Mba Me Notes
Mba Me Notes
5. Capital management: The problems relating to firm’s capital investments are perhaps the most complex and
troublesome. Capital management implies planning and control of capital expenditure because it involves a large
sum and moreover the problems in disposing the capital assets off are so complex that they require considerable
time and labour. The main topics dealt with under capital management are cost of capital, rate of return and selection
of projects.
A Business economist helps the management by using his analytical skills and highly developed techniques in
solving complex issues of successful decision-making and future advanced planning.
The role of Business economist can be summarized as follows:
1. He studies the economic patterns at macro-level and analysis it’s significance to the specific firm he is
working in.
2. He has to consistently examine the probabilities of transforming an ever-changing economic environment
into profitable business avenues.
3. He assists the business planning process of a firm.
4. He also carries cost-benefit analysis.
5. He assists the management in the decisions pertaining to internal functioning of a firm such as changes in
price, investment plans, type of goods /services to be produced, inputs to be used, techniques of production
to be employed, expansion/ contraction of firm, allocation of capital, location of new plants, quantity of
output to be produced, replacement of plant equipment, sales forecasting, inventory forecasting, etc.
6. In addition, a Business economist has to analyze changes in macro- economic indicators such as national
income, population, business cycles, and their possible effect on the firm’s functioning.
7. He is also involved in advicing the management on public relations, foreign exchange, and trade. He guides
the firm on the likely impact of changes in monetary and fiscal policy on the firm’s functioning.
8. He also makes an economic analysis of the firms in competition. He has to collect economic data and
examine all crucial information about the environment in which the firm operates.
9. The most significant function of a Business economist is to conduct a detailed research on industrial
market.
10. In order to perform all these roles, a Business economist has to conduct an elaborate statistical analysis.
11. He must be vigilant and must have ability to cope up with the pressures.
12. He also provides management with economic information such as tax rates, competitor’s price and product,
etc. They give their valuable advice to government authorities as well.
13. At times, a Business economist has to prepare speeches for top management.
Q3. EXPLAIN THE RELATIONSHIP OF BUSINESS ECONOMICS WITH THE OTHER DISCIPLINE?
Q1. WHAT IS DEMAND? EXPLAIN THE LAW OF DEMAND ITS EXCEPTIONS AND ALSO THE
TYPES OF DEMAND?
Demand
Demand for a commodity refers to the quantity of the commodity that people are willing to purchase at a specific
price per unit of time, other factors (such as price of related goods, income, tastes and preferences, advertising, etc)
being constant. Demand includes the desire to buy the commodity accompanied by the willingness to buy it and
sufficient purchasing power to purchase it. For instance-Everyone might have willingness to buy “Mercedes-S class”
but only a few have the ability to pay for it. Thus, everyone cannot be said to have a demand for the car “Mercedes-s
Class”.
Demand may arise from individuals, household and market. When goods are demanded by individuals (for instance-
clothes, shoes), it is called as individual demand. Goods demanded by household constitute household demand (for
instance-demand for house, washing machine). Demand for a commodity by all individuals/households in the
market in total constitute market demand.
Demand Function
Demand function is a mathematical function showing relationship between the quantity demanded of a commodity
and the factors influencing demand.
Dx = f (Px, Py, T, Y, A, Pp, Ep, U)
In the above equation,
Dx = Quantity demanded of a commodity
Px = Price of the commodity
Py = Price of related goods
T = Tastes and preferences of consumer
Y = Income level
A = Advertising and promotional activities
Pp = Population (Size of the market)
Ep = Consumer’s expectations about future prices
U = Specific factors affecting demand for a commodity such as seasonal changes, taxation policy, availability of
credit facilities, etc.
Law of Demand
The law of demand states that there is an inverse relationship between quantity demanded of a commodity and it’s
price, other factors being constant. In other words, higher the price, lower the demand and vice versa, other things
remaining constant.
Demand Schedule
Demand schedule is a tabular representation of the quantity demanded of a commodity at various prices. For
instance, there are four buyers of apples in the market, namely A, B, C and D.
Demand schedule for apples
PRICE (Rs. per Buyer A (demand Buyer B (demand Buyer C (demand Buyer D (demand Market Demand
dozen) in dozen) in dozen) in dozen) in dozen) (dozens)
10 1 0 3 0 4
9 3 1 6 4 14
8 7 2 9 7 25
7 11 4 12 10 37
6 13 6 14 12 45
The demand by Buyers A, B, C and D are individual demands. Total demand by the four buyers is market demand.
Therefore, the total market demand is derived by summing up the quantity demanded of a commodity by all buyers
at each price.
Demand Curve
Demand curve is a diagrammatic representation of demand schedule. It is a graphical representation of price-
quantity relationship. Individual demand curve shows the highest price which an individual is willing to pay for
different quantities of the commodity. While, each point on the market demand curve depicts the maximum quantity
of the commodity which all consumers taken together would be willing to buy at each level of price, under given
demand conditions.
Demand curve has a negative slope, i.e, it slopes downwards from left to right depicting that with increase in price,
quantity demanded falls and vice versa. The reasons for a downward sloping demand curve can be explained as
follows-
1. Income effect- With the fall in price of a commodity, the purchasing power of consumer increases. Thus,
he can buy same quantity of commodity with less money or he can purchase greater quantities of same
commodity with same money. Similarly, if the price of a commodity rises, it is equivalent to decrease in
income of the consumer as now he has to spend more for buying the same quantity as before. This change
in purchasing power due to price change is known as income effect.
2. Substitution effect- When price of a commodity falls, it becomes relatively cheaper compared to other
commodities whose price have not changed. Thus, the consumer tend to consume more of the commodity
whose price has fallen, i.e, they tend to substitute that commodity for other commodities which have not
become relatively dear.
3. Law of diminishing marginal utility- It is the basic cause of the law of demand. The law of diminishing
marginal utility states that as an individual consumes more and more units of a commodity, the utility
derived from it goes on decreasing. So as to get maximum satisfaction, an individual purchases in such a
manner that the marginal utility of the commodity is equal to the price of the commodity. When the price of
commodity falls, a rational consumer purchases more so as to equate the marginal utility and the price
level. Thus, if a consumer wants to purchase larger quantities, then the price must be lowered. This is what
the law of demand also states.
Innumerable factors and circumstances could affect a buyer's willingness or ability to buy a good. Some of the more
common factors are:
I. Good's own price: The basic demand relationship is between potential prices of a good and the quantities
that would be purchased at those prices. Generally the relationship is negative meaning that an increase in
price will induce a decrease in the quantity demanded. This negative relationship is embodied in the
downward slope of the consumer demand curve. The assumption of a negative relationship is reasonable
and intuitive. If the price of a new novel is high, a person might decide to borrow the book from the public
library rather than buy it.
II. Price of related goods: The principal related goods are complements and substitutes. A complement is a
good that is used with the primary good. Examples include hotdogs and mustard, beer and pretzels,
automobiles and gasoline.(Perfect complements behave as a single good.) If the price of the complement
goes up the quantity demanded of the other good goes down. Mathematically, the variable representing the
price of the complementary good would have a negative coefficient in the demand function. For example,
Qd = a - P - Pg where Q is the quantity of automobiles demanded, P is the price of automobiles and P g is the
price of gasoline. The other main category of related goods are substitutes. Substitutes are goods that can be
used in place of the primary good. The mathematical relationship between the price of the substitute and
the demand for the good in question is positive. If the price of the substitute goes down the demand for the
good in question goes down.
III. Personal Disposable Income: In most cases, the more disposable income (income after tax and receipt of
benefits) a person has the more likely that person is to buy.
IV. Tastes or preferences: The greater the desire to own a good the more likely one is to buy the good. There
is a basic distinction between desire and demand. Desire is a measure of the willingness to buy a good
based on its intrinsic qualities. Demand is the willingness and ability to put one's desires into effect. It is
assumed that tastes and preferences are relatively constant.
V. Consumer expectations about future prices, income and availability: If a consumer believes that the
price of the good will be higher in the future, he/she is more likely to purchase the good now. If the
consumer expects that his/her income will be higher in the future, the consumer may buy the good now.
Availability (supply side) as well as predicted or expected availability also affects both price and demand.
VI. Population: If the population grows this means that demand will also increase.
VII. Nature of the good: If the good is a basic commodity, it will lead to a higher demand
VIII. This list is not exhaustive. All facts and circumstances that a buyer finds relevant to his willingness or
ability to buy goods can affect demand. For example, a person caught in an unexpected storm is more likely
to buy an umbrella than if the weather were bright and sunny.
TYPES OF DEMAND
i) Direct and Derived Demands
Direct demand refers to demand for goods meant for final consumption; it is the demand for
consumers’ goods like food items, readymade garments and houses. By contrast, derived demand
refers to demand for goods which are needed for further production; it is the demand for producers’
goods like industrial raw materials, machine tools and equipments.
ii) Domestic and Industrial Demands:- The example of the refrigerator can be restated to distinguish
between the demand for domestic consumption and the demand for industrial use. In case of certain
industrial raw materials which are also used for domestic purpose, this distinction is very meaningful.
iii) Autonomous and Induced Demand
When the demand for a product is tied to the purchase of some parent product, its demand is called
induced or derived.
For example, the demand for cement is induced by (derived from) the demand for housing.
Autonomous demand is not derived or induced. Unless a product is totally independent of the use of
other products, it is difficult to talk about autonomous demand. In the present world of dependence,
there is hardly any autonomous demand. Nobody today consumers just a single commodity; everybody
consumes a bundle of commodities. Even then, all direct demand may be loosely called autonomous.
iv) Perishable and Durable Goods’ Demands
Both consumers’ goods and producers’ goods are further classified into perishable/non-durable/single-
use goods and durable/non-perishable/repeated-use goods.
v) New and Replacement Demands
If the purchase or acquisition of an item is meant as an addition to stock, it is a new demand. If the
purchase of an item is meant for maintaining the old stock of capital/asset, it is replacement demand.
Such replacement expenditure is to overcome depreciation in the existing stock.
vi) Final and Intermediate Demands
This distinction is again based on the type of goods- final or intermediate. The demand for semi-
finished products, industrial raw materials and similar intermediate goods are all derived demands,
vii) Individual and Market Demands
This distinction is often employed by the economist to study the size of the buyers’ demand,
individual as well as collective. A market is visited by different consumers, consumer differences
depending on factors
viii) Total Market and Segmented Market Demands
This distinction is made mostly on the same lines as above. Different individual buyers together may
represent a given market segment; and several market segments together may represent the total
market.
x) Company and Industry Demands
An industry is the aggregate of firms (companies). Thus the Company’s demand is similar to an
individual demand, whereas the industry’s demand is similar to aggregated total demand. You may
examine this distinction from the standpoint of both output and input.
Q2. EXPLAIN THE ELASTICITY OF DEMAND AND ITS TYPES AND DIFFERENT DEGREES?
1. PRICE ELASTICITY OF DEMAND
The responsiveness or sensitivity of consumers quantity demanded to a change in price is
measured by the Price Elasticity of Demand. The price elasticity of demand is a measure of the
extent to which the quantity demanded of a good changes when the price of the good changes and
all other influences on buyers’ plans remain the same
.
1. The midpoint method uses the average of the initial price and new price in the denominator when calculating a
percentage change. Because the average price is the same between two prices regardless of whether the price
falls or rises, the percentage change in price calculated by the midpoint method is the same for a price rise and a
price fall.
(New
( New price + Initial price )÷2 )
price − Initial price
× 100 .
Use the midpoint method when calculating the percentage change in quantity.
(New
( New quantity + Initial quantity )÷2 )
quantity − Initial quantity
× 100 .
1. Minus Sign
Because a change in price causes an opposite change in quantity demanded, for the price elasticity of
demand we focus on the magnitude of the change by using the absolute value.
1. Substitution Effect
If good substitutes are readily available, demand is elastic. If good substitutes are hard to find, demand is
inelastic.
