A Lire 1
A Lire 1
Article
Green Bonds for the Transition to a Low-Carbon Economy
Andreas Lichtenberger 1, * , Joao Paulo Braga 1 and Willi Semmler 1,2,3
1 Economics Department, The New School, 66 West 12th Street, New York, NY 10011, USA;
[email protected] (J.P.B.); [email protected] (W.S.)
2 Faculty of Economics and Business Administration, University of Bielefeld, Universitätsstraße 25,
33615 Bielefeld, Germany
3 International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis (IIASA), Schloßplatz 1, 2361 Laxenburg, Austria
* Correspondence: [email protected]
Abstract: The green bond market is emerging as an impactful financing mechanism in climate change
mitigation efforts. The effectiveness of the financial market for this transition to a low-carbon economy
depends on attracting investors and removing financial market roadblocks. This paper investigates
the differential bond performance of green vs non-green bonds with (1) a dynamic portfolio model that
integrates negative as well as positive externality effects and via (2) econometric analyses of aggregate
green bond and corporate energy time-series indices; as well as a cross-sectional set of individual
bonds issued between 1 January 2017, and 1 October 2020. The asset pricing model demonstrates that,
in the long-run, the positive externalities of green bonds benefit the economy through positive social
returns. We use a deterministic and a stochastic version of the dynamic portfolio approach to obtain
model-driven results and evaluate those through our empirical evidence using harmonic estimations.
The econometric analysis of this study focuses on volatility and the risk–return performance (Sharpe
ratio) of green and non-green bonds, and extends recent econometric studies that focused on yield
differentials of green and non-green bonds. A modified Sharpe ratio analysis, cross-sectional methods,
harmonic estimations, bond pairing estimations, as well as regression tree methodology, indicate that
green bonds tend to show lower volatility and deliver superior Sharpe ratios (while the evidence for
Citation: Lichtenberger, Andreas, green premia is mixed). As a result, green bond investment can protect investors and portfolios from
Joao Paulo Braga, and Willi Semmler. oil price and business cycle fluctuations, and stabilize portfolio returns and volatility. Policymakers
2022. Green Bonds for the Transition are encouraged to make use of the financial benefits of green instruments and increase the financial
to a Low-Carbon Economy. flows towards sustainable economic activities to accelerate a low-carbon transition.
Econometrics 10: 11. https://doi.org/
10.3390/econometrics10010011 Keywords: green bonds; innovation; climate finance; dynamic portfolio decisions
Academic Editor: Claudio Morana
JEL Classification: C610; G120; O380; Q580
Received: 31 October 2021
Accepted: 21 February 2022
Published: 2 March 2022
as a Romer type of growth model with expenditure for innovations impacting economic
growth rates (see Greiner et al. 2005).
In terms of modeling (See Semmler et al. 2020) the possibility of having a fraction of
accumulated wealth going into consumption and an additional fraction spent on resources
for new technologies can be included. As in Romer (1986), we assume this latter fraction
as being spent on human capital-creating innovations. Yet, within the resource allocation
for innovations, either for green or fossil fuel-based innovations, the latter is assumed to
generate negative externalities in the long run. Thus, this spending is again subdivided
into two purposes, which will be taken, for reasons of simplicity, as fixed.
The investment of a fraction of wealth into innovation generates a time-varying return
r e (t) which can generate positive or negative effects on growth in the long run. The value
of an investment which does not create long-term negative externalities (such as renewable
energy) can, thus, have positive effects on growth but also increase portfolio returns,
whereas the value of an investment which creates long-run adverse effects for the economy
through negative externalities (such as CO2 emissions) will negatively affect the portfolio
return and growth.
Building on dynamic portfolio models of the Merton type (Merton 1973), the allocation
paths can be assumed to evolve, driven by a finite decision horizon. Further, we can also as-
sume that portfolio decisions that promote green innovations are likely to yield higher asset
returns than investment decisions that fund non-renewable energy technology. The latter
induces negative environmental externalities, which are usually not reflected in the asset
return but are maybe, in the long-run, having destructive effects and embodying greater
risk—climate risks—that are usually not immediately taken into account while investing.
Though assets from climate projects might not promise as high returns as fossil fuel
assets (since they are still in the stage of learning and with a high risk of failure), they are
usually less vulnerable to exogenous shocks and should be of interest for private long-term
investors. This has been shown in empirical studies comparing bonds of the same issuer
and similar maturity; see Kapraun and Scheins (2019) and Section 4. A comparison of
the financial performance of fossil fuel bonds and green bonds often show lower yields
of the latter. Yet, the puzzle concerns the reason it can be beneficial for long-run asset
accumulation—is it the case that low-yield real investors (for example, in the renewable
energy sector) can issue bonds purchased by financial investors that pursue the social and
environment good, and thus, that those would be expected to add, in the long-run, social
returns? Is there a long run service that a green bond provides for the environment that is
not accounted for in the market yield?
If this is the case, then we must take into account the immediate private yields and the
additional social returns which would then provide a higher return for green energy than
for fossil fuel energy. Yet, this evaluation effect is undertaken, presumably, very imperfectly
in the market and, thus, the evidence for the performance of green investments might
be mixed. Additionally, of course, the overall performance of green investments would
come out more distinctively if, at the same time, fossil fuel energy is facing a carbon tax
or is forced to disclose CO2 emissions—which is presumably also imperfectly done. Thus,
in theory we would expect clear results, even though the empirics could look mixed; see
Section 4.
Yet, pursuing the theory nexus, first we develop a portfolio model of wealth accumula-
tion in Section 3, in which we consider a fixed-decision horizon and compare the possibility
of the different externality impacts associated with portfolio decisions on wealth accumula-
tion (either a positive impact due to environmental investments, or a negative impact due
to fossil fuel investments and negative externalities). Though the model will first be written
in terms of regular fixed-income fossil fuel and green bonds, convertible green bonds will
be introduced later, which could be a good transitional instrument to avoid excess debt
accumulation and ensure varying returns linked to green innovation success.
In terms of financial accumulation, a model that is sensitive to negative externalities
would predict a better long-term wealth accumulation for green compared to non-green
Econometrics 2022, 10, 11 5 of 31
assets. Negative environmental externalities feed into uncertainties in the financial market
and can have deteriorating impacts on investment. Therefore, negative environmental
impacts can be seen as disruptive elements with volatility-inducing impacts. For a contin-
uous and steady accumulation of wealth, green assets are hypothesized to deliver better
long-term investment opportunities.
Given those model-driven predictions, the major question pursued is whether the
predictions from theory hold in a visible way in the empirics. We argue that the theoretical
predictions may be clarified better by studying not only the returns, but the return–risk
ratio, or the Sharpe ratio. Still, regarding the returns, there are puzzling results, presumably
arising from the fact that positive and negative externality effects are currently rarely
considered in the actual trading by financial decisions in the financial markets.
We also provide some considerations on convertible green bonds, an innovative
financial instrument that seems to help to achieve sustainable debt. Convertible bonds
have recently been issued with green labels as an alternative to conventional fixed-income
bonds, given the surge of convertible instruments after the COVID-19 crisis (Gregory 2020).
high variation of premia across currencies and issuer types. Kapraun and Scheins (2019)
do control for public vs. corporate investors; however, they do not control for different
corporate bond-issuing sectors (e.g., energy, finance, utilities) and their analysis does not
deal with bond price volatility.
