
Clothes D1
Q
Ordinary & Giffen Goods
◦ Ordinary Goods: Demand P
decreases as price increases.
◦ Giffen Goods: The demand for a
good increases as its price
increases.
◦ (Flawed) observations of increases in
price and quantity in 19th Century C.E.
◦ May not actually exist.
◦ Luxury Goods: The demand for a
good increases as it gets more
expensive.
◦ Similar to the idea of Giffen Goods.
Q
Individual to Market Demand
◦We have spent a lot of time on individual demand.
◦When we start thinking about firms, we care about the total
demand in the market.
◦Therefore, the market demand is the sum of all individual
demands for a single product.
◦Therefore, demand can increase through two means:
◦ Intensive Margin: Individual existing consumers buying more.
◦ Extensive Margin: New (more) consumers entering the market.
Market Demand Example: Identical Demands
◦Suppose that we have 3 P
individuals with Demand: 12.5
◦ QD = 25 – 2p
◦If price = $10, how many
will we sell?