2. Three factors determine how easy substitutes are to find:
a. Luxury versus necessity—there are few substitutes for necessities (so demand is price inelastic) and
there are many substitutes for luxuries (so demand is price elastic).
b. Narrowness of definition—the more narrowly defined the good is, the more elastic its demand. The
more broadly defined the good, the less elastic its demand.
c. Time elapsed since price change—the longer the time that has passed since the price change, the
more elastic is demand.
3. Income Effects
The larger the proportion of income spent on the good, the more elastic is demand because a price
change has a large, noticeable impact on the budget. The smaller the proportion of income spent on the
good, the less elastic is demand.
D. Computing the Price Elasticity of Demand
V. Perfectly Elastic Demand – Quantity demanded will go from 0 to infinity at a particular product
price. That is, if the price isn’t right, 0 is demanded, as soon as the price is right, infinite amounts
will be demanded. Ed = INFINTE
F. Determinants of price elasticity of demand
1. Substitutability – the greater the number of substitute goods that are available, the greater the price
elasticity of demand (more substitute goods = demand is more sensitive to price). Ex/ there is not a good
substitute for insulin, therefore it is relatively inelastic demand; however, there are many substitutes for
Fritos corn chips, therefore, demand for them is relatively elastic
2. Luxury versus Necessity – The more that a good is considered a luxury rather than a necessity, the
greater is the price elasticity of demand. Ex/ Heating, Food, water are all considered necessities, therefore
demand for them will be rather inelastic.
3. Proportion of Income – The higher the price of a good relative to consumers’ incomes, the greater the
price elasticity of demand. Ex/ a 100% increase in the price of a two penny box of matches is a very low
fraction of my annual salary, compared to a 100% increase in the price of a porshe boxter (60K to 12K)
So the price elasticity of demand on the match box will be much more inelastic than on the porshe boxter
4. Time – demand is more elastic the longer the period under consideration. Ex/ if the price of a CokaCola
goes up, I might not switch to Pepsi at first, but the more time I have to pay the higher price, the more
willing I am to try Pepsi and to determine whether Pepsi or other substitute products are good enough
2. CROSS ELASTICITY OF DEMAND
The cross elasticity of demand is a measure of the extent to which the demand for a good changes when the
price of a substitute or complement changes, other things remaining the same.
The income elasticity of demand is a measure of the extent to which the demand for a good changes when
income changes, other things remaining the same. The formula used to calculate the income elasticity of
demand is:
Percentage change in quantity demanded
Income elasticity of demand = .
Percentage change in income
For a normal good, the income elasticity of demand is positive.
When the income elasticity of demand is greater than 1, demand is income elastic.
When the income elasticity of demand is between zero and 1, demand is income inelastic. For an inferior
good, the income elasticity of demand is less than 0.
Q3. WHAT IS DEMAND FORECASTING? EXPLAIN THE TECHINQUES OF DEMAND
FORECASTING?
A forecast is a prediction or estimation of future situation. It is an objective assessment of future course of action.
Since future is uncertain, no forecast can be percent correct. Forecasts can be both physical as well as financial in
nature. The more realistic the forecasts, the more effective decisions can be taken for tomorrow.
In the words of Cundiff and Still, “Demand forecasting is an estimate of sales during a specified future period which
is tied to a proposed marketing plan and which assumes a particular set of uncontrollable and competitive forces”.
Therefore, demand forecasting is a projection of firm’s expected level of sales based on a chosen marketing plan and
environment.
In Fig. 1, AB is the trend line which has been drawn as free hand curve passing through the various points
The regression equation can also be written in a multiplicative form as given below:
Quantum of Sales = (Price)a + (Advertising)b+ (Price of the rival products) c + (Personal disposable income Y + u
In the above case, the exponent of each variable indicates the elasticities of the corresponding variable. Stating the
independent variables in terms of notation, the equation form is QS = P°8. Ao42 . R°.83. Y2°.68. 40
Then we can say that 1 per cent increase in price leads to 0.8 per cent change in quantum of sales and so on.
If we take logarithmic form of the multiple equation, we can write the equation in an additive form as
follows:
log QS = a log P + b log A + с log R + d log Yd + log u
In the above equation, the coefficients a, b, c, and d represent the elasticities of variables P, A, R and
Yd respectively.
The co-efficient in the logarithmic regression equation are very useful in policy decision making by the
management.
(iv) Econometric Models:
Econometric models are an extension of the regression technique whereby a system of independent regression
equation is solved. The requirement for satisfactory use of the econometric model in forecasting is under three
heads: variables, equations and data.
The appropriate procedure in forecasting by econometric methods is model building. Econometrics attempts to
express economic theories in mathematical terms in such a way that they can be verified by statistical methods and
to measure the impact of one economic variable upon another so as to be able to predict future events.
Criteria of a Good Forecasting Method:
There are thus, a good many ways to make a guess about future sales. They show contrast in cost, flexibility and the
adequate skills and sophistication. Therefore, there is a problem of choosing the best method for a particular demand
situation.
There are certain economic criteria of broader applicability. They are:
(i) Accuracy, (ii) Plausibility, (iii) Durability, (iv) Flexibility, (v) Availability, (vi) Economy, (vii) Simplicity and
(viii) Consistency.
(i) Accuracy:
The forecast obtained must be accurate. How is an accurate forecast possible? To obtain an accurate forecast, it is
essential to check the accuracy of past forecasts against present performance and of present forecasts against future
performance. Accuracy cannot be tested by precise measurement but buy judgment.
(ii) Plausibility:
The executive should have good understanding of the technique chosen and they should have confidence in the
techniques used. Understanding is also needed for a proper interpretation of results. Plausibility requirements can
often improve the accuracy of results.
(iii) Durability:
Unfortunately, a demand function fitted to past experience may back cost very greatly and still fall apart in a short
time as a forecaster. The durability of the forecasting power of a demand function depends partly on the
reasonableness and simplicity of functions fitted, but primarily on the stability of the understanding relationships
measured in the past. Of course, the importance of durability determines the allowable cost of the forecast.
(iv) Flexibility:
Flexibility can be viewed as an alternative to generality. A long lasting function could be set up in terms of basic
natural forces and human motives. Even though fundamental, it would nevertheless be hard to measure and thus not
very useful. A set of variables whose co-efficient could be adjusted from time to time to meet changing conditions in
more practical way to maintain intact the routine procedure of forecasting.
(v) Availability:
Immediate availability of data is a vital requirement and the search for reasonable approximations to relevance in
late data is a constant strain on the forecasters patience. The techniques employed should be able to produce
meaningful results quickly. Delay in result will adversely affect the Business decisions.
(vi) Economy:
Cost is a primary consideration which should be weighted against the importance of the forecasts to the business
operations. A question may arise: How much money and Business effort should be allocated to obtain a high level of
forecasting accuracy? The criterion here is the economic consideration.
(vii) Simplicity:
Statistical and econometric models are certainly useful but they are intolerably complex. To those executives who
have a fear of mathematics, these methods would appear to be Latin or Greek. The procedure should, therefore, be
simple and easy so that the management may appreciate and understand why it has been adopted by the forecaster.
(viii) Consistency:
The forecaster has to deal with various components which are independent. If he does not make an adjustment in
one component to bring it in line with a forecast of another, he would achieve a whole which would appear
consistent.
UNIT-III
Q1. WHAT IS PRODUCTION ANALYSIS? EXPLAIN THE LAWS OF PRODUCTION?
PRODUCTION ANALYSIS
PRODUCTION
Production is concerned with the way in which resources or inputs such as land, labor, and machinery
are employed to produce a firm’s product or output. Production may be either services or goods. To produce the
goods we use inputs. Basically inputs are divided into two types. those are fixed inputs and variable inputs. Fixed
inputs are the inputs that remain constant in short-term. Variable inputs are inputs, which are variable in both short-
term and long-term.
Production Function
Production function expresses the relationship between inputs and outputs. Production function is an
equation, a table, a graph, which express the relationship between inputs and outputs. Production function explains
that the maximum output of goods or services that can be produced by a firm in a specific time with a given amount
of inputs or factors of production.
Production Function: Q = f (K, L)
We are producing Q quantities of goods by employing K capital and L labor.
Here
Q Represents quantity of goods
K Represents Capital employed
L Represents Labor employed
Production Function:
“Production Function” is that function which defines the maximum amount of output that can be
produced with a given set of inputs.
– Michael R Baye
“Production Function” is the technical relationship, which reveals the maximum amount of output
capable of being produced by each and every set of inputs, under the given technology of a
firm. - Samuelson
From the above definitions, it can be concluded that the production functions is more concerned with
physical aspects of production, which is an engineering relation that expresses the maximum amount of output that
can be produced with a given set of inputs.
Production function enables production manager to understand how better he can make use of
technology to its greatest potential.
The production function is purely a relationship between the quantity of output obtained or given out by
a production process and the quantities of different inputs used in the process. Production function can take many
forms such as linear function or cubic function etc.
1. Production function shows the maximum output that can be produced by a specific set of combination of input
factors.
2. There are two types of production function, one is short-run production function and the other is long-run production
function. The short-run production explains how output change is relation to input when there are some fixed
factors. Similarly, long run production function explains the behaviors of output in relation to input when all inputs
are variable.
3. The production function explains how a firm reaches the most optimum combination of factors so that the unit costs
are the lowest.
4. Production function explains how a producer combines various inputs in order to produce a given output in an
economically efficient manner.
5. The production function helps us to estimate the quantity in which the various factors of production are combined.
Short-Term production function is a function, which we are producing goods in the short-term by employing two
inputs that are :
Capital (K) : It is fixed input which is constant in the short-term.
Labor (L) : It is variable input in the short-term.
In the short-term we are producing only one product by employing two inputs
The two inputs are K capital and L is labor.
In the short term we will increase L input and we will keep K as constant.
It follows that:
100 units of output require
1 (2C + 2L) = 2C + 2L
200 units of output require
2 (2C + 2L) = 4C + 4L
300 units of output require
3 (2C + 2L) = 6C + 6L
The returns to scale are constant when internal economies enjoyed by a firm are neutralised by internal
diseconomies so that output increases in the same proportion. Another reason is the balancing of external economies
and external diseconomies.
Constant returns to scale also result when factors of production are perfectly divisible, substitutable, homogeneous
and their supplies are perfectly elastic at given prices. That is why, in the case of constant returns to scale, the
production function is homogeneous of degree one.
Alternative Method:
We have explained above the three laws of returns to scale separately on the assumption that there are three
processes and each process shows the same returns over all ranges of output. “However, the technological
conditions of production may be such that returns to scale may vary over different ranges of output. Over some
range, we may have constant returns to scale, while over another range we may have increasing or decreasing
returns to scale.”
To explain it we draw an expansion path OR from the origin in Fig. 11 This are divided into segments by the
successive isoquants representing equal increments in output, i.e., 100, 200, 300 and so on. As we move along the
expansion path, the distance between the successive isoquants diminishes, it is a case of increasing returns to scale.
This stage is shown in the figure from К to M. The distance between KL and Z.M becomes smaller LM<KL. The
firm, therefore, requires smaller increases in the quantities of labour and capital to produce equal increments of
output.
If the segments between two isoquants are of equal length, there are constant returns to scale. If labour and capital
are doubled, the output would also be doubled. Thus, when output increases from 300 to 400 and to 500 units, the
isoquants representing these output levels mark off equal distances along the scale line, up to point P, i.e., MN = NP.
If these are decreasing returns to scale, the distance between a pair of isoquants would become longer on the
expansion path. ST is longer than PS. It shows that to increase output larger increases in quantities of labour and
capital are required. Thus, on the same expansion path from К to M, there are increasing returns to scale, from M to
P, there are constant returns to scale and from P to T, and there are diminishing returns to scale.
The table 1 shows that the five combinations of labour units and units of capital yield the same level of output, i.e.,
200 metres of cloth. Thus, 200 metre cloth can be produced by combining.
