Transforming Taiwan's Economic Structure in The 20th Century (Tun-Jen, 2001)
Transforming Taiwan's Economic Structure in The 20th Century (Tun-Jen, 2001)
Transforming Taiwan's Economic Structure in The 20th Century (Tun-Jen, 2001)
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted
digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about
JSTOR, please contact [email protected].
Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
http://about.jstor.org/terms
School of Oriental and African Studies, Cambridge University Press are collaborating with
JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The China Quarterly
This content downloaded from 154.59.124.102 on Sun, 18 Sep 2016 07:37:38 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Transforming Taiwan's Economic Structure
in the 20th Century
Cheng Tun-jen
This article analyses Taiwan's economic changes that have occurred from
the Japanese colonization of Taiwan in 1895 to the recent Asian financial
crisis, focusing on the interplay between policy and structure. Pre-
colonial Taiwan was a frontier society with a settlement economy,
primarily subsistence-based, and with a thin state structure, politically
barely governed by the Qing dynasty. Under Japanese rule, Taiwan was
turned into an essentially open economy and an agrarian base of the
Japanese Empire. In the post-Second World War era, the Taiwanese
economy under the Nationalist regime was briefly turned inward for
import substitution industrialization, but rapidly transformed into one
based on industrial exports in labour-intensive sectors, and increasingly
on modern services as well. By the end of the century, Taiwan had
already become the world's third largest maker of information technology
products, behind the United States and Japan. The permutation of owner-
ship structure was equally drastic. Dominant Japanese capital in the
pre-war era became omnipresent state capital in the immediate post-war
era. Subsequently, however, indigenous private capital overwhelmed the
industrial sector and, towards the end of the century, made inroads in the
financial sector as well. All these structural changes in market orientation,
sector composition and ownership pattern did not reflect natural evol-
ution, but rather were cumulative results of government policies under
three successive regimes in Taiwan, the colonial, the Nationalist authori-
tarian and the democratic.
Economic policies in colonial Taiwan were predetermined by its
assigned role in the Japanese Empire. In the post-war era, the local state
elite had more latitude in making policy choices. Policies, imposed or
homemade, are effective only if the state can elicit compliance or inspire
responses from private economic agents. Throughout the century, Taiwan
has had a state capable of leading concerted actions for economic
modernization. Autonomous, yet highly penetrative and effective, the
colonial state built and staffed by expatriates quickly embarked on
agricultural development and turned Taiwan into a taxable surplus base.
Upon its retreat from the mainland to Taiwan, the Kuomintang (KMT)
regime, as heir to the colonial state structure, reinvented itself, shook off
its predatory nature and provided political space for technocrats to
implement a series of industrialization strategies. The state in post-war
Taiwan has displayed economic leadership as in Korea, but often via a
more hands-off, less discretionary approach in fostering entrepreneurship,
encouraging investment and shaping industrial structure. This approach to
industrial transformation helped Taiwan to cope with the challenge of
globalization and endure the recent financial crisis.
This article is organized in the following way. The first section
? The China Quarterly, 2001
This content downloaded from 154.59.124.102 on Sun, 18 Sep 2016 07:37:38 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
20 The China Quarterly
analyses how the colonial state initiated and shaped the course of
economic development from 1895 to 1941. The next section discusses
regime transition and its impacts on the state-economy relationship.
This is followed by an examination of the economic take-off and indus-
trial upgrading from the 1960s on. The final section assesses the Tai-
wanese developmental model in the light of democratization,
globalization and the fin-de-siecle region-wide financial crisis. Through-
out, Korea serves as a benchmark for comparison as it shared the
developmental trajectory.
Colonial Development
1. Mark Peattie, "Introduction," in Ramon Myers and Mark Peattie (eds.), The Japanese
Colonial Empire (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1984).
