Yang Zhang, 2020
Yang Zhang, 2020
Yang Zhang, 2020
Economy
Author(s): Yang Zhang
Source: World Review of Political Economy , Spring 2020, Vol. 11, No. 1 (Spring 2020), pp.
4-27
Published by: Pluto Journals
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and
facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected].
Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
https://about.jstor.org/terms
Pluto Journals is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to World Review
of Political Economy
Yang Zhang is a post-doctoral researcher at the School of Marxism, Peking University, China. His
study mainly focuses on Marxist political economy. Email: [email protected]
Abstract: Since China’s reform and opening up four decades ago, the establishment
and healthy development of the socialist market economy has been closely
linked to the forward-looking theoretical analysis and policy suggestions given
by representatives from the School of New Marxist Economics. By comparative
analysis of a variety of cited literature, the author argues that the School of New
Marxist Economics scholars Guoguang Liu, Enfu Cheng, and Zuyao Yu, have made an
outstanding contribution not only to the construction of the socialist market economy
theory and socialist political economy with Chinese characteristics academically, but
also to the comprehensive deepening of reform and the strengthening of technology
power building in practice.
Key words: socialist market economy; “Chinese School” of socialist market economy;
School of New Marxist Economics in China
It is definitely incorrect to say that market economy only exists in capitalist society
or there is only capitalist market economy. Why can’t socialism adopt market
economy which should not be labeled capitalist . . . Market economy was in its
embryonic stage as early as in the feudal society. Socialism can also engage in
market economy. (Deng 1983, 236)
In 1992, the 14th National Congress of the Communist Party of China (CPC)
officially proposed: “The socialist market economy system is established in order
that the market plays a basic role in the allocation of resources under the macro
regulation of the socialist country” (Central Literature Research Office of the CPC
1996, 19). In 2013, the Third Plenary Session of the 18th CPC Central Committee
proposed: “ensuring that the market plays a decisive role in the allocation of
resources and the government plays a better role” (Central Literature Research
Office of the CPC 2014, 513). This rewording reflects a development in theory.
The establishment and healthy development of the socialist market economy
theory since China’s reform and opening up four decades ago have been closely
linked to the forward-looking theoretical analysis and policy suggestions of rep-
resentatives from the School of New Marxist Economics at the Chinese Academy
of Social Sciences (hereafter referred to as the CASS), including Guoguang Liu,
Enfu Cheng, Zuyao Yu, and others (Cheng 2009).1 This paper, based on the lit-
erature and from the perspective of the history of economic thought, is limited
to elaborating the contribution and practical value of these three. It demonstrates
their taking the lead in advocating the establishment and healthy development of
the socialist market theory and thereby demonstrates the “Chinese School” of the
socialist market economy theory, namely, part of the innovative academic thought
of the School of New Marxist Economics.
be called the Long March of the new era in its transformation from an administra-
tive planned economy to a socialist market economy” (Yu 2005c, 54).
capitalist market economy. “As long as one talks about utilizing the market, he is
labeled as implementing capitalism” (65). The second traditional idea is to equate
the planned economy with the natural economy, resulting in the practice of con-
ducting the socialist planned economy by means of natural economy. He further
emphasized that the practice of the natural economy was passed off as that of the
socialist planned economy owing to the constraints of productivity at that time.
Starting from the interaction of “two traditional ideas,” Liu presented “four
replacements:”
Shenzhen, Zhuhai, Shantou and Xiamen, Hainan can implement the market econ-
omy oriented by the international market under the national macro-economic
guidance” (cited in Chen and Hu 1988, 20). The preparatory group for the estab-
lishment of Hainan Province accepted his proposal and put it into practice.