(a) 1 units of labour and 15 units of capital
(b) 2 units of labour and 11 units of capital
(c) 3 units of labour and 8 units of capital
(d) 4 units of labour and 6 units of capital
(e) 5 units of labour and 5 units of capital
Iso-Product Curve:
From the above schedule iso-product curve can be drawn with the help of a diagram. An. equal product curve
represents all those combinations of two inputs which are capable of producing the same level of output. The Fig. 1
shows the various combinations of labour and capital which give the same amount of output. A, B, C, D and E.
Iso-Product Map or Equal Product Map:
An Iso-product map shows a set of iso-product curves. They are just like contour lines which show the different
levels of output. A higher iso-product curve represents a higher level of output. In Fig. 2 we have family iso-product
curves, each representing a particular level of output.
The iso-product map looks like the indifference of consumer behaviour analysis. Each indifference curve represents
particular level of satisfaction which cannot be quantified. A higher indifference curve represents a higher level of
satisfaction but we cannot say by how much the satisfaction is more or less. Satisfaction or utility cannot be
measured.
An iso-product curve, on the other hand, represents a particular level of output. The level of output being a physical
magnitude is measurable. We can therefore know the distance between two equal product curves. While indifference
curves are labeled as IC1, IC2, IC3, etc., the iso-product curves are labelled by the units of output they represent -100
metres, 200 metres, 300 metres of cloth and so on.
The Fig. 3 shows that when the amount of labour is increased from OL to OL1, the amount of capital has to be
decreased from OK to OK1, The iso-product curve (IQ) is falling as shown in the figure.
The possibilities of horizontal, vertical, upward sloping curves can be ruled out with the help of the following
figure 4:
(i) The figure (A) shows that the amounts of both the factors of production are increased- labour from L to Li and
capital from K to K1. When the amounts of both factors increase, the output must increase. Hence the IQ curve
cannot slope upward from left to right.
(ii) The figure (B) shows that the amount of labour is kept constant while the amount of capital is increased. The
amount of capital is increased from K to K1. Then the output must increase. So IQ curve cannot be a vertical straight
line.
(iii) The figure (C) shows a horizontal curve. If it is horizontal the quantity of labour increases, although the quantity
of capital remains constant. When the amount of capital is increased, the level of output must increase. Thus, an IQ
curve cannot be a horizontal line.
2. Isoquants are Convex to the Origin:
Like indifference curves, isoquants are convex to the origin. In order to understand this fact, we have to understand
the concept of diminishing marginal rate of technical substitution (MRTS), because convexity of an isoquant implies
that the MRTS diminishes along the isoquant. The marginal rate of technical substitution between L and K is
defined as the quantity of K which can be given up in exchange for an additional unit of L. It can also be defined as
the slope of an isoquant.
It can be expressed as:
MRTSLK = – ∆K/∆L = dK/ dL
Where ∆K is the change in capital and AL is the change in labour.
Equation (1) states that for an increase in the use of labour, fewer units of capital will be used. In other words, a
declining MRTS refers to the falling marginal product of labour in relation to capital. To put it differently, as more
units of labour are used, and as certain units of capital are given up, the marginal productivity of labour in relation to
capital will decline.
This fact can be explained in Fig. 5. As we move from point A to B, from B to C and from C to D along an isoquant,
the marginal rate of technical substitution (MRTS) of capital for labour diminishes. Everytime labour units are
increasing by an equal amount (AL) but the corresponding decrease in the units of capital (AK) decreases.
Thus it may be observed that due to falling MRTS, the isoquant is always convex to the origin.
3. Two Iso-Product Curves Never Cut Each Other:
As two indifference curves cannot cut each other, two iso-product curves cannot cut each other. In Fig. 6, two Iso-
product curves intersect each other. Both curves IQ1 and IQ2 represent two levels of output. But they intersect each
other at point A. Then combination A = B and combination A= C. Therefore B must be equal to C. This is absurd. B
and C lie on two different iso-product curves. Therefore two curves which represent two levels of output cannot
intersect each other.
In the Fig. 7, units of labour have been taken on OX axis while on OY, units of capital. IQ 1 represents an output
level of 100 units whereas IQ2 represents 200 units of output.
5. Isoquants Need Not be Parallel to Each Other:
It so happens because the rate of substitution in different isoquant schedules need not be necessarily equal. Usually
they are found different and, therefore, isoquants may not be parallel as shown in Fig. 8. We may note that the
isoquants Iq1 and Iq2 are parallel but the isoquants Iq3 and Iq4 are not parallel to each other.
6. No Isoquant can Touch Either Axis:
If an isoquant touches X-axis, it would mean that the product is being produced with the help of labour alone
without using capital at all. These logical absurdities for OL units of labour alone are unable to produce anything.
Similarly, OC units of capital alone cannot produce anything without the use of labour. Therefore as seen in figure
9, IQ and IQ1cannot be isoquants.
The analysis of cost is important in the study of Business economics because it provides a basis for two important
decisions made by managers:
In this Unit, we shall discuss some important cost concepts that are relevant for Business decisions. We analyse the
basic differences between these cost concepts and also, examine how accountants and economists differ on
treating different cost concepts. We will continue the discussion on cost concepts and analysis .
Explicit costs are those costs that involve an actual payment to other parties. Therefore, an explicit cost is the
monitory payment made by a firm for use of an input owned or controlled by others. Explicit costs are also
referred to as accounting costs. For example, a firm pays Rs. 100 per day to a worker and engages 15 workers
for 10 days, the explicit cost will be Rs. 15,000 incurred by the firm. Other types of explicit costs include
purchase of raw materials,
renting a building, amount spent on advertising etc. On the other hand, implicit costs represent the value of
foregone opportunities but do not involve an actual cash payment. Implicit costs are just as important as explicit
costs but are sometimes neglected because they are not as obvious. For example, a manager who runs his own
business fore goes the salary that could have been earned working for someone else as we have seen in
our earlier example. This implicit cost generally is not reflected in accounting statements, but rational decision-
making requires that it be considered. Therefore, an implicit cost is the opportunity cost of using resources that
are owned or controlled by the owners of the firm. The implicit cost is the foregone return, the owner of the
firm could have received had they used their own resources in their best alternative use rather than using the
resources for their own firm’s production.
for a long time, there has been a considerable disagreement among economists and accountants on how costs should
be treated. The reason for the
difference of opinion is that the two groups want to use the cost data for dissimilar purposes. Accountants always
have been concerned with firms’
financial statements. Accountants tend to take a retrospective look at firms finances because they keep trace of
assets and liabilities and evaluate past
performance. The accounting costs are useful for managing taxation needs as well as to calculate profit or loss of the
firm. On the other hand,
economists take forward-looking view of the firm. They are concerned with what cost is expected to be in the future
and how the firm might be able to
rearrange its resources to lower its costs and improve its profitability. They must therefore be concerned with
opportunity cost. Since the only cost that
matters for business decisions are the future costs, it is the economic costs that are used for decision-making.
Accountants and economists both include explicit costs in their calculations. For accountants, explicit costs are
important because they involve direct payments made by a firm. These explicit costs are also important
for economists as well because the cost of wages and materials represent money that could be useful elsewhere. We
have already seen, while discussing actual costs and opportunity costs, how economic cost can differ from
accounting cost. In that example we have seen how a person who owns business chooses not to consider his/her own
salary. Although, no monitory transaction has occurred (and thus would not appear as an accounting cost), the
business nonetheless incurs an opportunity cost because the owner could have earned a competitive salary by
working elsewhere. Accountants and economists use the term ‘profits’ differently. Accounting profits are the firm’s
total revenue less its explicit costs. But economists define profits differently. Economic profits are total revenue less
all costs (explicit and implicit costs). The economist takes into account the implicit costs (including a
normal profit) in addition to explicit costs in order to retain resources in a given line of production. Therefore, when
an economist says that a firm is just
covering its costs, it is meant that all explicit and implicit costs are being met, and that, the entrepreneur is receiving
a return just large enough to retain his/her talents in the present line of production. If a firm’s total receipts
exceed all its economic costs, the residual accruing to the entrepreneur is called an economic profit, or pure
profit. Example of Economic Profit and Accounting Profit Mr. Raj is a small store owner. He has invested Rs. 2
lakhs as equity in the store and inventory. His annual turnover is Rs. 8 lakhs, from which he must deduct the cost of
goods sold, salaries of hired staff, and depreciation of equipment and building to arrive at annual profit of the store.
He asked help of a friend who is an accountant by profession to prepare annual income
statement. The accountant reported the profit to be Rs. 1.5 lakhs. Mr. Raj could not believe this and asked the help
of another friend who is an economist
by profession. The economist told him that the actual profit was only Rs. 75,000 and not Rs. 1.5 lakhs. The
economist found that the accountant
had underestimated the costs by not including the implicit costs of time spent as Manager by Mr. Raj in the business
and interest on owner’s equity. The twoincome statements are shown below:
Controllable costs are those which are capable of being controlled or regulated by executive vigilance and,
therefore, can be used for assessing
executive efficiency. Non-controllable costs are those, which cannot be subjected to administrative control and
supervision. Most of the costs are
controllable, except, of course, those due to obsolescence and depreciation. The level at which such control can
be exercised, however, differs: some costs (like, capital costs) are not controllable at factory’s shop level, but
inventory costs can be controlled at the shop level. Out-of-pocket costs and Book costs Out of pocket costs are
those costs that improve current cash payments to outsiders. For example, wages and salaries paid to the
employees are out-of pocket costs. Other examples of out-of-pocket costs are payment of rent, interest, transport
charges, etc. On the other hand, book costs are those
business costs, which do not involve any cash payments but for them a provision is made in the books of
account to include them in profit and loss accounts and take tax advantages. For example, salary of owner
manager, if not paid, is a book cost. The interest cost of owner’s own fund and
depreciation cost are other examples of book cost. The out-of-pocket costs are also called explicit costs and
correspondingly book costs are called implicit or imputed costs. Book costs can be converted into out-of-pocket
costs by selling assets and leasing them back from buyer. Thus, the difference between these two categories of
cost is in terms of whether the company owns it or not. If a factor of production is owned, its cost is a book cost
while if it is hired it is an out-of-pocket cost. Past and Future costs Past costs are actual costs incurred in the
past and they are always contained in the income statements. Their measurement is essentially a record
keeping activity. These costs can only be observed and evaluated in retrospect. If they are regarded as
excessive, management can indulge in post-mortem checks just to find out the factors responsible for the
excessive costs, if any,
without being able to do anything about reducing them. Future costs are those costs that are likely to be incurred
in future periods. Since the future is uncertain, these costs have to be estimated and cannot be expected to be
absolutely correct figures. Past costs serve as the basis for projecting future costs. In periods of inflation and
deflation, the two cost concepts differ significantly. Business decisions are always forward looking and
therefore they require estimates of future costs and not past costs. Unlike past costs, future costs are subject to
management control and they can be planned or avoided. If the future costs are considered too high,
management can either plan to reduce them or find out ways and means to meet them. Management needs
to estimate future costs for a variety of reasons such as expense control pricing, projecting future profits and
capital budgeting decisions. When historical costs are used instead of explicit projections, the assumption is
made that future costs will be the same as past costs. In periods of significant price variations, such an
assumption may lead to wrong Business decisions.
The historical cost of an asset is the actual cost incurred at the time, the asset was originally acquired. In
contrast to this, replacement cost is the cost, which will have to be incurred if that asset is purchased now.