2. Christopher Howe, The Origins of Japanese Trade Supremacy (Chicago: University
of Chicago Press, 1996), pp. 344--45; Lin Jong-shiung, "Tai-wan jing-ji fa-zhan de ji chu"
("The foundation of economic development in Taiwan"), in Taiwan ming-yun de hui-gu
yu zhang-wang (Taiwan's Destiny: Retrospect and Prospect) (Taipei: Ji-yu xi-bao, 1996),
pp. 102-107.
3. Samuel P. S. Ho, Economic Development of Taiwan 1860-1970 (New Haven: Yale
University Press, 1978), p. 37.
This content downloaded from 154.59.124.102 on Sun, 18 Sep 2016 07:37:38 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Taiwan's Economic Structure 21
4. Ibid. p. 66; Tun-jen Cheng, "Guarding the commanding heights: the state as b
Taiwan," in S. Haggard, C. Lee and S. Maxfield (eds.), The Politics ofFinance in D
Countries (Ithaca: Cornell University Press 1993), p. 61.
5. Howe, Origins, p. 309
6. Guang-fu tai-wan ji chou-hua yu shou-hsing jie-shou (Plan on Recovering
Receiving Japanese Surrender and Taking Over Taiwan) (Taipei: Zhong-guo-guo-
zhong-yang-wei-yuan-hui, dang-xi-wei-yuan-hui, 1990) the collection of historica
of modern China, No. 4, p. 393
7. Edward I-Te Chen, "Japanese colonialism in Korea and Formosa: a compariso
systems of political control," Harvard Journal ofAsiatic Studies, Vol. 30 (1970), pp
8. Wei Chi-lin, "Bai-nien-lai taiwan chan-yeh de guo-ji dao-shian" ("Inter
orientations of Taiwan's industry in the 20th century"), in Toshiyuki Mizoguchi and
Umemura (eds.), Taiwan ming-yun (Taiwan's Destiny), pp. 132, 153; Kyunihon shok
keizai tokei (Economic Statistics on Former Japanese Colonies) (Tokyo: Toy
shimposha, 1988), pp. 296-97.
This content downloaded from 154.59.124.102 on Sun, 18 Sep 2016 07:37:38 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
22 The China Quarterly
and other consumer goods - were from Japan. The expansion of industry
paled when compared with agricultural development. After Western firms
abandoned the Asian market in the 1910s, the number of factories grew
drastically, primarily in sugar refining and other food-processing indus-
tries. As the sugar industry matured in the 1930s, the growth of the
industrial sector declined substantially, in spite of a major effort to
diversify Taiwan's industry. The rise of chemical fertilizer, textile, metal
and industrial chemical industries did little to transform Taiwan's indus-
trial base.9 After all, such a "crash industrialization programme" was
essentially for war preparation and in most case a relocation of used
production facilities. The industrialization decelerated as trade within the
Empire dwindled, sea transport closed and eventually air raids intensified
during the Pacific War.
Thanks to the declining mortality rate, the population in Taiwan grew
from around three million to seven million during the colonial era.
Income level was elevated, twice as high as that in China on the eve of
the Sino-Japan war.1o Taiwan, along with Japan and Korea, and unlike the
rest of Asia, exceeded Latin America in terms of per capita output." The
Japanese colonial state developed as well as exploited the Taiwanese
economy. While domestic uses and capital formation were close to output
in the mid-1910s, they subsequently dropped to 10 per cent below gross
output.12 The growth rate of per capita consumption was far behind that
of per capita production, thanks to cartelized sugar production, organized
export and the control of input materials such as chemical fertilizer.
Effective taxation in the rural sector was a defining feature of the
Japanese colonial state in Taiwan. Other colonial states in natural re-
source-rich economies, such as France in Africa, only had to franchise
away permits for plantation and mineral exploration, while collecting
rents from the licensees. Japan, in contrast, maintained a smallholder
system in Taiwan's primary sector; even sugar plantations were essen-
tially based on tenant-owners rather than wage earners. Modernizing a
smallholder-based agriculture required the expansion of the state appar-
atus, which in turn enhanced state capacity for extraction.
