0% found this document useful (0 votes)
16 views

OLD Model Hendriks Note

This document describes an overlapping generations economic model. It introduces the model setup with households living for two periods and production added via firms. It covers the key elements of demographics, preferences, endowments, technology, markets, and capital timing. The model is used to show how household savings decisions may lead to overaccumulation of capital in the economy.

Uploaded by

Jason S
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
16 views

OLD Model Hendriks Note

This document describes an overlapping generations economic model. It introduces the model setup with households living for two periods and production added via firms. It covers the key elements of demographics, preferences, endowments, technology, markets, and capital timing. The model is used to show how household savings decisions may lead to overaccumulation of capital in the economy.

Uploaded by

Jason S
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 48

Overlapping Generations Model

Prof. Lutz Hendricks

Econ720

August 24, 2020

1 / 48
Introduction

Two approaches for modeling the household sector

1. households live forever (infinite horizon)


tractable
2. households live for finite number of periods (overlapping
generations)
can talk about questions where demographics matter

2 / 48
Why choose OLG?

1. Demographic structure matters:


1.1 Social security and tax analysis (pioneered by Auerbach and
Kotlikoff 1987)
1.2 Human capital: schooling followed by on-the-job learning (e.g.,
many papers by Heckman and his students)
1.3 Income or wealth inequality (e.g., Huggett 1996; Huggett et al.
2011)
These are usually computational many-period models.
2. Analytical tractability:
Usually two period OLG models.
With log utility consumption becomes independent of rt+1 .
Easy dynamics because agents behave as if not foward looking.
E.g., Aghion et al. (2002), Galor (2005), Krueger and Ludwig
(2007)

3 / 48
What we do in this section

How to set up and solve an OLG model


Show that the world is not efficient: households may save too
much.
“Social security” can prevent overaccumulation

We can make households "infinitely lived" by adding altruistic


bequests.

4 / 48
What we don’t do in this section

I We sidestep some technical issues:


I why is there a representative household?
I why is there a representative firm?
I We come back to those later.

5 / 48
An OLG Model Without Firms
Steps

We go through the standard steps:

1. Describe the economy: demographics, endowments,


preferences, technologies, markets
2. Solve each agent’s problem
3. Market clearing
4. Competitive equilibrium

We discuss why we make various modeling choices.

7 / 48
Digression: What makes a good model?

Should a model be “realistic” or “unrealistic?”

Should it be simple or complex?

8 / 48
Digression: Why do we use models?

Or: What do models actually do?

9 / 48
Demographics

Time is discrete and goes on forever.


At each date t a cohort of size

Nt = N0 (1 + n)t

is born.
Each person lives for two periods.
At each date there are Nt young and Nt−1 old households.
I Nt /Nt−1 = 1 + n

10 / 48
Endowments, Preferences

Endowments
I Young households receive endowments wt .

Preferences: u(cyt ) + β u(cot+1 ).


I u is strictly concave
I β > 0 is the discount factor.

Note: Putting anything other than consumption and leisure in


preferences is frowned upon (in macro, but not in micro). Why?

11 / 48
Technology

Endowments can be stored.


Storing st today yields f (st ) tomorrow.
I f is strictly concave and increasing

Resource constraint:
I Output = consumption + investment
I Y = C+I
I Closed economy: saving = investment; S = I

Nt wt + Nt−1 f (st−1 ) = Nt cyt + Nt−1 cot + Nt st (1)


| {z } | {z } |{z}
Yt Ct It

12 / 48
Technology

Resource constraints
Technological constraints that describe the set of feasible choices.
Contain only quantities (no prices).
Often identical to market clearing conditions.

13 / 48
Markets

Goods are traded in competitive spot markets.


I the price of the good is normalized to 1 for all t
(why can we do this?)

Households can issue one period bonds with interest rate rt+1 .

We are done with the description of the environment.


Next step: solve the household problem.

14 / 48
A Missing Market

Even though there is a bond market, intergenerational borrowing


and lending is not possible.
The reason: the young at t cannot borrow from the old because the
old won’t be around at t + 1 to have their loans repaid.
I If households live for more periods, the problem becomes
weaker, but does not go away.

An asset that stays around forever solves this problem


I e.g., money, land, shares

15 / 48
Household Problem

The budget constraints are

wt = cyt + st+1 + bt+1


cot+1 = f (st+1 ) + bt+1 (1 + rt+1 )

Why are there no prices for bonds and s?

16 / 48
Lifetime budget constraint
There really is only one constraint that the household cares about:
At what rate can one exchange cot+1 against cyt ?
Substitute out bonds:

cot+1 = f (st+1 ) + (1 + rt+1 ) wt − cyt − st+1



(2)

The relative price of old vs. young consumption is the interest rate.

Lifetime budget constraint:

f (st+1 ) co
wt + − st+1 = cyt + t+1
1 + rt+1 1 + rt+1

Present value of income = present value of spending.


