A Consistent Input-Output Formulation of Shared Producer and Consumer Responsibility
A Consistent Input-Output Formulation of Shared Producer and Consumer Responsibility
KEY WORDS : Extended responsibility, producer, consumer, supply chain, environmental impact
Correspondence Address: Blanca Gallego, School of Physics, A28, The University of Sydney NSW 2006,
Australia. Email: [email protected]
different actors’ spheres of influence are not reflected’ (Spangenberg and Lorek, 2002,
p. 131).
On the other hand, a number of studies have highlighted that final consumption and
affluence, especially in the industrialised world, are the main drivers for the level and
growth of environmental pressure.1 Even though these studies provide a clear incentive
for complementing producer-focused environmental policy with some consideration for
consumption-related aspects, demand-side measures to environmental problems are
rarely exploited (Princen, 1999, p. 348).
When thinking about environmental impacts, producers and consumers, crucial
questions arise such as: who is responsible for what, or: how is the responsibility to be
shared, if at all? For example: should a firm have to improve the eco-friendliness of its
products, or is it up to the consumer to buy or not to buy? And further: should the firm
be held responsible for only the downstream consequences of the use of its products, or
– through its procurement decisions – also for the implications of its inputs from upstream
suppliers? And if so, how far should the downstream and upstream spheres of responsibil-
ity extend? Similar questions can be phrased for the problem of deciding who takes the
credit for successful abatement measures that involved producers and consumers.
As with many other allocative problems, a politically viable consensus probably lies
somewhere between producer and consumer responsibility. It is intuitively clear that the
responsibility for impacts associated with transactions in a productive system has to be
somehow divided between the supplier and the recipient of the respective delivered com-
modity. In order to assign responsibility to agents participating in these transactions, one
has to know the respective supply chains or inter-industry relations.
One method that deals with inter-industry relations is input – output analysis. This
technique is mostly applied in order to determine quantity and price impacts of exogen-
ously stated perturbations. It can also be used to re-trace the flow of past transactions,
and examine ex-post how, for example, inputs of resources or outputs of pollution were
associated with these transactions. In this view, input – output analysis is not used as a
causal (quantity or price) impact model, but rather as a descriptive tool. Therefore, in
this work, we apply input – output analysis in a descriptive, ex-post manner for distributing
responsibility for resource use and pollution caused during industrial production.
The novel idea in our work is that – having responsibility as a metric, rather than
quantities or monetary values – flows can be divided, and for each transaction be assigned
partly to the supplier, and partly to the recipient of the commodity. Accordingly, the
main part of this article is about how to describe this division and distribution with an
input –output model. Thus, our approach addresses the fact that ‘no scientifically
rigorous macro-level allocation of responsibilities for the impacts of consumption to
specific groups of actors . . . has been developed so far’ (Spangenberg and Lorek, 2002,
p. 128).
In the following sections, we first review the literature on the topic, and then define
terms and variables, and outline the basic equations of the relevant input – output
theory. We continue by describing a previous attempt for including both producers and
consumers into an input –output-type impact model. Highlighting the shortcomings of
this total flow model helps us to motivate our own approach. We illustrate how our
new formulation describes shared responsibility, discuss implications for practice, and
conclude. While our exposition of the topic is coined in terms of environmental
impacts, it is equally applicable to other types, such as social impacts.
Shared Producer and Consumer Responsibility 367
input –output models. A vector of coefficients f is defined, where each element fj represents
the impact (use, release, quantity) in terms of the production factor (in its own physical
units) associated with one unit of gross output xj of sector j.
Using the Leontief model, responsibility for factor impacts can be distributed across
final demand. The elements lij of the Leontief inverse can be understood as the amount
of gross output in industry i needed to satisfy final demand j. Final demanders are ulti-
mately responsible for the impacts fi lij that these outputs entailed during their production.
Using the Ghosh model, the responsibility for factor impacts can be distributed across
primary inputs. The elements lij of the Ghosh inverse can be interpreted as the amount
of gross output of industry j generated by a unit primary input into industry i. Primary
input providers are ultimately responsible for the impacts lij fj that these outputs entailed
to be produced.4
Accordingly, within generalised input – output analysis, total responsibility F for factor
impacts can be represented as the responsibility of producers, because of their productive
activities:
X X X (p)
F¼ F (p) ¼
i i i
f i x i ¼ f 0 x ¼ x0 f ¼ i
F i (1)
Note that final demanders and providers of primary inputs represent the same segment of
society, since the entirety of citizens occupies simultaneously (i) the roles of private con-
sumers, consumers of capital, consumers in the public service, and consumers of imported
goods, and (ii) those of a employees, providers of savings for investment, public servants,
and producers of exports. Hence, equations (2) and (3) describe the responsibility for
impacts of citizens in their non-corporate roles. Equation (1) describes the responsibility
of those citizens that are owners of the means of production.
Neither the Leontief nor the Ghosh model is capable of assigning partial responsibility
for factor impacts to various agents along a supply chain (which is the aim of our work).
They either deal with consumer/worker-investor citizens (and then with entire supply
chains) or with producers (and then only on-site). The Leontief model for example ‘is
an unsatisfactory basis to determine the influence of households as state and business
do not show up as influencing environmental impacts: their activities are considered to
be totally demand driven. De facto, however, they influence the environmental impact
370 B. Gallego & M. Lenzen
by their own decisions (how to produce and provide goods and services) as well as through
their influence on consumer decisions’ (Spangenberg and Lorek, 2002, p. 131). Ideally, a
responsibility measure should include all actors that play a role in production and
consumption.
An early attempt to develop an impact measure that deals with producers and consumers
in a supply-chain formulation is Szyrmer (1992); based on Jeong’s (1982; 1984) total flow
concept, which we review in the following section.
of the Leontief inverse L, normalised by the diagonal elements ljj . These coefficients
‘translate the change in the jth gross output into a change in the jth final demand . . .
