What Drives Loss Given Default? Evidence From Commercial Real Estate Loans at Failed Banks
What Drives Loss Given Default? Evidence From Commercial Real Estate Loans at Failed Banks
What Drives Loss Given Default? Evidence From Commercial Real Estate Loans at Failed Banks
Published as “Loss Given Default, Loan Seasoning and Financial Fragility: Evidence from Commercial Real Estate Loans at
Failed Banks.” The Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics 63, no. 4 (2021): 630-661. Available online.
fdic.gov/cfr
The Center for Financial Research (CFR) Working Paper Series allows CFR staff and their coauthors to circulate
preliminary research findings to stimulate discussion and critical comment. Views and opinions expressed in CFR Working
Papers reflect those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect those of the FDIC or the United States. Comments and
suggestions are welcome and should be directed to the authors. References should cite this research as a “FDIC CFR
Working Paper” and should note that findings and conclusions in working papers may be preliminary and subject to
revision.
What Drives Loss Given Default? Evidence From Commercial Real
Estate Loans at Failed Banks ∗
Emily Johnston Ross† Lynn Shibut ‡
Abstract
This paper extends what we know about loss given default (LGD) by examining a newly
available dataset on commercial real estate (CRE) loan losses. These data come from 295 failed
banks resolved by the FDIC using loss-share agreements between 2008 and 2013. We examine
over 14,000 distressed CRE loans to study the relationship between LGD and loan size, workout
period, loan seasoning, asset price changes over the life of the loan, and other factors related
to losses. We also examine the relationship between LGD and certain bank characteristics.
The results inform commercial lenders and regulators about the factors that influence losses on
defaulted loans during periods of distress.
Keywords: loss given default; recovery rates; credit risk; commercial real estate
JEL Classification Codes: G21, G32
Opinions expressed in this paper are those of the authors and not necessarily those
of the FDIC.
∗
The authors are very grateful to A.J. Micheli for valuable research assistance. We also thank Rosalind Bennett,
Christine Blair, Oscar Mitnik, and Phil Ostromogolsky, as well as seminar participants at the FDIC Center for
Financial Research and the 2014 Federal Regulatory Interagency Risk Quantification Forum. All errors are entirely
our own.
†
Emily Johnston Ross is a financial economist at the FDIC.
‡
Corresponding author. Lynn Shibut is a senior economist at the FDIC. Email: [email protected].
1 Introduction
Commercial real estate (CRE) lending is a major source of income—and losses—at commercial
banks. It is also a major contributor to bank failure: over 70 percent of U.S. bank failures during
2008–2011 were CRE lending specialists.1 Therefore, a good understanding of CRE credit risk is
Yet large gaps remain in the accumulated knowledge. In his review on loss given default (LGD),
Schuermann (2004) states: “[M]ost of the published research treats recoveries of bonds rather than
loans for the simple reason that that’s where the data is.”2 In addition, most of the LGD literature
has focused on general commercial lending rather than CRE. The research that is available on CRE
loans relies on data from life insurers, securities or large loans that trade on secondary markets.3
A few studies are based on the commercial loan portfolios of very large banks.4 But how relevant
are these results to the portfolios and performance of smaller CRE loans at smaller banks?
This paper begins to fill that gap by exploiting a newly available dataset on CRE loans held by
295 banks that failed in the recent crisis and were resolved using loss-sharing arrangements between
the FDIC and acquiring institutions. Of course, these banks can hardly be characterized as typical.
The banks failed during the worst downturn in 60 years, and the results cover only this distress
period. Even so, an analysis of a wide variety of CRE loans held by small and mid-sized banks
provides important insights. This is the first available study that focuses on LGD for smaller CRE
loans that were originated and held by small and mid-sized banks. Because the sample includes
loans from so many banks, it also enables us for the first time to analyze the effects of certain bank
characteristics on LGD.
LGD is a key component for expected loss, which is central to credit risk management. The
X
EL = P Di × LGDi × EADi (1)
i
1
Source: FDIC calculations. The definitions for lending specialty follow FDIC (2012).
2
Schuermann (2004), 259.
3
For example, see Ciochetti (1997), Gupton, Gates and Carty (2000), Acharya, Bharath and Srinivasan (2003),
and Altman et al. (2005).
4
Asarnow and Edwards (1995) examine loans from Citibank. Araten, Jacobs and Varshney (2004) examine loans
from JPMorgan Chase. Both studies include a mix of commercial loan types, including CRE.
1
where PD is the probability of default from obligor i; LGD is the loss given default, expressed as
a proportion of the total exposure that is lost if default occurs; and EAD is the value in dollars
of that exposure at the time of default. LGD is also directly tied to the recovery rate (RR) on a
defaulted loan. The recovery rate is the proportion of bad debt that may be recovered in the event
of default: RR=1-LGD.
LGD affects several areas of bank operations. It influences the economic capital required to
support the loans, as well as the regulatory capital requirement (at least for large banks that are
risks, including the development of risk metrics, stress testing, and the estimation of loan-loss
reserves on bank financial statements. Many smaller banks struggle with these calculations because
it is difficult to quantify LGD when the bank does not have many defaulted loans—especially if
there are also difficulties in measuring historical LGD for those loans. The results of this study
provide useful insights and benchmarks for these banks and their regulators.
Theoretically, CRE loans default when two conditions are met: 1) the net operating income of
the property falls below the cost of servicing the debt, and 2) the value of the property falls below
the outstanding loan balance.5 In addition, CRE loans might default if the loan has a balloon
payment at maturity and the borrower is unable to obtain new financing, even if one or both of the
above conditions are not met. The subsequent losses are (or may be) influenced by four primary
factors: origination quality, servicing quality, changes in property prices and market conditions,
Origination Quality
Origination quality includes a combination of tangible and intangible items. The loan-to-value
ratio (LTV) and the debt-service coverage ratio (DSCR) are probably the most important; others
include the property type, the quality of the borrower, the extent of the relationship between the
borrower and lender, and the usage of covenants or guarantees to enhance loan quality. Seniority
of creditor status and collateral type have consistently been found to be major determinants of
LGD.6 However, authors who focus solely on CRE loans or structured securities generally omit lien
5
See Moody’s (2011b) and Kim (2013) for additional discussion. Brown, Ciochetti and Riddiough (2006) present
a more nuanced model. Construction and development loans have additional risks.
6
Examples include Acharya, Bharath and Srinivasan (2003), Altman et al. (2005), Schuermann (2004), Araten,
2
status.7 In addition, results of CRE studies can sometimes be inconsistent. For example, Pender-
gast and Jenkins (2003) and Fitch (2012) stratify commercial mortgage-backed securities (CMBS)
recovery rates by property type: Pendergast and Jenkins (2003) find that the retail sector is among
those with the lowest loss severity (31.2%) whereas Fitch (2012) finds retail properties to have the
Servicing Quality
Servicing quality is difficult to measure, but practitioners have often emphasized its impor-
tance.9 Proactive identification and management of problem credits can have a major impact on
LGD. Several authors have found that LGD increases with the length of the workout period.10
However, when interpreting results, it can be difficult to separate servicing effects from the quality
Market Conditions
Numerous studies have focused on the effects of changing market conditions on asset prices.