The difference between the historical and replacement costs results from price changes over time. Suppose a
machine was acquired for Rs. 50,000 in the year 1995 and the same machine can be acquired for Rs. 1,20,000 in
the year 2001. Here Rs. 50,000 is the historical or original cost of the machine and Rs. 1,20,000 is its
replacement cost. The difference of Rs.70,000 between the two costs has resulted because of the price change of
the machine during the period. In the conventional financial accounts the value of assets is shown at their
historical costs. But for decision-making, firms should try to adjust historical costs to reflect price level
changes. If the price of the asset does not change over time, the historical cost will be the same as the
replacement cost. If the price raises the replacement cost will exceed historical cost and vice versa. During
periods of substantial price variations, historical costs are poor indicators of actual costs Historical costs and
replacement costs represent two ways of reflecting the costs of assets in the balance sheet and establishing the
costs that are used to determine net income. The assets are usually shown in the conventional accounts at their
historical costs. These must be adjusted for price changes for a correct estimate of costs and profits. Business
decisions must be based on replacement cost rather than historical costs. The historical cost of an asset
is known, for it is actually incurred while acquiring that asset. Replacement cost relates to the current price of
that asset and it will be known only if an enquiry
is made in the market.
A further distinction that is useful to make - especially in the public sector - is between private and social costs.
Private costs are those that accrue directly to the individuals or firms engaged in relevant activity. Social costs, on
the\ other hand, are passed on to persons not involved in the activity in any direct way (i.e., they are passed on to
society at large). Consider the case of a manufacturer located on the bank of a river who dumps the waste into
water rather than disposing it of in some other manner. While the private cost to the firm of dumping is zero, it is
definitely harmful to the society. It affects adversely the people located down current and incur higher costs in terms
of treating the water for their use, or having to travel a great deal to fetch potable water. If these external costs were
included in the production costs of a producing firm, a true picture of real, or social costs of the output would
be obtained. Ignoring external costs may lead to an inefficient and undesirable allocation of resources in society.
The relevant costs for decision-making purposes are those costs, which are incurred as a result of the decision
under consideration. The relevant costs are
also referred to as the incremental costs. Costs that have been incurred already and costs that will be incurred in
the future, regardless of the present
decision are irrelevant costs as far as the current decision problem is concerned.
There are three main categories of relevant or incremental costs. These are the present-period explicit costs, the
opportunity costs implicitly involved in the decision, and the future cost implications that flow from the
decision. For example, direct labour and material costs, and changes in the variable overhead costs are the
natural consequences of a decision to increase the output level. Also, if there is any expenditure on capital
equipments incurred as a result of such a decision, it should be included in full, not withstanding that the
equipment may have a useful life remaining after the present decision has been carried out. Thus, the
incremental costs of a decision to increase output level will include all present-period explicit costs, which will
be incurred as a consequence of this decision. It will exclude any present-period explicit cost that will be
incurred regardless of the present decision. The opportunity cost of a resource under use, as discussed earlier,
becomes a relevant cost while arriving at the economic profit of the firm. Many decisions will have implications
for future costs, both explicit and implicit. If a firm expects to incur some costs in future as a consequence of
the present analysis, such future costs should be included in the present value terms if known for certain.
8. Sunk Costs and Incremental Costs
Sunk costs are expenditures that have been made in the past or must be paid in the future as part of contractual
agreement or previous decision. For
example, the money already paid for machinery, equipment, inventory and future rental payments on a
warehouse that must be paid as part of a long term lease agreement are sunk costs. In general, sunk costs are not
relevant to economic decisions. For example, the purchase of specialized equipment designed to order for a
plant. We assume that the equipment can be used to do only what it was originally designed for and cannot be
converted for alternative use. The expenditure on this equipment is a sunk cost. Also, because this equipment
has no alternative use its opportunity cost is zero and, hence, sunk costs are not relevant to economic decisions.
Sometimes the sunk costs are also called as non-avoidable or non-escapable costs.
On the other hand, incremental cost refers to total additional cost of implementing a Business decision. Change
in product line, change in output
level, adding or replacing a machine, changing distribution channels etc. are examples of incremental costs.
Sometimes incremental costs are also called as avoidable or escapable costs. Moreover, since incremental costs
may also be regarded as the difference in total costs resulting from a contemplated change, they are also called
differential costs. As stated earlier sunk costs are irrelevant for decision making, as they do not vary with the
changes contemplated for future by the management.
There are some costs, which can be directly attributed to production of a given product. The use of raw material,
labour input, and machine time involved in the production of each unit can usually be determined. On the other
hand, there are certain costs like stationery and other office and administrative expenses, electricity charges,
depreciation of plant and buildings, and other such expenses that cannot easily and accurately be separated and
attributed to individual units of production, except on arbitrary basis. When referring to the separable costs of first
category accountants call them the direct, or prime costs per unit. The accountants refer to the joint costs of the
second category as indirect or overhead costs. Direct and indirect costs are not exactly synonymous to what
economists refer to as variable costs and fixed costs. The criterion used by the economist to divide cost into either
fixed or variable is whether or not the cost varies with the level of output, whereas the accountant divides the cost on
the basis of whether or not the cost is separable with respect to the production of individual output units. The
accounting statements often divide overhead expenses into ‘variable overhead’ and ‘fixed overhead’ categories. If
the variable overhead expenses per unit are added to the direct cost per unit, we arrive at what economists call as
average variable cost
Costs can also be classified on the basis of their traceability. The costs that can be easily attributed to a product,
a division, or a process are called
separable costs. On the other hand, common costs are those, which cannot be traced to any one unit of
operation. For example, in a multiple product firm
the cost of raw material may be separable (traceable) product-wise but electricity charges may not be separable
product-wise. In a university the
salary of a Vice-Chancellor is not separable department-wise but the salary of teachers can be separable
department-wise. The separable and common costs are also referred to as direct and indirect costs respectively.
The distinction between direct and indirect costs is of particular significance in a multi-productfirm for setting
up economic prices for different products.
Total cost (TC) of a firm is the sum-total of all the explicit and implicit expenditures incurred for producing a
given level of output. It represents the
money value of the total resources required for production of goods and services. For example, a shoe-maker’s
total cost will include the amount she/
he spends on leather, thread, rent for his/her workshop, interest on borrowed capital, wages and salaries of
employees, etc., and the amount she/he charges for his/her services and funds invested in the business. Average
cost (AC) is the cost per unit of output. That is, average cost equals the total cost divided by the number of units
produced (N). If TC = Rs. 500 and N = 50 then AC = Rs. 10. Marginal cost (MC) is the extra cost of producing
one additional unit. At a given level of output, one examines the additional costs being incurred in producing
one extra unit and this yields the marginal cost. For example, if TC of producing 100 units is Rs. 10,000 and the
TC of producing 101 units is Rs. 10,050, then MC at N = 101 equals
Rs.50. Marginal cost refers to the change in total cost associated with a one-unit change in output. This cost
concept is significant to short-term decisions about profit maximizing rates of output. For example, in an
automobile manufacturing plant, the marginal cost of making one additional car per production period would be
the labour, material, and energy costs directly associated with that extra car. Marginal cost is that sub category
of incremental cost in the sense that incremental cost may include both fixed costs and marginal costs
However, when production is not conceived in small units, management will be interested in incremental cost
instead of marginal cost. For example, if a firm produces 5000 units of TV sets, it may not be possible to
determine the change in cost involved in producing 5001 units of TV sets. This difficulty can be resolved by
taking units to significant size. For example, if the TV sets produced is measured to hundreds of units and total
cost (TC) of producing the current level of three hundred TV sets is Rs. 15,00,000 and the firm decides to
increase the production to four hundred TV sets and estimates the TC as Rs. 18,00,000, then the incremental
cost of producing one hundred TV sets (above the present production level of three hundred units) is Rs.
3,00,000. The total cost concept is useful in break-even analysis and finding out whether a firm is making profit
or not. The average cost concept is significant for calculating the per unit profit. The marginal and incremental
cost concepts are needed in deciding whether a firm needs to expand its production or not. In fact, the relevant
costs to be considered will depend upon the situation or production problem faced by the manager.
Fixed costs are that part of the total cost of the firm which does not change with output. Expenditures on
depreciation, rent of land and buildings, property taxes, and interest payment on bonds are examples of fixed
costs. Given a capacity, fixed costs remain the same irrespective of actual output. Variable costs, on the other
hand, change with changes in output. Examples of variable costs are wages and expenses on raw
material. However, it is not very easy to classify all costs into fixed and variable. There are some costs, which
fall between these extremes. They are called semi variable costs. They are neither perfectly variable nor
absolutely fixed in relation to changes in output. For example, part of the depreciation charges is fixed, and part
variable. However, it is very difficult to determine how much of depreciation cost is due to the technical
obsolescence of assets and hence fixed cost, and how much is due to the use of equipments and hence
variable cost. Nevertheless, it does not mean that it is not useful to classify costs into fixed and variable. This
distinction is of great value in break-even analysis and pricing decisions. For decision-making purposes, in
general, it is the variable cost, which is relevant and not the fixed cost. To an economist the fixed costs are
overhead costs and to an accountant these are indirect costs. When the output goes up, the fixed cost per unit of
output comes down, as the total fixed cost is divided between larger units of output.
The short run is defined as a period in which the supply of at least one element of the inputs cannot be changed.
To illustrate, certain inputs like
machinery, buildings, etc., cannot be changed by the firm whenever it so desires. It takes time to replace, add or
dismantle them. Long run, on the
other hand, is defined as a period in which all inputs are changed with changes in output. In other words, it is
that time-span in which all adjustments and
changes are possible to realise. Thus, in the short run, some inputs are fixed (like installed capacity) while
others are variable (like the level of capacity
utilisation); but in the long run all inputs, including the size of the plant, are variable. Short-run costs are the
costs that can vary with the degree of utilisation of plant and other fixed factors. In other words, these costs
relate to the variation in output, given plant capacity. Short-run costs are, therefore, of two types: fixed costs
and variable costs. In the short-run, fixed costs remain unchanged while variable costs fluctuate with output.
Long-run costs, in contrast, are costs that can vary with the size of plant and with other facilities
normally regarded as fixed in the short-run. In fact, in the long-run there are no fixed inputs and therefore no
fixed costs, i.e. all costs are variable. Both short-run and long-run costs are useful in decision-making. Short-run
cost is relevant when a firm has to decide whether or not to produce and if a decision is taken to produce then
how much more or less to produce with a given plant size. If the firm is considering an increase in plant size, it
must examine the long-run cost of expansion. Long-run cost analysis is useful in investment decisions.
UNIT-IV
Market is a place where buyers and sellers meet and exchange goods or services. And now if we extend this concept
a little more, there are certain conditions which create the structure of a market. Such conditions can be condensed in
the following –
Number of Buyers
Number of sellers
Buyer Entry Barriers
Seller Entry Barriers
Size of the firm
Product Differentiation/ Homogeneous Product
Market Share
Competition
In market economies, there are a variety of different market systems that exist, depending on the industry and the
companies within that industry. It is important for small business owners to understand what type of market system
they are operating in when making pricing and production decisions, or when determining whether to enter or leave a
particular industry.
1. Perfect Competition
Perfect competition is a market system characterized by many different buyers and sellers. In the classic
theoretical definition of perfect competition, there are an infinite number of buyers and sellers. With so many
market players, it is impossible for any one participant to alter the prevailing price in the market. If they attempt
to do so, buyers and sellers have infinite alternatives to pursue. Though in concept perfect competition exists,
however in real life only near perfect competition can exist. And the staple food and vegetables we buy from the
market is perfect competition. However when they start branding they move toward oligopoly.
In case of Monopsony and Oligopsony there are almost no practical examples though they are just the opposite
of monopoly and oligopoly respectively (buyers rule).
Perfect competition, a theoretical market structure that features no barriers to entry, an unlimited number of
producers and consumers, and a perfectly elastic demand curve
2. Monopoly
A monopoly is the exact opposite form of market system as perfect competition. In a pure monopoly, there is only
one producer of a particular good or service, and generally no reasonable substitute. In such a market system, the
monopolist is able to charge whatever price they wish due to the absence of competition, but their overall revenue
will be limited by the ability or willingness of customers to pay their price. Companies which are state owned and
entry for other players are not allowed. If we take example from Indian perspective there is one example we can
think of is Indian railway which is the monopoly as there is no other contributor exercising in the same market.
where there is only one provider of a product or service.