Only the primary sector was significantly transformed. As Table 1
shows, the shares of the secondary sector fluctuated, but were often high
in comparison with those of the primary sector, and were much higher
than those for the first two decades of the post-war era. These figures do
not denote substantial industrial change in pre-war Taiwan, as a relatively
large share of the industrial sector in the economy was based on sugar
This content downloaded from 154.59.124.102 on Sun, 18 Sep 2016 07:37:38 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Table 1: Taiwan's GDP and Employment by Sector, 1905-1998
GDP Employment
Sources:
Pre-1952 GDP data is from Wu Tsong-min, "1910 nien zhi 1950 nien tai-wan di-chu
ji gu-ji" ("An estimation of Taiwan's gross domestic product, 1910-1950"), Jin-ji lu
Economic Review), Vol. 19, No. 2 (1991), pp 165-172; pre-war employment figures
Ho, Economic Development of Taiwan 1860-1970 (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1
figures are from Taiwan Statistical Data Book, various issues. GDP figures are based on
in brackets are on constant prices.
This content downloaded from 154.59.124.102 on Sun, 18 Sep 2016 07:37:38 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
24 The China Quarterly
13. Wu Tsong-min, "1910 nien zhi 1950 nien tai-wan di-chu guo-nei sheng-chan mao-er
ji gu-ji" ("An estimation of Taiwan's gross domestic product, 1910-1950"), Jin-ji lun-wen
tsong-kan (Taiwan Economic Review), Vol. 19, No. 2 (1991), pp. 127-173.
14. Ho, Economic Development, p. 90.
This content downloaded from 154.59.124.102 on Sun, 18 Sep 2016 07:37:38 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Taiwan's Economic Structure 25
This content downloaded from 154.59.124.102 on Sun, 18 Sep 2016 07:37:38 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
26 The China Quarterly
commercial crops became the main export items until the mid-1960s.
Through tax payment in kind, the fertilizer-grain barter system and the
monopoly of sugar refining, farmers were squeezed to support the indus-
trial sector. Between 1952 and 1969, the official purchasing price for rice
was 27.1 per cent below the market level, while that for sugar was 12.54
per cent below the international price.19 The government collected about
50 per cent of rice that left the village, and about 60 per cent of that
collected was used to feed members of the military and civil service and
their dependents, with the rest used for the domestic and export markets,
either to stabilize prices or earn foreign exchange.20 The extraction of
agricultural surplus also helped the government to blunt wages and
entertain the tax incentive policy to promote industry.
It was in the industrial sector that there was an entirely new strategy,
namely import substitution industrialization (ISI) in the non-durable
consumer good sectors. Based on the infant industry argument and
endorsed by influential development economists such as Raul Prebisch,
ISI was in the 1950s a prevailing ideology for late industrializers. For the
KMT regime, ISI was not so much a choice as a situational imperative.21
The demand-pull inflation in the period of post-war reconstruction and
lack of savings led the regime to restrict imports, allocate foreign
exchanges and tolerate overvalued exchange rates. Once the government
slipped into ISI, it pursued this strategy most vehemently. Initially, three
industries were earmarked for expansion: chemical fertilizer, plastics and
textile. The first was to be undertaken by the existing state firms, the
second to be transferred to the private sector, while the third was to be
entrusted to existing firms. Subsequently, the synthetic fibres, glass and
food industries were added to the list, all assigned to the private sector.
ISI industries received tariff protection, hard currencies, targeted loans
and the government's tight control over new entrants. In the textile
industry, the government also used American aid cotton and guaranteed
purchases of output to encourage mill owners to expand their capacity, a
modus operandi akin to the shokusan kogyo formula in the colonial era.
While in the plastics and synthetic fibre industries the state often had to
cajole private firms to take over model plants it built, in the textile
industry there was no shortage of investors, given the huge and assured
profits. ISI industries were criticized for seeking unfair policy privileges
yet producing low-quality goods. The government remained vigilant on
corruption and suspended policy loans in 1958.