The authors have found a strong relationship between LGD and industry-wide default rates. For
example, Altman et al. (2005) find that supply and demand factors play a large role in this result.
Acharya, Bharath and Srinivasan (2003) find that distress of the borrower industry dominates over
general macroeconomic conditions. Brown, Ciochetti and Riddiough (2006) explore the effects of
market conditions on the interaction between lender and borrower and related decisions to fore-
close or restructure. They demonstrate why foreclosures and long workout periods occur more often
Loan Seasoning
Loan seasoning matters for LGD because poorly underwritten or poorly managed projects tend
Jacobs and Varshney (2004), and Moody’s (2000). Senior tranches have much lower LGDs. The best collateral type
is marketable securities.
7
For example, Ciochetti (1997), Hu and Cantor (2004) and Fitch (2012). No reason for the omission is stated.
Junior liens may be rare for large loans.
8
Pendergast and Jenkins (2003), 31, and Fitch (2012), 7. Pendergast and Jenkins (2003) report on liquidations
that occurred from 1998 through 2002; Fitch (2012) reports on losses that occurred in 2010.
9
See Bohn (2009), and Cermele, Donato and Mignanelli (2002).
10
See Acharya, Bharath and Srinivasan (2003) and Esaki, L’Heureax and Snyderman (1999).
3
to default shortly after origination, and because market rents and asset prices generally rise over
time (thus current LTV improves). If a loan defaults near its maturity date, the property’s net
income is likely high enough to support the debt payments, making the LGD relatively modest.
Our empirical methodology in this paper is largely driven by the bimodal nature of the LGD
data: we observe a high frequency of defaulted loans that fully recover, with the remainder of those
loans dispersed across a broad range of losses. To address this characteristic, we use a two-stage
estimation approach that allows the factors that influence cure rates to differ from the factors
that influence loss severity. First, we ask what influences the probability of a loan experiencing
zero versus non-zero losses. Second, conditional on experiencing non-zero losses, we ask what
influences the loss severity. We then combine these two stages to estimate the overall marginal
impact on expected LGD. The two-stage approach provides a better understanding of these factor
We see several contributions of this study to the literature: 1) We examine the behavior of
LGD for CRE loans at small and mid-sized banks—the existing literature on LGD has focused on
very large loans or bonds, and it is not known how applicable those results are for typical loans at
typical banks. 2) Because our sample is comprised of defaulted loans at numerous failed banks, we
are able to look at certain bank-level characteristics and their influence on LGD. To our knowledge,
no other papers have examined bank factors affecting LGD. 3) Our two-stage methodology reveals
additional insights that distinguish influences on the probability of zero versus non-zero losses and
on loss severity. 4) We show new evidence suggesting a relationship between loan seasoning and
LGD. (Existing literature has focused on loan seasoning and probability of default (PD).) 5) We
are the first to empirically explore the relationship between judicial foreclosure and out-of-territory
lending and LGD. 6) We also find a new potential channel that increases losses to the FDIC if
The rest of this paper is organized as follows: Section 2 describes the LGD data; Section 3
outlines our methodology; Section 4 presents the results of our analysis; and Section 5 concludes.
4
2 Data
In this section, we describe the FDIC loss-share program (our primary data source) and our defi-
From 2008 through 2013, the FDIC closed 304 banks under its loss-share program. These banks
held $68 billion in CRE loans at failure.11 Under loss share, the acquiring institution purchases
loans from a failed bank and the FDIC indemnifies in part the subsequent credit losses for those
assets. The FDIC uses a database to manage its associated risk exposure and support program
administration. Our definition of LGD flows from the provisions of the loss share program and
related data availability, and our sample covers losses reported from IV/2008 through II/2014.
Under the program, the FDIC covers the following types of losses:
• Expenses paid to third parties related to the asset, except servicing fees (legal fees, foreclosure
If the asset goes into foreclosure, the FDIC is entitled to share in any income earned from the
collateral. The full indemnification period is five years. For an additional three years, the acquirer
is required to continue reporting all losses and recoveries, and continues to share recoveries (net of
Although the FDIC’s share of losses varies by agreement, most of the agreements provide the
acquirers with 80% indemnification for most assets. The FDIC loss coverage may weaken the
incentives of acquirers to work assets effectively. However, the FDIC has taken several actions to
mitigate the potential effects.12 Based on comparisons of these data to other studies, discussions
11
Excluding construction and development loans. The FDIC also entered into a loss-sharing agreement with
Citibank in 2008. This analysis excludes this agreement.
12
Requirements include: a) acquirers must manage the covered assets in the same way that they manage their own
assets; b) acquirers must provide regular standardized reporting, adequate workpapers and evidence that the loans
5
with loss share monitoring staff and program evaluations, we conclude that the mitigation is largely
effective.
Another important provision is that the acquirers only receive FDIC loss-share coverage on bulk
loan sales if the FDIC concurs. Bulk sales of loss share assets have not occurred often because they
generally result in higher LGDs than more active workout strategies. Therefore, for banks that
rely heavily on bulk loan sales to dispose of their problem loans, the results in this paper may not
be very relevant.
• A charge-off was taken on the loan, or any claim was made under the loss-share program
Except as described below, the sample includes all defaulted loans, regardless of whether the ac-
The denominator (EAD) is defined as the exposure at default. The numerator is defined as the
discounted net principal recovery minus expenses. Acquirers do not report all cash inflows under
the loss-share program, but they report principal losses and expenses. Therefore, we estimate
principal recovery as the exposure at default minus principal losses (defined as chargeoffs (COt )
net of recoveries (RECt ) plus the loss on sale (LOSALEt )). We also assume that the entire net
are being worked effectively; and c) the FDIC performs regular reviews of loss claims and on-site compliance reviews
at least once a year. If the FDIC identifies a problem, the agency may demand program improvements, reverse
loss claims or, in the case of a serious contract breach, abrogate the loss share coverage altogether. Acquirers have
the right to contest any FDIC actions. For an example agreement, see https://www.fdic.gov/bank/individual/
failed/oldecypress_p_and_a.pdf.
6
principal recovery occurs when the asset is extinguished.13 Expenses (EXPt ) consist of legal fees,
foreclosure expenses, appraisal fees, property preservation costs, property taxes, etc., and AIt is
the unpaid accrued interest on the loan.14 The loan’s interest rate rt is used as the discount rate.15
Loans with LGDs that exceed 100 percent occur relatively often: for example, they occur any
time that a loan is fully charged off (as a result of unpaid accrued interest plus any collection
expenses). A cap at 100 percent appears reasonable but might understate true losses in light of the
uncertainties and costs involved with a problem loan portfolio. After examining the distribution of
LGDs in our sample, we cap LGD at 130 percent of exposure at default.16 If the loan defaults but
Our definition differs somewhat from the definition of economic loss that is set forth in the
guidance on LGD for the Basel II Advanced Approach models. In addition to the items in our
definition, the Basel II definition includes servicing costs and unpaid fees at the time of default.
