The Ethiopian Economy - at A Cross Road APRIL-2018: Ermyas Amelga
The Ethiopian Economy - at A Cross Road APRIL-2018: Ermyas Amelga
The Ethiopian Economy - at A Cross Road APRIL-2018: Ermyas Amelga
Overview
The Ethiopian economy is in the midst of a financial and economic crisis that
threatens to derail and reverse the dramatic economic growth and development it
has achieved over the last 15 years.
While the entire nation has been distracted and preoccupied with the political
situation, the economy has deteriorated to a point of collapse. It is displaying all the
symptoms of a grossly out of equilibrium and deteriorating economy. These include
acute and chronic foreign exchange shortages, high and accelerating inflation and
declining economic activity.
The imbalances have reached a tipping point where economic activity across all
sectors of the economy has stalled. At the same time, inflation in the economy has
remerged at an alarming and accelerating rate. We have stagflation. It is among
the most problematic of economic problems to resolve as the policy prescriptions to
address one exacerbate the other, thereby, driving the economy into a circular
recessionary cycle.
Give the massive scale of the investment capital required and the equally daunting
and well known implementation capacity gaps of the state, the failure to have a
financial plan is inexplicable.
By chance, as GTP-1 got underway eight years ago, a variety of favorable internal
and external conditions coalesced into a receptive developing country debt market
that was particularly keen on Africa and its Rising Lions. Ethiopia was at the top of
the list of Rising Lions and was able to borrow freely and especially so from China.
It even managed to issue a billion dollar Eurobond under these favorable
conditions. GTP-1&2 ended up being fueled by large amounts of foreign debt.
Corrective policy measures are urgently needed to restore economic activity and
balance. Fiscal and monetary policy cannot be restrictive but we must manage
inflation and the current account balance. The economy needs a large (non-debt)
foreign currency infusion and a liberalization of the exchange rate regime to a
managed float (it can be done). The large sunk costs in projects underway must be
salvaged. The collapse in aggregate demand caused by the collapse in public and
private investment must be reversed. We are facing stagflation in a poor
underdeveloped debt burdened economy. Seems like mission impossible but its
not.
Fortunately, in Ethiopia’s case, there is a viable path out of this mess. Privatization,
even if only partially, of a few large state owned enterprises (“SOE’s”) can finance
all of the GTP objectives.
Privatization will not just solve the GTP’s financing problem, a worthy enough
accomplishment in its self, but would also help address macroeconomic problems.
These include funding/driving aggregate demand, financing aggregate investment,
solving the foreign exchange shortage, rebalancing the balance of payments,
dampening inflation and reviving general economic activity. May seem improbable
but its not.
In the context of the huge financing needs to fulfill the plans under the GTP,
privatization represents an excellent means of cashing out on the accumulated net
worth of Ethiopia’s SOE’s. Indeed, there is arguably no more justifiable use of this
accumulated net worth than spending it on the GTP that the government itself
believes is worthy of supreme sacrifice from all corners of society.
We need look no further then the debt fueled booms and busts witnessed in Latin
America in the 1970’s and ‘80’s to see what the alternative is. It took Latin
American countries decades to recover.
I will review the theoretical foundations of GTP-1&2 and examine the shortcomings
in strategy and policy that that have brought the economy to this point. From there,
I suggest a package of reform measures that would be appropriate in response.
Every economy in the world started its journey of growth and development from
poverty. Underdeveloped economies such as Ethiopia’s are characterized
by backwardness and poor utilization of resources.
Prime Minister Meles was a believer in the Big Push or Developmental State
strategy and it is the framework for Ethiopia's ongoing "Growth and
Transformation" plan.
The theory stresses the need for planned industrialization of under developed
economies where backward and poverty riddled agriculture is the dominant sector.
The state takes the lead in creating high levels of aggregate demand in the
economy by financing and undertaking a high minimum quantum of investment in
infrastructure and interdependent industries to enlarge the size of the market. This
economic takeoff is analogous to a large jumbo jet taking off. It requires a minimum
speed and velocity to liftoff.