[, and] the jth final demand into ith gross output’ (Szyrmer, 1992, p. 925). Note that
instead of the causal relationship x ¼ Ly linking final demand (cause) with total output
(effect) in the simple Leontief model, the total flow model assumes a particular (non-
causal) association between xj and yj . The element l1 jj determines the magnitude of
final demand yj that is necessary to absorb a total output xj . As a consequence, ‘the
total flow coefficients . . . do not express the changes in the economy created by Dxj ,
but those associated with Dxj ‘(Szyrmer, 1992, p. 928).
Szyrmer (1992, p. 928) correctly points out an important disadvantage of the total flow
concept, which is also at the heart of the argument pursued in this article:
A computational consequence of the non-causal nature of the total flow model is its
nonadditivity feature. As is well known, in the standard Leontief model, each unit of
final demand has its own ‘support network’, that is, its own direct and indirect inputs
that are perfectly separable from other inputs required by other final demand units.
Thus, the whole production system becomes a collection of mutually exclusive and
Shared Producer and Consumer Responsibility 371
A further disadvantage of the total flow concept is that the coefficients are highly depen-
dent on the diagonal entries ljj of the Leontief inverse, which in turn are somewhat arbi-
trary because they depend critically on the degree and nature of aggregation over
enterprises and products in the respective input –output table. In contrast, Leontief-type
inverse coefficients are independent of the magnitude of the diagonal entries of the
direct requirements matrix (for a proof see Weber, 1998).
Another approach seeking to describe the effect of producing entities on production
factors or total output is the hypothetical extraction method (Strassert, 1968), which oper-
ates by eliminating a sector (or a company) from an input – output table (by setting to zero
the corresponding row and column), and then examining the effect of this elimination on
multipliers. Hypothetical extractions have often been used for calculating linkages and
identifying ‘key sectors’ (see for example Dietzenbacher et al., 1993). Szyrmer and
Walker (1983) introduced the notion of total flow, using a hypothetical extraction
approach instead of equation (4). In fact, both methods are equivalent as first pointed
out by Szyrmer (1992), and proven in Appendix 1. As the total flow method, hypothetical
extractions are affected by non-additivity, since when adding up all extraction effects, each
transaction between two producers is eliminated twice.
Non-additivity was already recognised as a problem for determining indirect require-
ments for gross output by Milana (1985). Based on Miyazawa’s (1966) formalism for
partitioned input – output matrices, Milana and later Heimler (1991) constructed multi-
pliers for the gross output of an industry sector or a company by separating that sector
or company from the rest of the economy.7 Indexing a company with p and the remainder
of the economy with q,8 a partitioned formulation of the Leontief system is
xp a pp a0 pq xp yp
¼ þ (5)
xq aqp Aqq xq yq
The term aqp xp represents the company’s purchased inputs, and (I Aqq )1 aqp xp are the
total output requirements for producing these inputs. In equation (6), the company is effec-
tively treated as part of final demand, and feedback a0 pq from the company into the rest of
the economy is excluded. As with the total flow and hypothetical extraction methods, if the
above procedure was repeated for each company, intermediate transactions would appear
372 B. Gallego & M. Lenzen
multiply in different companies’ total output requirements, and thus lead to double
counting.9
Finally, Ferng’s (2003) production-benefit principle involves double counting for
similar reasons. Even his shared-responsibility formulation FA þ (1 2 F)B, where A
and B are allocations of responsibility according to the consumer- and producer-benefit
principles and 0 , F , 1, does not solve the problem, since double counting is always
inherent in the second term.
We have dealt with the total flow concept in more detail because it provides us with the
main motivation for our work: to find a responsibility measure that combines all actors in a
supply-chain context, but that is not affected by non-additivity/double counting. Since this
measure has to avoid assigning supply chains fully to more than one producing entity, our
formulation automatically leads to the feature of shared responsibility.
F ¼ Fe(p) ¼ fe xe (7)
The other possibility contemplated in the generalised Leontief model in equation (2), con-
sists of re-allocating these emissions as an upstream responsibility to final consumers. The
Primary inputs ve 0 vc
CO2 emissions Fe 0 0
responsibility for the power sector’s CO2 emissions would then be distributed among final
demands as:
where j is any sector the final demand yj of which requires some output from the electricity
sector e, in any layer of production. For example, the final consumers of cars yc would be
assigned the amount fe lec yc , which divides into fe aec yc for the car manufacturing industry’s
direct use of thermal electricity, as well as the amount fe aes asc yc from the use of electricity
in the steel industry s that provides its steel to car manufacturers. Since car manufacturers
are assumed to produce no CO2, there is no direct CO2 responsibility associated with
buying a car.
The producer responsibility approach (equation (7)) ignores using industries and final
consumers that are located downstream in the demand chain, and that ultimately drive pro-
duction, and – one could argue – should therefore be partly responsible. On the other
hand, the consumer responsibility approach (equation (8)) fails to consider industrial
sectors that are playing a part in the production process but that deliver only to other indus-
trial sectors and not into final demand. Returning to our simple example, even though
being a part of the industrial metabolism by driving electricity demand and therefore
emissions, the steel sector is not responsible for any amount of CO2, neither under produ-
cer nor under consumer responsibility.
Similar arguments hold in the case of downstream responsibility for waste.11 Under
producer responsibility only the car manufacturers are responsible:
(p)
F ¼ F c ¼ xc fc (9)
(c)
F j ¼ nj l jc fc (10)
where j is any sector with primary input nj driving some output from the car manufacturing
sector c into final demand, via any number of production layers. For example, working or
investing in a power plant (value ne ) would be assigned the responsibility nelec fc , which
divides into ne a ec fc for the power plant’s involvement in the car industry c, as well as
374 B. Gallego & M. Lenzen
ne a es a sc fc for the power plant’s involvement in the steel industry s that provides its steel to
car manufacturers.