Because unpaid fees are usually small, the main difference between our definition and the Basel II
definition for economic loss is the exclusion of servicing costs. Servicing costs can be material yet
All of the loans in our sample were originated prior to the originating bank’s failure, existed
when the bank failed, and were extinguished after the bank failed. Unlike other studies, most of the
loans in our analysis likely underwent a change in the servicing regime over the life of the loan.18
13
An asset is extinguished when it is paid off in full, written off in full, sold, or when it is foreclosed and the
collateral is sold.
14
Details on the expenses and offsetting income covered by loss share can be found at www.fdic.gov. An example
agreement can be found at www.fdic.gov/bank/individual/failed/oldecypress_p_and_a.pdf We use the accrued
interest claim as our estimate for accrued interest costs. In cases where the loan was placed in nonaccrual status prior
to bank failure, the acquirer cannot make such a claim, and unpaid accrued interest has probably been capitalized
into the loan by the failed bank. Our definition excludes capital gains. The loss-share program sets a number of
restrictions on fees imposed on defaulted loans.
15
In a few cases, the interest rate is not available. For these loans, we estimate the interest rate as the rate charged
by the bank for similar loans or, for banks with small portfolios, the average rate charged by all banks for similar
loans. Because we lack a full payment history, we assume that borrowers paid no interest after default if the loan did
not cure, and that borrowers repaid all interest due if the loan cured. Cured loans are defined as loans that defaulted
but were extinguished with no loss claims.
16
LGDs exceed 130 percent before adjustment for 0.9 percent of the loans in the sample. We are not the first
authors to report LGDs above 100 percent. See Araten, Jacobs and Varshney (2004).
17
The Congressional Oversight Panel noted that special servicers that handle problem loans ”typically earn a
management fee of 25 to 50 basis points on the outstanding principal balance of a loan in default as well as 75
basis points to one percent of the new recovery of funds.” See Congressional Oversight Panel (2010), 44. They were
discussing servicing arrangements under Commercial Mortgage Backed Securities, or CMBS. Banks frequently do not
hire special servicers to handle their problem loans, and bank loans are much smaller. Therefore, servicing costs for
bank loans might differ substantially from CMBS loans.
18
A few loans may not have been funded until after the bank failed. A few acquirers may not have made significant
changes to the servicing for some parts of the portfolio.
7
Because many private sector banks retain and service the CRE loans that they originate, servicing
regime changes are less likely at other banks. Because all of the originating banks failed in our
sample, the quality of the loan servicing during the early period of the loan might be weaker than
average. In addition, the originating banks in our sample might have been slow to recognize losses
or aggressively work out their troubled loans to avoid the associated harm to earnings and capital.
On the other hand, the acquiring bank had good reason to recognize losses and work out troubled
loans promptly so that losses could be realized before the FDIC’s loss share coverage expired.
We exclude from the sample foreign loans and very small loans (under $100 exposure at default).
We also exclude loans with meaningful data quality problems for the dependent or independent
variables, and loans where independent variables are missing. The largest number of exclusions
are made for loans that have not yet been extinguished (right-censored).19 LGDs on loans that
are right-censored are difficult to predict because the loans are active assets with unknown future
losses. Unlike most other LGD studies, our dataset is left-censored as well. This occurs because
loans that defaulted and either cured, modified or were extinguished prior to bank failure are not
reported in the loss share data. Therefore, not all loans that defaulted shortly after origination
are present in the sample. These loans are likely to have had relatively low LGDs. Loans that
defaulted well before failure are also excluded. The net effect of left- and right-censoring on LGD
Our final sample for this study includes 14,225 loans from 295 failed banks.21 The data are not
highly concentrated by bank: the top five banks by number of loans hold less than 20 percent of
the sample. The geographic concentrations are much stronger: 19 percent of the loans are from
Georgia, and 65 percent are located in the top five states by number of loans.22 Mean LGD is
44 percent, and the median is slightly lower at 41 percent. Table 1 presents further details. Like
previous authors,23 we find a strong bimodal distribution for LGD, depicted in Figure 1. About 30
19
A total number of 18,035 exclusions (56 percent) were made from a starting sample of 32,460 defaulted loan
observations. Of these 18,035 exclusions, 13,592 (75 percent) were made for censoring (most of these were assets that
were still active). Another 2,691 (15 percent) of the exclusions lacked data for explanatory variables. Other reasons
included foreign assets (4 percent), loan size below $100 (4 percent) and data errors (2 percent).
20
The nature of this censoring has both dependent and independent variable observations missing. These are not
missing relative to any particular threshold values. They are simply outside the snapshot of losses captured at the
time of loss share reporting. Censored or truncated regression modeling would not be suitable for these data.
21
Five banks participated in the loss-share program but had no CRE loans.
22
The top five states are Florida, Georgia, Illinois, California and Washington.
23
See Asarnow and Edwards (1995), Araten, Jacobs, and Varshney (2004), and Schuermann (2004).
8
percent of the loans cured, and 10 percent had LGDs that exceeded 100 percent.
Because our sample is drawn from banks that failed during a severe recession, the results
should be interpreted with care.24 Banks rarely fail unless their portfolios have unusually high
default rates. Moreover, bank failures during the recent crisis were concentrated in geographic
regions that experienced higher-than-average economic distress. Of the 353 banks headquartered
in Georgia at year-end 2007, 87 (25 percent) failed by the end of 2013. None of the banks in North
Dakota failed.25 Despite the sample characteristics, our analysis supports the view that the LGDs
are generally comparable to other CRE bank loans during high-stress periods.26
3 Methodology
The approach we take is motivated largely by the empirical distribution of the LGD data. In Figure
1 we observe a large spike in the LGD distribution for defaulted loans with zero losses, after which
the frequency drops off dramatically. The abrupt spike on the far left tail suggests that the loans
with zero losses may behave differently from the rest of the defaulted loans. In his survey of the
LGD literature, Schuermann (2004) makes a similar observation: “Defaults resulting in 100 percent
recovery (0 percent LGD) are probably somewhat special and should be modeled separately. Put
differently, it is likely that there may be different factors driving this process, or that the factors
With this in mind, we use a two-stage approach in our analysis. In the first stage we ask: What
factors influence the probability of a defaulted loan incurring losses? We assign LGD observations
into binary categories: loans having zero losses are set equal to 0; and loans that incur losses are set
equal to 1. Then we perform a logit regression on the probability of incurring a loss. In the second
stage we ask: Conditional on a defaulted loan incurring losses, what influences the loss severity?
We isolate the sub-sample of defaulted loans that experience losses and perform a linear regression
using their continuous LGD values. We then combine results from the two stages to examine the
marginal impact on expected LGD. Modeling the combination of loss probability and loss severity
in this way allows us to distinguish between drivers of LGD for defaulted loans that experience full
24
Eighty-two percent of the loans in the sample were held by banks that failed in 2009 and 2010.
25
Source: FDIC.
26
See Shibut and Singer (2014) for additional discussion.
27
Schuermann (2004), 270.
9
recoveries and those that do not.
