WorkingPaper 99
WorkingPaper 99
WorkingPaper 99
Darakhshan Younis
Attiya Yasmin Javid
Darakhshan Younis
Pakistan Institute of Development Economics, Islamabad
and
E-mail: [email protected]
Website: http://www.pide.org.pk
Fax: +92-51-9248065
List of Tables
(iv)
ABSTRACT
Dividend policy is an important issue of corporate finance and the present
study examines the effect of market imperfections such as asymmetric
information, agency costs and transaction cost of issuing external on corporate
dividend policy for 138 firms selected from all major manufacturing sectors of
Karachi Stock Exchange over the period 2003 to 2011. The results show that
dividend yield depends on the last year’s dividend yield and current year
earnings that supports the Lintner (1956) model suggesting that management
follow smooth dividends and are reluctant to change dividend policy. The results
confirm that dividends signal the firm value (returns) and firm performance
(returns on assets, market to book value and earnings). The positive and
significant relation of free cash flow and collateral capacity with dividend
indicate that dividends help to reduce agency cost problems and these findings
support agency cost theory. The results confirm that dividends are used as a tool
to reduce transaction cost of issuing external finance and that firm size and sales
growth are more effective instruments to reduce transaction costs. Large and
more profitable firms pay more dividends. Firm age, market to book value and
price to earnings ratio are used to capture firm maturity the results show the firm
life cycle theory of dividend is not valid. The irrelevance of life cycle theory
further confirms signalling theory of dividend more relevant in explaining
dividend decisions in case of Pakistan. Free cash flow and return on asset are
significant and support free cash flow hypothesis. The results support dividends
are used as signalling devise for outside investors that firm is running on
profitable lines and reduce the agency cost and transaction costs but signalling
theory is the most dominant This evidence is in confirmation with empirical
findings of other emerging markets.
JEL Classification: G0, G3, G32, G35
Keywords: Dividend Policy, Signalling Theory, Agency Theory,
Transaction Theory, Smooth Dividend, Manufacturing Firms
1. INTRODUCTION
Dividend policy has been considered an important but undecided issue by
financial economists for over a half century. “The harder we look at the picture,
the more it seems like a puzzle, with pieces that don’t fit together” [Black
(1976)]. This discussion goes back to the seminal work of Miller and Modigliani
(1961) who held the view that dividend policy was irrelevant in deciding the
share value under perfect capital market condition. The “Bird-in-the-hand”
theory advanced by Lintner (1962) and Gordon (1963) on the other hand
suggests that increase in dividend payout raises firm value. Some investors
consider dividends more profitable than an uncertain future capital gain. Some
other theories suggest that corporate dividend policy has an impact on firm value
because different tax systems that prevail in the market [Litzenberger and
Ramaswamy (1979); Poterba and Summers (1984); Ang, et al. (1991); Barclay
(1987)]. Latter Pettit (1977) and Scholz (1992) find that “Clientele Effects” also
respond to dividend policy decisions because investors are divided into different
clienteles according to their preferences and they choose a company where their
investment objectives are in line with their dividend decisions. Bhattacharya
(1979; Miller and Rock (1985) and Bali (2003) suggest that dividends signal the
market about the firm’s performance. This is called the “Signalling theory”
which states that dividend helps to reduce information asymmetries between the
manager and the shareholder. Another theory, namely the “Agency” theory,
states that dividend is a source that helps to mitigate the cost arising from
conflict of interest between the manager and the shareholder.
Dividends also monitor the firm’s management activities [Rozeff (1982);
Easterbrook (1984); Jensen (1986)] maintain that dividend paying ability
reduces extra funds available to management and through which it resolves the
over-investment problem.
The finance managers have to deal with two main operational decisions—
investment and finance. The finance manager may also deal with a third
decision which arises when the firm starts making profit. The finance managers
have to decide what portion of earnings should be distributed to shareholders as
dividend or should it be reinvested into business. Managers have also to
consider that their dividend policy also affects the share price [Bishop, et al.
(2000)]. Generally, shareholders receive dividends when a company generates
2
profit. Hence dividends are not regarded as expense but as sharing of profits
with shareholders. The Board of Directors and the management decide the
dividend policy. Even though enormous research has been done on dividend
policy yet little is known about how companies make dividend policies. Market
imperfections are a factor which can be categorised into at least three
divisions—agency costs, irregular information and transaction cost—whose role
in influencing the dividend decisions of manufacturing firms must be
investigated.
However, in case of Pakistan very few studies have been done on the
issue and those that have been done mainly focus on the effect of corporate
dividend policy on share price, the determinants of this policy and the impact of
corporate governance on it [Nishat and Irfan (2003); Mehar (2005); Naeem and
Nasr (2007); Ahmed and Javid (2009); Nazir, et al. (2010); Akbar and Baig
(2010) and Asghar and Suleman (2011)]. These studies pay no attention to the
effect of different market imperfections on dividend decisions of the firms.
The present study tries to fill this gap by analysing the role of different
market imperfections in explaining corporate dividend policy of manufacturing
industries listed on the Karachi Stock Exchange. It tests the relevance of the
Lintner (1956) model in explaining the dividend policies and checks whether
firms in the manufacturing sector follow a smooth and stable dividend policy or
not. It also investigates how dividends help in reducing agency and transaction
costs of the firms and how the policy reduces information asymmetry by
signalling corporate operating characteristics of these firms. This study also tests
the life cycle hypothesis to know whether mature, profitable, low growth firms
pay more dividends or not.
The present study contributes to the existing literature by examining how
market imperfections affect dividend decisions in Pakistan which is an important
emerging market. This study tests the significance of dividend theories such as
signalling, agency, transaction and residual, life cycle and stability on
manufacturing sector firms listed on KSE. The questions relating to dividend
policy are important for emerging markets for many reasons. Firstly, the
stability and growth of firms can be signalled by its dividend paying capacity.
Investors use dividends as indicator for the firm’s long-term consistency in
earnings. Secondly, as the residual dividend theory states, a firm decides to pay
dividend when it has less possibilities of profitable investment. Further, many
researchers believe that a firm’s dividend decision is related to investment
decision and that the firm’s stock price is also influenced by it.