Once again, in this simplified example, the producer responsibility approach (equation
(9)) ignores supplying industries, workers and investors who are located upstream in the
supply chain, and who are ultimately supporting and facilitating production, and – one
could argue – should therefore be partly responsible. On the other hand, the worker/inves-
tor responsibility approach (equation (10)) fails to account for sectors that form part of the
industrial metabolism but require no (or realistically, few) primary inputs. In fact, even
though enabling car manufacturing, the steel sector is not responsible for any waste at
all, neither under producer nor under worker/investor responsibility.
The responsibility for the remaining fraction a of the sector’s intermediate output is
assigned to its intermediate downstream users. Furthermore, the accountable output of a
given sector k includes the parts of xk associated with both the industry k as well as the
final consumers of sector k. Here, the final consumers are made responsible for a fraction
b of the final demand byk , while the rest of the accountable output is assigned to industry k.
In this way the responsibility for the output of sector k, is distributed as follows:
8
>
> byk ! assigned to final consumers of sector k
>þ
>
<
xk ¼ (1 b)yk þ (1 a)(xk yk ) ! assigned to industry k (12)
>
>
>þ
>
: P
a(xk yk ) ¼ a j akj xj ! assigned to sectors j downstream from k
The same responsibility distribution is applied to the gross output xj of each sector j. That
is, each industry j buying from k is made responsible for k’s impact due to a fraction
aakj ½(1 b)yj þ (1 a)(xj yj ) of xk ; the final consumers purchasing from k are
assigned the fraction aakj byj , and the rest is distributed amongst the sectors that purchase
from j:
8
>
> aakj byj ! assigned to final consumers of sector j
>
>
<þ
aakj xj ¼ aakj (1 b)yj þ (1 a)(xj yj ) ! assigned to industry j
>
>
>
> þ P
:
aakj a(xj yj ) ¼ a2 akj i a ji xi ! assigned to sectors i downstream from j
(13)
Shared Producer and Consumer Responsibility 375
The same distribution process repeats itself as we move down the demand chain. As a
result, the responsibility of a given sector i for the production of an upstream sector k is
given by
X
dki þ aaki þ a2 j
a kj a ji þ . . . y(i a) ¼ l(kia) y(i a) (14)
where dki ¼ 1 if k ¼ i and 0 otherwise,12 and where L(a) ¼ (I aA)1 . The quantity in
equation (14) includes the responsibility allocated to industry i,
Summing over all the supply chain, the upstream shared responsibility of a given sector
i is:
X
Fi(a) ¼ k
fk l(kia) y(i a) (17)
and the total upstream responsibility for production impacts F can be written as:
X X X
(a )
F¼ F (a ) ¼
i i i j
fj l(jia) y(i a) ¼ f 0 L y(a) (18)
The shape of this formulation is similar to that in equation (2), with L and y
replaced by
The parameters a (the producer responsibility share) and b (the consumer respon-
sibility share) are numbers between 0 and 1. At the limit a ¼ 0, where L(a) ¼ I
and y(a) ¼ x, we recover the producer responsibility formulation F ¼ f 0 x. Meanwhile,
at the other extreme where a ¼ 1, we have L(a) ¼ L and y(a) ¼ y. Allocating the
sector’s responsibility solely to the final consumers by setting b ¼ 1, we recover
the consumer responsibility formulation F ¼ f 0 Ly.
The introduction of the responsibility share a allows for two important properties: first,
the upstream responsibility for a given impact decreases by a factor a each time we move
downstream in the demand chain. This is an interesting feature since it seems logical to
assume that the further a receiving sector is located from the producer of the impact,
the less influence it has over that impact. A discussion on the choices of a and b, and
the implications for policy can be found in the next section.
Another important implication of the responsibility share a is that it allows for additi-
vity, that is the upstream responsibilities for a given impact are shared amongst all down-
stream agents in the demand chain without incurring double counting: the sum over all
376 B. Gallego & M. Lenzen
contributions of sectors k to the responsibility for the impact of an industry i is equal to the
total impact of that industry:
X
Fi(a) ¼ f l (a ) ½ y k
k i ik
þ (1 a)(xk yk )
X
¼ f l (a ) ½ x k
k i ik
a(xk yk )
X X
(a )
¼ k
f i l ik x k a j
a kj x j (20)
X (a )
X
¼ fl
k i ik j
½I aAkj xj
X
¼ f d x ¼ fi xi ¼ Fi(p)
j i ij j
Returning to our three-sector economy in Figure 1, and using the shared responsibility
framework, the CO2 emissions F ¼ fe xe from the generation of thermal electricity are
distributed amongst agents of the economy according to (see Figure 2)
The responsibility Fe(a) assigned to the electricity sector is proportional to its accountable
output:
Of this responsibility, bfe ye rests with the final consumers of electricity, and the remainder
with the power plant operators.
The CO2 responsibility Fs(a) assigned to the steel industry for its demand of electricity is
proportional to a fraction aaes of its accountable output. In the absence of final demand,
the accountable output is just a fraction (1a) of total output xs :
Note that, since ys ¼ 0, this sector is completely ignored in both the producer responsibil-
ity (a ¼ 0) as well as in the consumer responsibility (a ¼ 1) approach. Finally, the respon-
sibility Fc(a) assigned to the car manufacturing sector consists of two parts: one part is
associated with its direct purchase of electricity and is proportional to a fraction aaec of
its accountable output (see the second layer in Figure 2). The other part is associated
with the purchase of electricity by the steel sector, which then delivers steel to the car
industry. It is therefore proportional to a fraction a2 aes asc of the accountable output
(see the third layer in Figure 2):
Fc(a) ¼ fe l(eca) y(ca) ¼ fe aaec þ a2 aes asc yc (24)
Once again, portions b of the responsibility for final demands yc are assigned to final con-
sumers, with the remainder resting with the car manufacturers.