The expected value of LGD in our model is not a simple mean, but is weighted by the probability
n
X
E(LGD) = LGDi × πi + 0 × (1 − πi ) (3)
i=1
where n is the number of defaulted loan observations, LGDi is the estimate of loss given default,
πi is the probability of loan i incurring a loss, and (1 − πi ) is the probability of loan i incurring no
loss. The probability πi of incurring a loss on the defaulted loan is computed from the logit model,
and the loss severity LGDi is computed from the linear regression model.28
In the first stage, we examine what influences the probability of a defaulted loan in our sample
incurring zero versus non-zero losses. We separate the defaulted loans into two categories: those
with losses and those without losses. We have for outcome variable yi :
1 if defaulted loan i incurs a loss
yi =
0 if defaulted loan i has no loss
Then for yi = {0, 1}, the probability of observing realization yi from random variable Yi is:
where πi is the probability that yi takes a value of 1 and (1 − yi ) is the probability that it takes
a value of 0. The logit function takes the underlying probabilities for realization {y1 , · · · , yn } and
28
Leow and Mues (2012) use a similar approach to model LGD for residential mortgage loans. They have a
probability of repossession model to capture the likelihood of an account undergoing repossession given that it has
gone into default, and a haircut model to estimate the discount on the sale price of the repossessed property. The
former is estimated with a logistic regression; the latter uses Ordinary Least Squares, or OLS.
10
links them to the linear predictor variables:
πi
logit(πi ) = log( ) = x0i β (5)
1 − πi
where xi is the vector of covariates and β is the vector of regression coefficients. Solving for the
exp{x0i β}
πi = (6)
1 + exp{x0i β}
In the second stage, we take the LGD loss sample and perform a linear regression. Conditional
on incurring losses, the LGD associated with defaulted loan i takes the form:
where xi is again the vector of covariates and β is the vector of regression coefficients. This allows us
to examine the relationship between explanatory covariates and the severity of losses on these loans.
To control for bank-level fixed effects in our analysis, we use cluster-robust standard errors in
estimation.
4 Analysis
In this section, we describe the explanatory variables in our regressions and discuss our results.
11
4.1 Explanatory variables and expected effects
The defaulted loans in our sample are far smaller in asset size than those examined elsewhere in
the LGD literature. Our sample has a mean loan balance of $929,599 and a median loan balance of
$306,797 at the time of default. For comparison, Esaki et al. (1999) report a mean asset size of $4
million in their sample of CRE loans held by life insurers.29 The smallest loan reported by Gupton
et al. (2000) in their study of U.S. syndicated loans was $60 million.30 Ghent and Valkanov (2014)
report a mean size of $58 million for CMBS loans.31 Because certain collection costs are fixed or
semi-fixed, there is reason to expect that smaller loans would have higher LGDs. We therefore
include ln loan bal, or the log of the asset size at default, in our analysis.
We include several variables related to the seasoning of the loan at the time of default. First,
we include the age of the loan at default, age, to capture the observed tendency for worse quality
loans to default sooner. About 10 percent of the defaulted loans in our sample did so in the first
year, and 43 percent defaulted within the first three years.32 We include the squared term sq age
to allow nonlinear effects of age on LGD. In addition, we include pct remain, the percentage of the
original loan balance remaining unpaid at default. We expect loans that default early, with a high
percentage of the original balance remaining, to have higher LGDs. We also include a dummy for
loans already in default when the bank failed: def ault at f ailure. We expect a positive relationship
with LGD because we anticipate that the servicing quality is generally lower at failed banks than
A key way that banks differentiate loan quality at origination is through the interest rate
offered to the borrower.33 Because our sample includes loans originated in a variety of interest-rate
environments, we use the difference between the loan’s interest rate and the analogous Treasury
29
Esaki et al. (1999), 80.
30
Their primary source is Moody’s, and their analysis covers commercial loans from 1989 through 2000. In the
appendix, they provide loan level information for defaults that occurred in 1999 and 2000; the $60 million is the
smallest figure reported there.
31
They also report a mean size of $23 million for bank CRE loans, but their bank loan sample is not comparable
to the sample in this paper because it excludes loans below $2.5 million.
32
To check for the possibility that loan age is really capturing effects of loan vintage, we included dummies for year
of loan origination. We found that these were insignificant when added to the regression equation and did not change
the impact of loan age on LGD. It appears that our inclusion of the change in the commercial property price index
(CPPI), between origination and extinction, cppi change, appears to effectively control for loan vintage effects.
33
In fact, Morgan and Ashcraft (2003) find that interest rates align with asset quality more closely than with bank
risk metrics calculated at origination.
12
rate at origination.34 The mean interest-rate premium rate prem on these loans is 3.32 percent.
The workout period is an important indicator of both servicing quality (good servicers stay of
top of the assets and move promptly as needed) and origination quality (foreclosure takes time and
occurs more frequently for weaker credits). We include variables for the workout period (wkout),
the squared workout period (sq wkout), and a foreclosure dummy (foreclose). The mean workout
period is 6.12 quarters, and 29 percent of the loans in the sample were foreclosed.
In recognition of the additional costs associated with judicial foreclosure, we include a dummy
indicator for loans where the collateral is located in states that require judicial foreclosures (judi-
cial ).35 We expect that judicial foreclosure will increase LGD, both for foreclosed loans (because of
increased expenses) and other loans with losses (because of stronger bargaining power for distressed
borrowers). As a result of potential complications in both the origination and servicing of loans
that are collateralized by assets outside of the bank’s geographic footprint, we include a dummy
indicator for out-of-territory loans (out territory). The definition follows that of the Community
Reinvestment Act, except that we base the designation on the collateral location rather than the
borrower location. We believe our paper is the first paper that provides empirical evidence on the
We exclude lien status from the core regression on account of missing data for about 3,000
observations. However, we separately report the estimated effect of lien status on LGD in our
results section below. About 10 percent of the remaining loans had junior liens.
We lack data for several relevant items that are related to the origination process and have
been found in prior research to influence LGD. We do not have the original LTV, and thus we
cannot estimate the current LTV. We do not have net operating income for the collateral, and thus
cannot calculate the DSCR. We do not know the type of property (for example, multi-family or
office building); neither do we know the borrower’s industry. We also do not know about the extent
of the relationship between lender and borrower—that is, whether a bank made multiple loans or
13
4.1.2 Bank characteristics
Because banks of different sizes may differ in their resources for the origination and servicing of
loans, we include a variable for the log bank size, ln bank size. The mean failed bank size in our
sample is $805 million, and the median is $281 million. In addition, strong asset growth prior to the
demise of a failed bank could harm the origination and servicing capabilities of the bank. To test
for these effects, we include the average annual loan growth rate of the failed bank for the three-
year period leading up to the peak size of the failed bank: peak growth.36 We base this window
on regulator evidence concerning the life cycle of bank failures.37 We expect that both smaller
banks and banks that grew quickly before failure would face challenges in origination and servicing,
and thus would have higher LGDs. We also include the number of quarters that the bank had a
CAMELS rating of 4 or 5 during the period leading up to failure: delay close. Because failed banks
that experience serious distress for a long time are likely to face more serious resource constraints
than those that fail quickly, and because serious resource constraints might harm servicing quality,
We examined several other bank-level variables that were dropped because of insignificance. The
bank’s coverage ratio and its default rate at failure were expected to serve as further indicators of
bank origination and servicing quality. However, we did not find either of these to be significant in
our regressions. Dummy indicators for year of bank failure were also tested but were not significant.