Natural monopoly, a monopoly in which economies of scale cause efficiency to increase continuously with the
size of the firm. A firm is a natural monopoly if it is able to serve the entire market demand at a lower cost than
any combination of two or more smaller, more specialized firms.
In which a market is run by a small number of firms that together control the majority of the market share. Let’s take
a common example. Look around your locality. There are some good numbers of restaurants serving their
customers. Though they might be producing same kind of recipes, the branding would be different. And that’s the
catch of monopolistic competition. Many buyers, many sellers, almost same product but different branding and
fierce competition.
3. Monopolistic Competition
Monopolistic competition is a type of market system combining elements of a monopoly and perfect competition.
Like a perfectly competitive market system, there are numerous competitors in the market. The difference is that
each competitor is sufficiently differentiated from the others that some can charge greater prices than a perfectly
competitive firm. An example of monopolistic competition is the market for music. While there are many artists,
each artist is different and is not perfectly substitutable with another artist
In monopolistic competition, we still have many sellers (as we had under perfect competition). Now, however, they
don’t sell identical products. Instead, they sell differentiated products—products that differ somewhat, or
are perceived to differ, even though they serve a similar purpose. Products can be differentiated in a number of
ways, including quality, style, convenience, location, and brand name. Some people prefer Coke over Pepsi, even
though the two products are quite similar. But what if there was a substantial price difference between the two? In
that case, buyers could be persuaded to switch from one to the other. Thus, if Coke has a big promotional sale at a
supermarket chain, some Pepsi drinkers might switch (at least temporarily).
How is product differentiation accomplished? Sometimes, it’s simply geographical; you probably buy gasoline at the
station closest to your home regardless of the brand. At other times, perceived differences between products are
promoted by advertising designed to convince consumers that one product is different from another—and better than
it. Regardless of customer loyalty to a product, however, if its price goes too high, the seller will lose business to a
competitor. Under monopolistic competition, therefore, companies have only limited control over price.
4. Oligopoly
An oligopoly is similar in many ways to a monopoly. The primary difference is that rather than having only one
producer of a good or service, there are a handful of producers, or at least a handful of producers that make up a
dominant majority of the production in the market system. While oligopolists do not have the same pricing power as
monopolists, it is possible, without diligent government regulation, that oligopolists will collude with one another to
set prices in the same way a monopolist would. In US and other countries people buy their automobiles from
different companies. Here the buyers are many, sellers are few, and competition is high. Oligopoly means few
sellers. In an oligopolistic market, each seller supplies a large portion of all the products sold in the marketplace. In
addition, because the cost of starting a business in an oligopolistic industry is usually high, the number of firms
entering it is low.
Companies in oligopolistic industries include such large-scale enterprises as automobile companies and airlines. As
large firms supplying a sizable portion of a market, these companies have some control over the prices they charge.
But there’s a catch: because products are fairly similar, when one company lowers prices, others are often forced to
follow suit to remain competitive. You see this practice all the time in the airline industry: When American Airlines
announces a fare decrease, Continental, United Airlines, and others do likewise. When one automaker offers a
Q2. EXPLAIN THE CONCEPT OF FIRM, INDUSTRY, AND PRICE UNDER PERFECT COMPETITION
It is essential to know the meanings of firm and industry before analyzing the two. A firm is an organization which
produces and supplies goods that are demanded by the people. According to Prof. S.E. Lands-bury, “Firm is an
organization that produces and sells goods with the goal of maximizing its profits. In the words of Prof. R.L.
Miller, “Firm is an organization that buys and hires resources and sells goods and services.”
Industry is a group of firms producing homogeneous products in a market. In the words of Prof. Miller, “Industry is
a group of firms that produces a homogeneous product.” For example, Raymond, Maffatlal, Arvind, etc., are cloth
manufacturing firms, whereas a group of such firms is called the textile industry.
Equilibrium of the Firm:
a) Meaning:
A firm is in equilibrium when it has no tendency to change its level of output. It needs neither expansion nor
contraction. It wants to earn maximum profits. In the words of A.W. Stonier and D.C. Hague, “A firm will be in
Equilibrium of the firm can be analysed in both short-run and long-run periods. A firm can earn the maximum
profits in the short run or may incur the minimum loss. But in the long run, it can earn only normal profit.
b) Short-run Equilibrium of the Firm:
The short run is a period of time in which the firm can vary its output by changing the variable factors of production
in order to earn maximum profits or to incur minimum losses. The number of firms in the industry is fixed because
neither the existing firms can leave nor new firms can enter it.
It’s Conditions:
The firm is in equilibrium when it is earning maximum profits as the difference between its total revenue and total
cost.
(1) MC = MR, and (2) the MC curve must cut the MR curve from below at the point of equality and then rise
upwards.
The price at which each firm sells its output is set by the market forces of demand and supply. Each firm will be able
to sell as much as it chooses at that price. But due to competition, it will not be able to sell at all at a higher price
than the market price. Thus the firm’s demand curve will be horizontal at that price so that P = AR = MR for the
firm.
1. Marginal Revenue and Marginal Cost Approach:
The short-run equilibrium of the firm can be explained with the help of the marginal analysis as well as with total
cost-total revenue analysis. We first take the marginal analysis under identical cost conditions.
2. Their costs are equal. Therefore, all cost curves are uniform.
3. They use homogeneous plants so that their SAC curves are equal.
5. All firms sell their products at the same price determined by demand and supply of the industry so that the price
Determination of Equilibrium:
Given these assumptions, suppose that price OP in the competitive market for the product of all the firms in the
industry is determined by the equality of demand curve D and the supply curve S at point E in Figure 1(A) so that
their average revenue curve (AR) coincides with the marginal revenue curve (MR).
At this price, each firm is in equilibrium at point L in Panel (B) of the figure where (i) SMC equals MR and AR, and
(ii) the SMC curve cuts the MR curve from below. Each firm would be producing OQ output and earning normal
profits at the maximum average total costs QL. A firm earns normal profits when the MR curve is tangent to the
If the price is higher than these minimum average total costs, each firm will be earning supernormal profits. Suppose
the price rises to 0Рг where the SMC curve cuts the new marginal revenue curve MR 2 (=AR2) from below at point A
which now becomes the equilibrium point. In this situation, each firm produces OQ 2 output and earns supernormal
If the price falls below OP1the firm would make a loss because the SAC would be higher than the price. In the short-
run, it would continue to produce and sell OQ 1 output at OP1price so long as it covers its AVC. S is thus the shut-
down point at which the firm is incurring the maximum loss equal to SK per unit of output. If the price falls below
OP1 the firm will close down because it would fail to cover even the minimum average variable cost. OP 1 is thus the
shut-down price.
We may conclude from the above discussion that in the short-run each firm may be making either supernormal
profits, or normal profits or losses depending upon the price of the product.
2. Total Cost Revenue Analysis:
The short-run equilibrium of the firm can also be shown with the help of total cost and total revenue curves. The
firm is able to maximize its profits at that level of output where the difference between total revenue and total cost is
the maximum. This is shown in Figure 2 where TR is the total revenue curve and TC total cost curve.
The total revenue curve is an upward sloping straight line curve starting from O. This is because the firm sells small
or large quantities of its product at a constant price under perfect competition. If the firm produces nothing, total
revenue will be zero. The more it produces, the larger is the increase in total revenue. Hence the TR curve is linear
The firm will maximize its profits at that level of output where the gap between the TR curve and the 1C curve is the
maximum. Geometrically, it is that level at which the slope of a tangent drawn to the total cost curve equals the
slope of the total revenue curve. In Figure 2, the maximum amount of profit is measured by TP at OQ output. At
outputs smaller or larger than OQ between A and В points, the firm’s profits shrink. If the firm produces
OQ1 output, its losses are the maximum because the TC curve is i above the TR curve. At Q 1 its profits are zero.
Since the marginal revenue equals the slope of the total о revenue curve and the marginal cost equals the slope of the
tangent to the total cost curve, it follows that where the slopes of the total cost and revenue curves are equal as at P
and T, the marginal cost equals the marginal revenue. It should be clear of that the point of maximum profits lies in
the region of rising marginal cost (when TC is below TR) and of maximum loss in the falling marginal cost region
The explanation of the equilibrium of the firm by using total cost-revenue curves does not throw more light than is
provided by the marginal cost-marginal revenue analysis. It is useful only in the case of certain marginal decisions
where the total cost curve is also linear over a certain range of output.
But it makes the equilibrium of the firm a cumbersome and difficult analysis particularly when one has to compare
the change in cost and revenue resulting from a change in the volume of output. Further, maximum profits cannot be
known at once. For this, a number of tangents are required to be drawn which is a real difficulty
3Long-run Equilibrium of the Firm:
In the long-run, it is possible to make more adjustments than in the short-run. The firm can adjust its plant capacity
and scale of operations to the changed circumstances. Therefore, all costs are variable. Firms must earn only normal
profits. In case the price is above the long-run AC curve firms will be earning supernormal profits.
Attracted by them, new firms will enter the industry and supernormal profits will be competed away. If the price is
below the LAC curve firms will be incurring losses. As a result, some of the firms will leave the industry so that no
firm earns more than normal profits. Thus “in the long-run firms are in equilibrium when they have adjusted their
plant so as to produce at the minimum point of their long-run AC curve, which is tangent (at this point) to the
demand (AR) curve defined by the market price” so that they earn normal profits.
It’s Assumptions:
3. All factors are homogeneous. They can be obtained at constant and uniform prices.
Determination:
Given these assumptions, each firm of the industry will be in the following two conditions.
(1) In equilibrium, its short-run marginal cost (SMC) must equal to its long-run marginal cost (LMC) as well as its
short-run average cost (SAC) and its long-run average cost (LAC) and both should be equal to MR=AR=P. Thus the
Both these conditions of equilibrium are satisfied at point E in Figure 3 where SMC and LMC curves cut from
below SAC and LAC curves at their minimum point E and SMC and LMC curves cut AR = MR curve from below.
All curves meet at this point E and the firm produces OQ optimum quantity and sell it at OP price.
Since we assume equal costs of all the firms of industry, all firms will be in equilibrium m the long-run. At OP price
a firm will have neither a tendency to leave nor enter the industry and all firms will earn normal profit.
Equilibrium of the Industry under Perfect Competition:
An industry is in equilibrium:
(i) When there is no tendency for the firms either to leave or enter the industry, and (ii) when each firm is also in
equilibrium. The first condition implies that the average cost curves coincide with the average revenue curve of all
the firms in the industry. They are earning only normal profits, which are supposed to be included in the average
cost curves of the firms. The second condition implies the equality of MC and MR. Under a perfectly competitive
industry, these two conditions must be satisfied at the point of equilibrium, i.e.,
SMC = MR
SAC = AR
P = AR = MR
SMC = SAC = AR = P
An industry is in equilibrium in the short run when its total output remains steady, there being no tendency to
expand or contract its output. If all firms are in equilibrium, the industry is also in equilibrium. For full equilibrium
of the industry in the short run, all firms must be earning only normal profits. The condition for this is SMC = MR =
AR = SAC. But full equilibrium of the industry is by sheer accident because in the short run some firms may be
Even then, the industry is in short- run equilibrium when its quantity demanded and quantity supplied are equal at
the price which clears the market. This is illustrated in Figure 4, where in Panel (A), the industry is in equilibrium at
point E where its demand curve D and supply curve S intersect which determine OP price at which its total output
OQ is cleared. But at the prevailing price OP some firms are earning supernormal profits PE 1ST as shown in Panel
(B), while some other firms are incurring FGE2P losses as shown in Panel (C) of the figure.