Thus, upstream responsibility is consistently and consecutively either allocated to
industries and consumers, or passed on downstream to the following layer of intermediate
demand. In our simplified example, this process stops after two rounds, with no intermedi-
ate demand left to be passed on, i.e. a2 fe aes asc (xc yc ) ¼ 0 in Figure 2. The total impact
fe xe has been exhaustively distributed to producing and consuming agents.
Of this quantity, workers-investors are made responsible for a fraction b of primary inputs
b vk , while the rest of the accountable input is assigned to industry k. The responsibility for
the remaining fraction a of the sector’s intermediate input is assigned to its intermediate
upstream suppliers.
378 B. Gallego & M. Lenzen
Applying this responsibility distribution to all the gross inputs throughout the supply
chain in a similar fashion as in the upstream formulation, we obtain that the responsibility
of a given sector i for (its association with) the production of a downstream sector k is
given by
(a )
v(i a )lik (26)
(a )
where L̄ ¼ (I a Ā)1 . The quantity in equation (26) includes the responsibility
allocated to industry i,
(a )
½(1 b )vi þ (1 a )(xi vi )lik (27)
(a )
b vi lik (28)
Summing over all the demand chain, the downstream shared responsibility of a given
sector i is:
X
(a )
F i ¼ n(i a ) l(a ) f (29)
k ik k
and the total downstream responsibility for production impacts F can be written as:
X X X
F¼
(a )
F ¼ v(a ) l(a ) fj ¼ (v(a ) )0 L̄(a ) f (30)
i i i i j ij
The shape of this formulation is similar to that in equation (3), with L̄ and v replaced by
(a )
L̄ ¼ (I a Ā)1 and v(a ) ¼ b v þ (1 b )v þ (1 a )(x v) (31)
Once again, the parameters a (the producer responsibility share) and b (the worker/
investor responsibility share) are numbers between 0 and 1. At the limit a ¼ 0, where
(a )
L̄ ¼ I and v(a ) ¼ x, we recover the producer responsibility formulation F ¼ x0 f. If a ¼
(a )
1 we have L̄ ¼ L̄ and v(a ) ¼ v. Allocating the sector’s responsibility solely to the
primary inputs by setting b ¼ 1, we recover the worker/investor responsibility formu-
lation F ¼ v0 L̄f.
As before, the downstream responsibility for a given impact decreases by a factor a
each time we move upstream in the supply chain, and it is shared amongst all upstream
agents in the supply chain without incurring double counting. Returning to our three-
sector economy in Figure 1, and using the shared responsibility framework, the waste
impact F ¼ xc fc resulting from manufacturing cars is distributed amongst agents of the
economy according to (see Figure 3)
(a )
F c ¼ ½vc þ (1 a )(xc vc ) fc (33)
(a )
F s ¼ (1 a )xs a a sc fc (34)
Note that, since ns ¼ 0, this sector is completely ignored in both the producer respon-
sibility (a ¼ 0) as well as in the worker/investor responsibility (a ¼ 1) approach.
(a )
Finally, the responsibility F e assigned to the electricity sector consists of two parts
One part is associated with its direct delivery to car manufacturers and is proportional
380 B. Gallego & M. Lenzen
to a fraction a a ec of its accountable input n(ea ) (see the second layer in Figure 3). The other
part is associated with the purchase of electricity by the steel sector, which then delivers
steel to the car industry. It is therefore proportional to a fraction a 2 a es a sc of the accoun-
table input n(ea ) (see the third layer in Figure 3):
(a )
F e ¼ ve a a ec þ a 2 a es a sc fc (35)
Once again, portions b of the responsibility for primary inputs ne are assigned to workers-
investors, with the remainder resting with power plant operators.
Thus, downstream responsibility is consistently and consecutively either allocated to
industries and workers-investors, or passed on upstream to the following layer of inter-
mediate supply. In our simplified example, this process stops after two rounds, with no
intermediate supply left to be passed on, i.e. (xe ne )a 2 a es a sc fc ¼ 0 in Figure 3. The
total impact xc fc has been exhaustively distributed to producing and working/investing
agents.
The formulations and additivity features of all frameworks dealt with in this article,
using both the Leontief and the Ghosh model, are summarised in Table 2.
Table 2. A summary of frameworks that can be used for assigning producer and consumer
responsibility
(a )
Similarly, the tensorial forms of the Ghosh inverse L and accountable input v(a ) in the
downstream shared responsibility framework are:
(a )
1 and v(a ) ¼ b #v þ (s b )#v þ ½(s a )#T0 s
L ¼ (I a #A) (38)
Note that, as in the case of constant responsibility shares, the tensorial formulation by con-
struction avoids the problem of double counting, and the proof of additivity in equation
(20) still holds.
investment (SRI) in dealing with corporate performance, and managing bodies of SRI
portfolios screen companies not only as to their own products, but also as to their upstream
and downstream involvement in harmful or unethical production practices. In the opposite
direction, companies themselves, especially those with a high proportion of purchased
inputs, are the drivers behind supply-chain thinking in terms of financial risk from
upstream and downstream environmental impacts.
Within CSR, the need for assigning responsibility for impacts in a standardised and
accepted way has been expressed recently.13 One problem within the Sustainability
Reporting Guidelines set out by the Global Reporting Initiative (2002) is how to define
appropriate system boundaries for sustainability assessments (Dey et al., 2002). In
particular,
Input –output analysis has been suggested as a suitable and standard technique to deal with
these boundary problems (Global Environmental Management Initiative, 2002; Suh et al.,
2004).
Using the technique outlined in the previous sections, a sustainability report for an
organisation could be compiled using equations (18) and (31), based on the organisation’s
financial expenditure and sales accounts (providing the data for intermediate demand x – y
and supply x – v, see equations (17) and (30)), sales to final demand y, and wage, tax and
capital bills v. Given that this information is readily available in financial accounting
systems, enumerating equations (18) and (31) should not pose unsurmountable barriers.