Here lies a puzzle. The KMT regime did not display so much of a
19. Teng-hui Lee, Intersectoral Capital Flows in the Economic Development of Taiwan
1895-1960 (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1971), and Ban Yu-yuan, "Taiwan nong-yeh
jai jing-ji fa-zhan guo-chen zhong ji gong-hsien yu de-wei" ("Taiwan's economic
development: the contribution and role of the agricultural sector"), Taiwan yin-hang ji-kan
(Bank of Taiwan Quarterly), Vol. 23, No. 2, p. 33.
20. Ho, Economic Development, p. 182.
21. Tun-jen Cheng, "Political regimes and development strategies," in Gary Gereffi and
Donald Wyman (eds.), Manufacturing Miracles (Princeton: Princeton University Press,
1990), p. 144.
This content downloaded from 154.59.124.102 on Sun, 18 Sep 2016 07:37:38 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Taiwan's Economic Structure 27
22. For the pre-war era, see Albert Feuerwerker, Economic Trends in the Repu
China, 1912-1949 (Ann Arbor: Center for Chinese Studies, University of Michigan
Park M. Coble, Jr., The Shanghai Capitalists and the National Government, 1927
(Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1986); Thomas Rawski, Economic Gro
Prewar China (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1989), ch. 1, especially p.
23. Fu Chi-xue etal., Zhong-hua min-guojian-cha-yuanji yen-chiu (A Study of the C
Yuan in the Republic of China), n.d.
24. Wen xing-ying, Jing-ji chi-ji de bei-hou (Behind Economic Miracle) (Ta
Independent Evening News Publisher, 1989), p. 226; Ho, Economic Development,
This content downloaded from 154.59.124.102 on Sun, 18 Sep 2016 07:37:38 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
28 The China Quarterly
while aid funds were key to the emergence of the plastics, synthetic fibre,
glass and cement industries. Under donors' persuasion, the KMT regime
accepted their growing autonomy in economic activity and permitted
technocrats to have a high degree of operational freedom. And because of
the mismanagement of aid by the regime on the mainland, the aid agency
in Taiwan was involved in both allocative decisions and auditing, much
more so than in South Korea.25
American aid, geopolitical ties with the West, and the sub-ethnic divide
between Taiwanese and mainlanders had important implications for the
development of the indigeneous private sector. The regime dominated
heavy industry, and thus left some room for the private sector to develop
in the light industry area. Yet investment opportunities initially went to
Shanghai and Shandong capitalists - who loyally migrated to Taiwan -
rather than to native entrepreneurs who were believed to have no mana-
gerial skills.26 In the financial sector, only non-bank financial intermedi-
aries, such as co-operative credit and insurance, were open to the private
sector. Only four major state enterprises were divested to compensate the
landowners in the wake of land reform. State capitalism was in line with
the teaching of Sun Yat-sen, founding father of Nationalist China, and the
preference of many socialist-oriented KMT ideologues. However, the
doctrine and praxis of restraining private capital did not work well with
the reality of Taiwan's political association with Western capitalism. The
aid agency constantly prescribed specific development programmes to
nurture the private sector.27 Moreover, given the criticism of their inti-
mate ties with mainlander capitalists, technocrats - already burdened with
the task of managing huge state enterprises - began to entertain the idea
of promoting Taiwanese capitalists.
25. David C. Cole, "Foreign assistance and Korean development," in David C. Cole,
Youngil Lim and Paul W. Kuznets, The Korean Economy: Issues of Development (Berkeley:
Institute of East Asian Studies, 1980).
26. Huang Chin-shing, Ban xi-ji de fun-dou: Wu Ho-xi sien-sheng kou-xou zhoung-ji
(Business as a Vocation: the Autobiography of Mr Wu Ho-su) (Taipei: Asian Culture
Company, 1990), p. 151.