Löffler et al. (2021) analyze the conventional and green bond performance and find that
the primary as well as the secondary market yield for green bonds is, on average, 15–20-bps
lower than for conventional bonds, and that the ask yield volatility of matched green bonds
is higher than that of matched conventional bonds. The latter finding motivates their claim
that the negative green premium results in a preference for buying green-labeled assets.
Their study uses two different bond-pairing approaches, propensity score matching (PSM)
and coarsened exact matching (CEM) methodology, to determine a sample of conventional
bonds that is most similar to the sample of green bonds. However, compared to our
analysis, they do not control for bond rating and amount issued, and their conclusions on
bond volatility relies on a single volatility measure, whereas our analysis includes three
different volatility measures.
Bachelet et al. (2019) analyze a set of 89 paired green and conventional bonds from
2013 until 2017. Their matching criteria are based on issuer, currency, rating, amount issued,
coupon rate, maturity date, and coupon type. They analyze green versus conventional
bonds with regard to differences in the bond premium (only for secondary markets), the liq-
uidity, and the bond price volatility (also based on secondary bond market prices). Similar
to Kapraun and Scheins (2019), they differentiate between private and institutional bond
issuers, and find that the yield differential of green minus conventional bonds is positive
and about 2–3 bps for private issuers and negative, between −1.9 bps and −9.6 bps,
for institutional issuers. For private issuers without a green label, the green premium
is even bigger, in the range of 3.2 bps and 11.2 bps. This difference also holds for the
volatility analysis: green bonds are significantly and slightly less volatile than conventional
bonds in the case of established issuers, i.e., institutional and green-certified private is-
suers. Bachelet et al. (2019) does not pursue a sector-specific analysis and provides a single
measure only for the volatility analysis (ex-post standard deviation of bond yields which
considers a spanning period of 20 days). In contrast, our empirical analysis looks into
different sectors and uses three different volatility measures with spanning periods of 30,
90, and 260 days.
Hachenberg and Schiereck (2018) analyze risk–return profiles for a sample of green and
non-green bonds, sampled between 1 October 2015 and 31 March 2016. They find evidence
that green bonds, on average, do not trade significantly tighter than their counterparts,
but with some tendencies, such as statistically significant pricing differentials for single A-
rated bonds, with green bonds trading 3.88-bps (4.87%) tighter than comparable non-green
bonds. Similar to Kapraun and Scheins (2019), their study also emphasizes the relevance
industry-related pricing differentials, namely, through government-related and financial
issuers. Therefore, the analysis presented also includes a sector-specific analysis of the
bond trends.
A systematic summary on green bond returns was delivered by MacAskill et al. (2021),
who confirm the existence of a green premium. They report a green premium within 56% of
primary and 70% of secondary market studies, particularly for those green bonds that are
government-issued, investment-grade, and that follow defined green bond governance and
reporting procedures. The green premium varies widely for the primary market; however,
an average greenium of 1 to 9 bps on the secondary market is observed.
Flammer (2021) examines corporate green bonds by looking into the effects of issuance
announcments. The results of the author supports the ”signaling argument”. She finds
improved environmental performance after the issuance of green bonds and an increase in
ownership by long-term and green investors. Looking at a messaging sentiment from a
network perspective, Piñeiro-Chousa et al. (2021) analyze how investor sentiment, based
on social networks, influences the green bond market. Using a panel data analysis, they,
basically, find a positive impact on green bond returns through tweets, which reflects the
Econometrics 2022, 10, 11 7 of 31
positive attitude of the public towards green bonds. These study results can encourage
investors and markets to consider social networks as relevant sources of information.
Huynh and Xia (2021) look into the risk-performance profile of corporate bonds and
estimate the extent to which climate change news are priced in. They find that bonds
with a higher climate change news beta earn lower future returns, which is also consistent
with asset pricing demand for bonds with high potential to hedge against climate risk.
Therefore, corporate policies aimed at improving environmental performance pay off when
the market is concerned about climate change risk.
In addition, Pham and Nguyen (2021) study the performance of green bonds under
conditions of uncertainty. Their work sheds light on the diversification capability of green
bond markets by analyzing the effects of stock volatility, oil volatility, and economic policy
uncertainty (EPU) on green bond returns. They are using four major green bond indices
and three uncertainty indices, from October 2014 to November 2020. The authors find
that a time-varying and state-dependent relation of green bonds, and also that uncertainty
diversification benefits are higher in times of high uncertainty, as during the COVID-19
pandemic, i.e., hedging the capabilities of green bonds in times of uncertainty. Therefore,
green bonds can be relevant for policy to stabilize the financial markets during periods
of crisis.
None of the papers that use a bond-pairing algorithm investigate extensively the
financial performance of green and brown bonds based on a risk–reward performance
measure such as the Sharpe ratio (SR). While Ehlers and Packer (2017) use the Sharpe ratio
to investigate the green bond performance, they only use a cross-sectional sample of 21
green bonds issued between 2014 and 2017. Therefore, our individual bond data sample
includes 1529 green bonds issued between 2017 and 2020 and, in contrast to their bond
analysis, our algorithm also controls for rating. Their study finds that the risk-adjusted
performance (i.e., the Sharpe ratio) was, in some cases, slightly higher for green bond
indices than for global bond indices, though that difference was not statistically significant
to evaluate the bond performance of green bonds.
The paper by Han and Li (2022), with a dynamic R-vine copula-based mean-CVaR
model, finds that green bonds improve the SR of a stock–bond portfolio in different market
environments and can provide downside risk protection during the COVID-19 pandemic.
Their study reports that the benefits from green bonds arise from an increase in the return
and a decrease in the volatility for most of the cases. Additionally, the paper by Tiwari et al.
(2022) shows that green bonds help to significantly reduce the investment risk of other assets
in bilateral portfolios. Their study examines the transmission of return patterns between
green bonds, carbon prices, and renewable energy stocks with a dynamic connectedness
approach to model the interconnectedness of a predetermined network and construct
numerous bivariate and multivariate portfolios.
In relation to the portfolio model, we are going to study patterns of wealth accumula-
tion on an empirical level by using the Sharpe ratio (as well as yield and volatility measures),
and we expect green bonds to be a more stable form of investment, i.e., to have higher
Sharpe ratios than non-green bonds. The Sharpe ratio is a risk–return measure; it discounts
the portfolio return by its risk structure, which is described by a volatility measure. Assets
with a higher degree of fluctuation will report lower Sharpe ratios than assets with stable
conditions. Though results will be different across sectors, we expect especially higher
Sharpe ratios for green energy in the energy sector, given the immediate connection to
environmental externalities, fossil fuel-based emissions, and oil price fluctuations.
The novelty of the empirics of our paper is to combine an established bond-pairing
procedure with new bond-performance measures—that is, the Sharpe ratio and several
volatility measures, in addition to primary and secondary market yield measures—to
analyze a recent dataset of individual green and conventional bonds (from 2017 until
2020). Additionally, these results are contrasted with an application of recently developed
advancements of the Sharpe ratio measures to aggregate MSCI time series data. A cate-
gorization and regression tree analysis is included, which has not been so far applied in
Econometrics 2022, 10, 11 8 of 31
the analysis of bond performance. The individual bond dataset used is obtained through
the Bloomberg terminal and considers the sectors in which most green bonds were is-
sued globally: finance, utilities, energy, and government (i.e., we consider the following
Bloomberg Industry Classification Sectors (BICS 2): banks, real estate, power generation,
utilities, sovereigns, renewable energy, and development banks).
Next, we want to explore the long-term implications of holding green assets by allow-
ing positive and negative externality effects on asset pricing.