17 / 48
Lagrangian

Γ = u(cyt ) + β u(cot+1 )
+λt {[wt − cyt − st+1 ] − [cot+1 − f (st+1 )]/[1 + rt+1 ]}

FOCs:

u0 (cyt ) = λt
β u0 (cot+1 ) = λt /(1 + rt+1 )
f 0 (st+1 ) = 1 + rt+1

In words...

18 / 48
Interpretation
What does this say in words:

f 0 (st+1 ) = 1 + rt+1 (3)

General insight: the household does things in two steps

1. Maximize lifetime income.


2. Optimally distribute consumption over time.

19 / 48
Euler equation

u0 (cyt ) = β (1 + rt+1 ) u0 (cot+1 )

Interpretation:
Give up 1 unit of consumption when young and buy a bond.

Marginal cost: u0 cyt




Marginal benefit:
(1 + rt+1 ) units of consumption when old
valued at β u0 cot+1


20 / 48
A general point

The household decides sequentially:

1. Make choices to maximize lifetime income (here: choose s and


b)
2. Use the Euler equation to decide how to allocate that income
over time
so that marginal utility is “equalized” across periods (adjusting
for the incentives to postpone consumption to earn interest)

21 / 48
Household Solution

A vector (cyt , cot+1 , st+1 , bt+1 ) which satisfies


I 2 FOCs (an EE and the foc for s)
I 2 budget constraints.

22 / 48
Equilibrium

A CE is an allocation
and a price system
that satisfy:

We are done with the definition of equilibrium.


Next step: characterize equilibrium.

23 / 48
Characterization
There is no trade in equilibrium (bt = 0)
goods t+1

wt goods t

24 / 48
A Production Economy
A Production Economy

The model is modified by adding firms who rent capital and labor
from households.
The endowment w is now interpreted as labor earnings.
Households supply one unit of labor inelastically to firms when
young.
Capital depreciates at rate δ .

This is a standard setup in many macro models.

26 / 48
Model Elements

I Unchanged: demographics, preferences


I Endowments:
I at t = 0 each old household owns k0 units of capital
I each young has 1 unit of work time
I Technology

F (K , L ) = Ct + Kt+1 (1 − δ ) Kt (4)
| {zt t} | {z }
Yt It

I constant returns to scale


I Inada conditions
I Markets:
I goods (numeraire), capital rental (q), labor rental (w)

27 / 48
Capital and timing

At the start of period t:


I the economy is endowed with the capital stock Kt

During t:
I labor Lt and Kt are used to produce Yt
I households eat Ct and save St = Yt − Ct
I fraction δ of the capital stock disappears

At the end of t:
I Kt+1 = (1 − δ ) Kt + St is taken into t + 1

28 / 48
Notes

Representative household
I All households are the same.
I So we talk as if there were only 1 household, who behaves
competitively.

The household owns everything


I The firm rents capital from the household in each period
I That makes the firms’ problem static (easy)
I It is usually convenient to pack all dynamic decisions into 1
agent

In this model, who owns the capital makes no difference - why not?

29 / 48
Welfare theorems

Roughly speaking:
If all markets are competitive and there are no exter-
nalities or distortionary taxes
then
Any competitive equilibrium is Pareto optimal.
Though there is a technical wrinkle that derails efficiency in this
model...

30 / 48
Households

Budget constraints:

wt = cyt + st+1 + bt+1


cot+1 = eo + (st+1 + bt+1 )(1 + rt+1 )

eo : any other income received when old (currently 0)


There are no profits b/c the technology has constant returns to
scale.

31 / 48
Lifetime budget constraint

Combine the 2 budget constraints:

wt − cyt = cot+1 − eo /[1 + rt+1 ]




or
eo co
Wt = wt + = cyt + t+1 (5)
1 + rt+1 1 + rt+1
| {z } | {z }
p.v. of income p.v. of consumption

Wt : present value of lifetime earnings

32 / 48
Permanent Income Hypothesis

The lifetime budget constraint only depends on Wt , not on timing


of income over life.

cot+1 = (1 + rt+1 ) Wt − cyt



(6)

Therefore, the optimal consumption path only depends on Wt .

This is a somewhat general implication that has been tested many


times. example:
I One example: Hsieh (2003) [Nice example of using a natural
experiment to test a theory.]

Overall, the evidence seems favorable.

33 / 48
Lagrangian

Γ = u(cyt ) + β u(cot+1 )
+λ {Wt − cyt − cot+1 /[1 + rt+1 ]}

FOCs:

u0 (cyt ) = λ
β u0 (cot+1 ) = λ /(1 + rt+1 )

In words...

34 / 48
Households

Euler:

u0 (cyt ) = β (1 + rt+1 )u0 (cot+1 )

Solution: A vector (cyt , cot+1 , st+1 , bt+1 ) that satisfies 2 budget


constraints and 1 EE.
We lack one equation! Why?