The industry is in equilibrium in the long run when all firms earn normal profits. There is no incentive for firms to
leave the industry or for new firms to enter it. With all factors homogeneous and given their prices and the same
technology, each firm and industry as a whole are in full equilibrium where LMC = MR =AR(=p) =LAC at its
minimum. Such an equilibrium position is attained when the long-run price for the industry is determined by the
determined by the intersection of the demand curve d and the supply curve s at point E. At this price op, the firms
are in equilibrium at point A in Panel (B) at OM level of output where LMC =SMC= MR= p (=AR) =SAC= LAC at
its minimum. At this level, the firms are earning normal profits and have no incentive to enter or leave the industry.
It follows that when the industry is in long-run equilibrium, each firm in the industry is also in long-run equilibrium.
If both the industry and the firms are in long-run equilibrium, they are also in short-run equilibrium.
Even though all firms in a perfectly competitive industry in the long run have the same cost curves, the firms can be
of different efficiency. Firms using superior resources or inputs such as superior management must pay them higher
rewards, otherwise they will shift to new firms which offer them higher prices.
So the forces of competition will force the more efficient firms to pay superior resources higher prices at their
opportunity cost. As a result, the lac curve of the more efficient firms will shift upwards and they will benefit in the
form of higher output at the higher long-run equilibrium price set by the industry.
Unable to pay higher prices to resources or inputs, less efficient firms will be competed away. New firms which are
able to pay more and attracted by the new higher market price will enter the industry. But at the new long-run
equilibrium price of the industry, all firms will be producing at the minimum LAC.
This is illustrated in Figure 6 where the industry is in initial equilibrium at point E with price OP m Panel (A) and
the more efficient firms like all other firms are in equilibrium at point A in Panel (B). As the industry is in
equilibrium, the new firms do not exist as they are not in a position to cover their costs at OP price.
When the more efficient firms pay higher prices to resources or inputs, their LAC curve rises to LAC 1 At the new
long-run equilibrium price of the industry set at OP 1 the more efficient firms are in equilibrium where P 1 = LAC1 at
its minimum point A1 in Panel (B). They are now producing larger output OM1 even though they earn normal
profits. The new firms also earn normal profits at point A 2, as shown in Panel (C). But they produce less output
MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION
In monopolistic competition, every firm has a certain degree of monopoly power i.e.every firm can take initiative to
set a price. Here, the products are similar but notidentical, therefore there can never be a unique price but the prices
will be in agroup reflecting the consumers’ tastes and preferences for differentiated products.In this case the price of
the product of the firm is determined by its cost function,demand, its objective and certain government regulations,
As the price of a particular product of a firm reduces, it attracts customers from its rival groups (as defined by
Chamberlin). Say for example, if ‘Samsung’ TV reduces its price by a substantial amount or offers discount, then
the customers from the rival group who have loyalty for, say ‘BPL’, tend to move to buy ‘Samsung’ TV sets. As
discussed earlier, the demand curve is highly elastic but not perfectly elastic and slopes downwards.
The market has many firms selling similar products, therefore the firm’s output is quite small as compared to the
total quantity sold in the market and so its price and output decisions go unnoticed. Therefore, every firm
acts independently and for a given demand curve, marginal revenue curve and cost curves, the firm maximizes profit
or minimizes loss when marginal revenue is equal to marginal cost. Producing an output of Q selling at price P
In the short run, a firm may or may not earn profits. Figure shows the firm, which is earning economic profits. The
equilibrium point for the firm is at price P and quantity Q and is denoted by point A. Here, the economic profit is
given as area PAQR. The difference between this and the monopoly case is that here the barriers to entry are low or
weak and therefore new firms will be attracted to enter. Fresh entry will continue to enter as long as there are profits.
As soon as the super normal profit is competed away by new firms, equilibrium will be attained in the market and no
new firms will be attracted in the market. This is the situation corresponding to the long run and is discussed in the
next section.
We have discussed the price and output determination in the short run. We now discuss price and output
determination in the long run. You will notice that the long run equilibrium decision is similar to perfect
competition. The core of the discussion under this head is that economic profits are eliminated in the long run, which
is the only equilibrium consistent with the assumption of low barriers to entry. This occurs at an output where price
is equal to the long run average cost. Thedifference between monopolistic competition and perfect competition is
that in monopolistic competition the point of tangency is downward sloping and does not occur at minimum of the
average cost curve and this is because the demand curve is downward sloping.
Looking at figure , under monopolistic competition in the long run we see that LRAC is the long run average cost
curve and LRMC the long run average marginal curve. Let us take a hypothetical example of a firm in a
typical monopolistic situation where it is making substantial amount of economic profits.
Here it is assumed that the other firms in the market are also making profits. This situation would then attract new
firms in the market. The new firms may not sell the same products but will sell similar products. As a result, there
will be an increase in the number of close substitutes available in the market and hence the demand curve would
shift downwards since each existing firm would lose market share. The entry of new firms would continue as long as
there are economic profits.
The demand curve will continue to shift downwards till it becomes tangent to LRAC at a given price P1 and output
at Q1 as shown in the figure. At this point of equilibrium, an increase or decrease in price would lead to losses. In
this case the entry of new firms would stop, as there will not be any economic profits.
Due to free entry, many firms can enter the market and there may be a condition where the demand falls below
LRAC and ultimately suffers losses resulting in the exit of the firms. Therefore under the monopolistic competition
free entry and exit must lead to a situation where demand becomes tangent to LRAC, the price becomes equal to
average cost and no economic profit is earned. It can thus be said that in the long run the profits peter out
completely.
One of the interesting features of the monopolistically competitive market is the variety available due to product
differentiation. Although firms in the long run do not produce at the minimum point of their average cost curve, and
thus there is excess capacity available with each firm, economists have rationalized this by attributing the higher
price to the variety available. Further, consumers are willing to pay the higher price for the increased variety
available in the market.
UNIT-V
National income is the final outcome of all economic activities of a nation valued in terms of money. National
income is the most important macroeconomic variable and determinant of the business level and environment of a
country. The level of national income determines the level of aggregate demand for goods and services. Its
distribution pattern determines the pattern of demand for goods and services, i.e., how much of which good is
demanded. The trend in national income determines the trends in aggregate demand, i.e., the demand for the goods
and services, and also the business prospects. Therefore, business decision makers need to keep in mind these
aspects of the national income, especially those having long-run implications. National income or a relevant
component of it is an indispensable variable considered in demand forecasting. Conceptually, national income is the
money value of the end result of all economic activities of the nation. Economic activities generate a large number
of goods and services, and make net addition to the national stock of capital. These together constitute the national
income of a ‘closed economy’—an economy which has no economic transactions with the rest of the world. In an
‘open economy’, national income includes also the net results of its transactions with the rest of the world (i.e.,
Gross National Product (GNP) Of the various measures of national income used in national income
analysis, GNP is the most important and widely used measure of national income. It is the most
comprehensive measure of the nation’s productive activities. The GNP is defined as the value of all final
goods and services produced during a specific period, usually one year, plus incomes earned abroad by the
nationals minus incomes earned locally by the foreigners. The GNP so defined is identical to the concept of
gross national income (GNI). Thus, GNP = GNI. The difference between the two is only of procedural
nature. While GNP is estimated on the basis of product-flows, the GNI is estimated on the basis of money
Gross Domestic Product (GDP ) The Gross Domestic Product (GDP) is defined as the market value of all
final goods and services produced in the domestic economy during a period of one year, plus income
earned locally by the foreigners minus incomes earned abroad by the nationals. The concept of GDP is
similar to that of GNP with a significant procedural difference. In case of GNP the incomes earned by the
nationals in foreign countries are added and incomes earned locally by the foreigners are deducted from the
market value of domestically produced goods and services. In case of GDP, the process is reverse –
incomes earned locally by foreigners are added and incomes earned abroad by the nationals are deducted
Net National Product (NNP) NNP is defined as GNP less depreciation, i.e.,
NNP = GNP – Depreciation. Depreciation is that part of total productive assets which is used to replace the capital
worn out in the process of creating GNP. Briefly speaking, in the process of producing goods and services
(including capital goods), a part of total stock of capital is used up. ‘Depreciation’ is the term used to denote the
worn out or used up capital. An estimated value of depreciation is deducted from the GNP to arrive at NNP. The
NNP, as defined above, gives the measure of net output available for consumption and investment by the society
(including consumers, producers and the government). NNP is the real measure of the national income. NNP = NNI
(net national income). In other words, NNP is the same as the national income at factor cost. It should be noted that
NNP is measured at market prices including direct taxes. Indirect taxes are, however, not a point of actual cost of
production. Therefore, to obtain real national income, indirect taxes are deducted from the NNP. Thus, NNP–
C) NNP ≡ GNP less Depreciation NDP (Net Domestic Product) ≡ NNP less net income from abroad
A. GNP at factor cost ≡ GNP at market price less net indirect taxes
B. NNP at factor cost ≡ NNP at market price less net indirect taxes
C. NDP at factor cost ≡ NNP at market price less net income from abroad
D. NDP at factor cost ≡ NDP at market price less net indirect taxes
E. NDP at factor cost ≡ GDP at market price less Depreciation
For measuring national income, the economy through which people participate in economic activities, earn their
livelihood, produce goods and services and share the national products is viewed from three different angles.
(1) The national economy is considered as an aggregate of producing units combining different sectors such as
(2) The whole national economy is viewed as a combination of individuals and households owning different kinds of
factors of production which they use themselves or sell factor-services to make their livelihood.
(3) The national economy may also be viewed as a collection of consuming, saving and investing units (individuals,
Following these notions of a national economy, national income may be measured by three different corresponding
methods:
(1) Net product method—when the entire national economy is considered as an aggregate of producing units;
(2) Factor-income method—when national economy is considered as combination of factor-owners and users;
(3) Expenditure method—when national economy is viewed as a collection of spending units. The procedures
which are followed in measuring the national income in a closed economy—an economy which has no economic
transactions with the rest of the world—are briefly described here. The measurement of national income in an open
economy and adjustment with regard to income from abroad will be discussed subsequently.
Net Output or Value-Added Method The net output method is also called the value added method. In its
standard form, this method consists of three stages: (i) Estimating the gross value of domestic output in the
(ii) Determining the cost of material and services used and also the depreciation of physical assets; and
(iii) Deducting these costs and depreciation from gross value to obtain the net value of domestic output…”
The net value of domestic product thus obtained is often called the value added or income product which is
equal to the sum of wages, salaries, supplementary labour incomes, interest, profits, and net rent paid or
accrued.
Factor-Income Method This method is also known as income method and factor-share method. Under this
method, the national income is calculated by adding up all the “incomes accruing to the basic factors of
production used in producing the national product”. Factors of production are conventionally classified as land,
labour, capital and organization. Accordingly, the national income equals the sum of the corresponding factor
earning. Thus, National income = Rent + Wages + Interest + Profit. Thus, the total factor-incomes are
(i) Labour Incomes included in the national income have three components:
(a) Wages and salaries paid to the residents of the country including bonus and commission, and social
security payments;
(b) Supplementary labour incomes including employer’s contribution to social security and employee’s
(c) Supplementary labour incomes in kind, e.g., free health and education, food and clothing, and
accommodation, etc. Compensations in kind in the form of domestic servants and such other free-of-cost
(ii) Capital Incomes According to Studenski, capital incomes include the following capital earnings:
(c) interest on bonds, mortgages, and saving deposits (excluding interests on war bonds, and on consumer-
credit);
(d) interest earned by insurance companies and credited to the insurance policy reserves;
(iii) Mixed Incomes.;. Mixed Income. Mixed incomes include earnings from
(c) other professions, e.g., legal and medical practices, consultancy services, trading and transporting etc.