The study is organised as follows: Section two provides a review of
theoretical and empirical literature on the dividends policy in developed and
developing markets. Section three explains the methodological framework,
variable description and data collection sources. The empirical results are
discussed in section four and section five concludes the study.
3
2. LITERATURE REVIEW
Since the seminal work of Modigliani and Miller (1965), postulating that
dividends are irrelevant under perfect market conditions, researchers investigated
the firms’ dividend decisions under imperfect market conditions. This lead to
the development of different theories of dividend distribution and a large body
of empirical literature emerged to test these theories. This section is divided into
two sub-sections; Section 2.1 reviews the theoretical literature and Section 2.2
reviews relevant empirical literature in this area.
and further advanced by Shefrin and Statman (1984). They emphasise that
investors regard home dividend as less favourable than dividend paying stocks
because of what is termed as self control dilemma. Small retail investors require
stable cash flows whereas corporate and institutional investors may not need
that. The behavioural theory comes in when in the market individual investors
are more powerful.
Shamser (1993) and Gupta and Lok (1995) and they also find similar results.
Pandey and Bhat (1994)check the validity of the Lintner model in India and they
find that Indian firms favour its findings. Ariff and Johnson (1994), Adaoglu
(2000) test the Lintner model for firms listed on Turkish stock exchange. Glen,
et al. (1995) have carried out a study of dividend policy in seven developing
countries: Chile, Jamaica, India, Mexico, Thailand, Turkey and the Philippines.
The study concludes that firms in developing markets set a targeted dividend
payout ratio and try to maintain this payout ratio ignoring short term changes in
earnings. Anyhow, when firms have a target payout ratio they usually give less
importance to changes in dividends overtime and as a result dividend’s
smoothing with time becomes less relevant. Consequently it is found that
dividend policies of emerging markets are more volatile than developed
countries.
is greater need for outside monitoring to reduce the free rider problem.
Deshmukh Sanjay (2005) has found negative and insignificant relationship
between insider ownership and dividend yield. Harada and Nguyen (2006) and
Khan (2006) have concluded that firms with high ownership concentration pay
lower dividends. Mancinelli and Ozkan (2006) show that when ownership
concentration is high, managers are reluctant to distribute dividends to
shareholders.
Mollah, et al. (2007) show that agency cost variables had less explanatory
power in ownership concentrated firms before the financial crisis of 2008 period
and had no support after the crisis period. Obema, et al. (2008) find that only
institutional ownership has a significant relationship with dividend policy
because they vote for higher payout ratios to increase managerial control by
external capital markets. Kouki and Guizani (2009) show that institutional
ownership is negatively and ownership of the five largest shareholders is
positively related to dividend payments that supports the view that multiple
large shareholders have a positive role in dividend policy. Chen and Dhiensiri
(2009) have examined the signalling, agency, residual and stability theories of
dividend, and strongly favour the agency cost theory.
Afza (2010) shows that in Pakistan, corporate governance is not
performing well so managers have the opportunity to hold cash in their hands
and not pay dividends to shareholders. Sharif, et al. (2010)have concluded that
the payout ratio has significant positive relation with ownership concentration
and institutional shareholding in the case of Tehran stock exchange. Afza and
Mirza (2010) have shown that for Pakistani listed firms individual ownership,
managerial ownership and cash flow sensitivity are negatively related to cash
dividends. Harada and Nguyen (2011) find dividend policy is used as a
substitute for shareholder control and concentrated ownership is negatively
related to dividend payout.
funds. So the relationship between dividend yield and size is positive in large
firms. Sawiciki (2005) has examined that large firms face the problem of
ownership dispersion and are unable to monitor the firms’ inside and outside
activities which reduces management efficiency. As a solution of this problem
firms can pay large amounts of dividend to shareholders and finance their
investment activities through external finance which leads to increase the control
of the creditors over large firms. Grullon, et al. (2002) have discussed the
maturity hypothesis which states that capital expenditure declines as firms
become more mature because their growth and investment opportunities are
reduced. The over-investment problem can be eased because firms face less risk
and pay more dividends. Chen and Dhiensiri (2009) have used four proxy
variables for testing transaction and residual theory—size, beta, growth rate of
revenues and their results—that to some extent favour the transaction and
residual theory. Elston (1996) states that dividends and investments both need
funds from retained earnings and compete with each other. High growth and
investment possibilities are negatively related to dividends. It is also consistent
with the free cash flow hypothesis [Jensen (1986)] and Lang and Litzenberger
(1989). Kanwal and Sujata (2008) show a negative relation between growth
possibilities and dividend which is related to the pecking order theory.
Rozeff (1982), Jensen, et al. (1992), Alli, et al. (1993), Mohammed, et al.
(2006) find that dividends and investment opportunities are negatively related.
Fama and French uphold the view that dividends are influenced by investment
opportunities. Firm decision of paying dividend is independent of investment
policy [Grill, et al. (1983)]. When growth increases, firm needs more external
finance which in turn increases its sales and cash inflows [Higgins (1981)].
Rozeff (1982), Lloyd, et al. (1985), Collins, et al. (1996), and recently Amidu
and Abor (2006) find that historical sales growth and dividend payout are
significantly and negatively related.
it is also not necessary that the firm faces large increases in earnings. Evidence
has shown that firms that announce to pay dividends are less likely to face a fall
in their earnings.
Bhattacharya (1979) states that firms pay dividends only when they hope
a good cash position in the future which is based on their decision to invest in
profitable projects. On the strength of quality projects managers can signal
investors by announcing high dividends. Asquith and Mullins (1983) and Healy
and Palepu (1988) have shown that stock price and decision of paying dividend
are positively related. Similarly, the signalling theory has examined that
financial markets do not take any decrease or dividend cut as a good sign for
firm value [Benartzi, Michaely, and Thaler (1997), Healy and Palepu (1988),
Michaely, Thaler, and Womack (1995)]. Managements are reluctant to pay
dividends if they feel that in the long term the firm would not be able to pay
constant dividends because there is a perception that the market punishes firms
that fail to pay dividends more than reward those that pay.