To finance the required level of investment for the Big Push, under-developed
economies must increase their national savings rates and also have an efficient
mechanism for sustainably, efficiently and optimally collecting savings and
This failure also undermines the important objective of making the economic
growth pro-poor. There is large body of evidence that shows that financial sector
development is an integral and indispensable imperative for sustainable economic
growth, development and poverty reduction. Financial Infrastructure increases the
savings rate and the availability of savings for investment. It facilitates and
encourages inflows of foreign capital and optimizes the allocation of capital
between competing uses.
However, the poor in Ethiopia often do not have access to ongoing, formal financial
services, and are forced to rely instead on a narrow range of often risky and
expensive, informal services. This constrains their ability to participate fully in
markets, to increase their incomes and to contribute to economic growth.
In the words of Prime Minister Meles, “The continent is trapped in a low lending-low
savings trap. Interest rate spreads and real interest rates have become very high
effectively pricing productive investment out. There is excess liquidity in countries
that have extreme scarcity of capital. Banks have no interest in actively mobilizing
savings and are at times turning savers away in countries where savings are very
low any way. The financial sector has completely failed in its task of financial
intermediation.
The reforms have not only failed in bringing about efficient financial intermediation
and have reached a dead end in this regard but have also failed to overcome rent
seeking in the financial market. The main actor in rent seeking in the sector is no
longer the state as state. The main actor is the private sector, although of course in
Africa with so much “straddling” it is not always easy to identify where the one
begins and the other ends. By narrowly focusing on rent seeking by the state it has
in effect opened widely the door for private sector rent seeking. By limiting the
effort of reducing rent seeking activity to reducing the role of government in the
economy, it has left the other aspect of rent seeking, the private sector aspect
almost intact.
Practice has shown that market failures are as bad as government failures and
both have led to a dead end. The predatory state and its “statist” policies, and the
Washington consensus have in their own different ways ended up by leading the
financial sector in Africa into dead ends. One dead end is as bad as the other. It
appears both approaches have to be scrapped if the financial sector in Africa is to
get out of these dead-ends.”
The Prime Minister’s views on financial sector strategy are very clear.
So the question becomes which is worse… the potential failures of the market or
the ongoing failures of the state?
What to do?
Market forces within the context of state oversight, must be introduced and allowed
to guide the allocation of resources in the economy and rebalance the country’s
trade and current account imbalances. A large non-debt infusion of foreign
currency must be sourced to kick-start economic activity from which base the
appropriate set of market based and state coordinated policy reforms can kick-in
and sustain growth.
The strategy to address the immediate and serious threat to the economy arising
from the foreign exchange crisis is to liberalize the exchange rate regime by
moving to a managed float of the Birr as outlined below.
Economic theory is clear that a managed devaluation of the real effective exchange
rate should help reduce the costs of the required balance of payments adjustment
by shifting demand from imports to domestically produced goods and by
encouraging exports. And, although it may take some time to establish new export
capacities, the balance of payments improvement will be immediate (through
increased inflows from such sources as remittances, reduced export revenue
leakages, etc.).
For countries such as Ethiopia that are mostly price takers on world markets, a
depreciation should improve the current account balance by reducing imports.
To answer this question, lets first look at what would be required to do so? What is
required is a hard currency war chest of approximately $6 billion to absorb the
initial currency demand surge from multiple sources that will accompany the
liberalization of the foreign exchange regime.
Privatization will not just solve the GTP’s financing problem, a worthy enough
accomplishment in it’s self, but would also help address three chronic
macroeconomic problems. Inflation, the suffocating foreign exchange crisis and the
unduly tight squeeze on credit to the private sector.
In the context of huge financing needs to fulfill the plans under the GTP,
privatization represents an excellent means of cashing out on the accumulated net
worth of Ethiopia’s SOE’s. Indeed, there is arguably no more justifiable use of this
accumulated net worth than spending it on the GTP that the government itself
believes is worthy of supreme sacrifice from all corners of society.
Most valuable among the state-owned assets are what may be termed the BIG 5
state enterprises which have a particularly impressive operational and financial
record: Ethiopian Airlines, Ethiopian Shipping Lines, Ethiopian Telecom, the
Ethiopian Insurance Corporation, and the Commercial Bank of Ethiopia. These can
be seen as the crown jewels of the SOE’s, consistently showing high growth and
high levels of profitability in recent years.