Unlike a total-flow-type method, using a shared responsibility formulation for producer
impacts such as developed in this work avoids double counting.
Extending responsibility beyond producers’ and consumers’ premises into the
supply-chain network leads to decision-makers not only targeting on-site impacts, but
also indirect impacts. Abatement would be achieved both through on-site measures and
procurement policies, and could be streamlined and prioritised using input –
output-related techniques such as structural path analysis (for a corporate example see
Lenzen et al., 2003). These techniques would assist in answering vital management
questions such as ‘Which of my suppliers has the greatest impact on my environmental
performance?’ [and] “How far down the supply chain do I go?’’ (CIPS, 1993, p. 19).
A problem is of course determining the values for a, b, a and b . It is possible for these
values to result from a legislative process, involving dialogue between the government,
consumers, organisations participating in various supply chains, and other stakeholders.
It is difficult to say whether there would be ‘optimal’ values. However, given that ‘differ-
ent (groups of) economic agents occupy overlapping spheres of social, economic and
Shared Producer and Consumer Responsibility 383
consistent and fair procedures – such as the one proposed in this work – in order to assess
corporate responsibility. One aspect of consistency and fairness will be that supply-chain
relations are appropriately represented in reporting procedures, to reflect the integration
and interdependence of producers and consumers in a modern economy, and hence
their shared responsibility for impacts that their activities entail.
Notes
1
Wolvén (1991); Mélanie et al. (1994); Parikh and Painuly (1994); Parikh (1996); Hamilton and Turton
(1999, 2002); Lenzen and Smith (2000); Wier et al. (2001).
2
See CIPS (1993); Barry (1996); Carillion (2001); Ford Motor Company of Australia Limited (2003,
pp. 9-10); Norwich Union Central Services (2003); Toyota Motor Corporation (2003, p. 5).
3
In the following, we refer to intermediate demand as between industries, while gross output – comprising
intermediate and final demand – is that of sectors. We will denote scalars in italic not bold, vectors in italic
and bold, and matrices in bold not italic.
4
Since the Ghosh model is usually interpreted as a price model, and not as a quantity model, a qualification
is needed as to how changes in the direct sales matrix A have to be interpreted. Let as assume an increase
(from one year to another) in the primary inputs into the industry i that generates an increase in the price of
final demands without any changes in physical flows. In our interpretation, more responsibility would be
assigned to primary inputs into i in the second year than in the first, on the basis of higher monetary inputs
utilised in downstream production. However, in the absence of input– output tables in physical units, there
is simply no other means of distributing this responsibility.
5
For the sake of simplicity, we will refer to these citizens in the following as ‘consumers’ and ‘workers-
investors’ (i.e. knowing that we have neglected the public sector and foreign countries).
6
Compare Miller and Blair’s (1985, p. 320) interpretation of reductions in primary inputs leading to
reductions in gross output.
7
See also Tiebout (1967) and Billings and Katz (1982) on the separation technique.
8
Instead of using one row and one column, a company can also be represented as an entire subsystem of
intra-company processes (see Farag, 1967; Polenske, 1997; Lin and Polenske, 1998; Albino et al.,
2002; Heijungs and Suh, 2002).
9
Milana (1985, p. 289) writes that ‘the sum of total output and primary input requirements for gross output
. . . leads to a double counting procedure because some indirect requirements of one industry are indirect
requirements of other industries which use part of that output of that industry as an intermediate input.’
Similarly, Heimler (1991, p. 263) acknowledges that ‘gross output of different industries cannot be
summed because of double counting of intermediate consumption.’
10
Since in our example, car manufacturing does not supply any other industry, there is no upstream respon-
sibility for any agent in terms of waste, only a sharing (b) between car manufacturers and buyers of cars.
11
Since in our example, the electricity industry has no intermediate suppliers, there are no downstream
impacts for any agent in terms of CO2 emissions, only a sharing (b) between power plant operators and
electricity consumers.
12
Note that dki is the element (k, i) of the identity matrix I.
13
The Global Reporting Initiative (2002, p. 4) states: ‘Inconsistent reporting approaches developed by
business, government, and civil society continue to appear. At the same time, many other organisations
wonder how best to engage in reporting. As diverse groups seek information, the multiplicity of infor-
mation requests gives rise to redundancy, inefficiency, and frustration.’ On the standardisation problem,
see also Olsthoorn et al. (2001).
References
ABARE (1999) Australian energy consumption and production, Research Report, Catalogue No: 99.4 Common-
wealth of Australia. (Canberra: Australian Bureau of Agricultural and Resource Economics).
ABS (1996) Labour force survey, Australia, Revisions to historical ANZSIC industry data, Information Paper,
Catalogue No: 6259.0 (Canberra: Australian Bureau of Statistics).
Shared Producer and Consumer Responsibility 385
Albino, V., Izzo, C. and Kühtz, S. (2002) Input–output models for the analysis of a local/global supply chain,
International Journal of Production Economics, 78, pp. 119– 131.
Barry, A. (1996) Buyers start to spread the ‘green’ message, Purchasing & Supply Management, February, p. 21.
Bastianoni, S., Pulselli, F.M. and Tiezzi, E. (2004) The problem of assigning responsibility for greenhouse gas
emissions, Ecological Economics, 49, pp. 253 –257.
Billings, R.B. and Katz, J.L. (1982) A technique to obtain accurate impact multipliers for individual firms by
means of existing input–output models, Environment and Planning A, 14, pp. 739–744.
Carillion (2001) Sustainable supply chain management, Sustainability Report (Wolverhampton: Carillion).
[Available at http://www.carillionplc.com/sustain2001/sustainable_supply_chain_managem.htm.]
Cerin, P. and Karlson, L. (2002) Business incentives for sustainability: a property rights approach, Ecological
Economics, 40, pp. 13 –22.