Miller and Rock (1985) conclude that dividends are a signal of good news
and their findings are consistent with Bhattacharya’s reasoning. Raei, et al.
(2012) have concluded that dividends provide information about return and
earnings, therefore the signalling theory plays an important role in determining
the return and earnings of the firm. A positive relation between dividend and
return is shown by Park (2010) and Lettaua and Ludvigson (2005). Chen, et al.
(2005) conclude that dividend and performance are weakly related. Harada and
Nguyen (2005) have stated that dividend signals on performance and return.
Weak relation between dividend and earnings is shown by Brave, et al. (2005).
De Angelo, et al. (2000) and Fukuda (2000) have divided information about
earnings. Powell and Baker, et al. (2000) and Healy and Palepu (1998) have
stated that dividends affect earnings positively.
Mostly researchers have used the proxy of the firm’s age to capture growth and
investment opportunities. Afza and Mirza (2011) have found non-linear
relationship between age and dividend payouts of corporations. De Angelo and
Stulz (2006) have tested the life cycle theory of dividend by using the proxy of
retained earnings to total assets. It is stated that firms with high retained earnings
to total asset ratio are more mature with more profits and so pay more dividends.
Their results support the life cycle theory of dividends and show positive
significant relationship between dividend and retained earnings to total assets.
Where Dit* is the target level dividend for fund i year t, αi is the optimal amount
of dividend as a percentage of the profit for fund i. Eit is the profit company i
made in year t. The value of α lies between 0 and 1 since companies usually
won’t pay more dividends than their profits. When the profit changes the actual
amount of dividend paid differs from the optimal amount that follows out of (1).
To compensate for this difference the company will gradually adjust the
12
dividends, as seen in the next Equation (2) called the Lintner full adjustment
model:
− =
∗ −
… … … … (2)
Where, c is Velocity at which a company adjusts the dividend that lies between
0 and 1.
− = +
∗ −
+ … … … (3)
Where D*it is the desired dividend payment during period ‘t’, Dit is actual dividend
payment during period ‘t’, αi is Target payout ratio, Eit is earnings of firm during
period ‘t’, ai is a constant related to dividend growth, Ci is partial adjustment factor,
uit is error term. Positive value of constant ‘a’ shows that firms avoid dividend cuts
and try to increase dividend paying ability at a steady rate.
This model can further be simplified in the form of a multiple regression
equation
− = +
∗ −
+ … … … (4)
− = +
−
+ … … (5)
= +
+ 1 −
+ … … … (6)
Where DPSit is dividend per share during period t, EPSit is earning per share
during period t, α, β1 and β2 is the regression coefficient of dividend per share
during period t–1 i.e. (1–c) and c is the adjustment factor. This implies αi is
target payout ratio which is β1/(1–β2). The actual changes in dividends
correspond to expected changes if α has zero value and Ci is 1. On the contrary
when Ci is 0 no change in dividend policy can be observed towards expected
levels. Corporations adjust their dividend policies gradually with changes in the
level of earnings which shows that the speed of adjustment coefficient lies
between 0 and 1. Furthermore, the positive value of constant α shows the
management avoids dividend cuts.
The three proxies used for signalling (SIGNAL) by the firms are: returns,
performance and earnings. The variables used are annual returns during the year t;
for performance: ROA (return on asset) for year t, MB (market to book value of
equity) for period t; for earnings: NI (net income) for period t; Div for total amount
of dividends for year t; for SIZE: natural logarithm of total assets for year t.
Finally all three proxy variables are used collectively in one mode with
the control variables.
Finally, all three proxy variables used in the above equations are
estimated collectively in this model. Where net income (NI) to estimated
transaction cost, and earning per share(EPS) are used as a control variables.
Lagged dividend yield (DYt–1) helps to remove serial auto correlation.
Life cycle and free cash flow hypotheses are together estimated with the
help of following model for robustness check.
15
= + 4
4 + $- + " 56 + % / + 8 ))0()
+ 9 & + ' 4.1.6)
4. EMPIRICAL RESULTS
The empirical significance of different dividend theories is tested in this
study by using data of 138 manufacturing firms listed at KSE from the period
2003-2011.The empirical result discussion starts with summary statistics of the
data. After that regression results are presented.
probability J-statistic shows the instruments are valid in all the models. The
common effect model, fixed effect model and random effect model are
estimated. The F* test supports the fixed effect model compared to common
effect model and among fixed effect and random effect models the Haussman
test’s p value indicates that the random effect model better describes the data.
Table 1
Results of Lintner Model
Regressors CEM FEM REM
NI 0.23*(2.44) 0.08(0.48) 0.23*(2.54)
Dt-1 0.57*(19.8) 0.30*(9.01) 0.57*(20.63)
Constant 0.012*(8.26) 0.02*11.64) 0.012*(8.58)
Adjusted R-squared 30.7% 35.92% 30.7%
Sargantest (p-value) 0.4 0.97 0.4
Hausman Test 0.60
Durbin Watson(p-value) 2.1 2.0 2.1
The speed of adjustment (1-ai ) 43% 70% 43%
The target payout ratio (β/(1-ai)) 53% 11.42% 53%
Firms 138 138 138
Observations 966 966 966
Note: The values in the parenthesis are t-values. The * indicates significance at 1 percent,
** significance at 5 percent and *** indicates significance at 10 percent.
share and highly significant. The target payout ratio at 25 percent is lower than
Lintner’s suggested target payout ratio of 50 percent and the speed of adjustment
is 32 percent. The high speed of adjustment coupled with low target payout ratio
shows absence of dividend stability.
Table 2
Results of Dividend Stability
Regressors CEM FEM REM
EPS 0.08*(13.07) 0.07*(10.38) 0.08*(14.77)
DPSt-1 0.68*(31.26) 0.27*(8.90) 0.68*(35.35)
Constant 0.30*(2.07) 1.98*(12.11) 0.30*(2.35)
Adjusted R-squared 70.92% 76.90% 70.92%
Hausman test(p-value) 0.49
Sargantest (p-value) 0.124 0.061 0.115
Durbin Watson(p-value) 2.3 2.2 2.3
The speed of adjustment (1-ai ) 32% 73% 32%
The target payout ratio (β/(1-ai)) 25% 9% 25%
Firms 996 996 996
Observations 138 138 138
Note: The values in the parenthesis are t-values. The * indicates significance at 1 percent, **
significance at 5 percent and *** indicates significance at 10 percent.