Using standard valuation methodologies and estimated 2018 revenues and profits,
these five companies alone are worth well in excess of USD 30 billion. This figure
does not include dozens of profitable state-owned enterprises beyond the BIG 5
that could generate substantial additional sums.
Even a partial privatization could potentially not only generate a large foreign
exchange infusion for the economy but also pay the government more in future tax
and dividend revenues than what is earned by retaining the telecom in public
hands.
India provides an interesting example of a large poor population that is being lifted
and transformed at amazing speed and scale by a vibrant and competitive
information and communications sector.
Currently, Ethiopia is the North Korea of telecoms regulatory practice but maintains
that its monopoly plays a crucial role in closing the digital divide. In reality, its
equipment and network procurement has been a mess and even with Chinese
loans, it is still serving fewer customers than it might if it were in private hands.
Prices remain high, service poor and market development retarded.
Is There Any Reason Why Ethiopia Should Not Privatize its SOE’s?
Given the large sums involved, there are of course alternate viewpoints that would
object to the above prescription to cash out on Ethiopia’s accumulated state
enterprise wealth. Broadly speaking, such dissenting perspectives would tend to
question: (i) the advisability of privatizing state-owned firms that are doing so well;
(ii) the appropriateness of such massive privatization for a developmental state;
and (iii) the loss of policy influence and national priority-setting that may occur
following the privatization of some key sectors. These are addressed in turn, but
none of them are persuasive.
The simple answer is that Ethiopia needs cash now and it makes perfect sense to
liquidate the net worth held in long-accumulated assets for something as grand as
ensuring a transformative change in the country‘s economic history. In other words,
it is precisely because the BIG 5 are highly valuable that they deserve to be prime
candidates for privatization. For example, the BIG 5 firms alone could, according to
our calculations, fully finance all of Ethiopia’s mega projects including the Grand
Renaissance Dam.
In addition to the above, privatizing the best performers need not be seen as a
negative given the possibility of seeing them do even better and, over time, of
generating tax and employment benefits that may exceed the income they would
have generated within the public sector. The case of BGI, a beer factory privatized
is exemplary. Infused with foreign investment and management, it is now among
the country‘s largest taxpayers and employers.
It is certainly the case that many other developmental states have had and still
retain large state enterprise sectors, most notably for example in Vietnam and
First, Ethiopia does not have a large FDI sector within the economy that is driving
growth in key areas such as manufacturing and exports. The East Asian countries
have large FDI-dominated sectors that have provided large pools of investment
that propelled economy- wide growth and exports even in the presence of large
state enterprises.
Second, Ethiopia simply doesn’t have the savings rates of countries like China or
Vietnam, or for that matter any of the East Asian miracle economies where large
domestic supplies of savings within the banking system offered enough financing
for both state enterprises and a thriving, credit-utilizing private sector.
Given the sheer scope of state enterprise holdings, there is very little substantive
and meaningful loss of policy influence that would result in selling some state
enterprises. There are of course some potentially sensitive cases, such as the
large state-owned bank (CBE) where the ability for policy-directed lending could
conceivably diminish with privatization.
In such cases, and if public ownership must be retained, there is of course a readily
available middle-ground solution: government can retain majority stakes of 51
percent (with the associated ability to keep majority Board seats and strategy-
setting rights within the enterprises) while selling off the remaining 49 percent to
private foreign/domestic investors.
The benefits of privatization extend well beyond just providing funds for the GTP,
though that itself would be a worthy and remarkable accomplishment in itself. Two
other major advantages of privatization are as important, if not more so, than
getting funding for the GTP.
First and foremost, privatization will, if done rightly, offer a cure for inflation.
Inflation in Ethiopia has been linked heavily to a financing problem. The public
sector‘s large financing needs have been met through large credit growth in the
banking system and high levels of direct advances from the Central Bank. If past
patterns continue, the situation will only get worse in the coming years as the
prospective financing requirements will not abate.
Such massive borrowing can be sought from three sources - from the central bank,
commercial banks or from abroad. The first (essentially printing money) is highly
inflationary, the second sucks away bank loans that would have otherwise gone to
the private sector, and the third leads to an accumulation of potentially dangerous
external debt. In short, given the scale of the GTP financing needs and the need to
moderate and even reverse rising debt ratios, government needs funds that can be
secured without any borrowing. Privatization offers precisely such a non-inflationary
and non-indebting source of funds.