CIPS (1993) Green purchasing: are you buying into the environment?, Report, Catalogue No: 03097242 (Easton
on the Hill, Stamford, UK: Chartered Institute of Purchasing and Supply).
CIPS (1999) Ethical business practices in purchasing and supply, Positions on Practice (Easton on the Hill,
Stamford, UK: Chartered Institute of Purchasing and Supply). [Available at http://www.epolitix.com/
data/companies/images/Companies/Chartered-Institute-of-Purchasing-and-Supply/ethics.pdf.]
CIPS (2000) Environmental purchasing and supply management summary, Policies and Positions (Easton on
the Hill, Stamford, UK: Chartered Institute of Purchasing and Supply). [Available at http://www.epolitix.
com/data/companies/images/Companies/Chartered-Institute-of-Purchasing-and-Supply/environmental.
pdf.]
Danish EPA (1998) Denmark’s second national communication on climate change submitted under the
UN FCCC (Copenhagen: Danish Environmental Protection Agency). [Available at http://www.mst.dk/
homepage/.]
Dey, C., Lenzen, M., Foran, B. and Bilek, M. (2002) Addressing boundary issues in the Global Reporting
Initiative, Comments on the Draft 2002 Sustainability Reporting Guidelines (Sydney: The University
of Sydney, CSIRO Sustainable Ecosystems). [Available at http://www.globalreporting.org/feedback/
PublicComments2002/UniversityofSydneyCSIRO.pdf.]
Dietzenbacher, E. (1997) In vindication of the Ghosh model: a reinterpretation as a price model, Journal of
Regional Science, 37, pp. 629– 651.
Dietzenbacher, E., van der Linden, J.A. and Steenge, A.E. (1993) The regional extraction method: Applications to
the European Community, Economic Systems Research, 5, pp. 185–206.
EPA NSW (2003) Extended producer responsibility priority statement, Consultation Paper, Catalogue No: 2003/
10 (Sydney: Environment Protection Authority of New South Wales).
Farag, S.M. (1967) Input–Output Analysis: Applications to Business and Accounting (Urbana: Center for
International Education and Research in Accounting).
Ferng, J.-J. (2003) Allocating the responsibility of CO2 over-emissions from the perspectives of benefit principle
and ecological deficit, Ecological Economics, 46, pp. 121–141.
Ford Motor Company of Australia Limited (2003) Policies and organisation, Broadmeadows Public Environment
Report 2002/2003 (Campbellfield, Australia: Ford Motor Company of Australia Limited). [Available at
www.ford.com.au/resources/pdf/environment/7.pdf.]
Ghosh, A. (1958) Input–output approach in an allocation system, Economica, 25, pp. 58 –64.
Global Environmental Management Initiative (2002) How to Tally Emissions (Washington, DC: Global
Environmental Management Initiative).
Global Reporting Initiative (2002) Sustainability Reporting Guidelines (Boston: Global Reporting Initiative).
Hamilton, C. and Turton, H. (1999) Population policy and environmental degradation: sources and trends in
greenhouse gas emissions, People and Place, 7, pp. 42–62.
Hamilton, C. and Turton, H. (2002) Determinants of emissions growth in OECD countries, Energy Policy, 30,
pp. 63 –71.
Heijungs, R. and Suh, S. (2002) The Computational Structure of Life Cycle Assessment (Dordrecht: Kluwer).
Heimler, A. (1991) Linkages and vertical integration in the Chinese economy, Review of Economics and
Statistics, 73, pp. 261 –267.
Imura, H. and Moriguchi, Y. (1995). Economic interdependence and eco–balance: accounting for the flow of
environmental loads associated with trade, in: S. Murai (Ed.) Toward Global Planning of Sustainable
Use of the Earth, pp. 189 –208 (Amsterdam: Elsevier).
Jeong, K. (1982) Direct and indirect requirements: a correct economic interpretation of the Hawkins–Simons
conditions, Journal of Macreconomics, 4, pp. 349–356.
386 B. Gallego & M. Lenzen
Jeong, K. (1984) The relation between different notions of direct and indirect input requirements, Journal of
Macreconomics, 6, pp. 473–476.
Korhonen, J. (2002) Two paths to industrial ecology: applying the product-based and geographical approaches,
Journal of Environmental Planning and Management, 45, pp. 39–57.
Lenzen, M., Lundie, S., Bransgrove, G., Charet, L. and Sack, F. (2003) Assessing the ecological footprint of a
large metropolitan water supplier – lessons for water management and planning towards sustainability,
Journal of Environmental Planning and Management, 46, pp. 113– 141.
Lenzen, M., Pade, L.-L. and Munksgaard, J. (2004) CO2 multipliers in multi-region input–output models,
Economic Systems Research, 16, pp. 391 –412.
Lenzen, M. and Smith, S. (2000) Teaching responsibility for climate change: three neglected issues, Australian
Journal of Environmental Education, 15/16, pp. 69 –78.
Lin, X. and Polenske, K.R. (1998) Input–output modeling of production processes for business management,
Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 9, pp. 205–226.
Lloyd, M. (1994) How green are my suppliers? – Buying environmental risk, Purchasing & Supply Management,
October, p. 36.
Maxie, E. (1994) Supplier performance and the environment. Paper at the IEEE International Symposium on
Electronics & the Environment, San Francisco.
Mélanie, J., Phillips, B. and Tormey, B. (1994) An international comparison of factors affecting carbon dioxide
emissions, Australian Commodities, 1, pp. 468–483.
Milana, C. (1985) Direct and indirect requirements for gross output in input–output systems, Metroeconomica,
37, pp. 283–292.
Miller, R.E. and Blair, P.D. (1985) Input–Output Analysis: Foundations and Extensions (Englewood Cliffs, NJ:
Prentice-Hall).
Miyazawa, K. (1966) Internal and external matrix multipliers in the input–output model, Hitotsubashi Journal of
Economics, 7, pp. 38– 55.