First, model results show stock returns negatively and significantly affect
dividends. Lie (2005) also finds negative market reaction to dividend declaration
because market regards fall in dividend support as earning for management, not
for investment. In second model the return on asset is used as a proxy of
performance for testing signalling theory. Results show return on asset is
positive and highly significantly related to dividend yield. This result is
consistent with findings of Power, et al. (2007) Belans, et al. (2007) and varies
from the results of Sawaminath, et al. (2002). In the third model MB (market to
book value) is also used as a proxy variable for performance testing the
signalling theory. The relationship between market to book value and dividend
yield is positive is by using random effect model but insignificant. It shows
dividends are not sensitive to market to book value. The results reject the
hypothesis that there is relationship between market to book value and dividend
policy. In the fourth model, the results of random effect model show net income
is positive and significantly affects the firm’s dividend policy. Kim and Ettredge
(1992), Priestley and Garrett (2000), Bhattacharya (2003), Wilson, et al. (2006),
Amidu and Abor (2006), Belans, et al. (2007) support the results. However, this
result is different from the findings of Bhat and Pandey (2007), Kapoor and Anil
(2008), as well as Jeong’s (2008).
Table 3
Results of Signalling Model
Regressors Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4
Constant –0.003(1.02) –0.008(0.229) –0.003(0.85) 0.005**(1.91)
Return –0.039**(1.98)
ROA 0.04*(5.82)
MB 0.08(0.96)
NI 0.179**(1.92)
SIZE 0.002*(4.75) 0.0016*(3.30) 0.0023*(4.47) 0.002*(3.40)
Leverage –0.008 (1.63) –0.004(0.91) –0.009***(1.8)
***
–0.004(0.90)
DYt-1 0.56*(21.73) 0.51*(19.11) 0.54*(19.02) 0.54*(18.69)
Adjusted R-squared 34.81% 35.75% 31.75% 31.42%
Hausman test(pvalue) 0.321 0.3228 0.321 0.32
Sargantest(p-value) 0.07 0.07 0.09 0.56
Durbin Watson(p value) 2.11 2.04 2.08 2.08
Firms 138 138 138 138
Observations 1104 1104 966 966
Note: The values in the parenthesis are t-values. The * indicates significance at 1 percent,
** significance at 5 percent and *** indicates significance at 10 percent.
In all four models the large sized firms pay more dividends because they
have easy access to capital markets, and able to generate more funds and
therefore they distribute more dividends to shareholders. This view is supported
by Osobov (2008), Hosami (2007), Aivazian (2003), Al-Twaijry (2007), Eriotis
(2005), Ahmed and Javid (2009), Kuwari (2009), and Olantundun (2000).
20
Table 4
Results for Agency Cost Theory
Regressors REM REM REM
FCF 0.032*(2.32)
MSO 0.005(1.16)
LNFIX 0.016*(2.34)
SG 0.015*(3.25) 0.09*(2.48) 0.09*(2.31)
ROA 0.02(1.55) 0.05*(6.87) 0.05*(6.47)
*
DYt-1 0.53 (16.25) 0.5*(17.76) 0.48*(16.36)
*
Constant 0.09 (5.37) 0.09*(5.51) -0.017(0.314)
Adjusted R-squared 38.25% 34.12% 33.64%
Hausman test(p-value) 0.21 0.21 0.21
Sargantest(p-value) 0.107 0.138 0.110
Durbin Watson(p-value) 1.99 2.02 2.03
Firms 138 138 138
Observations 690 966 924
Note: The values in the parenthesis are t-values. The * indicates significance at 1 percent,
** significance at 5 percent and *** indicates significance at 10 percent.
Table 4 reports only the results of random effect model as Huasman test
supports these results. First, this study has estimated free cash flow (FCF) with
two control variables which are sales growth and return on asset. The free cash
flow is positively related with dividend yield and is highly significant under the
random effect model. Free cash flow comes to firms for distribution to
shareholders as dividends. It is also used for debt payment and lowers the
chances of these funds being invested in unfeasible projects [Jensen (1986),
Amidu and Abor (2006)]. The growth return on asset and lagged dividend are
statistically significant and also positively related with dividend yield. Sales
growth is used as a proxy in signalling theory. The result indicates that high
21
growth firms are more likely to pay high dividends. Increase in sales of the
company’s products is likely to raise its profits and provide more cash for its use
and operational activities. So firms have sufficient amount of cash to distribute
to shareholders as dividend. These results are supported by findings of Naceure,
et al. (2006), Belans, et al. (2007), Jeong (2008) and deviate from the findings
of D’Souza (1999), Amidu and Abor (2006).
In the second model of agency cost theory, this study has estimated the
insider ownership (MSO) with two control variables—growth and return on
asset. The result shows that insider ownership is positively associated with
dividend yield but is insignificant in case of Pakistani markets. Non-financial
firms listed on KSE with more concentrated ownership pay more dividends.
Farina and Fronda (2005), Amidu and Abor (2006) and Mehar (2005) also find
similar results. Growth and return on assets are positively related with dividend
yield and are highly significant.
In the third model of agency cost theory this study has estimated the
natural log of fixed asset (Lnfix) with two control variables—growth and return
on asset. The collateral capacity is positively related with dividend yield and
highly significant. Firms with more fixed assets are able to pay more dividends
because it is easy for them to raise funds than from those firms that have few
fixed assets. Finally, all three proxy variables for agency cost free cash flow,
insider ownership and collateral capacity are estimated collectively and two
control variables, growth and return on asset. The results remain the same.
Lagged dividend is also positively related with dividend yield and is significant
at 1 percent significance level.