In this sense, it can be seen as the magic bullet needed to reach many GTP
targets without having to follow a slower or more moderated strategy as advocated
by some.
More broadly, with government divesting its holdings in key areas of the economy,
there would be a healthy rebalancing of ratios such as private investment-to-GDP
and private manufacturing-to-GDP. This would be all the more important since
some new parastatals are already emerging or expanding well beyond their
traditional tasks. The Metals and Engineering Corporation (METEC); the Ethiopian
Sugar Corporation; the Ethiopian Railways Corporation; the Ethiopian Shipping and
Logistics Enterprise; the Ethiopian Grain Trading Enterprise (which has somehow
got itself into large-scale coffee exports though once a domestic cereals trading
firm); and finally a new public sector commodities distributor.
In summary, it is desirable to have not one but two strong engines (both private
and public) driving Ethiopia‘s economy and privatization by attracting foreign
investment, know how, and dynamism in key GTP supported sectors can play a
major part in making this possible. Privatization would also be a cure for the
nations current account deficit, which is driving the foreign currency crisis.
Privatization really may be the magic bullet that can cure the Ethiopian economy.
Privatization has become the normal process by which state-owned enterprises are
converted to market economy players with visible gains for the industry, its
employees and its customers.
As recently as the 1970’s and 80’s even in advanced economies like that of United
Kingdom, the state owned and controlled vast swaths of the economy including the
coal industry, the steel industry, electricity generation, gas supplies, railways,
docks, canals, and trucking. The government owned the telecoms industry, along
with aircraft and shipbuilding, much of car manufacture, North Sea oil, and more.
In spite of this, governments thinking of moving important industries from the public
to the private sector will confront a number of specific anxieties expressed as
concerns for the national interest. The opponents of privatization will raise fears
about foreign involvement and possible foreign control, about endangered
revenues and strategic supplies, about the survival of uneconomic but socially
necessary services. The list will be long, and most of the issues raised will be
perfectly legitimate matters for a responsible government to worry about.
The mistake made by those who raise these fears as obstacles to privatization,
however, is in assuming state ownership to be the only remedy. It is entirely
possible for a government to protect and defend any aspect of any industry without
owning it, either through provisions in the privatization legislation or simply through
the use of normal government powers.
Stock Exchange
Venture capital
Private equity
Investment banks
Commercial banking – allow foreign banks and address National Bank’s
capacity constraints
Build national electronic payment system
Modernize insurance industry; allow foreign insurance companies
Implement high priority policy changes with regard to exchange rate policy. A
liberalization of Ethiopia’s capital account and foreign exchange regime would
find several billion dollars in the form of a stabilization fund from the IMF and
other development partners.
Prioritize and initiate private sector development policies and programs, which
could garner substantial additional financial support.
Ethiopia’s top 10 imports accounted for over two-thirds (70.3%) of the overall value
of its product purchases from other countries.
Summary
This being said, the set of policy recommendations indicated may seem to be an
improbably drastic and liberal departure from the policies pursued to date but they
are not. The suggested policy package is not a departure from the fundamental
theoretical framework of the Big Push or Developmental State model. The
suggested recommendations are in line with the evolution and refinement of the
best practice delineations of the roles and responsibilities of the state and market
forces within the theoretical model.
Ethiopia must urgently adopt and implement more appropriate economic policies
and reforms to navigate the economic crisis confronting it. The seemingly strong
GDP numbers in the range of 6%-8% still being forecast by the government and
others have given us a false sense of complacency. This is a historically precarious
and pivotal time in the country’s history and a failure to act with deliberation and
speed would be a historic failure. The political crisis has been center stage for the
past three years but we neglect the economy at our peril.
The numbers
To crystalize the situation, below are a set of projections for the key
macroeconomic indicators for the Ethiopian economy. Keeping in mind how
macroeconomic forecasting is as much art as science, these projections still
provide a useful tool to crystalize the problem diagnosis and policy prescription.
The assumptions underlying these projections are the author’s and do not reflect
the views of any institution or group.