2π 2π 2π 2π
r egreen (t) = 0.029 sin( (t)) + 0.0273 cos( (t)) − 0.0119 sin( (t)) − 0.007 cos( (t))
60 60 20 20
2π 2π 2π 2π
+ 0.004 sin( (t)) + 0.0217 cos( (t)) − 0.0037 sin( (t)) − 0.0004 cos( (t)), (1)
30 30 15 15
2π 2π
r ef ossil f uel (t) = −0.0361 sin(
(t)) + 0.0113 cos( (t)). (2)
30 30
Next, we presume that, in a stylized baseline portfolio model, an investor invests
a fraction of his/her wealth to each risky asset, defining the share of green assets given
by the decision variable πt , which may also allow for divestment in fossil fuels as well.
Thus, we can have πt > 1. The decision on the share of investment for innovations and
consumption is a maximization problem with a budget constraint. The maximization of
the value function is expressed using the usual dynamic discounting cash flow model:
Z T
V (W, x, t) ≡ max{cs ,πs } E{ e−δ0 (s−t) F (cs Ws , us Ws )ds}, (3)
t
The budget constraint of Equation (4) is a sum of wealth gains from the different
types of investment (πt rtegreen Wt + (1 − πt )rte f ossil f uel Wt ) minus a fraction of the assets going
to consumption (ct Wt ) and minus additional adjustment costs that the investor incurs by
obtaining the equity assets (X (Πt , Wt )). The preferences in Equation (3) are defined by a
log–utility function over both objectives.
Econometrics 2022, 10, 11 9 of 31
s.t.Ẇ (t) =πt rte‘green Wt + (1 − πt )rte‘f ossil f uel Wt − (ut + ct )Wt − X (Πt , Wt ). (6)
The investment of a fraction of wealth into innovation efforts, which could be an invest-
ment into renewable and/or fossil fuel energy innovations, generates a time-varying return
r e‘ (t) which can be positively or negatively affected by the investment decision (depending
on whether there are positive or negative externalities). The renewable energy-oriented
innovation investments additionally take into account the long-term return benefits of
green investments (lower volatility of returns and higher social returns). We can, thus,
define the two types of returns:
r e‘ e
green ( t ) = (1 + µ ( νut ))( α + γ ∗ r green ( t )), (7)
r e‘f ossil f uel (t) = (1 − µ((1 − ν)ut ))r ef ossil f uel (t). (8)
Hereby, the fractions of wealth used for renewable energy innovations, ν, and the
remaining part used for fossil fuel innovations, 1 − ν, will be taken as fixed with equal
shares.7
As defined by rie‘ (t) in Equation (7), an investment which does not create long-term
negative externalities (such as renewable energy) and which has positive externality effects
will be positive (+µ(νut )) and, additionally, will have lower a volatility of returns (stressed
by a γ lower than 1) , and possibly higher returns in the long-run (α is a mean-adjustment
term that represents the positive impact of externalities, which will vary in our simulations).
Asset returns expressed by Equation (8) are associated with long-run adverse effects on the
economy, which are caused by the creation of negative externalities (such as CO2 emissions,
affecting temperature and creating damages in the long run). This negatively affects their
returns; thus, (−µ((1 − ν)ut )).
As mentioned, the terms µ(νut ) and µ((1 − ν)ut ) could depend, for example (as in
the Romer model), on the engineers’ innovation efforts and the therefrom resulting returns.
However, in order to smooth out the transition, we use in the simulation a logistic function
for ut so that the renewable energy innovations have the following form:
in which µ is the externality scale factor (for example, set as 0.2); βut is the fraction of
wealth now in the logistic function, allocated to green or fossil fuel innovations. The logistic
function L is here introduced to capture the possibly increasing social returns of innovation
efforts (Hall et al. 2010; Leibowicz 2018 and Jones and Summers 2020). The logistic function
is given by:
L( βut ) = 130/(1 + e−30ut ). (10)
The upper bound in the logistic function is based on estimations by Jones and Summers
(2020). They estimate that the social returns of an innovation expense in the health sector is
from 79% to 159%.
Econometrics 2022, 10, 11 10 of 31
Furthermore, the adjusted-returns for green and fossil fuel assets for the cases of α in
Equations (7) and (8) are equal to 0.034, 0.024, and 0.014, which are shown by Figure 1.
Figure 1. Returns for green (reg) and fossil fuel bonds (rec): adjusted harmonic estimations as in
Equations (7) and (8).
Using harmonic estimations for Equations (1) and (2), we obtain the return paths of
green energy bonds, reg, and carbon energy bonds, rec, for different scaling factors (see
Figure 1). Since the actual empirical effects are not known with certainty, we explore the
paths of the harmonic estimates for different sizes of α.
Though assets from climate projects often do not promise such high returns as fossil
fuel assets, they are less vulnerable to exogenous shocks and should be of interest for
investors. This has been shown in empirical studies comparing bonds of the same issuer
and similar maturity (see Kapraun and Scheins (2019) and Semmler et al. (2021)). We
explore a stochastic version of this model in Appendix B to account for these shocks in
order to analyze the model behavior when investors face additional financial risks. A shock
to asset returns is added to the model, and the realizations of the different shock sequences
create slightly different solution paths. We simulate a case with a higher volatility (a larger
shock to stranded fossil fuel assets, as found empirically) and another case with a lower
shock (and, thus, smaller volatility, as found in the case of green bonds).
Complementary measures to a green bond strategy such as a carbon tax or disclosure
requirements can decrease risky returns. This could visibly reduce fossil fuel returns,
and make green bonds even with negative bond premia, as reported in Kapraun and
Scheins (2019), profitable in dynamic portfolios, successfully helping the transition to a
low-carbon economy. Moreover, to indicate this possible positive externality effect, the “+”
we introduced reflects a positive drift in the returns arising from energy innovation, the α.
The negative externality effect is represented by the negative sign, the “−”.8
The possibility of (negative) premia for green bonds could also be explained in the
light of asset-buyer preferences, which could drive short- and medium-run effects. Thus,
there can be (direct) negative premia for green bonds (see Kapraun and Scheins 2019). Yet,
the positive externality for society of green investments (green energy, conservation of
energy, etc.) through some “extra productivity” or “service” (e.g., through scale effects
with freely available energy and avoidance of destruction through CO2 ) should show up in
extra long-run returns in green portfolio holdings, indicated by the the size of the α.
Next, numerical solutions are obtained by applying to our model the method of Non-
linear Model Predictive Control (NMPC) as a solution procedure; see Gruene et al. (2015).
On the other hand, as climate research has shown, fossil fuel bonds and fossil fuel eq-
uity are linked to negative externalities through CO2 emissions, temperature rises, weather
extremes, and climate disasters, requiring a carbon tax to internalize the externality cost.
Fossil fuel assets might also be quite volatile in value, in particular in contractions and
recessionary periods, triggering financial instability. Introducing carbon taxation as well as
the threat of financial instability and the disclosure requirements will lead to either lower
net cash flows of fossil fuel firms and/or their assets will face a devaluation in the market,
triggered by higher discount rates capturing the long-run environmental risk involved.10
The above-mentioned two opposite effects on the return and firm value can be illus-
trated by simulations for the dynamic system; see Equations (5)–(8). The dynamic saving
and asset allocation choices are modeled in continuous time. In the objective function, we
have included, in addition to spending a fraction ct of wealth on consumption, a policy
maker’s decision to also spend a fraction ut of the wealth on innovation efforts; efforts are
aimed, for instance, at developing new energy technologies, and are weighted in the utility
function with w1 and (1 − w1 ), respectively. As noted, this is in line with the previous work
of Acemoglu et al. (2012) on directed technical change. We have have further split up the
innovation effort u in different fractions, one fraction for clean energy and one fraction for
fossil fuel energy. We can then explore the modeling procedure on the time-consumption–
wealth ratio, the time varying returns, and the rate of wealth dynamics. This will allow us
to observe whether wealth is increasing or decreasing over time for our two types of assets.