Table 4(a)
Results of Combined Model of Agency Cost Theory
Regressors CEM FEM REM
FCF 0.05*(5.72) 0.054*(4.95) 0.05*(6.03)
MSO 0.00814(1.28) 0.003*(2.05) 0.00814(1.35)
*
LNFIX 0.018 (2.06) 0.06*(3.09) 0.018*(2.17)
SG 0.015*(3.04) 0.008*(2.07) 0.015*(3.20)
* *
DYt-1 0.52 (14.60) 0.30 (9.58) 0.52*(15.38)
*
Constant –0.06(0.841) –0.04 (2.57) –0.06(0.886)
Adjusted R-squared 37.32% 38.10% 37.32%
Hausman test(p-value) 0.27
Sargantest(p-value) 0.106 0.187 0.106
Durbin Watson(p-value) 2.0 2.0 2.0
Firms 136 137 136
Observations 657 1064 657
Note: The values in the parenthesis are t-values. The * indicates significance at 1 percent,
** significance at 5 percent and *** indicates significance at 10 percent.
22
Table 5
Results for Transaction Cost and Residual Theory
Regressors REM REM REM
Beta –0.039(0.172)
SIZEA 0.017* (3.27)
SG 0.011*(3.01)
NI 0.177**(1.90) 0.12(1.28) 0.168***(1.83)
EPS 0.02*(4.73) 0.02*(4.11) 0.0002*(4.35)
DYt-1 0.54*(19.19) 0.52*(18.34) 0.53*(19.09)
Constant 0.01*(6.85) –0.01(0.468) 0.01*(6.80)
Adjusted R-squared 32.10% 32.80% 32.69%
Hausman test(p-value) 0.17 0.11 0.10
Sargantest (p-value) 0.69 0.86 0.71
Durbin Watson(p-value) 2.07 2.05 2.06
Firms 138 138 138
Observations 966 966 966
Note: The values in the parenthesis are t-values. The * indicates significance at 1 percent, **
significance at 5 percent and *** indicates significance at 10 percent.
The Hausman test suggests that the random effect model is better,
therefore only results of random effect model are reported in Table 5. In the
first model the study has used proxy variable beta with two control variables
i.e. net income and earning per share. Beta is negatively related with
dividend yield but insignificant. Rozeff (1982) has also concluded that other
things remaining equal, expensive external financing leads to high beta.
Therefore such firms choose lower dividend payout policies. In the second
model of transaction cost and residual theory, this study has estimated size
with two control variables—net income and earning per share. Firm size is
positively related with dividend yield and significant at 1 percent level.
Higgins (1981), Aivazian, et al. (2003) and Sawiciki (2005) also find
positive relation with dividends because large firms can generate external
finance easily and secondly large firms may face the issue of ownership
dispersion. Therefore, increase in dividend payouts helps to reduce this
problem too. In the third model for transaction and residual theory this study
has estimated sales growth with the same two control variables i.e., net
income and earning per share. The sales growth is positively and
23
Table 5(a)
Results of Overall Transaction and Residual Theory
Regressors CEM FEM REM
Beta –0.013(0.65) 0.449(0.019) –0.013(0.667)
SIZEA 0.017*(3.47) 0.027*(2.63) 0.017*(3.55)
*
SG 0.01 (2.80) 0.0082 (2.15) 0.010*(2.87)
*
Table 6
Results of Life Cycle Theory of Dividends
Regressors REM REM REM
AGE 0.0061 (0.725)
MB 0.0012 (1.40)
P/E 0.0023 (0.38)
NI 0.228* (2.46) 0.209* (2.25) 0.225* (2.40)
LEV –0.005 (1.02) –0.005 (0.90) –0.005 (1.01)
DYt-1 0.57* (20.42) 0.56* (19.96) 0.57* (20.50)
Constant 0.011* (3.83) 0.012* (6.68) 0.013* (7.41)
Adjusted R-squared 30.8% 30.7% 30.8%
Hausman test (p-value) 0.21 0.22 0.22
Sargantest(p-value) 0.75 0.05 0.64
Durbin Watson(p-value) 2.1 2.1 2.1
Firms 138 138 138
Observations 960 966 957
Note: The values in the parenthesis are t-values. The * indicates significance at 1 percent,
** significance at 5 percent and *** indicates significance at 10 percent.
Table 6 (a)
Overall Model for Life Cycle Theory of Dividends
Regressors CEM FEM REM
AGE 0.062 (0.70) –0.002 (0.16) 0.006 (0.74)
MB 0.001 (1.34) –0.006* (4.42) 0.001 (1.41)
P/E 0.0017 (0.27) –0.002 (0.38) 0.002 (0.28)
NI 0.202* (2.05) 0.114 (0.66) 0.202* (2.16)
LEV –0.0068 (1.17) –0.0017 (0.23) -0.0068 (1.23)
DYt-1 0.56*(18.78) 0.30* (8.9) 0.56* (19.72)
* *
Constant 0.012 (3.28) 0.028 (5.58) 0.012* (3.45)
Adjusted R-squared 30.8% 37.2% 30.8%
Hausman test (p-value) 0.18
Sargantest (p-value) 0.17 0.05 0.17
Durbin Watson(p-value) 2.1 2.1 2.1
Firms 138 138 138
Observations 957 957 957
Note: The values in the parenthesis are t-values. The * indicates significance at 1 percent,
** significance at 5 percent and *** indicates significance at 10 percent.
The random effect model fits the data well as shown by the Hausman
Test. The results of the random effect model are presented in Table 6(a). In the
first model this study has used firm age (AGE) as a proxy variable to capture
firm life cycle phase with two control variables, net income and Leverage.
25
Results show age is insignificant but positively related with dividend yield. Firm
maturity does not affect firm ability of paying dividend of non-financial firms
listed on Karachi stock exchange. In the second and third model, market to book
value (MB) and price earning ratio (P/E) are separately estimated with the same
two control variables. The results show market to book value (MB) and price
earning ratio (P/E) that are insignificant and do not support the firm life cycle
theory in case of Pakistani manufacturing sector. Net income and lagged
dividend both are significant positively related to dividend yield in all three
models. Now the present study will estimate all three proxy variables—firm age
(AGE), market to book value (MB) and price earning ratio (P/E) in one model
and test the significance of firm life cycle theory of dividends. As reported in
Table 6 (a) the model yields the same results.
