L2 Baldwin
L2 Baldwin
org)
Home > Globalisation 1.0 and 2.0 helped the G7. Globalisation 3.0 helped India and China instead. What will Globalisation 4.0 do?
Globalisation 1.0 and 2.0 helped the G7. Globalisation 3.0 helped
India and China instead. What will Globalisation 4.0 do?
Richard Baldwin 21 January 2019
Richard Baldwin describes how digital technology is allowing people and companies to arbitrage large relative price differences in wages
across countries, offering an enormous export opportunity for developing nations.
Related
Globalisation leapt forward in the late 19th century when steam power slashed the costs of moving goods internationally. This ‘old
globalisation’ came in two waves. Globalisation 1.0 started in 1820 and ended at the start of WWI, and Globalisation 2.0 began after WWII
and ended around 1990.1 In between, globalisation retreated.
Old globalisation was especially beneficial to today’s rich nations. The G7 (France, Germany, Italy, Britain, US, Japan, and Canada) saw
rapid growth of their exports, incomes, and industry compared to today's poor nations. This led to what Kenneth Pomeranz, a historian,
calls the Great Divergence.
The G7’s share of world GDP soared from one-fifth in 1820 to two-thirds in 1988. Its share of world trade rose to more than 50% (Figure 1).
Enormous differences in income between rich and poor nations first emerged at this time.
Figure 1 Spot the difference: Globalisations 1.0 and 2.0 (blue) and 3.0 (red)
Note: Gross domestic product (GDP) is a measure of a country’s total economic output and income.
Source: Author’s elaboration of Maddison online data.
The impact of Globalisation 1.0 on the global distribution of industry was equally shocking, as Figure 2 shows. Britain was the first
industrialiser. It maintained a massive lead until 1900, when it was surpassed by the US. The other G7 nations took off in the mid-to-late
1800s. Since the emergence of human civilisation, China, India-Pakistan and other ancient nations had been the leading industrial powers.
But as the G7 industrialised, these ancient nations de-industrialised.
Globalisation 1.0 drove northern industrialisation and southern de-industrialisation. This is not as widely known as it should be, but it has
long been recognised. As Simon Kuznets wrote in 1965:
“Before the 19th century and perhaps not much before it, some presently underdeveloped countries, notably China and parts of India,
were believed by Europeans to be more highly developed than Europe” (Kuznets 1965:20, cited in Baldwin and Martin 1999).2
What happened to the landscape of global manufacturing? Figure 3 shows that the G7 nations lost share gradually between 1970 and
1990, followed by an accelerated decline from 1990. To where did manufacturing go? Just six developing nations – which we might call the
‘Rapidly Industrialising 6’, or I6 for short – accounted for almost all of it. The I6 are China, Korea, India, Poland, Indonesia and Thailand.
China stands out. It gained almost 16 percentage points of world manufacturing in just 20 years.
Figure 3 Most of the G7’s share loss in manufacturing went to just seven rapidly industrialising nations
Source: UNSTAT.org.
To understand why globalisation today acts differently to its effect in the 20th century, we need a broader framework for thinking about
globalisation and the things that drive it. This was the theme of my 2016 book, The Great Convergence: Information Technology and the
New Globalisation.
This framework also helps us think about the effect that Globalisation 4.0 will have.
goods,
ideas,
people,
services, and
capital
move from one nation to another. Globalisation matters because these flows affect our jobs, salaries, income distributions, and so on.
(Many more things cross borders, but these are the main flows we are interested in when we analyse economic globalisation.)
But this list is too long. We should simplify to clarify. As Karl Popper said: “Science may be described as the art of systematic over-
simplification.” So if we want to understand how the flows affect economies and people, it is useful to narrow the list.
Capital is quite different from the other flows and so we set it aside. When services cross borders, they are either ideas (say, architectural
plans) or embedded in goods (say, diamonds that have been skilfully cut in India). This means we can lump services in with either ideas
and goods. this leaves us with three flows: goods, ideas, and people.
The next natural question is, what drives globalisation? The answer is equally simple. Globalisation is driven by arbitrage.
When companies exploit price differences – buying low and selling high – we get international trade. Companies buy what is relatively
cheap in Germany and sell it in China and buy what is relatively cheap in China and sell it in Germany. Trade is driven by a two-way buy-
low, sell-high arbitrage. This is not a new idea – David Ricardo was writing about it in 1817. There is also arbitrage in ideas and people. As
we saw, arbitrage of knowhow was particularly important in Globalisation 3.0.