We want to note that, so far, we referred to two generic risky assets in the model
above. However, we can allow the two risky assets to be a green and a fossil fuel bond
that display time-varying returns impacting wealth accumulation. These bonds can also
be long-term bonds, generating returns from some coupon payments. Hereby, the bond
prices for long-term bonds can be made dependent on the expected return of the short-term
bonds.11
In this section, we solve the model using NMPC for a decision horizon N = 6 fixed
and 160 iteration time periods T for the different returns shown in Figure 1. We solve the
model where the term (1 ± µ(ut Wt )) uses the logistic function, L. The “+” case implies that
µ(·) > 0, for example, for the new innovations in renewable energy firms. Note that there
might also be some temporary risk premium harvested by fossil fuel assets so that we have
µ(·) > 0. On the other hand, for the fossil fuel asset, we might have (1 ± µ(ut Wt )) < 1),
such that the “−” case holds, implying µ(·) < 0.
Our depicted cases in Figure 2 present only the results for µ(·) > 0, using, for example,
a computational parameterization of µ(·) = 0.2. In Figure 2, the lowest graph represents the
effect with a parameter α = 0.014, the middle graph is for α = 0.024, and the upper graph
for α = 0.034. The graph shows that the greater the positive externality effects, the more
wealth is accumulated over time. We do not solve for the case of negative externalities, as
these are likely to lead to less built-up asset value, but more specifically to dissipating asset
value in the long run. It is obvious that µ(·) < 0 will generate lower returns with mostly
fossil fuel bonds held in the portfolio (e.g., facing prospects of a carbon tax, stranded asset,
and downgrading through requirements of CO2 disclosure, higher liquidity, as well as
default risks and, hence, lower accumulation of wealth).
We observe that the referred effects on wealth and an investor’s asset value are well
associated with their portfolio composition choice. If investors hold a larger share of green
bonds, with long-term positive externality effects, the negative effects of climate transition
tend to be mitigated. Figure 3 shows the share of green bonds held by investors for the
three cases simulated in Figure 2. We observe that, in the case with α = 0.034, the left
panel of Figure 3, which is associated with the upper solution path of wealth accumulation,
investors invest only in green assets and divest fossil fuel assets, since the asset share
held in green assets is π = 1.2, meaning that there is short selling for the fossil fuel asset.
On the other hand, in the other two cases, investors tend to diversify and still choose
carbon-intensive securities in some periods.
Econometrics 2022, 10, 11 12 of 31
Figure 2. Solution paths of wealth for different asset returns; the upper graph with α = 0.034, middle
graphs with α = 0.024, and lower graph with α = 0.014 (N = 6, T = 160).
Figure 3. Portfolio decision—share of green assets for the cases with α = 0.034, α = 0.024, and
α = 0.014.
As mentioned in the model above, when referring to green and fossil fuel assets as the
two risky assets, we could also assume that we have green convertible bonds instead of
fixed-income securities. These are bonds that can be converted into equity. The condition
of convertibility to equity might be tight to some equity price per share through some
strike price, as the Merton model for debt suggests, and as the Black–Scholes model for
derivatives in general entails. A green bond is convertible to equity if the asset value
goes up, which might be the case of a successful green start-up firm. This is likely to be
accelerated if the distance to default also decreases, given the firm’s debt issuance, and if the
equity value of the firm increases.12 Moreover, if these are sovereign bonds, the conversion
of sovereign bonds into firms’ equity could allow the sovereign to reduce debt that it had
increased first by selling bonds and increasing debt. This way, debt sustainability could
be achieved.
Convertible bonds have recently been issued with green labels as an alternative to
conventional fixed-income bonds, but still represent a small share of the market (Gregory
2020). A convertible green bond is an innovative instrument that can address climate
challenges and benefit long-term issuers and investors, with higher future returns linked
to the success of green innovations. A surge in the convertible bond market was observed
in 2020 following the COVID-19 crisis, which created opportunities also for convertible
green bonds (Semmler et al. 2021). In the United States, new convertible bonds totaled
USD 77 billion as of September 2020, an increase of 45 percent over 2019 and 200 percent
over 2015. The convertible bond market index (ICE BofA US Convertible Index—VXA0)
outperformed the S&P 500 and S&P 500 bond index. In order to account for the effect of
external shocks and financial market risks, we also explore a stochastic version of the model
Econometrics 2022, 10, 11 13 of 31
in Appendix B. A shock to asset returns is added to the model and the realizations of the
different shock sequences create slightly different solution paths. A smaller shock is applied
to green bond returns (as expected for the case of green bonds, with lower volatility) as
well as a larger shock to fossil fuel returns (as expected in the case of fossil fuel bonds).
The results for the smaller shock do not differ significantly from the deterministic version
presented here and are more easily predictable, and thus, are less risky. The trajectory with
a larger standard deviation is much more noisy, reaching higher asset values.
develop an equality test of modified SR of investment forms. Candelon et al. (2021b) use
the definition of the relative Sharpe ratio loss (RSRL) as a measure of underdiversification
and the prior development of a modified Sharpe ratio to propose the modified relative
Sharpe ratio loss (mRSRL), which is robust to non-normality. Following Ledoit and Wolf
(2008) and Ardia and Boudt (2015), Candelon et al. (2021b) also use a studentized circle
block-bootstrap procedure to build robust confidence intervals.
Table 1. Descriptive statistics of collected conventional (CB) and green (GB) bond data issued between
1 January 2017 and 1 October 2020. (Source: Bloomberg terminal).
Categories CB GB
Sectors
Energy 809 100
Financials 4822 739
Government 2367 271
Utilities 1028 419
Ratings
A+:A− 2656 118
AAA:AA− 3310 188
B+:B− 349 7
BB+:BB− 482 34
BBB+:BBB− 1964 147
CCC+:D 136 1
Bond duration
long 1916 266
short 7011 1237
Currencies
AUD 525 27
BRL 55 46
CAD 252 25
CHF 147 13
CNY 175 157
EUR 2354 355
GBP 376 26
HKD 210 32
IDR 54 5
INR 58 29
Currencies
JPY 278 70
MXN 69 7
MYR 1 108
Econometrics 2022, 10, 11 15 of 31
Table 1. Cont.
Categories CB GB
Currencies
NOK 109 36
NZD 132 6
SEK 232 209
TRY 106 11
USD 3637 274
ZAR 78 14
Other 179 79
specific regression analysis (analysis 5). In this section, each analysis is presented in a
separate subsection. For further analysis of the expected return of bonds (yield at issue for
the primary bond market yields and the yield to maturity for the secondary bond market),
which are connected to the other financial literature on green bonds, please see Appendix C.
Table 2. Sharpe ratio comparison based on corporate energy (conventional) and green bond index
(green) time series data between 1 January 2017 and 1 October 2020. (Source: MSCI).