We looked at business lines for the failed banks; however, most of the banks were classified as CRE
lending specialists and exhibited very little variation. We also examined de novo status, which we
To gauge the overall market condition, we include the year-over-year change in the industry-wide
noncurrent rate for CRE loans at the time of default: industry nc.38 We also capture asset price
changes in commercial real estate from the Commercial Property Price Index (CPPI) published by
36
For banks that shrank for a long period prior to failure, we use the growth rate leading up to failure. For very
high-growth banks, we cap the growth rate at 1000 percent; 21 banks exceeded the cap. Almost all of them were de
novo banks.
37
FDIC (1997). The three-year period was the shorter range observed for the bank failure life cycle; we also tried
the longer range of five years and found similar results.
38
Source: FDIC calculations.
14
CoStar at the regional level. For this variable, we calculate the log change in the regional CPPI
(based on collateral location) between origination and the date when the asset was extinguished:
cppi change. The mean reduction in asset prices between origination and disposition is 20 percent,
and the median is even higher at 25 percent. Many of these properties suffered from very serious
We examined several alternative macro-level variables that were not included in the final re-
gression. We looked at quarterly GDP, unemployment and personal income at the state level,
and regional dummy indicators. We examined other variables to capture real estate market condi-
tions, including the Real Estate Investment Trust (REIT) Equity Index, CMBS delinquency rates,
and the quarterly volume and average price of commercial property repeat sales provided by Real
Capital Analytics. Most of these were eventually left out of the regression equation because of
multi-collinearity, but a few (personal income and regional indicators) were dropped because they
Table 2 presents our explanatory variables in context of the primary factors (origination quality,
servicing quality, changes in property prices and market conditions, and seasoning) described in
Table 4 summarizes our regression findings. Column (1) shows the coefficient estimates from a
simple linear regression using the full LGD sample for comparison. We next categorize LGD as a
binary “loss” variable, where loss=0 for defaulted loans with zero losses and loss=1 for defaulted
loans with losses. We run a logit regression, with the coefficients shown in column (2) and their
marginal effects in column (3).40 In the second stage of the analysis we use a linear regression for
the sub-sample where loss=1. Column (4) shows these coefficients for loss severity. The last column
shows the predicted marginal impact at the mean for a one-unit change in each of the regression
variables. These are calculated by combining results from both logit and linear regression stages
via equation (3). To improve the interpretation of various nonlinear relationships, Figures 2 and
39
Variable correlations and variance inflation factors were also considered in determining the final regression spec-
ification.
40
We also estimate probit and complementary log-log functions as possible alternative linking formulations and
found that the results were not significantly changed.
15
3 provide predictive margins and confidence intervals for selected variables and combinations of
variables. Our findings from the two-stage analysis are largely consistent with the initial linear
regression. However, the two-stage methodology enables a deeper understanding of the covariate
impacts on LGD.
We find that a larger loan size at default is associated with lower losses, aligning with our
intuition regarding the probable effects of fixed or semi-fixed collection costs on smaller loans.
Other explanations for this phenomenon could be that the banks are more actively working the
largest of their defaulted loans for recoveries, or that the larger loans are made to higher-quality
borrowers with better chances for recovery. Other authors have found mixed results regarding
asset size.41 If fixed costs or resource allocation underlie the results, it is logical that the effect
would be stronger for our sample than for other studies that are based on larger assets. Loan size
matters in both the full and loss sample linear regressions, but it is not statistically significant in
the logit regression. This gives us a more nuanced interpretation of loan size effects with respect
to LGD. It does not appear to affect the probability of incurring losses. However, conditional on
loss=1, smaller loans are associated with a higher LGD. The effects are material, especially for
smaller loans: an increase in loan size from $100,000 to $200,000 is associated with a 311 basis
point reduction in LGD; a similar $100,000 increase from $1 million to $1.1 million is associated
Consistent with the literature on effects of loan seasoning on the probability of default (PD),
we find evidence that loan seasoning relates to LGD. Loans defaulting soon after origination and
with higher proportions of unpaid balances remaining may be riskier or lower quality credits. This
influences both the likelihood of incurring losses as well as the loss severity. While the relationship
between loan seasoning and PD has been explored elsewhere, to our knowledge ours is the first
paper to show evidence for a relationship between loan seasoning and LGD. At the mean age of
just over four years, a one-quarter increase in the age of the loan at default is associated with a 47
basis point reduction in LGD. The effects are stronger early in the life of the loan: a one-quarter
increase at 1 year of age is associated with a 62 basis point reduction in LGD. The true marginal
effect might be lower than our measurement to the extent that loan seasoning is serving as a proxy
41
Acharya, Bharath and Srinivasan (2003) find that size is generally not significant at emergence from bankruptcy,
but is often significant for market prices at default. Schuermann (2004) concludes that asset size probably doesn’t
matter. Pendergast and Jenkins (2003) find that size matters for CMBS loans.
16
for origination or servicing quality effects. Loans with lower origination quality are likely to default
sooner. In addition, loans that defaulted before the originating bank failed also have higher losses,
suggesting that the servicing quality for those early defaults may have been weaker.
We also find that a higher percentage of the original loan balance remaining at default is
associated with a higher LGD. This may indicate that amortizing loans provide lenders a little
more safety than comparable balloon loans. The coefficient is significant in the logit regression but
is insignificant in the linear regression for the loss=1 sub-sample. It appears that the relationship
between high loan balances and LGD is driven more by the increased probability of incurring losses
We considered—but rejected—the possibility that the loan seasoning variables might be serving
in some way as a channel of the relationship between default rates and LGD. We include the change
in the industry noncurrent ratio (industry nc) was to try to control for these effects.42 We therefore
think that the relationship between LGD and loan seasoning may indeed matter.
The interest rate premium is insignificant in the linear regression for loss severity, but the logit
regression suggests that a higher interest rate premium is associated with a lower probability of
incurring losses. This may reflect more prudent underwriting standards on some of these loans.
However, the effect of the interest rate premium on the probability of incurring a loss is small.
Workout period appears to matter a great deal: longer workout periods are related to higher
losses, indicating that the servicing quality is an important factor for LGD. Origination quality
may be relevant to this result as well, because inherently weaker credits are less likely to cure
quickly and more likely to be foreclosed. The non-linear workout term indicates that increases in
the length of the workout period probably matter most early in the workout process. This implies
that early efforts in the workout process for defaulted loans may be important for reducing losses.
The workout period is highly significant in both the logit regression and the loss sample regression,
affecting both the probability of incurring loss and the severity of loss. At a mean of 6.2 quarters,
a one-quarter increase in the workout period is associated with a 295 basis point increase in LGD.
The marginal effects are considerably stronger for workout periods of less than two years than for
longer workout periods, perhaps because cures generally occur shortly after default. The marginal
17
As expected, materially higher losses occur with foreclosures. The estimated marginal effect
under the two-stage model is a full 20 percentage points. These loans may be associated with
weaker underwriting, higher expenses, weaker markets and longer time lines.
The judicial foreclosure indicator is insignificant in the logit regression, but it is highly significant
for the loss sample. Having collateral in a judicial foreclosure state does not appear to affect the
probability of a full-recovery on the loan. Intuitively, the additional costs associated with foreclosure
would have no effect on loans that are strong enough to avoid losses. However, these additional
costs are associated with a substantially higher loss severity conditional on loss=1. The estimated
effect is an increase of 550 basis points in severity for loans incurring losses, and 392 basis points for
expected LGD when combined with the logit effects of an increased probability of incurring losses.
One might expect that judicial foreclosure influences LGD for loans where the collateral is
foreclosed but not for other troubled loans. To test this hypothesis, we try interacting the judicial
foreclosure indicator with foreclosure status to see whether foreclosed loans in judicial foreclosure
states have higher losses. We find that the coefficient on this interaction term is insignificant.
Borrowers may be able to seek more concessions from lenders in these locations because both
parties are aware of the additional cost and delay associated with judicial foreclosure. This in turn
Consistent with what we think, loans made out-of-territory are associated with a higher LGD.
This may reflect a greater degree of asymmetric information with out-of-territory lending during
the origination or the servicing process (or both). This effect may also reflect a higher cost of
servicing these loans. The estimated marginal impact on expected LGD for out-of-territory loans
The coefficient for bank size is significant in the logit regression but is insignificant in the loss
sample regression. Bank size is associated with the probability of loss, with smaller banks appearing
to have lower full-recovery rates. This lower rate could be explained in part by better resources at
larger banks for identifying and working problem credits. It may also that some of these smaller
banks accepted more credit risk at origination or lent outside of their core specialization areas in
the lead-up to the crisis. Bank size does not appear to affect the severity of losses, however. Taking
both the logit and linear regression results into account, we estimate that a $100 million marginal
43
Judicial foreclosure (or location in a judicial foreclosure state) may also extend the workout period.
18
increase in bank size (at a median bank size of $281 million) is associated with a 51 basis point
reduction in LGD.
The bank’s asset growth prior to its demise is insignificant in our regression. However, there is
some collinearity of asset growth rates with bank size—smaller banks in our sample tend to have
higher growth rates. We also find that the significance of strong asset growth is affected by the age
of the loan as well as the inclusion of default-at-failure and out-of-territory dummy variables. In
other words, banks with higher growth rates appear more likely to have bad loans that defaulted
early, and they are more likely to have higher out-of-territory lending rates. Thus, the effect of
asset growth rates on LGD may already be captured through other aspects of the regression.
The length of time between being downgraded to a 4 or 5 CAMELS rating and bank failure is
not associated with whether losses occur in the logit regression. However, the time element does
have a positive relationship with loss severity for loans with loss=1. The relationship may indicate
delay the recognition of loan losses. This result also identifies a potential channel for increased
losses when regulators delay closure of problem banks. We estimate that a one-quarter lengthening
of the failed bank’s distress period at the mean of 4.82 quarters is associated with a 110 basis point
increase in LGD.
The change in the industry noncurrent rate is significant in both the logit and the loss sample
regressions, but their effects move in different directions. An increase in the industry noncurrent
rate is associated with a lower probability of incurring losses, but higher LGDs if losses occur. We
think that this may be a supply-side story—when the supply of defaulted loans is high, the market
may lower its valuation of the underlying collateral and thus greater losses may occur (hence the
positive effect in the loss sample). However, despite the higher incidence of noncurrent loans, many
of the better-quality borrowers may eventually be making good on their loans, resulting in a lower
A decline in the CPPI between origination and the end of the workout period is associated with
higher LGDs. This provides evidence that losses are affected by changes in asset prices relative to
origination. The coefficient is negative and statistically significant in both logit and loss sub-sample
regressions, affecting both the probability of incurring loss and loss severity. The marginal effect is
smaller than one might expect: the predicted marginal effect of a 1 percentage point drop in CPPI
19
on LGD at the mean is 16 basis points.
Previous literature has found seniority status to be important for corporate bonds and larger
bank loans.44 When we include a dummy indicator for junior lien status, we see a significant and
positive relationship to LGD. The logit regression suggests that lien status does not influence the
probability of incurring losses, but the linear regression suggests that it is an important factor for
loss severity: it increases the marginal expected losses by over 800 basis points.
Since we differ from others in the literature by capping LGD at 130 percent rather than at 100
percent, we explore how this might affect our results. Around 10 percent of our sample of defaulted
loans exceeds 100 percent. For comparison, we run the same regressions by imposing a cap of 100
percent and find that our results change very little. It does somewhat lower the impact for some
of the explanatory variables—but not in a statistically significant manner. The mean LGDs only
We try dropping our largest failed bank from the sample. We find that the bank size effect
disappears from the full-sample linear regression, but remains significant in the logit regression.
This supports our two-stage conclusion that larger banks have a lower probability of incurring
losses, but do not necessarily appear to differ in the severity of the losses.
Another consideration is loan size. The majority of the loans in our sample are small, with 77
percent below $1 million and 87 percent below $5 million. However, there is a very long right tail
that extends to just over $45 million. Dropping the largest loans in the tail of the loan distribution
produces no significant change in the loan size effects on loss severity. For the logit model, we
observe that loan size is significant in influencing the probability of loss for loans below $1 million,
but is insignificant when loans up to $5 million and above are included. This suggests that loan
We try creating a category for the very smallest loans in our sample. Many of the higher LGDs
come from smaller loans, so we allow for the possibility that these small loans may be driving the
loan size effects on LGD. We include a dummy variable for loans having a balance of $100,000 or
less at default (about 20 percent of the sample). We find this dummy coefficient to be significant,
44
See Acharya, Bharath and Srinivasan (2003) and Schuermann (2004), for example.
20
but the coefficient on loan size still matters. We therefore believe that the loan size effect on loss
severity is not being driven solely by high loss percentages on the smallest of the loans.
To test for the influence of regional factors on LGD, we try including regional dummies and find
that the coefficients on regional dummies are insignificant. Despite seeing geographic concentrations
in the data, there is not much unexplained regional variation in the results. The regional CPPI
index variable appears to have adequately captured the regional effects. Alternately, this result
may be partly explained by the broad reach of the recession during this time period, or because all
In addition, around 5.5 percent of our sample are loans from de novo banks. We include a
dummy indicator variable for de novo status, with the hypothesis that it is likely to be associated
with higher LGDs. The dummy is insignificant, but we do find that de novo status is correlated
with bank size and peak growth rates. Dropping these reveals a significant and positive influence
for de novo status in the logit regression. De novo status thus appears to matter for the probability
of incurring loss, but is otherwise captured through bank size and peak growth rate characteristics
in the regression.
5 Conclusion
In this paper we analyze a new dataset of over 14,000 defaulted CRE loans at 295 failed banks
during the recent financial crisis. We see several contributions of this study to the literature: 1)
We examine LGD for loans at small to mid-sized banks. Since the existing literature on LGD has
focused on large loans or bonds, and it is not known how applicable those results are to typical loans
at typical banks. 2) We provide new evidence suggesting a meaningful relationship between loan
seasoning and LGD. (Existing literature has focused on loan seasoning and probability of default
(PD).) 3) We identify certain bank-level characteristics that influence LGD. To our knowledge, no
other papers have examined bank factors affecting LGD. 4) Our two-stage approach reveals insights
that distinguish influences on the probability of loss and loss severity for LGD. 5) We find, as far
as we know for the first time in published research, empirical evidence of a relationship between
LGD and judicial foreclosure and out-of-territory lending. 6) We find a new potential channel that
could increase losses to the FDIC if regulators delay the closing of troubled banks.
21
We find evidence that the key factors that other authors have found to influence LGD for large
CRE loans tend to have similar effects on smaller CRE loans at failed banks. The length of the
workout period has a significant relationship with LGD, as does foreclosure. Lien status has a
strong effect, and changes in commercial property prices are important. Loan size has a stronger
relationship to LGD in our study than other authors—a characteristic possibly related to the effects
of fixed costs on a sample of loans that are much smaller than studied elsewhere. We estimate that
an increase in loan size from $100,000 to $200,000 is associated with a 311 basis point reduction in
LGD, and a $100,000 increase from $1 million to $1.1 million is associated with a 42 basis point
reduction in LGD. The channel appears to be a smaller severity of losses for loans that do not fully
Although it is well known that loan seasoning influences default rates, the effect of loan seasoning
on LGD for commercial loans has largely been unexplored to date. We find evidence that loan
seasoning has a substantial effect on both the full-recovery rate and the loss severity for uncured
loans. At the mean, a one-quarter increase in the age of the loan at default is associated with a 47
basis point reduction in LGD. The effects appear to be somewhat larger for loans that default shortly
after origination. In addition, the share of the original loan balance that remains outstanding at
default is positively related to loss severity and negatively related to the odds of a full recovery. We
believe that risk measurement and stress testing at banks can be improved by incorporating loan
seasoning into LGD estimation. Supervisors should be aware that loan seasoning influences LGD
as well as PD when considering policies and procedures associated with high loan growth.
We find that CRE loans at small banks tend to have higher LGDs because they experience
lower full-recovery rates than larger banks. At the median, a $100 million increase in bank size
is associated with a 51 basis point reduction in LGD. It is unclear whether this effect relates to
differences in the underwriting or the servicing quality at these banks. It may be that larger banks
are better able to identify problem credits promptly, or small banks face difficulties in maintaining
a high-quality workout staff. This bank size effect could be explained in part by some of these
smaller banks lending beyond their core specializations in the lead-up to the crisis, or by a large
We are able to isolate the relationship of out-of-territory lending to LGD, and find that out-of-
territory loans tend to have moderately higher LGDs, probably because they present challenges in
22
both the origination and servicing functions. In addition, we find that judicial foreclosure regimes
do not influence the odds of experiencing losses, but are associated with a material increase in LGD
for loans that do experience a loss, regardless of whether foreclosure occurs. It appears that judicial
foreclosure may improve the distressed borrower’s position in negotiating with the lender.
For CRE loans with non-zero losses, we find that loss severity is positively related to the length
of time that banks remain in trouble prior to failure. The effects are material: a one-quarter delay
in bank closure at the mean is associated with a 110 basis point increase in LGD. The result points
toward a previously unexplored channel for increasing losses to the FDIC if the closing of troubled
banks is delayed. Troubled banks might experience increasing difficulties in maintaining servicing
quality as their problems persist. This finding supports prompt corrective action provisions for
troubled banks.
All of our results are based on a censored sample of loans from small and mid-sized banks that
failed in the midst of a major recession. Moreover, the loans are geographically concentrated, and
most of them defaulted in the middle of the recession. Therefore, our results should be interpreted
with care.
References
[1] Acharya, V., S. Bharath and A. Srinivasan, (2003), “Understanding the Recovery Rates of
[2] Altman, E., B. Brooks, A. Resti and A. Sironi, (2005), “The Link Between Default and Recovery
Rates: Theory, Empirical Evidence, and Implications,” Journal of Business 78, no. 6:2203–2227.
[3] Altman, E., A. Resti and A. Sironi, (2004), “Default Recovery Rates in Credit Risk Modeling: A
Review of the Literature and Empirical Evidence,” Economic Notes 2: 2004 Review of Banking,
[4] Araten, M., M. Jacobs Jr. and P. Varshney, (2004), “Measuring LGD on Commercial Loans:
[5] Asarnow E. and D. Edwards, (1995), “Measuring Loss on Defaulted Bank Loans: a 24-Year
23
[6] Bellotti, T. and J. Crook, (2012), “Loss Given Default Models Incorporating Macroeconomic
Variables for Credit Cards,” International Journal of Forecasting 28, no. 1:171–182.
[7] Bohn, E., (2009), “The Commercial Real Estate Workout: Strategies for Minimizing Losses in
[8] Brown, D.T., B.A. Ciochetti and T.J. Riddiough, (2006), “Theory and Evidence on the Reso-
lution of Financial Distress,” The Review of Financial Studies 19, no. 4:1357–1397.
[9] Carey, M. and M. Gordy, (2004), “Measuring Systematic Risk in Recoveries on Defaulted Debt I:
Firm-Level Ultimate LGDs,” FDIC: CFR Spring 2005 Research Conference Paper (Draft Memo).
[10] Cermele, M., M. Donato and A. Mignanelli, (2002), “Good Money from Bad Debt,” The
[11] Ciochetti, B.A., (1997), “Loss Characteristics of Commercial Mortgage Foreclosures,” Real
[12] Congressional Oversight Panel, (2010), “Congressional Oversight Panel February Oversight
Report: Commercial Real Estate Losses and the Risk to Financial Stability,” February 10, 2010.
[13] Esaki, H. and M. Goldman, (2005), “Commercial Mortgage Defaults: 30 Years of History,”
[14] Esaki, H., S. L’Heureax and M. Snyderman, (1999), “Commercial Mortgage Defaults: An
[15] FDIC, (1997), History of the Eighties—Lessons for the Future: An Examination of the Banking
[17] FDIC Office of Inspector General, (2012), Evaluation of the FDIC’s Monitoring of Shared-Loss
[18] Federal Register, (2007), “Risk-Based Capital Standards: Advanced Capital Adequacy
24
[19] Felton, A. and J.B. Nichols, (2012), Commercial Real Estate Loan Performance at Failed U.S.
2012.
[22] Ghent, A. and R. Valkanov, (2014), “Comparing Securitized and Balance Sheet Loans: Size
[23] Gupton, G.M., D. Gates and L.V. Carty, (2000), “Bank-Loan Loss Given Default,” Moody’s,
November 2000:69–92.
[24] Hu, J. and R. Cantor, (2004), “Defaults and Losses Given Default of Structured Finance
[25] Hu, Y. and W. Perraudin, (2006), “The Dependence of Recovery Rates and Defaults,” Risk
[26] Kim, Y. (2014), “Modeling of Commercial Real Estate Credit Risks,” Quantitative Finance
[27] Leow, M. and C. Mues, (2012), “Predicting Loss Given Default (LGD) for Residential Mortgage
Loans: A Two-Stage Model and Empirical Evidence for UK Bank Data,” International Journal
of Forecasting 28:183–195.
[28] Moody’s, (2011), “Corporate Default and Recovery Rates, 1920-2010,” February 28, 2011.
[29] Moody’s, (2011), “Modeling Commercial Real Estate Loan Credit Risk: An Overview,” May
3, 2011.
[30] Morgan, D.P. and A.B. Ashcraft, (2003), “Using Loan Rates to Measure and Regulate Bank
Risk: Findings and an Immodest Proposal,” Journal of Financial Services Research 24, no.
2/3:181–200.
[31] Pendergast, L. and E. Jenkins, (2003), “CMBS Loss Severity Study: Portfolio Theory Aside,
25
[32] Shibut, L. and R. Singer, (2014), “Loss Given Default for Commercial Loans at Failed Banks,”
unpublished manuscript.
[33] Schuermann, T., (2004), “What Do We Know About Loss Given Default?” Credit Risk Models
26
6000 4000
Number of loans
2000 0
0 .5 1 1.5
LGD
27
Predictive Margins with 95% CIs Predictive Margins with 95% CIs Predictive Margins with 95% CIs
1
.9
.9
.9
.8
.8
.8
.4 .5 .6 .7
.4 .5 .6 .7
.4 .5 .6 .7
Expected LGD
Expected LGD
Expected LGD
.3
.3
.3
.2
.2
.2
.1
.1
.1
0
0
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 0 .1 .2 .3 .4 .5 .6 .7 .8 .9 1 0 .01 .02 .03 .04 .05 .06 .07 .08 .09 .1
Workout period (quarters) Percent of original loan balance remaining at default Interest rate premium on loan (x100%)
Predictive Margins with 95% CIs Predictive Margins with 95% CIs Predictive Margins with 95% CIs
1
1
.9
.9
.9
.8
.8
.8
.4 .5 .6 .7
.4 .5 .6 .7
.4 .5 .6 .7
Expected LGD
Expected LGD
Expected LGD
.3
.3
.3
28
.2
.2
.2
.1
.1
.1
0
0
0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 22 24 26 28 30 32 34 36 38 40 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
Age of loan at default (quarters) Three year to peak growth rate of failed bank (x100%) Delay to close after CAMELS 4/5 downgrade (quarters)
Predictive Margins with 95% CIs Predictive Margins with 95% CIs Predictive Margins with 95% CIs
1
1
.9
.9
.9
.8
.8
.8
.4 .5 .6 .7
.4 .5 .6 .7
.4 .5 .6 .7
Expected LGD
Expected LGD
Expected LGD
.3
.3
.3
.2
.2
.2
.1
.1
.1
0
0
-.5 -.4 -.3 -.2 -.1 0 .1 .2 .3 .4 .5 .6 .7 .8 .9 1 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17
Log difference in CPPI between loan origination and extinction (x100%) Log bank size at failure Log loan size at default
Figure 2: Plots of the predicted marginal effects on expected LGD for one-unit changes in continuous variables. Calculated by combining
logit and linear effects from both regression stages in equation (3).
Predictive Margins with 95% CIs Predictive Margins with 95% CIs
.8
.7
.6
.6
Expected LGD
Expected LGD
.5
.4
.4 .3
.2
.2
0
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16
Workout period (quarters) Workout period (quarters)
Predictive Margins with 95% CIs Predictive Margins with 95% CIs
.8
.7
.6
.6
Expected LGD
Expected LGD
.4 .5
.4
.3
.2
.2
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16
Workout period (quarters) Workout period (quarters)
Default at failure=0 Default at failure=1 Out of territory loan=0 Out of territory loan=1
Figure 3: Plots of the predicted marginal effects on expected LGD for a change for dummy variable status xi = 0 to xi = 1. Calculated
by combining logit and linear effects from both regression stages in equation (3). Presented relative to workout period as a baseline
trajectory.
Mean LGD 43.78%
Median LGD 41.06%
Standard deviation of LGD 39.48%
Number of loans 17,116
Aggregate loan balance at failure (in millions) $15,911
Total number of failed banks 295
Distribution of loan balances at failure
25th percentile $114,534
Median $306,797
75th percentile $869,104
Mean $929,599
Concentration by bank (based on asset counts)
% from largest bank 6%
% from five largest banks 17%
Concentration by bank (based on asset balances)
% from largest bank 7%
% from five largest banks 25%
Concentration by location
% from state with most failures (GA) 19%
% from 5 states with most failures (GA,CA,FL,IL,WA) 65%
30
Origination quality Servicing quality Property prices & Loan seasoning
market conditions
Loan characteristics
Size of loan at default X X
Age of loan at default X X
Percent remaining balance at default X X X
Loan in default at time of failure X X X
Interest rate premium X
Workout period X X X
Property foreclosed X X X
Collateral in judicial foreclosure state X X
31
Out-of-territory loan X X
Bank characteristics
Size of bank at failure X X
Three-year to peak asset growth rate X X
Ratings downgrading to failure X
Market conditions
Change in industry noncurrent rate X
Change in CPPI X
Unemployment rate X
Table 2: Explanatory variable factors influencing LGD within general classification framework.
Mean Median Std. Min Max
Loan characteristics
Size of loan at default $952,070 $314,055 $2,261,593 $103 $46,100,000
Age of loan at default (in quarters) 16.29 14.18 11.48 0.011 126.91
Percent remaining balance at default 0.867 0.954 0.215 0.0001 1.000
Loan in default at time of bank failure (dummy) 0.267 0 0.443 0 1
Interest rate premium 0.033 0.031 0.247 0 0.232
Workout period (in quarters) 6.12 5.22 5.05 0 30.08
Property foreclosed (dummy) 0.290 0 0.499 0 1
Collateral in judicial foreclosure state (dummy) 0.473 0 0.499 0 1
32
Table 3: Explanatory variable summary statistics. *Calculated across loans in the sample, not across banks.
Coefficients Predicted margin
LGD OLS-full Logit Logit-mfx OLS-loss (in percentage points)
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)
Table 4: Estimation results from (1) full sample linear regression, (2) logit regression estimating probability of nonzero losses, (3) logit
regression marginal effects, (4) linear regression for loss severity conditional on nonzero losses and (5) combined marginal effect on
expected LGD from two-stage logit and conditional loss regressions. Marginal impacts for dummies calculated as a change from 0 to 1;
all others calculated as a 1 unit change at the mean. For each margin calculation, the remaining variables are held constant at their
mean values. Separate squared-term marginal effects not shown as these are combined within the linear term marginal calculations.