Another model is also used to test the firm life cycle theory of dividends
and free cash flow hypothesis. The price earning ratio (P/E) and market to book
value (MB) are used to capture the investment opportunities available to the firm
and free cash flow (FCF) and return on asset (ROA) are applied to test the
hypothesis. (Table 6b).
Table 6(b)
Results of Life Cycle and Free Cash Flow Hypothesis
Regressors CEM FEM REM
FCF 0.028* (2.05) 0.034* (2.38) 0.028* (2.15)
ROA 0.03* (2.15) 0.04* (2.42) 0.03* (2.25)
*
MB –0.01 (1.59) –0.06 (5.42) –0.01 (1.59)
P/E –0.02 (0.38) –0.02 (0.26) –0.023 (0.39)
LEV –0.06 (0.11) –0.04 (0.30) 0.06 (0.12)
DYt-1 0.50* (16.8) 0.30* (9.68) 0.50* (17.63)
Constant 0.011* (5.68) 0.019* (8.02) 0.011* (5.78)
Adjusted R-squared 34.17% 39.1% 34.17%
Hausman test (p-value) 0.11
Sargantest (p-value) 0.11 0.29 0.11
Durbin Watson(p-value) 2.02 2.0 2.02
Firms 138 138 138
Observations 957 1094 957
Note: The values in the parenthesis are t-values. The * indicates significance at 1 percent,
** significance at 5 percent and *** indicates significance at 10 percent.
Table 6(b) shows the results of the common effect model, fixed effect model
and random effect model for comparison. The probability value of Hausman test is
(0.000) which supports the results of the random effect model. Free cash flow is
statically significant and positively related with dividend yield. Large firms have
more free cash flow and dividends are a help to reduce agency cost problems that
26
arise due to large cash flows and also support the free cash flow hypotheses. The
return on assets is used as a proxy variable for firm profitability. The results show
that a firm with high return on assets is more likely to pay more dividends. It
supports the free cash flow hypothesis which exhibits state positive relationship
between firm profitability and dividend yield. When firms are able to generate more
profits and have free cash flow in their reserves, then firms distribute some portion
of their earnings to shareholders as dividends. Although the price earning ratio and
market to book value are negatively related with dividend but insignificantly,
therefore they fail to support the firm life cycle theory of dividends.
Table7
Results of Lintner Model with Industrial Effect
Regressors CEM REM
NI –0.112(0.321) –0.122(0.498)
DYt-1 0.50* (7.69) 0.40* (9.562)
DAUTO 0.005(0.04) –0.346(1.743)
DCABELENG 0.044(0.673) 0.0273(0.246)
DCEM –0.0007(0.010) –0.1906(1.529)
DCHEM 0.124(1.45) 0.244* (2.092)
DFOOD 0.118*** (1.817) 0.1715(1.523)
DMISCL –0.006(0.138) –0.108(1.514)
DOILREF 0.06(0.764) 0.300* (2.748)
DPAPER 0.134(1.30) 0.387* (2.563)
DTEXTILE 0.063(1.016) 0.1979* (2.32)
Constant –0.042(0.886) –0.079(1.101)
Sargantest(p-value) 0.06 0.26
Durbin Watson(p-value) 2.0 2.1
Firms 138 138
Observations 966 966
Note: The values in the parenthesis are t-values. The * indicates significance at 1 percent,
** significance at 5 percent and *** indicates significance at 10 percent.
27
5. CONCLUSION
Dividend policy is a controversial issue in corporate finance. There are
numerous theories about dividend but this study focuses on some important
theories like the signalling, agency transaction and residual, life cycle and
stability theories and how they affect the corporate dividend policy of Pakistan’s
manufacturing sector firms listed on the Karachi Stock Exchange (KSE) for the
period 2003 to 2012. This study considers market imperfections such as
asymmetric information, agency and transaction costs of issuing external finance
and how these capital market deficiencies affect the dividend policy of
corporations. The panel data estimation technique suggested by Blunder and
Bond (1995) is used to deal with endogeneity. The random effect model is
supported by Hausman Test.
In the first part of the study the Lintner (1956) model is estimated using
three techniques for non-financial firms.. The results show that dividend yield
has a positive relationship with last year’s dividend yield and current year
earnings. It is concluded that manufacturing sector firms consider last year’s
dividend payout as an important factor. Further, earnings are also positively
related with dividend yield which indicates that more profitable firms are able to
pay more dividends without disturbing their financial obligations.
Using the Fama and Babiak (1968) model we find that the variation in the
speed of adjustment ranges from 32 percent to 73 percent, which is very high.
We conclude that non-financial firms follow a smooth dividend policy. This
speed of adjustment is higher than many developing countries. The target payout
ratio is found ranging from 9 percent to 25 percent which is very low as
compared to Lintner (1956). The high speed of adjustment coupled with low
target payout ratio shows the absence of stability in dividend policies of
Pakistani firms.
The evidence for signalling theory approach is established on the
hypothesis that individual investors outside the firm have less information than
the managers about the firm’s prospective circumstances and they have the
rationale to signal that information to the shareholders. This study has examined
the signalling theory by using three important variables: returns, performance
and earnings. The results show that returns are negatively and significantly
related with dividend yield. Two other proxies, returns on assets and market to
book value show that the former is significantly positively related and the latter
positively related with dividend yield but it is not significant in case of Pakistani
firms. Earnings are also significantly positively related with dividend yield. It
shows that dividends signal information by two operating characteristics of
firms, i.e. earnings and performance. Therefore the signalling theory is
supported by these variables in case of Pakistan’s manufacturing sector.