The slight superiority in the Sharpe ratio is also expressed through computing the
efficient forntier in a mean–variance chart after computing the revealed Markowitz weights;
see Figure 4. The straight lines, which are tangential to the efficient portfolio frontiers, reflect
the capital allocation lines (CAL). Their tangents point to the efficient frontier, reflecting
the optimal risky asset portfolio. The risk-minimizing portfolio is expressed through the
highest slope of the CAL, which is the case for the green bond index compared to the
corporate energy index. In both cases, we compared the portfolio allocation with the
10-year treasury bond as a benchmark, and used excess return rates through adjusting for
the risk-free rate. Looking at the 10-year treasury bond and the corporate energy index,
we find Markowitz weights of 0.96838 and 0.031622, respectively, while the weights of
the 10-year treasury bill vs. the green bond index yield a weight allocation of 0.89161 and
0.10839, respectively; i.e., green bond inclusion in a portfolio, given our benchmark, would
be preferable, since a higher Sharpe Ratio would be obtained.
Econometrics 2022, 10, 11 17 of 31
Figure 4. Efficient frontiers of the green bond GBUSTRUU index (GB) and corporate energy I00388US
index (CB). The straight lines reflect the respective capital allocation lines (CAL). Efficient frontiers and
Markowitz efficient weights are computed in MATLAB 2018b with our own script. Fully reproducible
code from the authors is available upon request.
Yi = β 0 + ∑ β k Xk,i + ei (11)
k
The extensions of model 1 are defined by Equation (12) for model 2, which controls for
different sectors, and by Equation (13) for model 3 and model 4, where a further currency
control is included through c = {USD, EUR}.
Regression results for the SRb regression in Table 3 show a positive impact for green
bonds on the bond-specific Sharpe ratios.
Econometrics 2022, 10, 11 18 of 31
Similar to the non-paired regression, we also find a positive impact of green bonds on
the bond-specific Sharpe ratio, i.e., the yield to maturity rates discounted by asset-specific
volatility measures. As Table 4 shows, the differences of green minus conventional bond
SRb are positive and significant in the case of models (1)–(3), and range from 1.79 to 1.54;
only in the case of EUR bonds do we not find a significant positive effect.
Comparing the results from the YTM regression (Table A4 in Appendix C) and the SRb
regression (Table 4), we see that the positive difference for paired green bonds increases
when we add volatility to the indicator. This means that the conventional bond yields that
are discounted by their bond-specific volatility measure show a weaker performance than
their green pairs. Thus, even if we look at a subset of data with similarly paired bonds,
Econometrics 2022, 10, 11 19 of 31
we find evidence that green bonds show lower volatility and are also able to reward the
investor with a better Sharpe ratio.
Different volatilities for the bonds depend highly on sector- and currency-specific
effects. Table 5 and Figure 5 show that the bond-specific volatilities of green bonds in
the energy and the government sectors (especially for the USD case) are significantly
smaller than their conventional matches. These patterns are also currency-sensitive: while
trends are clear for bonds in USD, the observations are less clearly structured for EUR-
denominated bonds. USD bonds in the energy and government sectors also show a clear
trend for different volatility periods: an increasing volatility period (i.e., moving from
the 30-day to the 90-day volatility) also significantly increases the difference of green and
conventional volatilities. Thus, taking finance bonds as the baseline, we find sector-specific
volatility effects that make USD-denominated green bonds less volatile when associated
with energy and government, and especially less volatile when looking over a longer period
of bond price changes.
Table 4. Paired bond regression results for bond-specific Sharpe ratio (SRb).
Figure 5. Analysis 2d—paired bond regression results for bond-specific volatilities (volat).
Econometrics 2022, 10, 11 20 of 31
Table 5. Analysis 2d—paired bond regression results for bond-specific volatilities (volat).
see that (i) the energy sector also appears as a high-volatility classifier for both currencies
(not necessarily as the top one but still appearing as a high-volatility predictor), and that (ii)
the bond type category shows lower volatilities for green bonds in the USD case but does
not appear as a strong predictor for the EUR case (a currency anomaly that we already see
in respect to the multivariate regressions).
Figure 6. Analysis 3—CART results based on the variables and their categories: type (green, con-
ventional (convent)), sectors (energy, finance (Fin), government (Gov), utility (Util)), maturity (long,
short), rating (investment-grade (inv gr), non-investment-grade (non-inv gr)). Results are computed
using R 4.0.3 (R Core Team 2020) and party (v1.3-7; Hothorn 2021). Fully reproducible code from the
authors is available upon request.
The regression results show that there is no clear evidence of a green premium for
bonds in the energy sector. Table 6 shows no significant effects of the green dummy on
yield to maturity rates. However, we do see that volatilities of green bonds are associated
with lower yields (especially in the case of 260d volatilities, as shown by models 1c and
Econometrics 2022, 10, 11 22 of 31
2c, but also in the 90d case of model 1b). This suggests that the volatility risk premium for
brown energy bonds is higher than for green energy bonds, or, said differently, the volatility
of brown bonds is associated with higher risk premia (higher yields) than in the case of
green bonds. This is especially interesting, since Table 7 suggests weak evidence of higher
Sharpe ratios for green bonds. It shows that, in the general case (first three columns with
no currency restriction, models 1a–3a), the bond-specific Sharpe ratio (SRb) is higher by
27.2 bps for a green bond when the 30-day volatility is used for the SR calculation, and by
9.8 bps in the 90-day volatility case; there is also a weak positive effect on the SR in the case
of green bonds issued in USD in the 90-day case (see model 2b).
The evidence of higher SRb for green bonds is weak. However, it has to be noted that
all significant green dummy effects are positive and that no negative effects of greenness
on the SRb have been recorded.
5. Conclusions
The combined findings of a dynamic portfolio model with the comparative, empirical
analysis of green bond data contributes to existing literature. We introduce green and
fossil fuel bonds into the dynamic portfolio framework, using some stylized movements
of returns obtained from a FFT of actual data from the US economy, adjusted to account
for climate policy and externalities. In relation to the portfolio model, we studied patterns
of wealth accumulation on an empirical level by combining recent Sharpe ratio analysis
tools for time series data with a regression-based approach for individual bond data that
has been popularized in the financial market literature. Empirical results reveal positive
financial performance aspects of green investment forms after applying recent financial
risk–return measure methods to aggregate time series indices, and exploring cross-sectional
data of individual bond observations. In any case, the environmental utility of green bonds
our study shows that investors can add green bonds to their portfolios also for economic
reasons. Policymakers can utilize the positive aspects of green financial vehicles for a shift
to a low-carbon economy.
The model-driven results show us that the fossil fuel-based assets—in our case, bonds—
should, if the negative externalities are properly priced in, exhibit empirically low (risk-
adjusted) returns, and possibly higher volatilities. On the other hand, one would expect,
for the green bonds delivering positive externalities in the long-run, higher returns and
lower volatility. Thus, taking externalities into account, green bonds should lead to superior
asset and wealth accumulation as compared to the first type of assets. This should also
lead—as the dynamic portfolio model predicts—to a change of portfolio holdings of the
two types of assets.
In general, the higher potential of asset accumulation is shown by the model-driven
results where certain preferences of individual bond holders (socially-oriented investors,
ESG investors, and social impact investors) allow the additional social returns to arise in
the long run, while not necessarily showing up in the shorter run in the trading of assets,
driven by short-termism and other forces. We can, therefore, have larger asset accumulation
in the case of renewable energy assets, compared to the case of fossil fuel energy, creating
negative externalities; see the upper curve in Figure 2. There should be a (shadow) tax on
fossil fuel energy that makes the return lower; see the lower two graphs. This resembles
earlier studies put forward in microeconomics as positive and negative externality effects,
which have been used in climate-oriented models by Acemoglu et al. (2012), but are here
now applied to bond prices and yields.26
Empirically, though we find heterogeneities for different currencies and sectors, our
econometric analysis concludes that green bonds show lower volatilities and achieve higher
Sharpe ratios (in the paired as well as in the unpaired analysis), which reflects an improved
wealth-accumulating characteristic of green bonds. Especially the comparative performance
of green vs non-green bonds in the energy sector shows the strongest differences with
regards to volatilities and Sharpe ratios. In particular, in the results of the regression
analysis of paired bonds, there are significant and positive secondary market yield effects
of green bonds. Yet, this effect is also ambiguous since unmatched yield to maturity rates
show significant negative yield differentials of green bonds (the conclusion for primary
market yields is, due to a weaker data availability, less clear).