Globalisation has been driven by reductions in the costs of moving goods, ideas and people, because when these costs fall, so does the
cost of separating production and consumption geographically. But, to understand globalisation, we need to distinguish the costs of
separation for each. Since the early 19th century, all three have fallen, but not at the same time. Shipping costs fell dramatically 150 years
before communication costs did. Face-to-face interactions remain costly, even today. This shaped how globalisation evolved.
To understand this, we can be guided in a gallop through the history of trade by a thought framework that I call the 'three cascading
constraints' (3CC) view of globalisation.
This isolation meant that the world economy was little more than a patchwork of village-level economies. The extreme separation of
production hindered innovation, because small-scale production meant innovation was worth little to the innovator, and their dispersion
meant that it was difficult for innovation to spread quickly. Modern growth, in other words, was stymied until Globalisation 1.0 took off.
The cost of moving goods was the first of the three to fall dramatically. From the early 19th century, steam power and transport
technologies improved in a process that helped create, and was helped by, the Industrial Revolution.
With cheaper international shipping, more people bought goods from far away. Kevin O’Rourke and Jeff Williamson, two economists of the
history of trade, date this to 1820. But while shipping got cheaper, the cost of moving ideas and people fell much less. This unbalanced
reduction in arbitrage costs triggered a sequence of changes that had a huge effect on the global economy:
1. As markets expanded globally, industry clustered locally. These clusters were in today’s developed nations. Today’s developing
nations de-industrialised.
2. Northern industrialisation triggered northern innovation, which stimulated northern growth. But ideas were costly to move, and so
northern innovations stayed in the north. The result was a vast imbalance in knowledge-per-worker ratios between the global north
and the global south. The localisation of innovation also meant that growth took-off later in today’s poor nations, and was slower
afterwards.
3. The growth differences between north and south generated the colossal, north-south income asymmetry that we still see today.
Globalisation accelerated again around 1990, when the ICT revolution radically lowered the cost of moving ideas. Globalisation’s second
unbundling – the geographic separation of each manufacturing stage, organised in 'global value chains' (GVCs) – became feasible when
the ICT revolution made it possible to organise complex activities at distance. The north-south wage gap inherited from the first unbundling
made this offshoring profitable.
Nature abhors a vacuum, economies abhor imbalances. It became cheaper to move ideas, and so this inevitably triggered massive north-
to-south flows of knowhow, which reconfigured the world economy as shown by the red lines in Figure 1. This new-style globalisation –
where high-tech moved to places where there was low-wage labour – turned the first unbundling on its head. It de-industrialised the north
and industrialised the south. Growth slowed in the north and accelerated in the south.
The knowledge that is moving north to south mostly belongs to firms based in the G7. Firms in the G7 have invested in GVCs to ensure
that they profit from the new ICT-enabled possibilities. The 21st-century contours of knowledge are increasingly defined by the geography
of the GVCs, rather than the geography of nations.
The 3CC view of globalisation argues that this outcome depends on the cost of moving people, not goods or ideas. Aeroplane fares have
fallen, but the time-cost of travel has continued to rise because we need to factor in the salaries of managers and technicians. Since it is
still expensive to move people around – and international production networks still need people to move among facilities – most advanced
manufacturing still occurs in nations that are close to the G7 industrial powerhouses, especially Germany, Japan and the US. India is an
exception, but this is because India has engaged in international production networks for which face-to-face contact is less important.
The industrialisation impact of the second unbundling was hyper-concentrated, but the Great Convergence is much broader because of the
knock-on effects of the rapid industrialisation of the I6. About half of the world's population lives in the I6, so rapid income growth has
triggered a boom in demand for raw materials. This, in turn, triggered the ‘commodity super-cycle’ that led to growth take-offs in
commodity-exporting nations. In other words, the second unbundling (Globalisation 3.0) drove growth in many developing nations that
were untouched directly by GVCs.
I have summarised the 3CC narrative in Figure 4. It's clear that a third unbundling becomes possible if face-to-face costs plummet. And
that, in my view, is what Globalisation 4.0 is all about.
Arbitrage of goods and ideas will continue, but there will be a new, disruptive aspect called 'tele-migration'. People will sit in one nation,
while working in offices in another nation.