The present study also investigates the agency theory using insider
ownership, free cash flow and collateral capacity to test whether dividends help
28
APPENDIX
Table A3(a)
Correlation Matrix for Lintner Model, Stability Model
and Signalling Theory
DY NI EPS DPS RETURN ROA MB
DY 1
NI 0.1504 1
EPS 0.2553 0.1818 1
DPS 0.4942 0.2550 0.6271 1
RETURN 0.0772 0.0256 0.1640 0.0986 1
ROA 0.3859 0.2766 0.5706 0.5189 0.2024 1
MB 0.1822 0.1894 0.2431 0.3147 0.2254 0.4185 1
Table 3A(b)
Correlation Matrix for Agency and Transaction Cost Theory
DY LNFIX MSO FCF BETA GS SIZEA LEV
DY 1
LNFIX 0.178 1
MSO –0.021 –0.043 1
FCF 0.3958 0.181 –0.111 1
BETA –0.010 0.077 –0.025 0.040 1
GS 0.114 0.041 –0.008 0.128 –0.009 1
SIZEA 0.216 0.873 –0.090 0.215 0.079 0.066 1
LEV –0.082 0.072 0.083 –0.158 –0.025 0.016 0.094 1
31
REFERENCES
Abor, J. and M. Amidu (2006) Determinants of Dividend Payout Ratio in
Ghana. Journal of Risk Finance 7:2,136–145.
Adaoglu, Chait (2000) Instability in the Dividend Policy of the Instanbul Stock
Exchange Corporations: Evidence from an Emerging Market. Emerging
Market Review 1:3, 252–270.
Adefila, J. J., J. A. Oladipo, and J. O. Adeoti (2004) The Effect of Dividend
Policy on the Market Price of Shares in Nigeria: Case Study of Fifteen
Quoted Companies. International Journal of Accounting 2:1.
Adesola, W. A. and A. E. Okwong (2009) An Empirical Study of Dividend
Policy of Quoted Companies in Nigeria. Global Journal of Social Sciences
8:1, 85–101.
Afza, T. and H. H. Mirza (2010) Ownership Structure and Cash Flows as
Determinants of Corporate. International Business Research 3:3, 210–221.
Ahmed, H. and A. Javid (2009) Dynamics and Determinants of Dividend Policy
in Pakistan (Evidence from Karachi Stock Exchange Non-Financial Firms).
International Journal of Finance and Economics 25, 148–171.
Aivazian , V., L. Booth, and S. Cleary (2003) Do Emerging Market Firms
Follow Different Dividend Policies from U.S. Firms. The Journal of
Financial Research 26, 371–3 87.
Akbar, M. and H. H. Baig (2010) Reaction of Stock Prices to Dividend
Announcements and Market Efficiency in Pakistan. The Lahore Journal of
Economics 15:1, 103–125.
Al-Kuwari, D. (2009) Determinants of the Dividend Policy in Emerging Stock
Exchanges: The Case of GCC Countries. Global Economy and Finance
Journal 2:2, 38–63.
Al-Kuwari, D. (2010) To Pay or Not to Pay: Using Emerging Panel Data to
Identify Factors Influencing Corporate Dividend Payout Decisions.
International Research Journal of Finance and Economics 42, 19–36.
Allen, D. E. and V. S. Rachim (1996) Dividend Policy and Stock Price
Volatility: Australian Evidence. Applied Financial Economics 6:2, 175–188.
Allen, D. E. and V. S. Rachim (1996) Dividend Policy and Stock Price
Volatility: Australian Evidence. Applied Financial Economics6:2, 175–188.
Allen, F. and R. Michaely (2002) Payout Policy. Centre for Financial
Institutions. (Working Papers, 01-21).
Allen, F. and R. Michaely (2003) Payout Policy. In G. M. Constantinides, M.
Harris, and R. M. Stulz (eds.) Handbook of the Economics of Finance.
Amsterdam: Elsevier. 337–429.
Alli, K. L., A. Q. Khan, and G. G. Ramirez (1993) Determinants of Corporate
Dividend Policy: A Factorial Analysis. The Financial Review 28:4, 523–547.
Alli, K., A. Khan, and G. Ramirez (1993) Determinants of Corporate Dividend
Policy: A Factorial Analysis. The Financial Review 28, 523–547.
32
Baskin, J. (1989) Dividend Policy and the Volatility of Common Stock. Journal
of Portfolio Management 3:15, 19–25.
Benartzi, S., R. Michaely, and R. Thaler (1997) Do Changes in Dividends Signal
Future or the Past? Journal of Finance 52, 1007–1034.
Bhattacharya, S. (1979) Imperfect Information, Dividend Policy and “the Bird in
the Hand” Fallacy. The Bell Journal of Economics 10:1, 259–270.
Bhattacharyya, N. (2003) Good Managers Work More and Pay Less
Dividends—A Model of Dividend Policy. Available at: http//papers.ssrn.
com/author = 115728.
Bishop, Steven R., R. Crapp Harvey, W. Faff Robert, and J. Twite Garry (2000)
Corporate Finance. Sydney: Prentice Hall Inc.
Black, F. (1976) The Dividend Puzzle. Journal of Portfolio Management 2, 5–
8.
Bradley, M., G. Jarell, and E. H. Kim (1984) On the Existence of an Optimal
Capital Structure: Theory and Evidence. Journal of Finance 39, 857–78.
Brav, A. A., J. Graham, C. Harvey, and R. Michaely(2003) Payout Policy in the
21st Century. Duke University.(Working Paper).
Brealey, R. A. and S. C. Myers (2003). Principles of Corporate Finance. 7th
Edition. New York: McGraw Hill.
Brennan, M. (1971) A Note on Dividend Irrelevance and the Gordon Valuation
Model. The Journal of Finance 26:5, 1115 –1121.
Brigham, E. F. and J. Houston (2004) Fundamentals of Financial Management.
Australia: Thompson South-Western.
Brittain, J. A. (1964) The Tax Structure and Corporate Dividend Policy.
American Economic Review 54:3, 272–287.
Brittain, J. A. (1966) Corporate Dividend Policy. Washington, DC: The
Brookings Institution.
Chen, C. R. and T. L. Steiner (1999) Managerial Ownership and Agency
Conflicts: A Non-linear Simultaneous Equation Analysis of Managerial
Ownership, Risk Taking, Debt Policy, and Dividend Policy. The Financial
Review 34, 119–136.
Chen, D.H., H. H. L. Huang, and T. Cheng (2009) The Announcement Effect of
Cash Dividend Changes on Share Prices: An Empirical Analysis of China.
The Chinese Economy 42:1, 62–85.
Chen, J. and N. Dhiensiri (2009) Determinants of Dividend Policy: The
Evidence from New Zealand. International Research Journal of Finance and
Economics 34, 18–28.