Munksgaard, J. and Pedersen, K.A. (2000) CO2 accounts for open economies: producer or consumer responsibil-
ity?, Energy Policy, 29, pp. 327–334.
Norwich Union Central Services (2003) Suppliers, Corporate Social Responsibility Report (Norwich: Norwich
Union Central Services). [Available at http://www.aviva.com/responsibility/2003report/reports/
nu_cent_suppliers.htm.]
OECD (2001) Extended Producer Responsibility: A Guidance Manual for Governments (Paris: Organisation for
Economic Co-operation and Development).
Olsthoorn, X., Tyteca, D., Wehrmeyer, W. and Wagner, M. (2001) Environmental indicators for business:
a review of the literature and standardisation methods, Journal of Cleaner Production, 9, pp.
453– 463.
Parikh, J. (1996) Consumption patterns: the driving force of environmental stress, in: P.H. May and R. Serôa da
Motta (Eds) Pricing the Planet, pp. 39– 48 (New York: Columbia University Press).
Parikh, J.K. and Painuly, J.P. (1994) Population, consumption patterns and climate change: a socioeconomic
perspective from the south, Ambio, 23, pp. 434 –437.
Polenske, K.R. (1997) Linked system of enterprise, regional and national input–output accounts for policy
analysis, in: M. Chatterji (Ed.) Regional Science: Perspectives for the Future, pp. 26–42 (Basingstoke,
UK: Macmillan).
Princen, T. (1999) Consumption and environment: some conceptual issues, Ecological Economics, 31, pp.
347– 363.
Proops, J.L.R., Faber, M. and Wagenhals, G. (1993) Reducing CO2 Emissions (Berlin: Springer-Verlag).
Spangenberg, J.H. and Lorek, S. (2002) Environmentally sustainable household consumption: from aggregate
environmental pressures to priority fields of action, Ecological Economics, 43, pp. 127 –140.
Strassert, G. (1968) Zur Bestimmung strategischer Sektoren mit Hilfe von Input–Output Tabellen, Jahrbücher
für Nationalökonomie und Statistik, 182, pp. 211–215.
Subak, S. (1995) Methane embodied in the international trade of commodities, Global Environmental Change, 5,
pp. 433 –446.
Suh, S., Lenzen, M., Treloar, G.J., Hondo, H., Horvath, A., Huppes, G., Jolliet, O., Klann, U., Krewitt, W.,
Moriguchi, Y., Munksgaard, J. and Norris, G. (2004) System boundary selection in life–cycle inventories,
Environmental Science & Technology, 38, pp. 657–664.
Szyrmer, J.M. (1992) Input–output coefficients and multipliers from a total-flow perspective, Environment and
Planning A, 24, pp. 921–937.
Shared Producer and Consumer Responsibility 387
Szyrmer, J.M. and Walker, R.T. (1983) Interregional total flow: a concept and application to a U.S. input–output
model, Review of Regional Studies, 13, pp. 12–21.
Task Force on National Greenhouse Gas Inventories (1996) Revised 1996 IPCC Guidelines for National Green-
house Gas Inventories – Reporting Instructions, Volume 1 (Tokyo: Institute for Global Environmental
Strategies, Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change – IPCC National Greenhouse Gas Inventories
Programme). [Available at http://www.ipcc-nggip.iges.or.jp/public/gl/invs4.htm.]
Tiebout, C.M. (1967) Input–output and the firm: a technique for using national and regional tables, Review of
Economics and Statistics, 49, pp. 260– 262.
Toyota Motor Corporation (2003) 2003 Environmental Report (Port Melbourne: Toyota Motor Corporation).
[Available at http://environment.toyota.com.au/TWP/Upload/Media/144.pdf.]
Weber, C. (1998) Zerlegung kumulierter Energieaufwendungen als Instrument der umweltorientierten Verflech-
tungsanalyse, Jahrbücher für Nationalökonomie und Statistik, 217, pp. 273–291.
Wier, M., Lenzen, M., Munksgaard, J. and Smed, S. (2001) Environmental effects of household consumption
pattern and lifestyle, Economic Systems Research, 13, pp. 259 –274.
Wolvén, L.-E. (1991) Life–styles and energy consumption, Energy, 16, pp. 959–963.
WBCSD (2002) Sustainable development reporting: striking the balance, Report (Conches–Geneva: World
Business Council on Sustainable Development). [Available at http://www.wbcsd.ch/DocRoot/
GGFpsq8dGngT5K56sAur/20030106_sdrepot.pdf.]
WBCSD and WRI, World Resources Institute (2001) The greenhouse gas protocol, Report (Conches–Geneva:
World Business Council on Sustainable Development). [Available at http://www.ghgprotocol.org/stan
dard/ghg.pdf, http://www.ghgprotocol.org/.]
Wyckoff, A.W. and Roop, J.M. (1994) The embodiment of carbon in imports of manufactured products –
Implications for international agreements on greenhouse gas emissions, Energy Policy, 22, pp. 187 –194.
Appendix 1: Equivalence between the hypothetical extraction and the total flow
formulations
In the following, the hypothetical extraction and the total flow formulations are shown to
be equivalent for the Leontief model, but equivalence applies equally to the Ghosh model.
In the total flow method, the requirement of gross output xk of a given industry k associated
with the gross output of another sector j is given by:
lkj
TFkj ¼ xj (A1)
l jj
Without loss of generality, we can partition the direct requirements matrix A into nine
blocks in order to separate row and column j from the rest of the matrix as indicated in
equation (A2). The diagonal blocks of this partitioned matrix are square matrices of
dimensions (j 1) (j 1), 1 1 and (n j) (n j), where n represents the number
of industrial sectors.