35 / 48
Consumption theory basics

The Euler equation + present value budget constraint are the


essence of the theory of consumption.
I The Euler equation gives the “slope” of the age-consumption
profile.
I The budget constraint gives the level.

E.g., log utility:


I u0 (c) = 1/c
I ct+1 /ct = β (1 + rt+1 )

Intuition: the effect of shocks... (graph)

36 / 48
Consumption and shocks

earnings

consumption

T age

37 / 48
Testable implications

Strong, testable implications


I all households have the same consumption growth rate
I when income is received over the life-cycle does not matter

The theory seems hopelessly simplistic.


But it gets better when income is stochastic (we study such models
later).

38 / 48
Firms
Firms maximize current period profits taking factor prices (q, w)
as given.

max F(K, L) − wL − qK

Note: When firms own something (e.g., capital), they solve an


intertemporal problem.
FOCs:

q = FK (K, L)
w = FL (K, L)

The solution to the firm’s problem is a pair (K, L) so that the 2


FOCs hold.
39 / 48
Firms

A wrinkle: We assume constant returns to scale.


The size of the firm is indeterminate (why?)
The FOCs only determine K/L (not K and L separately).

40 / 48
Firms: Intensive form

It is convenient to write the production function in intensive form:

F(K, L) = LF(K/L, 1)
= Lf (kF )

where kF = K/L and


f (kF ) = F(kF , 1)

41 / 48
Firms: Intensive form
Now the factor prices are

∂ Lf (K/L)
FK = = Lf 0 (kF )(1/L)
∂K
and
∂ Lf (K/L)
FL = ∂L = f (kF ) + Lf 0 (kF )(−K/L2 )
= f (kF ) − f 0 (kF )kF

Therefore:

q = f 0 (kF )
w = f (kF ) − kF f 0 (kF )

Important: q is the rental price of capital, which differs from the


interest rate r.
42 / 48
Market clearing

Capital rental: Nt st+1 = Kt+1


Labor rental: Lt = Nt
Bonds: bt = 0
Goods: resource constraint

Note: The saving of the young is the entire capital stock next
period.
I Undepreciated capital goes to the old who do not save.

43 / 48
Competitive Equilibrium
An allocation: cyt , cot , st , bt , Kt , Lt


Prices: (qt , rt , wt )
That satisfy:

1. Household: 3
2. Firm: 2
3. Market clearing: 4

We have 9 objects and 9 equations – one is missing.


We need an accounting identity linking r and q:
I The household receives 1 + rt+1 = qt+1 + 1 − δ per unit of
capital.
I Therefore, r = q − δ .

44 / 48
Competitive equilibrium

We could also write everything in terms of kF = K/L and drop L


from the CE definition.
Then
I Capital market clearing:

Kt+1
st+1 = = kt+1 (1 + n) (7)
Nt

I Goods market clearing:

f ktF + (1 − δ ) ktF = cyt + cot / (1 + n) + kt+1 (1 + n)



(8)

45 / 48
Reading

I Acemoglu (2009), ch. 9.


I Krueger, "Macroeconomic Theory," ch. 8
I Ljungqvist and Sargent (2004), ch. 9 (without the monetary
parts).
I McCandless and Wallace (1991) and De La Croix and Michel
(2002) are book-length treatments of overlapping generations
models.

46 / 48
References I

Acemoglu, D. (2009): Introduction to modern economic growth,


MIT Press.
Aghion, P., P. Howitt, and G. L. Violante (2002): “General purpose
technology and wage inequality,” Journal of Economic Growth, 7,
315–345.
Auerbach, A. J. and L. J. Kotlikoff (1987): Dynamic fiscal policy,
Cambridge University Press.
De La Croix, D. and P. Michel (2002): A theory of economic
growth: dynamics and policy in overlapping generations,
Cambridge University Press.
Galor, O. (2005): “From Stagnation to Growth: Unified Growth
Theory,” in Handbook of Economic Growth, ed. by P. Aghion
and S. N. Durlauf, Elsevier, vol. 1A, 171–293.

47 / 48
References II
Hsieh, C.-T. (2003): “Do consumers react to anticipated income
changes? Evidence from the Alaska permanent fund,” The
American Economic Review, 93, 397–405.
Huggett, M. (1996): “Wealth distribution in life-cycle economies,”
Journal of Monetary Economics, 38, 469–494.
Huggett, M., G. Ventura, and A. Yaron (2011): “Sources of
Lifetime Inequality,” American Economic Review, 101, 2923–54.
Krueger, D. and A. Ludwig (2007): “On the consequences of
demographic change for rates of returns to capital, and the
distribution of wealth and welfare,” Journal of Monetary
Economics, 54, 49–87.
Ljungqvist, L. and T. J. Sargent (2004): Recursive macroeconomic
theory, 2nd ed.
McCandless, G. T. and N. Wallace (1991): Introduction to dynamic
macroeconomic theory: an overlapping generations approach,
Harvard University Press.
48 / 48

You might also like