Chernykh, L. (2005) Ultimate Ownership and Corporate Performance in Russia.
Drexel University. (Doctoral Dissertation).
Collins, M. C., A. K. Saxena, and J. W. Wansley (1996) The Role of Insiders
and Dividend Policy: A Comparison of Regulated and Unregulated Firms.
Jorunal of Finance Strategic.
34
Correia da Silva, L., and M. Goergen, and L. Renneboog (2004) Dividend Policy
and Corporate Governance. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
D Suza, J. (1999) Agency Cost, Market Risk, Investment Opportunities and
Dividend Policy. Journal of Manager Financials 25.
DeAngelo, H. and L. DeAngelo (1990) Dividend Policy and Financial Distress:
An Empirical Investigation of Troubled NYSE Firms. The Journal of
Finance 45:5, 1415–1431.
DeAngelo, H., L. DeAngelo, and D. J. Skinner (1996) Reversal of Fortune
Dividend Signalling and the Disappearance of Sustained Earning Growth,
Journal of Financial Economics 40, 341–371.
DeAngelo, H., L. DeAngelo, and D. Skinner (2000) Special Dividends and the
Evolution of Dividend Signalling. Journal of Finance and Economic57, 309–
354.
Demsetz, H. and B. Villalonga (2001) Ownership Structure and Corporate
Performance. Journal of Corporate Finance 7:3, 209–233.
Demsetz, H. and K. Lehn (1985)The Structure of Corporate Ownership: Causes
and Consequences. Journal of Political Economy 93:6, 1155–1177.
Deshmukh, Sanjay (2005) The Effect of Asymmetric Information on Dividend
Policy. Quarterly Journal of Business and Economics 44:1/2, 107–127.
Dewenter, K. L. and V. A. Warther (1998) Dividends Asymmetric Information
and Agency Conflicts: Evidence from a Comparison of the Dividend Policies
of Japanese and U.S. Firms. Journal of Finance 53, 879–904.
Dorsman, A., K. van Montfort, and I. Vink (1999) An adjusted Lintner model
for the Netherlands, Research Memorandum 1999-2000. vrijeUniversiteit
Amsterdam.
Easterbrook, F. H. (1984) Two Agency-Cost Explanations of Dividends. The
American Economic Review 74:4, 650–659.
Eddy, A. and B. Seifert (1988) Firm Size and Dividend Announcements.
Journal of Financial Research.
Eriotis, N. (2005) The effect of Distributed Earnings and Size of the Firm to its
Dividend Policy: Some Greek Data,” International Business and Research
Journal 4:1, 67–74.
Fama, E. (1974) The Empirical Relationships between Dividend and Investment
Decisions of Firms. American Economic Review, June, 304–314.
Fama, E. and K. French (2001) Disappearing Dividends: Changing Firm
Characteristics or Lower Propensity to Pay. Journal of Finance and
Economic 60, 3–43.
Fama, E. F. and H. Babiak (1968) Dividend Policy: An Empirical Analysis.
Journal of the American Statistical Association 63:324, 1132–1161.
Fama, E. F. and M. C. Jensen (1983a). Separation of Ownership and Control.
Journal of Law and Economics 26, 301–325.
35
Manos, Ronny (2002) Dividend Policy and Agency Theory: Evidence on Indian
Firms. Finance and Development Research Programme Working Paper
Series. (Paper No. 41).
McConnell, J. and H. Servaes (1990) Additional Evidence on Equity Ownership
and Corporate Value. Journal of Financial Economics 27:2, 595–612.
Mehar, A. (2005) Corporate Governance and Dividend Policy. Pakistan
Economic and Social Review XLIII:1, 115–128.
Michaely, Roni, Richard Thaler, and Kent Womack (1995) Price Reactions to
Dividend Initiations and Omissions: Overreaction or Drift? Journal of
Finance 50:2, 573–608.
Miller, M. H. and F. Modigliani (1961) Dividend Policy, Growth and the
Valuation of Shares. The Journal of Business 34:4, 411–433.
Miller, M. H. and K. Rock (1985) Dividend Policy under Asymmetric
Information. The Journal of Finance 40:4, 1031–1051.
Miller, M. H. and K. Rock 1985 Dividend Policy Under Asymmetric
Information. The Journal of Finance 40, 1031–1051.
Modigliani, F. and M. H. Miller (1958)The Cost of Capital, Corporation Finance
and the Theory of Investment. The American Economic Review 48:3, 261–297.
Modigliani, F. and M. H. Miller (1959)The Cost of Capital, Corporation
Finance, and the Theory of Investment: Reply. The American Economic
Review 49:4, 655–669.
Modigliani, F. and M. H. Miller (1961) Dividend Policy, Growth, and the
Valuation of Shares. The Journal of Business 34:4, 411–433.
Modigliani, F. and M. H. Miller (1963) Dividend Policy and Market Valuation:
A Reply. The Journal of Business 36:1, 116–119.
Moh’d, M. A., L. G. Perry, and J. N. Rimbey (1995) An Investigation of the
Dynamic Relationship Between Agency Theory and Dividend Policy. The
Financial Review 30:2, 367–385.
Mollah, A. S., K. Keasey, and H. Short (2000) The Influence of Agency Costs
and Dividend Policy in Emerging Market: Evidence from the Dhaka Stock
Exchange. Retrieved November 25, 2001 from the World Wide Web:
www.bath.ac.uk/Centres/CDS/enbs-papers-pdfs/mollahnew.pdf
Mollah, A. S., R. B. Rafiq, and P. A. Sharp (2007) Relevance of Agency Theory
for Dividend Policy in An Emerging Economy: The Case of Bangladesh. The
IFCAI Journal of Applied Finance 13, 5–15.
Mollah, S., K. Keasey, and H. Short (2002) The Influence of Agency Costs on
Dividend Policy in an Emerging Market: Evidence from the Dhaka Stock
Exchange. (Working Paper). www.bath.ac.uk.
Morck, R., A. Shleifer, and R. Vishny (1988) Management Ownership and
Market Valuation: An Empirical Analysis. Journal of Financial Economics
20, 293–315.
39