1!(j1) j (jþ1)!n
z}|{ z}|{ z}|{
2 3
A(11) A(12) A(13)
6 (21) 7
A ¼ 4A A(22) A(23) 5 (A2)
A(31) A(32) A(33)
388 B. Gallego & M. Lenzen
Using basic matrix algebra, we can compute the inverse of the partitioned matrix (I A):
(I A)1 ¼
2 1 1 1 1 1
3
D(123) C(113) C(123) D(231) C(112) C(132) D(312) (A3)
6 1 1 1 1 1 7
4 C(223) C(213) D(123) D(231) C(221) C(231) D(312) 5
1 1 1 1 1
C(332) C(312) D(123) C(331) C(321) D(231) D(312)
where:
1
C(pqr) ¼ (I A)(pq) (I A)(pr) (I A)(rr) (I A)(rq)
1
(A4)
D(pqr) ¼ C(ppr) C(pqr) C(qqr) C(qpr)
with p, q and r representing the indices 1, 2 or 3, and (I A)(pq) representing the block
( pq) of (I A). Expression (A3) can be validated by proving that
(I A)(I A)1 ¼ I, which implies
1 1 1
½(I A)(pp) þ A(pq) C(qqr) C(qpr) þ A(pr) C(rrq) C(rpq) D(pqr) ¼I
1 1 1
(A5)
½A(qp) (I A)(qq) C(qqr) C(qpr) þ A(qr) C(rrq) C(rpq) D(pqr) ¼0
for any p, q = p and r = p, q and with 0 being a matrix with all elements being zero. In
order to prove equation (A5), the following identities will be used:
1 1
C(rrq) ¼ {(I A)(rr) A(rq) (I A)(qq) A(qr) }1
1 1
¼ {A(rq) (I A)(qq) ½(I A)(qq) A(rq) (I A)(rr) A(qr) }1
1
¼ {A(rq) (I A)(qq)
1 1
½(I A)(qq) A(qr) (I A)(rr) A(rq) A(rq) (I A)(rr) }1
1 1
¼ {A(rq) (I A)(qq) C(qqr) A(rq) (I A)(rr) }1
1 1 1
¼ (I A)(rr) A(rq) C(qqr) (I A)(qq) A(rq) (A6)
Shared Producer and Consumer Responsibility 389
1
C(rpq) ¼ ½A(rp) þ A(rq) (I A)(qq) A(qp)
1 1
¼ A(rq) (I A)(qq) ½(I A)(qq) A(rq) A(rp) þ A(qp)
1 1
¼ A(rq) (I A)(qq) ½{(I A)(qq) A(qr) (I A)(rr) A(rq)
1 1
þ A(qr) (I A)(rr) A(rq) }A(rq) A(rp) þ A(qp)
1 1 1
¼ A(rq) (I A)(qq) ½{(I A)(qq) A(qr) (I A)(rr) A(rq) }A(rq) A(rp)
1
þ {A(qp) þ A(qr) (I A)(rr) A(rp) }
1 1
¼ A(rq) (I A)(qq) ½C(qqr) A(rq) A(rp) C(qpr) (A7)
1
Substituting C(rrq) and C(rpq) by expressions (A6) and (A7) in equations (A5) we
obtain
1
½(I A)(pp) þ A(pq) C(qqr) C(qpr)
1 1 1 1
þA(pr) {(I A)(rr) A(rp) þ (I A)(rr) A(rq) C(qqr) C(qpr) }D(pqr)
1 1 1
¼ ½C(ppr) C(pqr) C(qqr) C(qpr) D(pqr) ¼ D(pqr) D(pqr) ¼I
(A8)
1
½A(qp) (I A)(qq) C(qqr) C(qpr)
1 1 1 1
þA(qr) {(I A)(rr) A(rp) þ (I A)(rr) A(rq) C(qqr) C(qpr) }D(pqr)
1 1 1
¼ ½C(qpr) C(qqr) C(qqr) C(qpr) D(pqr) ¼ ½C(qpr) C(qpr) D(pqr) ¼0
8 (113) (123)
lkj < C C x for k , j
kj j
TFkj ¼ xj ¼ xj for k ¼ j (A9)
l jj : C(331) C(321) x for k . j
kj j
On the other hand, in the hypothetical extraction method, the fraction of gross output xk of
a given industry k assigned to an industrial sector j is given by
HEkj ¼ xk x½j
k (A10)
where x½j
k is the hypothetical gross output of sector k in an economy without sector j.
Sector j is hypothetically extracted by zeroing row and column j in the direct require-
ments matrix, forming A½j , and by zeroing the sector’s final demand yj ¼ 0. In the
390 B. Gallego & M. Lenzen
X XX
x½j
k (k=j) ¼ (I A½j )1
ki yi ¼ (I A½j )1
ki (I A)il xl : (A11)
i i l
We can re-express matrix A as the sum of A½j plus a matrix A½j whose only non-zero
elements are the direct requirement coefficients in row and column j. Equation (A11)
then becomes
XX XX
x½j
k (k=j) ¼ (I A½j )1 ½j
ki (I A )il xl (I A½j )1 ½j
ki ail xl
i l i l
Using the same partitioning as in equation (A2), the inverse of I A½j can be expressed as
the partitioned matrix
2 1 1 3
C(113) 0 C(113) A(13) (I A(33) )1
(I A½j )1 ¼ 4 0 1 0 5 (A14)
1
(331)1
C(331) A(31) (I A(11) )1 0 C
Here, 0 represents a matrix with all elements being zero. It can be easily shown that
(I A½j )1 (I A½j ) ¼ I, since:
1 1 1
C(ppr) ½(I A)(pp) A(pr) (I A)(rr) A(rp) ¼ C(ppr) C(ppr) ¼ I
1 1 1
(A15)
C(ppr) ½A(pr) þ A(pr) (I A)(rr) (I A)(rr) ¼ C(ppr) ½A(pr) þ A(pr) ¼ 0
Shared Producer and Consumer Responsibility 391
(A17)
Comparing equations (A9) and (A17) we can conclude that HEkj ¼ TFkj .