0306 Glae
0306 Glae
Edward L. Glaeser is a professor of economics at Harvard University and The authors are grateful to Albert Saiz; Jesse Shapiro; and their discussant,
a faculty research fellow at the National Bureau of Economic Research; Brendan O’Flaherty, for comments. The views expressed are those of the
Joseph Gyourko is the Martin Bucksbaum Professor of Real Estate and Finance authors and do not necessarily reflect the position of the Federal Reserve Bank
at the University of Pennsylvania’s Wharton School. of New York or the Federal Reserve System.
<[email protected]>
<[email protected]>
Chart 1
House Prices/Construction Costs over Time
Central Cities
1989
1.0
Anaheim
0.7
Phoenix
0.6
Greensboro Denver
Dallas Sacramento
Philadelphia Jacksonville
0.5
San Antonio New Orleans Seattle
Austin
Baltimore Tampa Tucson
Fort Worth
0.4
Little Rock
El Paso Tulsa
Oklahoma City
0.3
Las Vegas
Chicago
Minneapolis Wichita
0.2
Columbus
Toledo
Omaha
0.1
Kansas City Milwaukee
Detroit
0
0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1.0
1999
Note: The x-axis (y-axis) denotes the share of homes in central cities with prices that are more than 40 percent above construction costs in the 1999
(1989) American Housing Survey.
Chart 2
House Prices/Construction Costs over Time
Suburban Areas
1989 Oxnard
1.0
San Francisco
Newark
San Diego Anaheim
0.9 Boston
Riverside
New York City Los Angeles
Sacramento
0.8
Philadelphia
Fort Lauderdale
Orlando Miami Seattle
0.7
Atlanta Chicago
Baltimore Phoenix
Rochester Albany
0.6
Fort Worth Dallas
Tampa
Birmingham
New Orleans
0.5
Columbus
0.4
Milwaukee
St. Louis
0.3
Minneapolis Cincinnati
Houston Detroit
Kansas City Cleveland Salt Lake City
0.2
Pittsburgh
0.1
0
0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1.0
1999
Note: The x-axis (y-axis) denotes the share of homes in suburban areas with prices that are more than 40 percent above construction costs in the 1999
(1989) American Housing Survey.
Albuquerque 0.02 0.82 0.03 0.83 Albany 0.06 0.63 0.00 0.40
Anaheim 0.00 1.00 0.00 0.93 Anaheim 0.02 0.96 0.03 0.96
Austin 0.00 0.46 0.06 0.71 Atlanta 0.03 0.67 0.06 0.58
Baltimore 0.18 0.41 0.30 0.27 Baltimore 0.05 0.66 0.01 0.61
Chicago 0.20 0.28 0.16 0.44 Birmingham 0.10 0.56 0.12 0.53
Columbus 0.33 0.18 0.12 0.29 Boston 0.01 0.87 0.02 0.86
Dallas 0.06 0.56 0.13 0.47 Chicago 0.06 0.67 0.05 0.74
Denver 0.04 0.60 0.08 0.86 Cincinnati 0.10 0.29 0.10 0.47
Detroit 0.85 0.05 0.54 0.20 Cleveland 0.15 0.23 0.05 0.58
El Paso 0.05 0.34 0.02 0.28 Columbus 0.12 0.47 0.03 0.61
Fort Worth 0.12 0.40 0.26 0.29 Dallas 0.03 0.58 0.06 0.52
Greensboro 0.13 0.59 0.00 0.69 Detroit 0.24 0.26 0.08 0.58
Houston 0.25 0.40 0.25 0.27 Fort
Indianapolis 0.25 0.22 0.24 0.22 Lauderdale 0.00 0.76 0.00 0.85