27. Neil H. Jacoby, U.S. Aid to Taiwan (New York: Praeger, 1966)
28. Stephan Haggard, Pathways from the Periphery (Ithaca: Cornell University Press,
1990), ch. 4.
This content downloaded from 154.59.124.102 on Sun, 18 Sep 2016 07:37:38 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Taiwan's Economic Structure 29
29. They display leadership, not followership, in Robert Wade's words. See his Governing
the Market (Princeton: Princeton University Press 1990), ch. 10.
This content downloaded from 154.59.124.102 on Sun, 18 Sep 2016 07:37:38 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
30 The China Quarterly
Note:
*The 1972 figures.
Source:
Taiwan Statistical Data Book, various issues.
Agriculture
(raw and processed) Industrial Heavy and chemical Others
Source:
Taiwan Statistical Data Book, various issues.
This content downloaded from 154.59.124.102 on Sun, 18 Sep 2016 07:37:38 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Taiwan's Economic Structure 31
30. For industrial promotion and deepening, I drew heavily from Cheng, "Politica
and development strategy," pp. 153-172.
This content downloaded from 154.59.124.102 on Sun, 18 Sep 2016 07:37:38 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
32 The China Quarterly
Source
Chi-yuan Liang, "Productivity growth in Asian
NIEs: a case study of the Republic of China,
1961-1993," APO Productivity Journal, Winter
1993, p. 20.
and low pollution effect. Two state financial institutions would advance
long-term lending to these industries, while the 1960 SEI underwent a
major revision in 1981 to encourage spending on research and develop-
ment as well as the use of energy-saving machinery.
The policy for industrial upgrading failed in the automotive industry,
fared better in the machine tool industry, and has been lauded in the
semi-conductor and computer sectors. A huge joint venture involving
Toyota, state and local capital did not happen, as Toyota hesitated to
commit to transferring technology and increasingly exporting the planned
outputs. Behind the high tariff wall, erected in 1961, Taiwan's five
automobile makers continued to assemble foreign components. In 1984,
the government suddenly lifted the entry restrictions, allowing seven
more firms to join the fray for a well-protected market. Yet industrial
shakeout did not ensue and Taiwanese cars remained not exportable.31
The condition for machine tools - the other pillar of the machinery
industry - has not been as dismal, however. It received less protection
and support from the government, thanks to the lack of political clout of
apprentice-turned entrepreneurs.32 While overshadowed by Korean firms,
Taiwan's machine tool makers were able to carve out some niches in the
international market.
Industrial policy for the information industry did not involve any
protection or public-private joint venture. But the government did lend
strong support to the industry, unlike the case of the machine tool
industry. Apart from extending tax incentives and concessionary loans, it
sponsored research and development activities, actively nurtured skilled
personnel and transfer technology to the private sector, participated in the
formation of venture capital firms, and established a science-based indus-
31. Chen Tein-chi, "1980 nien-dai i-lai tai-wan de mau-Iji-yu-hua" ("Trade liberalization
in post-1980 Taiwan"), in Shih Jian-sheng (ed.), 1980 nien-dai i-lai tai-wan jing-jifa-zhan
jing-yen (Economic Development in Post-1980 Taiwan) (Taipei: Chung-hua Institute of
Economic Research, 1999).
32. Staffan Jacobson, "Industrial policy for the machine tool industries of South Korea and
Taiwan," Institute of Development Studies Bulletin, Vol. 15, No. 2 (1984), pp. 44-49.