The above five-year projections of the Ethiopian economy’s key parameters under
“reform” and “no-reform” scenarios flesh out the quantitative outcomes of each
policy path. Aggregate GDP growth, even under the no-reform scenario, still
manages to stay in the 4% range. This number is probably in the mid range of
realistic probable outcomes of staying the current policy course. Even this scenario
is dependent on the crippling foreign exchange crisis somehow being addressed
over time via increased inflows and lower outflows.
So, given moderate projected growth rates even in the no-reform scenario, one
could ask how this can be the kind of alarming problem the body of this paper
presents. It may even seem misguided and unduly alarmist. Sustained four percent
growth in the near term hardly seems like an economic crises but, in its current
form and structure, this growth is at the price of ending our middle-income nation
ambitions.
The hidden underbelly of this growth will lead us into a low-income trap that will be
structural, long term and difficult to break. Just as Ethiopia is breaking out of a
multi-generational poverty trap, it is stepping into a low-income trap. The acclaimed
aggregate GDP growth rate is the tip of a dangerous iceberg.
This becomes evident when disaggregate GDP growth and look at the projected
sectorial growth numbers. In the no-reform scenario, we see agricultural sector
growth rates drop from 8% in 2016 to 4.5% in 2022. The industrial sector growth
rates collapse from 20% in 2015 to 5% in 2022. Services growth rates drop from
11% to just 3%. The danger is visible. The extraordinary projected collapse in the
growth rates of industry and services, if not avoided, is a time bomb.
These are the sectors, which are to provide jobs for the swelling (increasingly
urban) youth population.
The numbers show industrial and service sectors intended to drive jobs, growth
and structural transformation are faltering badly. The combination of widespread
unemployment, high inflation, shortages of basic food and consumer items in urban
centers and the sense of exclusion among the youth is at the core of the recent
unrest. The change in political leadership has bought the government some time
but not much. Starve the countryside and they die quietly on their farms - starve the
cities and they riot, revolt and burn. We just had a taste of this and it’s not the last
of it unless things change and change quickly. We need look no further than the
Arab Spring or the current unrest in Jordan to see the danger.
The policies to date were successful in moving Ethiopia from a poor pre-market
agrarian economy to a moderately more productive market oriented smallholder
agricultural and urban services dominated one - its first step in the development
continuum to middle income country status.
The Big Push/Developmental State strategy is the right strategy at the beginning of
the development process that all economies have undergone. Ethiopia has
managed to take the first step in the development process by implementing a
development state strategy. The role of the state in achieving liftoff is predominant
and necessary. Once liftoff is achieved, the aerodynamics of growth and
development change. Continued elevation to middle income status and beyond
requires a change in the main engines of growth and the building of the appropriate
new economic institutions, systems and infrastructures. This is where we are now.
The state must pull back and make room for market forces to take the lead in
directing and allocating resources within the economy. No state has the capacity to
do this once an economy reaches a certain level of momentum and complexity. If
appropriate reforms are not introduced, the bottlenecks, distortions and imbalances
that have developed will (have) become crippling. The economy may float along
with the support of dividends from its early heavy investments for some time but it
won’t gain any altitude. With time, the continuation of the current outdated policies
combined with diminishing returns from historical investments will make growth
difficult.
We need to see these technological advances and their implications coming and
think afresh about the appropriate structural transformation in the context of these
changing realities. There is no history for us to look back and learn from. We have
to make our own new history in the face of new realities. The recent experience of
early deindustrialization (manufacturing/GDP ratios) in virtually all developing (and
developed) countries is part of the new reality in the global economy. The service
sector is now the largest sector in almost all but a few (Asian) economies.
The appropriate balance between the role of markets and the state as well as that
of the private sector and the state need recalibration. Financial sector reform and
liberalization aimed at reversing the current policy of financial repression and
building robust financial sector is a must.
Ethiopia needs to make it’s own economic history. It must focus as much on
building its information and communications infrastructure as it does on building
dams, roads and bridges. It must invest in creating livelihoods for the youth as
much as it does for the poor farmer. Economic strategy and policy in todays fast
moving and changing world requires insight and foresight. The policy reforms
advocated earlier in this paper may be a good starting point.