Jacksonville 0.08 0.55 0.11 0.43 Fort Worth 0.09 0.59 0.09 0.49
Kansas City 0.33 0.09 0.40 0.12 Houston 0.23 0.24 0.08 0.31
Las Vegas 0.00 0.29 0.03 0.45 Kansas City 0.15 0.22 0.05 0.33
Little Rock 0.09 0.36 0.08 0.40 Los Angeles 0.04 0.91 0.04 0.89
Los Angeles 0.02 0.93 0.04 0.89 Miami 0.05 0.72 0.00 0.73
Milwaukee 0.32 0.10 0.27 0.22 Milwaukee 0.05 0.39 0.08 0.53
Minneapolis 0.22 0.21 0.20 0.30 Minneapolis 0.08 0.29 0.05 0.43
Nashville- Newark 0.01 0.96 0.01 0.72
Davidson 0.02 0.69 0.05 0.56 New Orleans 0.10 0.53 0.06 0.61
New Orleans 0.02 0.49 0.03 0.57 New York City 0.03 0.85 0.09 0.78
New York City 0.04 0.81 0.11 0.56 Orlando 0.03 0.70 0.04 0.61
Norfolk 0.01 0.87 0.02 0.66 Oxnard 0.00 1.00 0.04 0.93
Oklahoma Philadelphia 0.03 0.78 0.11 0.47
City 0.13 0.30 0.16 0.41 Phoenix 0.02 0.65 0.00 0.76
Omaha 0.21 0.15 0.30 0.21 Pittsburgh 0.23 0.19 0.25 0.21
Philadelphia 0.10 0.52 0.60 0.16 Riverside 0.05 0.87 0.02 0.76
Phoenix 0.02 0.69 0.05 0.65 Rochester 0.01 0.63 0.09 0.28
Raleigh 0.06 0.81 0.02 0.81 Sacramento 0.03 0.83 0.05 0.72
Sacramento 0.00 0.55 0.03 0.72 Salt Lake City 0.10 0.22 0.02 0.86
San Antonio 0.12 0.48 0.30 0.26 San Diego 0.04 0.92 0.05 0.88
San Diego 0.07 0.88 0.03 0.93 San Francisco 0.01 0.98 0.02 0.97
San Francisco 0.00 0.97 0.04 0.96 Seattle 0.02 0.72 0.01 0.90
Seattle 0.06 0.49 0.02 0.86 St. Louis 0.11 0.34 0.21 0.34
Tampa 0.09 0.43 0.13 0.49 Tampa 0.03 0.57 0.05 0.66
Toledo 0.27 0.16 0.40 0.23
Tucson 0.06 0.43 0.04 0.61
Tulsa 0.07 0.36 0.08 0.38
Wichita 0.18 0.21 0.13 0.48
Table 5
Density and the Distribution of House Prices in Cities, 1990
Dependent Variable
Fraction of Units
Valued at or above
Log Land Area Log Land Area Log Land Area 140 Percent Log Land Area Log Land Area
per Household per Household per Household of Construction Costs per Household per Householda
Fraction of units valued at or above -0.510 -0.576 1.177
140 percent of construction costs (0.451) (0.507) (0.880)
Notes: Standard errors are in parentheses. Density is defined as the log of the ratio of square miles of land in the city divided by the number of households.
a
Two-stage least squares: Mean January temperature as instrument.
Kansas City
-6.5 Fort Worth
El Paso
Little Rock
Indianapolis Austin
Tulsa Greensboro
San Antonio Phoenix Raleigh
-7.0 Tucson
Wichita Tampa New Orleans
Las Vegas
Houston Dallas Albuquerque San Diego
Omaha Columbus Denver
Toledo Sacramento
-7.5
Norfolk Anaheim
Milwaukee
Los Angeles
Detroit Seattle
-8.0
Minneapolis
Baltimore
Chicago
-8.5
Philadelphia
San Francisco
-9.0
New York City
-9.5
0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1.0
Central cities, 1989
Note: The x-axis denotes the share of homes in central cities with prices that are more than 40 percent above construction costs in the 1989 American
Housing Survey.