This content downloaded from 154.59.124.102 on Sun, 18 Sep 2016 07:37:38 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Taiwan's Economic Structure 33
trial park to house new ventures. The role of parastatals, most notably
Industrial Technology Research Institute, was crucial. Free from bu
cratic control, yet continuously receiving budgetary support, these par
tatals have trained more than 10,000 highly skilled workers, hou
returnees from Silicon Valley, established laboratories for testing p
ucts, and brokered R & D consortia. By identifying market opportuniti
diffusing technology and co-ordinating market players, these para
alleviated information and collective action problems, and incuba
engineers-turned-entrepreneurs.33 The role of government was thus es
tial during the 1980s - the seed and start-up stages - of Taiw
semi-conductor and computer industries, though less so during the 199
- the expansion period when local firms entered strategic alliances
leading Western firms.34
While the high tech sector made progress under government supp
others were not left in the cold. Almost all industries received fiscal
incentives one way or another. Export incentives remained intact. A
credit facility for "key industries" was also established to finance broad
types of investment in anti-pollution devices and automation, the pur-
chase of locally produced machinery and software, and projects supported
by the CEPD. Credit facilities for SMEs, which were greatly enhanced in
the 1970s to help them endure the hardship of economic downturn, saw
drastic improvement in the 1980s. More importantly, there was a crucial
evolution from supporting sectors to supporting functional-oriented activ-
1982 47.2 30.8 21.9 26.9 45.4 27.6 18.3 32.6 49.1
1985 45.9 35.6 18.5 24.5 48.7 26.8 18.8 33.6 47.6
1990 41.0 38.3 20.7 28.9 50.5 20.5 26.7 38.6 34.7
1995 36.4 40.6 23.0 31.9 56.5 11.6 36.5 41.4 22.0
1997 34.9 43.1 22.1 30.3 60.6 9.1 39.7 41.1 19.2
Source:
Taiwan Statistical Data Book, 1998.
33. Greg Noble, Collective Action in East Asia (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1998),
ch. 6; Tun-jen Cheng, Stephan Haggard and David Kang, "Institutions and economic
policies," the United Nations Conference of Trade and Development, 1996, pp. 88, 90.
34. See Chen Dung-sheng, "Ji-ti den-lu chan-yeh zhu-zhi wan-lo de shing-shih ji chi
hsing-chen de zhi-du ji-chu" ("The formation and institutional basis of network organizations
in Taiwan's integrated-circuit industry"), in Wei-an Chang (ed.), Taiwan de chi-yeh
(Enterprises in Taiwan) (forthcoming), p. 10; J. A. Mathews, "Silicon Valley of the East:
creating Taiwan's semiconductor industry," California Management Review, Vol. 39, No. 4
(1997), pp. 26-54; Chi Schive, "The next stage of industrialization in South Korea and
Taiwan," in Gereffi and Wyman, Manufacturing Miracles, pp. 285-88.
This content downloaded from 154.59.124.102 on Sun, 18 Sep 2016 07:37:38 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
34 The China Quarterly
ities. In 1990, the SEI was abolished and replaced by the Statute on the
Upgrading of Industry, under which the government no longer promotes
specific industries, but rather provides only "functional incentives" for R
& D, anti-pollution spending and other industrial upgrading activities.
Taiwan's industrialization accelerated in the 1960s, but it was during
the final two decades of the 20th century that Taiwan's industry was
drastically transformed. As Table 5 shows, between 1982 and 1997, the
technology intensity of Taiwan's exports had drastically improved. The
semi-conductor and computer sectors have become leading exporters and
the mainstay of Taiwan's industry. As revealed in Table 5, total factor
productivity grew significantly from 1982, departing from the previous
pattern of economic growth described by Paul Krugman as one based on
factor inputs rather than productivity improvement.35
35. Paul Krugman, "The myth of Asia's miracle," Foreign Affairs, Vol. 73, No. 6 (1994)
pp. 62-78; Chi-yuan Liang. "Productivity growth in Asian NIEs: a case study of the Republic
of China, 1961-1993," APO Productivity Journal, Winter 1995, pp. 17-40.
36. Chen Tein-chi, "Trade liberalization."
This content downloaded from 154.59.124.102 on Sun, 18 Sep 2016 07:37:38 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Taiwan's Economic Structure 35
This content downloaded from 154.59.124.102 on Sun, 18 Sep 2016 07:37:38 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
36 The China Quarterly
This content downloaded from 154.59.124.102 on Sun, 18 Sep 2016 07:37:38 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms