Module 3 Lecture 10
Module 3 Lecture 10
Competition
Vera Sharunova
Since the two firms sell their goods at the production cost in equilibrium, both firms
end up with zero profits. They may want to coordinate on a higher price to achieve
higher profits. Q: If explicit collusion were legal in the United States, what price should
the two firms coordinate on? What profits would each of them get? If two firms collude,
they act as a single monopolistic entity and maximize the joint profit. Therefore, they
1
ECON3308.01: Game Theory in Economics Summer 2021
pi
BR
pi > p−i −i pi = p−i
PM BRi
pi < p−i
c
NE
p−i
c PM
Figure 1: Best responses of the competing firms in Bertrand duopoly.
should agree on charging the monopoly price P M and split the monopoly profits ΠM in
some way, perhaps evenly.
Q: Do you think such collusion is sustainable? No, each firm would be tempted to
undercut the competitor’s price P M by an ε and steal all consumers. This game is sim-
ilar to prisoners’ dilemma, where both of the prisoners want to coordinate on defecting
(or, in our setting, not admitting to having a gun), but are too tempted to snitch and
therefore both choose to confess, ending up in a bad outcome with higher sentence. The
competitors may start off charging high prices, but eventually give into the tempta-
tion, and lower them. This phenomenon is well-documented empirically and is known
as Edgeworth price cycles. Figure 2 is an example of the fluctuations of average
daily and weekly gas prices at gas stations in Toronto and Windsor, Canada observed in
2007.1 As we can see, Toronto’s gas stations start each day with high prices, which get
progressively lower over the course of the day. Similar situation is observed at Windsor’s
gas stations with the evidence presented at the weekly level.
In reality, competitors are not allowed to discuss their pricing strategies with each other,
but may resort to tacit collusion. Tacit collusion is a situation in which firms silently
adopt strategies that minimize competition. Price-match guarantees are an example of
sustaining tacit price collusion. As described by Cabral et al. (2018), if a firm lowers
its price when both firms adopt price-match guarantees, it has the effect of lowering
1
The figure is taken from Noel (2015).
2
ECON3308.01: Game Theory in Economics Summer 2021
Figure 2: Weekly Edgeworth price cycle in Windsor and daily Edgeworth price cycle in
Toronto, 2007. Source: Figure 1 in Noel (2015).
the rival firm’s price by the same amount. Thus, temptation to cheat on the colluding
partner disappears. We will explore more examples of tacit collusion when we talk about
repeated prisoners’ dilemma later in the course.
First, we need to set up the profit functions of the two firms as a function of their
individual outputs qi and q−i . Since we only have two firms in the market, the total
quantity in the market is just the sum of the two firms’ individual quantities. In other
words, Q = qi + q−i . Notice also that the market demand curve is currently expressed
as a function of price P . Since the two firms compete in quantities, and therefore will
be maximizing their profits with respect to quantities, we need to rewrite the market
demand curve as a function of Q. In economics, we refer to this function P (Q) as an
inverse demand function.
A Q
Q(P ) = A − bP ⇒ bP = A − Q(P ) ⇒ P (Q) = −
b b
3
ECON3308.01: Game Theory in Economics Summer 2021
A
Plug Q = qi + q−i into the inverse demand function and let b
= α, 1b = β to get
A qi + q−i
P (qi , q−i ) = − = α − β(qi + q−i )
b b
We are now ready to set up the profit function of firm i.
max πi (qi , q−i ) = P (qi , q−i )qi − cqi = (α − β(qi + q−i ) − c)qi
qi | {z } |{z}
Total Revenue Total Cost
∂πi
= α − 2βqi − βq−i − c = 0
∂qi
Rearrange the first order condition to get the best response of firm i as a function of q−i
α − βq−i − c
qi = (1)
2β
Since both firms face the same inverse demand curve P (qi , q−i ) and have the same costs,
the best response of firm −i is the same as the best response of firm i.
α − βqi − c
q−i = (2)
2β
In order to find the pure-strategy Nash equilibrium of this game, we need to find a pair
of (qi∗ , q−i
∗
) that are best responses to each other. In other words, we are looking for a
∗ ∗
pair of (qi , q−i ) that simultaneously satisfy both equations (1) and (2).
{ { ( ) {
qi = α−βq2β−i −c α
qi = 2β − 21 α−βq
2β
i −c
− c
2β
= α
4β
− c
4β
+ qi
4 qi∗ = α−c
3β
α−βqi −c α−βqi −c ∗ α−c
q−i = 2β q−i = q−i = 3β
2β
∗ α − βq ∗ − c 3 α−c α−c
q = ⇒ q∗ = ⇒ q∗ =
2β 2 2β 3β
Let us now find the price at which a unit of the good is sold. Plug the equilibrium qi∗
∗
and q−i into the inverse demand function.
2(α − c) α + 2c
∗
P ∗ = P (qi∗ , q−i )=α−β =
3β 3
4
ECON3308.01: Game Theory in Economics Summer 2021
Similarly to the Bertrand duopoly, we can graph the two firms’ best responses in the
qi -q−i coordinate plane. See Figure ??.
qi
α−c
β
BR−i
α−c
2β
α−c NE
3β
BRi
q−i
α−c α−c α−c
3β 2β β
Figure 3: Best responses of the competing firms in Cournot duopoly.
Let us start by graphing firm i’s best response. Since it is linear in q−i , we only need to
find two points to graph it, e.g. its intercepts:
α−c
1. When q−i = 0, qi = .
2β
α−c
2. If qi = 0, q−i = .
β
The best response function of firm −i is symmetric to the best response of firm i. The
two lines intersect at qi∗ = q−i
∗
= α−c
3β
, which is the pure-strategy Nash equilibrium of the
Cournot duopoly game.
Notice that the best response functions are downward-sloping, meaning that when one
firm increases the output, the other firm will respond by decreasing its output. If one
player is decreasing (or increasing) its choice variable and the opponent responds by
increasing (or decreasing) its choice variable, then the two choice variables are called
strategic substitutes.
Collusion can also exist when firms compete in quantities. For example, OPEC is an
international cartel of oil producing countries, where the member states agree on pro-
duction quotas to control oil prices. The incentives to cheat and produce above the
agreed production quotas are still present, much like in the price collusion example.
5
ECON3308.01: Game Theory in Economics Summer 2021
References
[1] Cabral, L., Dürr, N., Schober, D., & Woll, O. (2018). Price Matching Guarantees
and Collusion: Theory and Evidence from Germany. Working Paper, New York
University.
[2] Noel, M. D. (2015). Do Edgeworth Price Cycles Lead to Higher or Lower Prices?.
International Journal of Industrial Organization, 42, 81-93.