Table 6
Zoning Regulations and the Distribution of House Prices
Dependent Variable
Fraction of Units Valued at or above Fraction of Units Valued at or above T/L from Table 4
140 Percent of Construction Costs 140 Percent of Construction Costs (Implied Zoning Tax)
Time to permit issuance for rezoning request 0.150 0.112 6.796
(0.051) (0.044) (3.048)
Log median family income, 1989 0.260
(0.255)
Percentage population growth, 1980-90 1.080
(0.411)
Intercept 0.111 -2.512 -3.527
(0.120) (2.634) (7.732)
2
R 0.16 0.40 0.15
Number of observations 40 40 22
Note: The independent zoning variable is a categorical measure of time lag between the application for rezoning and the issuance of a building permit
for development of a modest size, single-family subdivision.
A number of adjustments are made to the underlying house are estimated using the AHS. More specifically, we regress
price data in the comparison of prices and construction costs. house value per square foot (scaled down by the Goodman and
These include imputation of the square footage of living area Ittner [1992] correction) in the relevant year on a series of age
for observations from the Integrated Public Use Microdata controls and metropolitan area dummies. The age data are in
Series for the 1980 and 1990 census years. However, because interval form so that we can tell if a house is zero to five years
the results reported in this paper do not include census data, we old, six to ten years old, eleven to twenty-five years old, twenty-
omit the description of that imputation. See Glaeser and five to thirty-six years old, and more than forty-five years old.
Gyourko (2001) for those details. The coefficients on the age controls are each negative, as
Two adjustments have been made to the American Housing expected, and represent the extent to which houses of different
Survey (AHS) house price data to account for the depreciation ages have depreciated in value on a per-square-foot basis.
that occurs on older homes and to account for the fact that Finally, we note that our procedure effectively assumes that
research shows that owners tend to overestimate the value of units with a basement in the AHS have unfinished basements,
their homes. The remainder of this appendix provides the so that we underestimate construction costs for units with
details. finished basements. Having a basement adds materially to
As noted, one adjustment takes into account the fact that construction costs, according to data from R.S. Means
research shows that owners tend to overestimate the value of Company. Depending on the size of the unit, those with
their homes. Following the survey and recent estimation by unfinished basements have about 10 percent higher
Goodman and Ittner (1992), we presume that owners typically construction costs. Units with finished basements have up to
overvalue their homes by 6 percent.19 30 percent higher construction costs, again depending on the
Empirically, the most important adjustment takes into size of the unit. After these adjustments have been made, house
account the fact that the vast majority of homes are not new value is then compared with construction costs to produce the
and have experienced real depreciation. Depreciation factors distributions reported in our paper.
1. This is not to say that housing vouchers might not be a sensible part quantity of land is correlated with price and (omitted) amenities. It is
of an antipoverty program. However, if housing is not expensive, then easy to construct examples in which the bias goes in opposite
policies should be thought of as a response to poverty and not a directions. For example, land undoubtedly costs different amounts in
response to a housing affordability crisis. different parts of a given metropolitan area. Although our hedonic
model includes a control for whether the observation is located within
2. Goodman and Ittner (1992) document that self-reported values tend the central city of an area, this may only imperfectly capture a
to be about 7 percent higher than true sale prices. location-specific amenity that reflects, say, distance from a key
employment node. Thus, people could be buying bigger lots in those
3. Another relevant issue is change over time. The census reports a parts of the metropolitan area with lower costs, and by not being able
significant (15 percent) increase in the median value of a home over to control for this fully, our hedonic land price estimates will be biased
the 1990s. However, when we look at repeat-sales indices, which downward.
control for housing quality, we see much less of an increase over the That said, it is not at all clear that the net bias will be in that
1990s. direction. We find it at least equally plausible that richer households,
who tend to have larger lots, end up congregating in higher amenity
4. Two publications are particularly relevant for greater detail on the (and higher price) areas. In this case, our estimated hedonic price of
underlying data: R. S. Means Company’s Residential Cost Data, 19th land would be biased upward. Although we cannot be certain what the
ed., and Square Foot Costs, 21st ed. net bias is, we find it highly unlikely that our estimates are so severely
skewed downward that bias could account for the huge differential
5. See R. S. Means Company (2002). reported between land prices on the intensive and extensive margins.
Our estimates would have to be off by an order of magnitude for that
6. The actual computation is more complicated, as adjustments are possibility to be relevant.
made to correct for depreciation, inflation, the fact that owners tend
to overestimate the value of their homes, and regional variation in the 12. The coefficients are precisely estimated in the underlying
presence of basements. See the appendix for details. We also regressions and are available upon request. Because the hedonic land
performed the analysis using the 1991 AHS; the results are virtually price arising from the linear model is virtually uncorrelated with mean
unchanged from 1989’s results. house price, the analogous impact is near zero for that land price
series.
7. The Philadelphia numbers for 1989 are not typos. They reflect a
small sample bias associated with the number of units with basements. 13. Using population per square mile yields similar results.
This is a statistical oddity that does not show up in other samples,
whether in the AHS or decennial censuses. 14. There is a statistically and economically significant positive
relationship between mean January temperature and median house
8. There are only ninety-six observations in the Baltimore price. Those results are not reported here, but are available from the
metropolitan area, which is the smallest number across all cities. authors upon request.
Visual inspection of the findings found sensible results for most
traits when the number of observations was at or above 100. 15. We use the price series from the nonlinear hedonic in the
underlying regression. Only the regression involving the construction-
9. There are 43,560 square feet in an acre of land. based land prices (column 3 of Table 4) yields statistically significant
results at conventional levels.
10. The estimate from the linear specification is much lower, but
logging materially improves the overall hedonic in the case of 16. Other measures in the database include the analogue to this
San Francisco. rezoning question, except that the permit length time applies to a
completely new subdivision that does not require rezoning. We
11. This ratio obviously is sensitive to biases in our hedonic estimates. examined this and other variables and found correlation patterns
We need to be concerned especially about the possibility that the similar to those presented below.
17. Adding region dummies to the specification eliminates any 19. This effect turns out to be relatively minor in terms of its
significant positive correlation between this zoning control and the quantitative impact on the results.
fraction of expensive housing in the area.
Alonso, William. 1964. Location and Land Use: Toward a Roback, Jennifer. 1982. “Wages, Rents, and the Quality of Life.”
General Theory of Land Rent. Cambridge: Harvard University Journal of Political Economy 90, no. 6 (December): 1257-78.
Press.
Rosen, Sherwin. 1979. “Wage-Based Indices of Urban Quality of Life.”
Fischel, William. 1992. “Property Taxation and the Tiebout Model: In Mahlon R. Straszheim and Peter M. Mieszkowski, eds.,
Evidence from the Benefit View of Zoning and Voting.” Journal Current Issues in Urban Economics. Baltimore: Johns
of Economic Literature 30, no. 1 (March): 171-7. Hopkins University Press.
Glaeser, Edward L., and Joseph Gyourko. 2001. “Urban Decline and R. S. Means Company. 2000a. Residential Cost Data. 19th ed.
Durable Housing.” NBER Working Paper no. 8598, November. Kingston, Mass.
Goodman, John L., and J. B. Ittner. 1992. “The Accuracy of Home ———. 2000b. Square Foot Costs. 21st ed. Kingston, Mass.
Owners’ Estimates of House Value.” Journal of Housing
Economics 2, no. 1 (March): 339-57. ———. 2002. Building Construction Cost Data. 60th ed.
Kingston, Mass.
Gyourko, Joseph, and Joseph Tracy. 1991. “The Structure of Local
Public Finance and the Quality of Life.” Journal of Political University of Minnesota. 1997. “Integrated Public Use Microdata
Economy 99, no. 4 (August): 774-806. Series: Version 2.0.” Historical Census Projects, Minneapolis,
1990 Census Year.
Muth, Richard F. 1969. Cities and Housing: The Spatial Pattern
of Urban Residential Land Use. Chicago: University of U.S. Census Bureau. Various years. “American Housing Survey.”
Chicago Press. Data tapes.
The views expressed are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the position of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York
or the Federal Reserve System. The Federal Reserve Bank of New York provides no warranty, express or implied, as to the
accuracy, timeliness, completeness, merchantability, or fitness for any particular purpose of any information contained in
documents produced and provided by the Federal Reserve Bank of New York in any form or manner whatsoever.