There are certain reasons for the ambiguities and for why a gap persists between the
model-driven results and the empirics in some instances: different preferences of market
participants, that little information on the positive and negative externalities is integrated
into the actual trading, and that the green bond market represents an evolving market.
There seems to still be a steep learning curve to pricing green assets properly.
Our econometric results are, thus, mixed. The results, supported by previous findings
of the literature, show evidence of a negative yield differential of green minus conventional
bonds in the primary market, but positive yield differentials for a paired-bond analysis in
the case of the secondary market. A more distinctive result is obtained for the Sharpe ratio.
Our study shows that green bonds show a higher bond-specific Sharpe ratio in several
Econometrics 2022, 10, 11 24 of 31
regression designs, which makes green bonds an attractive investment form. Especially
due to lower volatilities, as identified with the CART and some cases in the regression
analysis, green bonds can help to improve the portfolios of investors and help to achieve
sustainable wealth accumulation. Moreover, the energy sector-specific analysis shows weak
evidence of an improved Sharpe ratio of green bonds, which points towards better volatility
discounted returns of green bonds compared to brown, i.e., fossil fuel-based, bonds.
Please note that, in this study, as in Semmler et al. (2020), by using the NMPC program
of asset accumulation, the returns for risky assets are made time-dependent, but they can
also be defined as impacted by stochastic shocks along their paths. Empirically estimated
low-frequency movements in returns are estimated and built into a dynamic portfolio
model; see Chiarella et al. (2016). An outlook for a stochastic version of the model is
also presented in Appendix B, considering a smaller shock to green bond returns or a
larger shock to fossil fuel returns. Our empirical results show that fossil fuel assets are
more risky, with higher volatility, while green bonds may have lower returns but also a
lower standard deviation and a higher Sharpe ratio. The results for the case with a smaller
shock do not differ significantly from the deterministic version in Figure 2, and are, thus,
more easily predictable and less risky. The trajectory for the case with a larger standard
deviation contains more statistical noise as per higher asset values. Overall, mobilizing
financial resources for climate protection is an important task. The results of this study
show compelling evidence for the beneficial usage of green bonds, compared to other forms
of investment.
The approach used in this research can also be used to control sovereign debt as much
as sovereign bonds are convertible into some equity. This is an important issue, since
many observers express the criticism that issuing green bonds for climate protection will
futher increase the debt to GDP ratio, leading to unsustainable levels of debt. This does
not need to occur if (shadow) tax rates are properly levied on returns from fossil fuel
assets and aid to provide incentives to create positive externalities of renewable energy.
The use of convertible bonds that turn into equity holdings when renewable energy firms
are successful helps reduce the debt of a sovereign issuer of bonds.27
Author Contributions: Conceptualization, A.L., J.P.B. and W.S.; Data curation, A.L. and J.P.B.; Formal
analysis, J.P.B.; Investigation, A.L.; Methodology, A.L. and W.S.; Project administration, A.L. and
J.P.B.; Software, A.L. and J.P.B.; Supervision, W.S.; Visualization, A.L. and J.P.B.; Writing—original
draft, A.L., J.P.B. and W.S.; Writing—review & editing, A.L., J.P.B. and W.S. All authors have read and
agreed to the published version of the manuscript.
Funding: This research received no external funding.
Institutional Review Board Statement: Not applicable.
Informed Consent Statement: Not applicable.
Data Availability Statement: Data for the econometric analysis as well as the harmonic estimations
were obtained from the Bloomberg Terminal.
Acknowledgments: We acknowledge the valuable comments of the two anonymous referees and the
managing editor for this Special Issue. Additionally, we appreciate the feedback and helpful sug-
gestions from participants at the IAC CAFRAD seminar series 2021, EUROFRAME 2021 conference,
and the FMM 2021 conference on the Macroeconomics of Socio-Ecological Transition. All remaining
errors are ours.
Conflicts of Interest: The authors declare no conflict of interest.
generates low-frequency movements using the monthly annual total returns for green and
fossil fuel monthly returns from December 2015 to December 2020 for the US:
k
2π 2π
y(t) = ∑(ai sin( τi (t − to )) + bi cos(
τi
(t − to ))). (A1)
i =i
As described by Semmler and Hsiao (2011), the first step to apply the FFT method is
to de-trend the real returns for each index in the time series. We, thus, subtract a linear
trend from the real returns:
The linear trend coefficients (b1 and b2 ) are obtained by a polynomial curve p( x ) of
degree 1 that returns the best fit (in a least-square sense) for the real returns data. The values
for t and t0 depend on the period covered by the time series. The FFT method picks up
the periods with the highest power (τi ). We obtain, then, the coefficients ai and bi for the
harmonic fit for the different values of k and the τi for the different periods (in months),
as in Equation (A1).
N −1
max E(
{us ,cs ,πs }
∑ δ(s−t) F (cs Ws , us Ws )), (A3)
t =0
s.t.
W (t + 1) = W (t) + {[πt rte‘green + (1 − πt )rte‘f ossil f uel − (ut + ct )]W (t) − X (Πt , Wt ) + (ψ + δlog( x3 (t)))rte‘i }, (A4)
bonds. Additionaly, climate risks are expected to affect strongly stranded fossil-fuel assets.
The greater σ represents, thus, the potential risks involved with holding fossil fuel assets.
For the case with α = 0.034, the trajectory with a larger standard deviation is much more
noisy, reaching higher asset values, while the simulations with a smaller shock are more
easily predictable, and thus, are less risky (Figure A1). Our empirical results show that
fossil fuel assets are more risky, with higher volatility, while green bonds have lower returns
but also lower standard deviations (and thus, a higher Sharpe ratio).
Figure A1. Stochastic version of the model shown in Figure 2 (σ(SD ) = 0.05 for green bonds;
σ(SD ) = 0.25 for fossil fuel bonds; α = 0.034).
However, the stochastic model is based on a discrete-time system and is solved with
small steps, which demands more iterations to reach a similar outcome. Nevertheless,
the use of the deterministic case, as shown in Figure 2, is a good proxy for the market
dynamics. In the stochastic case, there are market shocks to returns which can generate
multiple paths for the evolution of portfolio wealth. Yet, the overall direction of outcomes,
especially in the case with a lower shock, shows close similarity to the deterministic case
showing now, however, different paths for the different realizations of shocks.
Table A3. Analysis 2a—Paired bond regression results for yield at issue.
Table A4. Analysis 2b—Paired bond regression results for yield to maturity.
Notes
1 For example, short-termism in the financial market has been shown to be a roadblock; see Davies et al. (2014), Semmler et al. (2020).
2 For a survey, see Semmler et al. (2021).
3 However, one should note that there are still methodological challenges related to information asymmetry on the pricing
externality effects of conventional and green financial assets (Berg et al. 2019; Candelon et al. 2021a).