Expenditure Method The expenditure method, also known as final product method, measures national
income at the final expenditure stages. In estimating the total national expenditure, any of the two following
methods are followed: first, all the money expenditures at market price are computed and added up together,
and second, the value of all the products finally disposed of are computed and added up, to arrive at the total
national expenditure. The items of expenditure which are taken into account under the first method are
(c) payments to the non-profitmaking institutions and charitable organizations like schools, hospitals,
CHOICE OF METHODS
There are three standard methods of measuring the national income, viz., net product (or value added) method,
factor-income or factor cost method and expenditure method. All the three methods would give the same measure of
national income, provided requisite data for each method is adequately available. Therefore, any of the three
methods may be adopted to measure the national income. But all the three methods are not suitable for all the
economies simply for non-availability of necessary data and for all purposes. Hence, the question of choice of
method arises. The two main considerations on the basis of which a particular method is chosen are:
A) the purpose of national income analysis, and B) availability of necessary data. If the objective is to
analyse the net output or value added, the net output method is more suitable. In case the objective is to
analyse the factor-income distribution, the suitable method for measuring national income is the income
method. If the objective at hand is to find out the expenditure pattern of the national income, the
expenditure or final products method should be applied. However, availability of adequate and
appropriate data is a relatively more important consideration is selecting a method of estimating national
income. Nevertheless, the most common method is the net product method because: (i) this method
requires classification of the economic activities and output thereof which is much easier than to classify
income or expenditure; and (ii) the most common practice is to collect and organize the national income
data by the division of economic activities. Briefly speaking, the easy availability of data on economic
activities is the main reason for the popularity of the output method. It should be however borne in mind
that no single method can give an accurate measure of national income since the statistical system of no
country provides the total data requirements for a particular method. The usual practice is, therefore, to
combine two or more methods to measure the national income. The combination of methods again
depends on the nature of data required and sectoral break-up of the available data.
Q2. DESCRIBE IN BRIEF INFLATION? REASON FOR INFLATION AND ITS EFFECTS?
Inflation: Meaning
Inflation is a highly controversial term which has undergone modification since it was first defined by the neo-
classical economists. They meant by it a galloping rise in prices as a result of the excessive increase in the quantity
of money. They regarded it “as a destroying disease born out of lack of monetary control whose results undermined
the rules of business, creating havoc in markets and financial ruin of even the prudent.” Inflation is fundamentally a
monetary phenomenon. In the words of Friedman, “Inflation is always and everywhere a monetary phenomenon…
and can be produced only by a more rapid increase in the quantity of money than output.’” But economists do not
agree that money supply alone is the cause of inflation. As pointed out by Hicks, “Our present troubles are not of a
monetary character.” Economists, therefore, define inflation in terms of a continuous rise in prices. Johnson defines
“inflation as a sustained rise” 4 in prices. Brooman defines it as “a continuing increase in the general price
level.”5 Shapiro also defines inflation in a similar vein “as a persistent and appreciable rise in the general level of
prices.” Demberg and McDougall are more explicit when they write that “the term usually refers to a continuing rise
in prices as measured by an index such as the consumer price index (CPI) or by the implicit price deflator for gross
national product.”
However, it is essential to understand that a sustained rise in prices may be of various magnitudes. Accordingly,
different names have been given to inflation depending upon the rate of rise in prices.
TYPES OF INFLATION
1. Creeping Inflation:
When the rise in prices is very slow like that of a snail or creeper, it is called creeping inflation. In terms of speed, a
sustained rise in prices of annual increase of less than 3 per cent per annum is characterised as creeping inflation.
Such an increase in prices is regarded safe and essential for economic growth.
When prices rise moderately and the annual inflation rate is a single digit. In other words, the rate of rise in prices is
in the intermediate range of 3 to 6 per cent per annum or less than 10 per cent. Inflation at this rate is a warning
signal for the government to control it before it turns into running inflation.
3. Running Inflation:
When prices rise rapidly like the running of a horse at a rate or speed of 10 to 20 per cent per annum, it is called
running inflation. Such an inflation affects the poor and middle classes adversely. Its control requires strong
4. Hyperinflation:
When prices rise very fast at double or triple digit rates from more than 20 to 100 per cent per annum or more, it is
usually called runaway ox galloping inflation. It is also characterised as hyperinflation by certain economists. In
reality, hyperinflation is a situation when the rate of inflation becomes immeasurable and absolutely uncontrollable.
Prices rise many times every day. Such a situation brings a total collapse of monetary system because of the
The speed with which prices tend to rise is illustrated in Figure 1. The curve С shows creeping inflation when within
a period of ten years the price level has been shown to have risen by about 30 per cent. The curve W depicts walking
inflation when the price level rises by more than 50 per cent during ten years. The curve R illustrates running
inflation showing a rise of about 100 per cent in ten years. The steep curve H shows the path of hyperinflation when
prices rise by more than 120 per cent in less than one year.
5. Semi-Inflation:
According to Keynes, so long as there are unemployed resources, the general price level will not rise as output
increases. But a large increase in aggregate expenditure will face shortages of supplies of some factors which may
not be substitutable. This may lead to increase in costs, and prices start rising. This is known as semi-inflation or
7. Open Inflation:
Inflation is open when “markets for goods or factors of production are allowed to function freely, setting prices of
goods and factors without normal interference by the authorities. Thus open inflation is the result of the
uninterrupted operation of the market mechanism. There are no checks or controls on the distribution of
commodities by the government. Increase in demand and shortage of supplies persist which tend to lead to open
8. Suppressed Inflation:
Men the government imposes physical and monetary controls to check open inflation, it is known as repressed or
suppressed inflation. The market mechanism is not allowed to function normally by the use of licensing, price
controls and rationing in order to suppress extensive rise in prices. So long as such controls exist, the present
demand is postponed and there is diversion of demand from controlled to uncontrolled commodities. But as soon as
these controls are removed, there is open inflation. Moreover, suppressed inflation adversely affects the economy.
9. Stagflation:
Stagflation is a new term which has been added to economic literature in the 1970s. It is a paradoxical phenomenon
where the economy expedience’s stagnation as well as inflation. The word stagflation is the combination of‘ stag’
plus ‘flation’ taking ‘stag’ from stagnation and ‘flation’ from inflation. Stagflation is a situation when recession is
accompanied by a high rate of inflation. It is, therefore, also called inflationary recession. The principal cause of this
phenomenon has been excessive demand in commodity markets, thereby causing prices to rise, and at the same time
the demand for labour is deficient, thereby creating unemployment in the economy.
10. Mark-up Inflation:
The concept of mark-up inflation is closely related to the price-push problem. Modem labour organizations possess
substantial monopoly power. They, therefore, set prices and wages on the basis of mark-up over costs and relative
incomes. Firms possessing monopoly power have control over the prices charged by them. So they have
administered prices which increase their profit margin. This sets off an inflationary rise in prices. Similarly, when
strong trade unions are successful in raising the wages of workers, this contributes to inflation.
12. Sectoral Inflation:
Sectoral inflation arises initially out of excess demand in particular industries. But it leads to a general price rise
13. Reflation:
Is a situation when prices are raised deliberately in order to encourage economic activity. When there is depression
and prices fall abnormally low, the monetary authority adopts measures to put more money in circulation so that
Demand-Pull or excess demand inflation is a situation often described as “too much money chasing too few goods.”
According to this theory, an excess of aggregate demand over aggregate supply will generate inflationary rise in
prices. Its earliest explanation is to be found in the simple quantity theory of money.
The theory states that prices rise in proportion to the increase in the money supply. Given the full employment level
of output, doubling the money supply will double the price level. So inflation proceeds at the same rate at which the
In this analysis, the aggregate supply is assumed to be fixed and there is always full employment in the economy.
Naturally, when the money supply increases it creates more demand for goods but the supply of goods cannot be
increased due to the full employment of resources. This leads to rise in prices.
Modem quantity theorists led by Friedman hold that “inflation is always and everywhere a monetary phenomenon.
The higher the growth rate of the nominal money supply, the higher the rate of inflation. When the money supply
increases, people spend more in relation to the available supply of goods and services. This bids prices up. Modem
quantity theorists neither assume full employment as a normal situation nor a stable velocity of money. Still they
The quantity theory version of the demand-pull inflation is illustrated in Figure 3. Suppose the money supply is
increased at a given price level OP as determined by the demand and supply curves D and S 1 respectively. The
initial full employment situation OY F at this price level is shown by the interaction of these curves at point E. Now
with the increase in the quantity of money, the aggregate demand increase which shifts the demand curve D to D 1to
the right. The aggregate supply being fixed, as shown by the vertical portion of the supply curve SS 1 the D1 curve
The Keynesian theory on demand-pull inflation is based on the argument that so long as there are unemployed
resources in the economy; an increase in investment expenditure will lead to increase in employment, income and
output. Once full employment is reached and bottlenecks appear, further increase in expenditure will lead to excess
In his pamphlet How to pay for the War published in 1940, Keynes explained the concept of the inflationary gap. It
differs from his views on inflation given in his General Theory. In the General Theory, he started with
underemployment equilibrium. But in How to Pay for the War, he began with a situation of full employment in the
economy.
He defined an inflationary gap as an excess of planned expenditure over the available output at pre-inflation or base
prices. According to Lipsey, “The inflationary gap is the amount by which aggregate expenditure would exceed
aggregate output at the full employment level of income.” The classical economists explained inflation as mainly
due to increase in the quantity of money, given the level of full employment.
Keynes, on the other hand, ascribed it to the excess of expenditure over income at the full employment level. The
larger the aggregate expenditure, the larger the gap and the more rapid the inflation. Given a constant average
propensity to save, rising money incomes at full employment level would lead to an excess of demand over supply
and to a consequent inflationary gap. Thus Keynes used the concept of the inflationary gap to show the main
CAUSES OF INFLATION
Inflation is caused when the aggregate demand exceeds the aggregate supply of goods and services. We analyse the
Inflation is caused by an increase in the supply of money which leads to increase in aggregate demand. The higher
the growth rate of the nominal money supply, the higher is the rate of inflation. Modem quantity theorists do not
believe that true inflation starts after the full employment level. This view is realistic because all advanced countries
are faced with high levels of unemployment and high rates of inflation.
income may increase with the rise in national income or reduction in taxes or reduction in the saving of the people.
Government activities have been expanding much with the result that government expenditure has also been
increasing at a phenomenal rate, thereby raising aggregate demand for goods and services. Governments of both
developed and developing countries are providing more facilities under public utilities and social services, and also
nationalising industries and starting public enterprises with the result that they help in increasing aggregate demand.
The demand for goods and services increases when consumer expenditure increases. Consumers may spend more
due to conspicuous consumption or demonstration effect. They may also spend more whey they are given credit
Cheap monetary policy or the policy of credit expansion also leads to increase in the money supply which raises the
demand for goods and services in the economy. When credit expands, it raises the money income of the borrowers
which, in turn, raises aggregate demand relative to supply, thereby leading to inflation. This is also known as credit-
induced inflation.
6. Deficit Financing:
In order to meet its mounting expenses, the government resorts to deficit financing by borrowing from the public
and even by printing more notes. This raises aggregate demand in relation to aggregate supply, thereby leading to
employment and income, thereby creating more demand for goods and services. But it takes time for the output to
8. Black Money:
The existence of black money in all countries due to corruption, tax evasion etc. increases the aggregate demand.
People spend such unearned money extravagantly, thereby creating unnecessary demand for commodities. This
Whenever the government repays its past internal debt to the public, it leads to increase in the money supply with
the public. This tends to raise the aggregate demand for goods and services.
10. Increase in Exports:
When the demand for domestically produced goods increases in foreign countries, this raises the earnings of
industries producing export commodities. These, in turn, create more demand for goods and services within the
economy.
(a) Credit Control:
One of the important monetary measures is monetary policy. The central bank of the country adopts a number of
methods to control the quantity and quality of credit. For this purpose, it raises the bank rates, sells securities in the
open market, raises the reserved ratio, and adopts a number of selective credit control measures, such as raising
Monetary policy may not be effective in controlling inflation, if inflation is due to cost-push factors. Monetary
However, one of the monetary measures is to demonetise currency of higher denominations. Such a measure is
The most extreme monetary measure is the issue of new currency in place of the old currency. Under this system,
one new note is exchanged for a number of notes of the old currency. The value of bank deposits is also fixed
accordingly. Such a measure is adopted when there is an excessive issue of notes and there is hyperinflation in the
country. It is a very effective measure. But is inequitable for it hurts the small depositors the most.
