Week 7
Week 7
2
Introduction
• Last lecture we studied the CAPM, and saw
that under CAPM, all assets should be priced
by the formula:
E (r ) = r + β [E (r ) − r ]
i f i M f
3
Are all assets correctly priced by the CAPM?
• CAPM relies on several strong assumptions (see the discussion
in last lecture) that may not hold in reality. As such, CAPM is
not necessarily the correct asset pricing model.
• However, even if CAPM is the correct model for pricing all
assets, some assets could be mispriced
– In previous lectures, we assumed that all investors were rational,
which is surely at question.
– Some investors may subject to behavioral bias, and thus make
irrational investment decisions, which could affect asset prices.
– And there could be limits to arbitrage such as short sale constraints,
which allow for temporary deviation of an asset’s price from its
fundamental value.
– We will discuss both behavioral biases and limits to arbitrage in length
in the next lecture.
Mispricing 4
The Stiglitz paradox
• Asset prices should reflect fundamentals to some extent
– But for that to happen, costly analysis is required to map information
about a business into valuation
• According to the CAPM, everybody should buy the market
portfolio, so nobody has any incentive to do the analysis
– If everybody is a passive CAPM investor, there is no channel for
information about the real economy to enter the capital market
• Therefore, we usually think that prices may deviate enough
from their fundamental values for an analyst to achieve
enough excess returns to reward them for their work
– So mispricing is absolute, just by how much
• The CAPM still gives guidance on how to exploit such
mispricing
Mispricing 5
The Single Index Model
• Theoretically, the market portfolio should include all risky
assets, for example, individuals’ personal human capital.
• Since we cannot observe the true market portfolio, we try to
pick something that seems kind of close when using CAPM in
practice
– A common choice is a broad value-weighted market index, like the
S&P 500 for the U.S. or ASX 200 for Australia
• To emphasize that we are not dealing with the true market
portfolio, we sometimes refer to the resulting empirical model
as the Single Index Model, or the SIM
Mispricing 6
The Single Index Model
• We saw last time how it was convenient to think of CAPM in a
regression model:
[ ]
rit = rft + β i rMt − rft + ε it
– We are interested in variations in both the cross section and over
time, which is why we have added time indices
Mispricing 7
Jensen’s α
rit − rft = αi + β i [rMt − rft ] + ε it
• According to the CAPM the αi should be zero
• If it is not, asset i is mispriced according to the CAPM and αi is
a measure of this mispricing
Mispricing 8
Mispriced assets in E(r)-β space
C
E (ri ) αC > 0
SML
M
B
αA < 0
rf A
β
Mispricing 9
Exploiting one mispriced asset
• If we identify assets that are mispriced, like those in the
graph, we want to deviate from the market weights to exploit
the mispricing, α
– This means selecting an optimal risky portfolio, P*, that is not equal to
the market portfolio, M
– By doing so, we can increase expected return of our portfolio without
similar increase in volatility of portfolio returns
– As such, we can improve our utility.
1 + w0A (1 − β A )
A
αA E (rM ) − rf
where, w0A =
σ ε2A σ M2
CALP*
E (ri )
P* CALM
A
M
rf
σ
Exploiting mispricing – one asset 14
Numerical example
• Suppose you (or your research department)
has estimated the following data:
E ( rM ) = 10% β A = 1.2
σ M = 25% E ( rA ) = 13%
rf = 2% σ A = 40%
∑α
j =1
j σ ε2 j
Factor models 21
Should assets be priced by the CAPM?
• The exact theoretical prediction of CAPM may be wrong
– An asset’s expected return may not be determined only by its beta
which is in turn determined by the covariance of its return with
market returns
Factor models 22
Factor models
• The CAPM expresses the expected return of any asset as a
function of its covariance with the market portfolio
• We sometimes refer to the market portfolio as a risk factor,
and to the CAPM β as a loading on that factor
• In principle, we could imagine other risk factors with which
assets covary (or “load”) and gain other required return as a
result
• The theoretical arguments underpinning this interpretation
differs from our CAPM arguments, but the interpretations of
the resulting models are very similar
– Most empirical factor models are not derived formally with clearly
specified assumptions and investors’ objective functions
– The theoretical foundation for such models, if any, is typically
Arbitrage Pricing Theory proposed by Stephen Ross
Factor models 23
Factor models
• A general factor model expresses the return of an asset as
follows:
~ ~
ri = λ0 + β i ,1 f1 + ... + β i ,k f k + ε~i
~
where, ~
fj is jth systematic factor, and β i, j is the loading of asset i on the jth
factor
Factor models 24
Fama-French-Carhart four-factor model
• We typically express each factor as some appropriate portfolio
• The factor model most commonly used in practice is Fama-
French-Carhart four-factor model that include four portfolio
returns as factors: market portfolio, small-minus-big (size)
portfolio (SMB), high-minus-low (book-to-market ratio)
portfolio (HML), momentum (winner minus loser) portfolio
(MMT or UMD)
[ ]
E (ri ) = r f + β iM E (rM ) − rf + β iSMB E (rSMB ) + β iHML E (rHML ) + β iMOM E (rMOM )
Factor models 25
Fama-French-Carhart four-factor model
• Each new factor portfolio is self financing, i.e. it takes long
(buy) and short (sell) positions that offset each other so that
the net portfolio cost is zero
– The Small-Minus-Big portfolio, SMB, consists of a long position in the
market’s 50 % smallest firms by market cap (small) and a short
position in the market’s 50 % largest firms (big)
– The High-Minus-Low portfolio, HML, consists of a long position in the
30 % of the market with the highest Book-to-Market ratios (value
stocks) and a short position in the 30 % of the market with the lowest
Book-to-Market ratios (growth stocks)
– The Momentum portfolio, MOM, takes a long position in the 30 % of
the market that had the highest returns the preceding year (winners)
and a short position in the 30 % of the market that had the lowest
returns the preceding year (losers)
– The loading of any particular asset to each factor depends on its
covariance with the factor
Factor models 26
Factor models in practice
• It turns out that an asset’s loadings on these factors tend to
predict expected returns, in violation of the CAPM
– The four-factor model is able to explain a big variation of asset returns
in the cross section
• This is an empirical result - we don’t know why these
portfolios should require higher expected returns
– We often hesitate to call these factors risk factors, as it is unclear what
risks are associated with them
– Despite its theoretical shortcomings, the four-factor model is often
used in practice instead of the CAPM due to its ability to summarize
expected returns of assets
– There is nothing to stop a new popular factor model to emerge, as
long as it is able to predict expected returns of assets well.
– In fact, Fama and French recently proposed a five-factor model
Factor models 27