4 In economics, harmonic estimations can capture the business cycle feature of prices, industrial production, employment, and asset
returns. For the potential application of harmonic estimations, see Artis et al. (2007).
5 Respectively, the Bloomberg Barclays MSCI US Global Green Bond in USD (GBUSTRUU) and the Bloomberg Barclays US
Corporate Energy in USD (I00388US).
6 The harmonic estimations are obtained using a FFT. As described in Appendix A, we first de-trend the time series for the real
asset returns, and then we are able to apply the FFT in order to filter out short-term movements by estimating the coefficients for
a linear combination of a sine–cosine function, based on the original data. The harmonic regression model is estimated for six
different frequencies. We select the estimation with the lowest sum of squared errors.
7 Note that, in order to avoid additional state variables defining stocks of innovation capacity, we undertake a shortcut and let the
respective innovations be driven by the respective fraction of wealth. Simulations could be undertaken with various fractions
of νt .
8 We also want to note that the weights w1 and (1 − w1 ) of the two parts of the objective functions in Equations (3) and (5) can be
varied, and some Pareto frontier can be computed to explore which weights are the realistic ones (see Kaya and Maurer 2014).
Econometrics 2022, 10, 11 29 of 31
9 Risk aversion and discount rates have been explored in terms of their relevance to portfolio dynamics in chapters 4–5 in Chiarella
et al. (2016).
10 See Davies et al. (2014) for a discussion of stranded assets.
11 For details, see (Cochrane et al. 2001, chp. 19), where the bond price is solved for solving the appropriate discount rate forward.
In the portfolio context, see (Semmler 2011, chp. 17.5).
12 It might help to support green start-up firms, ensuring a minimum return if the business does not succeed but high returns if it
does. If we think in terms of green treasury bonds, it can help to reduce sovereign debt due to debt to equity swaps.
13 Both indices were also used for the harmonic estimations and the portfolio model.
14 It would be ideal for the analyis of long-term bonds to work with a longer trajectory of data. However, the market of green bonds
is still new and developing, and due to these market limitations, as well as to constraints in the data availability, we decided to
work with data from the period of January 2017 to October 2020.
15 We abbreviate volatility measures for these 30-, 90-, and 260-day ranges by writing 30d, 90d, and 260d, respectively.
16 In our empirical analysis, we compared the bond-specific Sharpe ratio results with and without the risk-free rate for the two
most frequent currencies (USD and EUR), and did not find a relevant change (differences in the size of the second or the third
digit after the decimal). Hence, for simplicity, we do not consider the risk-free rate in our analysis when reporting results on the
bond-specific Sharpe ratio SRb.
17 Even though the formal computation of the RSRL does not require computing the efficient frontier first, Candelon et al. (2021b)
used efficient portfolio returns in the computation of the RSRL to connect their analysis to the real estate literature.
18 YAI values showed few outliers and only observations above the 99th percentile were truncated. In terms of YTM observations,
values below the 2.5th percentile and above the 97.5th percentile were truncated. The SRb was calculated based on the filtered
YTM and volatility values and outliers below the 2.5th percentile and above the 97.5th percentile were truncated.
19 e.g., the bond price volatility variable only appears in YTM regressions since YAI is the recorded bond yield at the time of bond
issuance and its value is arguably not dependent on bond price changes of the more recent past, and SRb already includes
information on bond volatility in its denominator.
20 In order to reduce the impact of outliers, bid-ask spread observations below the 1st and above the 99th percentile were truncated.
21 We define long-term bonds similar to Kapraun and Scheins (2019), who categorize them as bonds with a maturity structure
of more than ten years (or, see https://www.thebalance.com/choosing-bond-fund-term-416948 (accessed on 18 September
2021)). Our non-long-term bonds include bonds with a maturity structure of 10 years or less and subsume short-term and
intermediate-term bonds. In order to reduce the influence of outliers, we excluded observations with a maturity structure of
more than 100 years.
22 In order to reduce the impact of outliers, coupon rate observations below the 1st and above the 99th percentile were truncated.
23 In order to reduce the impact of outliers, amount issued observations above the 97.5th percentile were truncated.
24 Since the subset of bonds for the energy sector offers less observations than our total sample, we reduced the date issued control
from a year-quarter combination to a yearly dummy.
25 Our energy-specific subset of data did not have enough observations to run regressions with the YAI rate.
26 Of course, as Kapraun and Scheins (2019) also argue, once the bonds are traded, there might be a multiplicity of drivers of actual
bond prices and yields; for example, relevant are the actual activities in portfolio management, monetary policy and interest
rates, varying risk premia, and also for other assets, the varying Distance to Default, and more.
27 For a further discussion of the utility of convertible bonds, see Section 5.2 of the WB report of Semmler et al. (2021)
28 The new parameters are set as follows: ρ̄ = 0.9; ψ = 0.01; δ = 0.05.
29 We carried out all analyses with all three different volatility measures, but for the matter of simplicity (and unless specified,
as in the case of analysis 4 on the energy sector), we only report regressions with the 90-day volatility measure. Results for the
different volatility measures are similar and are available upon request. In order to reduce the impact of outliers, the 90d volatility
observations above the 95th percentile were truncated.
References
Ardia, David, and Kris Boudt. 2015. Testing equality of modified Sharpe ratios. Finance Research Letters 13: 97–104. [CrossRef]
Acemoglu, Daron, Philippe Aghion, Leonardo Bursztyn, and David Hemous. 2012. The environment and directed technical change.
American Economic Review 102: 131–66. [CrossRef] [PubMed]
Artis, Michael J., José G. Clavel, Mathias Hoffmann, and Dilip Nachane. 2007. Harmonic regression models: A comparative review
with applications Working paper series. Institute for Empirical Research in Economics 2007: 333.
Bachelet, Maria J., Leonardo Becchetti, and Stefano Manfredonia. 2019. The Green Bonds Premium Puzzle: The Role of Issuer
Characteristics and Third-Party Verification. Sustainability 11: 1098. [CrossRef]
Barro, Robert J., and Xavier I. Sala-i-Martin. 2004. Economic Growth. Cambridge and London: The MIT Press.
Econometrics 2022, 10, 11 30 of 31
Berg, Florian, Julian F. Koelbel, and Roberto Rigobon. 2019. Aggregate Confusion: The Divergence of ESG Ratings. Cambridge: MIT Sloan
School of Management.
Campbell, John Y., and Luis M. Viceira. 2002. Strategic Asset Allocation: Portfolio Choice for Long-Term Investors (Clarendon Lectures
in Economics). Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Candelon, Bertrand, Jean-Baptiste Hasse, and Quentin Lajaunie. 2021a. ESG-Washing in the Mutual Funds Industry? From Information
Asymmetry to Regulation. Risks 9: 199. [CrossRef]
Candelon, Bertrand, Franz Fuerst, and Jean-Baptiste Hasse. 2021b. Diversification potential in real estate portfolios. International
Economics 166: 126–39. [CrossRef]
Chiarella, Carl, Willi Semmler, Chih-Ying Hsiao, and Lebogang Mateane. 2016. Sustainable Asset Accumulation. and Dynamic Portfolio
Decisions. Berlin/Heidelberg: Springer.
Cochrane, John H. 2001. Asset Pricing. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Davies, Richard, Andrew G. Haldane, Mette Nielsen, and W. Silvia Pezzini. 2014. Measuring the costs of short-termism. Journal of
Financial Stability 12: 25. [CrossRef]
Ehlers, Torsten, and Frank Packer. 2017. Green bond finance and certification. BIS Quarterly Review 2017: 89–104.