There is a simple driving force for this arbitrage. Salaries and wages for this type of work are much higher in rich nations. Hundreds of
millions, maybe billions, of people in poor nations would like to earn those wages. Today that is not technically possible, because there is a
high face-to-face cost, and we still need in-person interactions in many service and professional jobs. If digital technology relaxes this third
constraint on the global arbitrage of wage-rate differences, as I think this will, it would be a big change.
If digital technology allows people in poor nations to offer their labour services in advanced economies without actually having to be there,
a lot of people in advanced economies could lose their jobs. The necessary technology is already on the way. This is the topic of my new
book, The Globotics Upheaval: Globalisation, Robotics and the Future of Work.
A third unbundling
The service sector in G7 nations has been shielded from globalisation because most services require face-to-face contact. Times are
changing.
The third unbundling is unfolding before our eyes. It is all about processing and transmitting information. Laws of physics governing goods
do not govern data. The explosive growth of digital technology creates the possibility of remote intelligence (RI). Digital technology is
tearing down the barriers to arbitrage in labour services.
Firms already hire remote knowledge workers abroad at lower wages. As more companies in rich nations source labour this way, the
matchmaking network will grow. Many companies in the US and Europe seem unaware of the possibilities, or maybe they are hesitant to
explore what the consequences may be. But once a firm’s competitors start using low-cost foreign labour, competition will accelerate the
process.
Talented foreign workers will increasingly use digital platforms like Upwork.com, looking for work, and companies that use them will join the
platforms, looking for remote workers. My guess is that tipping-point economics will define the progress of global outsourcing of services.
Once people begin to trust these platforms – as they have rapidly come to trust internet services like Airbnb and Uber – it will snowball into
something very big, very fast.
Tele-migration will allow people with skills in developing nations to export their services directly. This may allow the emerging market
miracle to continue, but also to spread to many nations that until now have only been able to export commodities.
An accelerating process
The first two globalisations helped the G7 nations and hindered the developing nations – at least in a relative sense. Until 1990, most rich
nations grew faster than most poor nations. This is because it was easy to ship goods, but difficult to ship knowhow.
Offshoring manufacturing fostered innovation and rising competitiveness in the G7 nations, but the opposite in developing nations.
Coordinating complex activities was too expensive, and so the knowledge stayed in the G7, despite the very large imbalances. The ICT
revolution opened a way for G7 firms to arbitrage the big differences in knowhow-to-labour ratios that were responsible for wage
differences.
Now digital technology is allowing people and companies to arbitrage large relative price differences in wages. This will be an enormous
export opportunity for developing nations – especially ones, like India and China, that have fast internet in urban areas and millions of
workers with recognisable skills that companies and people in rich countries would like to buy. Tele-migration will also be an export
opportunity for many in the rich nations since competition in services is not always won by the cheapest. Quality and reliability still matter.
Will the Great Convergence continue? Will the G7’s share of world GDP continue to decline, and India’s and China’s continue to rise? The
answer to both questions is yes. The nature of future globalisation will great accelerate the process.
References
Baldwin, R (2016), The Great Convergence: Information Technology and the New Globalization, Belknap Press of Harvard University
Press.
Baldwin, R (2019), The Globotics Upheaval: Globalisation, Robotics and the Future of Work, Oxford University Press.
Baldwin, R, P Martin and G Ottaviano (2001), "Global Income Divergence, Trade, and Industrialization: The Geography of Growth Take-
Offs", Journal of Economic Growth 6(1): 5-37.
Braudel, F (1984), Civilisation and Capitalism, 15th-18th Century: The Perspective of the World. vol 3, Harper and Row.
Chaudhuri, K N (1966), "India’s Foreign Trade and the Cessation of the East India Company’s Trading Activities, 1828-40", Economic
History Review 19(2): 345-63.
Endnotes
[1] We could probably describe pre-modern globalisation – the opening of the Silk Road in 200 BCE, the golden age of Islam (8th to 14th
centuries), or the European age of discovery (15th to 17th centuries) – as beta globalisation, or maybe Globalisation 0.0. It was very
different, because it had a negligible impact on the living standards of the masses.
[2] Braudel (1984) and Chaudhuri (1966) show that, during the 18th century, the Indian cotton textile industry was the global leader in terms
of quality, production and exports. 18th-century India and China also produced the world’s highest-quality silk and porcelain. Before the
18th century, these manufactured goods were exported to Europe in exchange for silver, as European manufactures were uncompetitive in
the East (Barraclough 1978). Clearly, the civilisations that invented gunpowder, paper and aids for oceanic navigation were by no means
primitive societies, waiting for Europe to industrialise.