2. Fiscal Measures:
Monetary policy alone is incapable of controlling inflation. It should, therefore, be supplemented by fiscal measures.
Fiscal measures are highly effective for controlling government expenditure, personal consumption expenditure, and
The government should reduce unnecessary expenditure on non-development activities in order to curb inflation.
This will also put a check on private expenditure which is dependent upon government demand for goods and
services. But it is not easy to cut government expenditure. Though economy measures are always welcome but it
becomes difficult to distinguish between essential and non-essential expenditure. Therefore, this measure should be
supplemented by taxation.
(b) Increase in Taxes:
To cut personal consumption expenditure, the rates of personal, corporate and commodity taxes should be raised and
even new taxes should be levied, but the rates of taxes should not be so high as to discourage saving, investment and
production. Rather, the tax system should provide larger incentives to those who save, invest and produce more.
Further, to bring more revenue into the tax-net, the government should penalise the tax evaders by imposing heavy
fines. Such measures are bound to be effective in controlling inflation. To increase the supply of goods within the
country, the government should reduce import duties and increase export duties.
(c) Increase in Savings:
Another measure is to increase savings on the part of the people. This will tend to reduce disposable income with the
people, and hence personal consumption expenditure. But due to the rising cost of living, people are not in a position
to save much voluntarily. Keynes, therefore, advocated compulsory savings or what he called ‘deferred payment’
where the saver gets his money back after some years.
For this purpose, the government should float public loans carrying high rates of interest, start saving schemes with
prize money, or lottery for long periods, etc. It should also introduce compulsory provident fund, provident fund-
cum-pension schemes, etc. compulsorily. All such measures to increase savings are likely to be effective in
controlling inflation.
(d) Surplus Budgets:
An important measure is to adopt anti-inflationary budgetary policy. For this purpose, the government should give
up deficit financing and instead have surplus budgets. It means collecting more in revenues and spending less.
(e) Public Debt:
At the same time, it should stop repayment of public debt and postpone it to some future date till inflationary
pressures are controlled within the economy. Instead, the government should borrow more to reduce money supply
Like the monetary measures, fiscal measures alone cannot help in controlling inflation. They should be
The other types of measures are those which aim at increasing aggregate supply and reducing aggregate demand
directly:
(i) One of the foremost measures to control inflation is to increase the production of essential consumer goods like
of essential commodities.
(iii) Efforts should also be made to increase productivity. For this purpose, industrial peace should be maintained
through agreements with trade unions, binding them not to resort to strikes for some time.
Another important measure is to adopt a rational wage and income policy. Under hyperinflation, there is a wage-
price spiral. To control this, the government should freeze wages, incomes, profits, dividends, bonus, etc. But such a
drastic measure can only be adopted for a short period and by antagonising both workers and industrialists.
Therefore, the best course is to link increase in wages to increase in productivity. This will have a dual effect. It will
control wages and at the same time increase productivity, and hence increase production of goods in the economy.
(c) Price Control:
Price control and rationing is another measure of direct control to check inflation. Price control means fixing an
upper limit for the prices of essential consumer goods. They are the maximum prices fixed by law and anybody
charging more than these prices is punished by law. But it is difficult to administer price control.
(d) Rationing:
Rationing aims at distributing consumption of scarce goods so as to make them available to a large number of
consumers. It is applied to essential consumer goods such as wheat, rice, sugar, kerosene oil, etc. It is meant to
stabilise the prices of necessaries and assure distributive justice. But it is very inconvenient for consumers because it
leads to queues, artificial shortages, corruption and black marketing. Keynes did not favour rationing for it “involves
Inflation affects different people differently. This is because of the fall in the value of money. When prices rise or
the value of money falls, some groups of the society gain, some lose and some stand in between. Broadly speaking,
there are two economic groups in every society, the fixed income group and the flexible income group.
People belonging to the first group lose and those belonging to the second group gain. The reason is that price
movements in the case of different goods, services, assets, etc. are not uniform. When there is inflation, most prices
are rising, but the rates of increase of individual prices differ much. Prices of some goods and services rise faster, of
others slowly, and of still others remain unchanged. We discuss below the effects of inflation on redistribution of
There are two ways to measure the effects of inflation on the redistribution of income and wealth in a society. First,
on the basis of the change in the real value of such factor incomes as wages, salaries, rents, interest, dividends and
profits.
Second, on the basis of the size distribution of income over time as a result of inflation, i.e. whether the incomes of
the rich have increased and that of the middle and poor classes have declined with inflation. Inflation brings about
shifts in the distribution of real income from those whose money incomes are relatively inflexible to those whose
When prices start rising, production is encouraged. Producers earn wind-fall profits in the future. They invest more
in anticipation of higher profits in the future. This tends to increase employment, production and income. But this is
Further increase in investment beyond this level will lead to severe inflationary pressures within the economy
because prices rise more than production as the resources are fully employed. So inflation adversely affects
(1) Government:
Inflation affects the government in various ways. It helps the government in financing its activities through
inflationary finance. As the money income of the people increases, the government collects that in the form of taxes
on incomes and commodities. So the revenues of the government increase during rising prices.
Moreover, the real burden of the public debt decreases when prices are rising. But the government expenses also
increase with rising production costs of public projects and enterprises and increase in administrative expenses as
prices and wages rise. On the whole, the government gains under inflation because rising wages and profits spread
(2) Balance of Payments:
Inflation involves the sacrificing of the advantages of international specialisation and division of labour. It adversely
affects the balance of payments of a country. When prices rise more rapidly in the home country than in foreign
countries, domestic products become costlier compared to foreign products. This tends to increase imports and
reduce exports, thereby making the balance of payments unfavourable for the country. This happens only when the
country follows a fixed exchange rate policy. But there is no adverse impact on the balance of payments if the
(3) Exchange Rate:
When prices rise more rapidly in the home country than in foreign countries, it lowers the exchange rate in relation
to foreign currencies.
If hyperinflation persists and the value of money continues to fall many times in a day, it ultimately leads to the
By widening the gulf between the rich and the poor, rising prices create discontentment among the masses. Pressed
by the rising cost of living, workers resort to strikes which lead to loss in production. Lured by profit, people resort
spreads in every walk of life. All this reduces the efficiency of the economy.
(6) Political:
Rising prices also encourage agitations and protests by political parties opposed to the government. And if they
gather momentum and become unhandy they may bring the downfall of the government. Many governments have
In economics, profit is called pure profit, which may be defined as a residual left after all contractual costs have
been met, including the transfer costs of management insurable risks, depreciation and payment to shareholders,
sufficient to maintain investment at its current level.
There are various theories of profit in economics, given by several economists, which are as follows:
1. Walker’s Theory of Profit as Rent of Ability
This theory is pounded by F.A. Walker. According to Walker, “Profit is the rent of exceptional abilities that an
entrepreneur may possess over others”. Rent is the difference between the yields of the least and the most efficient
entrepreneurs. In formulating this theory, Walker assumed a state of perfect completion in which all firms are
presumed to possess equal Business ability each firm receives only the wages which in Walker view forms no part
of pure profit. He considered wages of management as ordinary wages thus, under perfectly competitive conditions,
there would be no pure profit and all firms would earn only wages, which is known as normal profit.
2. Clark’s Dynamic Theory
This theory is propounded by J.B. Clark According to him, “Profits arise in a dynamic economy and not in static
economy.”
A static economy and the firms under it, has the following features:
Homogeneous goods.
Factors of production enjoy freedom of mobility but do not move because their marginal product in very
Increase in capital.
The major function of entrepreneurs or managers in a dynamic economy is to take the advantage of all of the above
features and promote their business by expanding their sales and reducing their costs of production.
According to J.B. Clark, “Profit is an elusive sum, which entrepreneurs grasp but cannot hold. It slips through their
fingers and bestows itself on all members of the society”. This result in rise in demand for factors pf production and
therefore rises in factor prices and subsequent rise in the cost of production. On the other hand, because of rise in
cost of production and the subsequent fall in selling price of the commodities, the profit disappears. Disappearing of
profit does not mean that profit arise in dynamic economy once only, but it means that the managers take the
advantage of the changes taking place in the economy and thereby making profits.
3. Hawley’s Risk Theory of Profit
The risk theory pf profit is propounded by F.B. Hawley in 1893. Risk in business may arise due to obsolescence of a
product, sudden fall in prices, non-availability of certain materials, introduction of a better substitute by a competitor
and risks due to fire, war, etc. Hawley’s considered risk taking as an inevitable element of production and those who
take risk are more likely to earn larger profits. According to Hawley, Profit is simply the price paid by society
assuming business risks. In his opinion in excess of predetermined risk. They also look for a return in excess of the
wags for bearing risk is that the assumption of risk is irrelevant and gives to trouble and anxiety. According to
One Part represents compensation for actual or average loss supplementing the various classes of risk.
The other part represents a penalty to suffer the consequences of being exposed to risk in the entrepreneurial
activities.
Hawley believed that profits arise from factor ownership as long as ownership involves risk. According to Hawley,
an entrepreneur has to assume risk to earn more and more profit. In case of absence of risks, an entrepreneur would
cease to be an entrepreneur and would not receive any profit. In this theory, profits arise out of uninsured risks. The
amount of reward cannot be determined, until the uncertainly ends with the sale of entrepreneur products profit in
his opinion is a residue and therefore Hawley theory is also called as Residual theory.
This theory of profit is propounded by frank H. Knight who treated profit as a residual return because of uncertainly,
and not because of risk bearing. Knight made a distinction between risk and uncertainly by dividing risk into two
Calculable risks are those, the prodigality of occurrence of which van be calculated on the basis of available
data. For example risk, due to fire theft accidents etc. are calculable and such risks are insurable.
Incalculable risks are those the probability of occurrence of which cannot be calculated. For Instance there may
be a certain elements of cost, which may not be accurately calculable and the strategies of the competitors may
not be precisely assessable. These risk are called includable risks. The risk element of such incalculable costs is
also insurable.
It is in the area of uncertainly which makes decision-making a crucial function for an entrepreneur. If his decisions
prove to be right, the entrepreneur makes profit, Thus according to knight profit arises from the decisions taken and
implemented under the conditions of uncertainly. The profits may arises as a result of decision related to the state of
market such as decision, which increase the degree of monopoly, decisions regarding holding of stocks that give rise
to windfall gains and the decisions taken to introduce new techniques or innovations.
5. Schumpeter’s Innovation Theory of Profit
Joseph A. Schumpeter developed the innovation theory of Profit. According to Schumpeter, factors like emergence
of interest and profits, recurrence of trade cycles only supplement the distinct process of economic development. To
explain the phenomenon of economic development and profit, Schumpeter starts from the state of a stationary
equilibrium, which is characterized by the equilibrium in all the spheres. Under these conditions stationary
equilibrium, the total receipts from the business are exactly equal to the cost. This means that there will be no profit.
The profit can be earned only by introducing innovations in manufacturing technique and the methods of supplying
The factor prices tend to increase while the supply of factors remains the same. As a result, cost of production
increase. On the other hand with other firms adopting innovations, supply of goods and services increases resulting
in a fall in their prices. Thus, on one hand, cost per unit of output goes up and on the other revenue per unit decrease.
Finally, a stage comes when there is no difference between costs and receipts. As a result there are no profits at all.
Here, economy has reached a state of equilibrium, but there is the possibility of existence of profits. Such profits are
in the nature of quasi-rent arising due to some special characteristics of productive services. Furthermore, where
profits arise due to factors such as patents, trusts, etc. they will be in the nature of monopoly revenue rather than
entrepreneurial profits.