Engle, Robert F., Stefano Giglio, Bryan Kelly, Heebum Lee, and Johannes Stroebel. 2020. Hedging climate change news. The Review of
Financial Studies 33: 1184–216. [CrossRef]
Favre, Laurent, and José-Antonio Galeano. 2002. Mean-modified value-at-risk with hedge funds. The Journal of Alternative Investments 5:
21–25. [CrossRef]
Flammer, Caroline. 2021. Corporate green bonds. Journal of Financial Economics 142: 499–516. [CrossRef]
Gregoriou, Greg, and Jean-Pierre Gueyie. 2003. Risk-adjusted performance of funds of hedge funds using a modified Sharpe ratio. The
Journal of Wealth Management 6: 77–83. [CrossRef]
Gregory, Aidan. 2020. “Nascent” Green Convertible Bond Market Is Cause for Optimism. Global Capital. July 23. Available on-
line: https://www.globalcapital.com/article/28mu9tpjsiu015prdxb7k/equity-linked/nascent-green-convertible-bond-market-
is-cause-for-optimism (accessed on 20 September 2020).
Greiner, Alfred, Willi Semmler, and Gang Gong. 2005. The Forces of Economic Growth. Princeton: Princeton University. [CrossRef]
Gruene, Lars, Willi Semmler, and Marleen Stieler. 2015. Using nonlinear model predictive control for dynamic decision problems in
economics. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 60: 112–33. [CrossRef]
Hachenberg, Britta, and Dirk Schiereck. 2018. Are green bonds priced differently from conventional bonds? Journal of Asset Management
19: 371–83. [CrossRef]
Hall, Bronwyn H., Jacques Mairesse, and Pierre Mohnen. 2010. Measuring the Returns to R&D. Handbook of the Economics of Innovation
2: 1033–82.
Han, Yingwei, and Jie Li. 2022. Should investors include green bonds in their portfolios? Evidence for the USA and Europe. International
Review of Financial Analysis 80: 1057–5219. [CrossRef]
Hasse, Jean-Baptiste. 2021. DiversificationR: Econometric Tools to Measure Portfolio Diversification. R Package. Available online:
https://cran.r-project.org/web/packages/DiversificationR/index.html (accessed on 15 January 2022).
Hothorn, Torsten, Kurt Hornik, Carolin Strobl, and Achim Zeileis. 2021. Party: A Laboratory for Recursive Partytioning. R Package
Version 1.3-7. Available online: https://CRAN.R-project.org/package=party (accessed on 8 May 2021).
Huynh, Thanh, and Ying Xia. 2021. Climate change news risk and corporate bond returns. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis
56: 1985–2009. [CrossRef]
Immel, Moritz Immel, Britta Hachenberg, Florian Kiesel, and Dirk Schiereck. 2020. Green bonds: Shades of green and brown. Journal of
Asset Management 22: 96–109. [CrossRef]
Jones, Benjamin F., and Lawrence H. Summers. 2020. A Calculation of the Social Returns to Innovation. No w27863. National Bureau of
Economic Research. Available online: https://www.nber.org/papers/w27863 (accessed on 8 May 2021).
Kaya, C. Yalcin, and Helmut Maurer. 2014. A numerical method for nonconvex multi-objective optimal control problems. Computational
Optimization and Applications 57: 685–702. [CrossRef]
Kapraun, Julia, and Christopher Scheins. 2019. (In)-Credibly Green: Which Bonds Trade at a Green Bond Premium? SSRN Electronic
Journal doi: 10.2139/ssrn.3347337. [CrossRef]
Ledoit, Oliver, and Michael Wolf. 2008. Robust performance hypothesis testing with the Sharpe ratio. Journal of Empirical Finance 15:
850–9. [CrossRef]
Leibowicz, Benjamin D. 2018. Welfare improvement windows for innovation policy. Research Policy 47: 390–98. [CrossRef]
Lintner, John. 1965. Security prices, risk, and maximal gains from diversification. The Journal of Finance 20: 587–615.
Löffler, Kristin Ulrike, Aleksandar Petreski, and Andreas Stephan. 2021. Drivers of green bond issuance and new evidence on the
“greenium”. Eurasian Economic Review 11: 1–24. [CrossRef]
MacAskill, Stefen, Eduardo Roca, Benjamin Liu, Rodney Anthony Stewart, and Oz Sahin. 2021. Is there a green premium in the green
bond market? Systematic literature review revealing premium determinants. Journal of Cleaner Production 280: 124491. [CrossRef]
Markowitz, Harry. 1952. The utility of wealth. Journal of Political Economy 60: 151–58. [CrossRef]
Merton, Robert C. 1973. An Intertemporal Capital Asset Pricing Model. Econometrica 41: 867887. [CrossRef]
Munk, Claus. 2012. Dynamic Asset Allocation. Lecture Notes. Available online: https://sites.google.com/view/clausmunk/teaching
(accessed on 6 June 2021).
Econometrics 2022, 10, 11 31 of 31
Nisbet, Robert, Gary Miner, and Ken Yale. 2018. Handbook of Statistical Analysis and Data Mining Applications. Amsterdam; Elsevier;
Cambridge: Academic Press.
Pham, Linh, and Canh Phuc Nguyen. 2021. How do stock, oil, and economic policy uncertainty influence the green bond market?
Finance Research Letters 102128: 1544–6123. [CrossRef]
Piñeiro-Chousa, Juan, M. Ange;es López-Cabarcos, Jerome Caby, and Aleksandar Šević. 2021. The influence of investor sentiment on
the green bond market. Technological Forecasting and Social Change 162: 120351. [CrossRef]
R Core Team. 2020. R: A Language and Environment for Statistical Computing. In R Foundation for Statistical Computing. Vienna,
Austria: R Core Team. Available online: https://www.R-project.org/ (accessed on 30 October 2021).
Romer, Paul M. 1986. Increasing returns and long-run growth. Journal of Political Economy 94: 1002–37. [CrossRef]
Semmler, Willi. 2011. Asset Prices, Booms and Recessions: Financial Economics from a Dynamic Perspective. Berlin/Heidelberg: Springer
Science & Business Media.
Semmler, Willi, and Chih-Ying Hsiao. 2011. Dynamic Consumption and Portfolio Decisions with Estimated Low Frequency Movements
of Asset Returns. The Journal of Wealth Management 14: 101–11. [CrossRef]
Semmler, Willi, K. Lessman, and I. Tahri. 2020. Energy Transition, Asset Price Fluctuations, and Dynamic Portfolio Decisions. Available
online: Https://ssrn.com/abstract=3688293 (accessed on 8 May 2021). [CrossRef]
Semmler, Willi, Joao Paulo Braga, Andreas Lichtenberger, Marieme Toure, and Erin Haider. 2021. Fiscal Policies for a Low-Carbon
Economy. Washington, DC: World Bank.
Sharpe, William F. 1964. Capital asset prices: A theory of market equilibrium under conditions of risk. The Journal of Finance 19: 425–42.
Sharpe, William F. 1994. The Sharpe ratio. Journal of Portfolio Management 21: 49–58. [CrossRef]
Tiwari, Aviral Kumar, Emmanuel Joel Aikins Abakah, David Gabauer, and Richard Adjei Dwumfour. 2022. Dynamic spillover effects
among green bond, renewable energy stocks and carbon markets during COVID-19 pandemic: Implications for hedging and
investments strategies. Global Finance Journal 51: 100692. [CrossRef]
Tobin, James. 1958. Liquidity preference as behavior towards risk. The Review of Economic Studies 25: 65–86. [CrossRef]