In 1990, Qiushi magazine held a seminar on “the combination of planned
economy and market regulation.” At the meeting, Liu once again expounded his
view on the relation between planning and market, stressing that “the government
should make more use of the market mechanism in economic regulation” (Liu
2005b, 130). He took Guangdong and other open coastal areas as examples to
demonstrate that “the more market-oriented areas are, the greater the achieve-
ments of reform” (130). However, he believed that socialist countries needed to
implement the market economy, which is “the market-oriented reform with
adherence to the dominant position of public ownership, planned guidance and
macro control” (130). On the issue of market-oriented reform, he put forward
“two assertions to adhere to” and “two mistakes to avoid” based on dialectical
materialism, namely, adherence to market economy and avoidance of blind faith
in market economy, adherence to planned economy and avoidance of blind faith in
planned economy. In his opinion, due to the limitations of information and inter-
ests, the practice of having blind faith in the plan system without considering the
law of value, demand and supply of the market, and the national conditions and
power leads to serious problems, whereas there are obvious defects of the market
in adjusting the industrial structure, realizing fair competition, promoting effi-
cient development, preventing monopolies, protecting the ecological environ-
ment, and so on. In short, Liu reckoned that “we must combine the plan and the
market, and one-sided emphasis on any one aspect is not appropriate” (133).
Later in 1992, Liu comprehensively summarized the whole process of the
development of the socialist market economy theory over a period of more than
ten years from the Third Plenary Session of the 11th Central Committee of the
CPC to Deng Xiaoping’s Southern Talks in “On Several Issues on the Theory of
Socialist Market Economy.” In this article, he scientifically expounded major the-
oretical issues involved in the case that the socialist commodity economy should
be changed to the socialist market economy. He argued the “commodity economy
is antithetical to the natural economy and product economy, which is concerned
with whether there is a commodity nature in the behavioral exchange in human
socio-economic activities.” “The market economy is antithetic to the planned
economy as a method for resource allocation.” “From a logical perspective, the
commodity economy is of a relatively abstract and essential content level, while
the market economy is of a concrete and specific form level” (Liu 2005c, 207,
208). He further pointed out:
We now propose to use the concept of market economy to replace the concept of
planned commodity economy, in order to emphasize the need to further develop
the commodity economy, and on the issue of allocation of resources to replace
the methods of relying mainly on administrative plans with the market
mechanism. This is the essence of the current economic reform in China and it
cannot be fully covered and expressed by the concept of the “planned commodity
economy.” (Liu 2005c, 209)
Liu also made a scientific formulation on why the attributive “socialist” was added
before “market economy” and the characteristics that distinguished it from the
capitalist market economy. He pointed out,
With the leadership of the Communist Party of China, the public ownership as the
basis, and the goal of common prosperity, we are more likely to consciously
proceed from the combination of the overall social benefits and local interests in
the operation of the socialist market economy. Hence we can and will achieve a
better performance than the capitalist market economy in dealing with the
relation between planning and market, between flexibility in micro operation
and coordination in macro regulation, and between stimulating efficiency and
realizing social justice, etc. (Liu 2005c, 215–216)
As the commodity economy of the primary stage, it is on the one hand essentially
a new type and the most advanced form of commodity economy relative to the
capitalist commodity economy from the perspective of the evolution history of
relations of production, but on the other hand it is also rather imperfect per se,
calling for the establishment of a suitable market system and a proper market
I have always believed that the viewpoints that deny that the sum of production,
distribution, exchange and consumption of commodities is equal to commodity
economy and deny that the socialized commodity economy is equivalent to
market economy are neither favorable to the scientific study of the economic
operation of contemporary capitalism and socialism, nor in accordance with the
whole analytical logic of Capital, a view grounded on the fact that Marx did not
use the categories of “commodity economy” and “market economy.” (Cheng
2010b, 643)
He further proposed,
We can in theory use the term “commodity economy” to express the meaning of
“market economy,” as well as critically adopt the term “market economy” once
stipulated by Western economics. However, considering the international
acceptability of the economic terms, we shall employ the concept of “market
economy” more often in the future. (Cheng 2010b, 643)
Second, Cheng led the way in his advocacy of the gradual establishment of a
new type of regulating mechanism with dual functions “based on market regula-
tion and dominated by state regulation” in the reform of the economic system.
in 1998, Cheng argued that the economic functions of China as a socialist country
reflected in respects of scientific management, efficient governance, people-
oriented service, and self-disciplined integrity would be shown to be superior to
the capitalist governments. Thus, the pattern of building both a strong market and
a strong government is not only conducive to giving full play to the efficient regu-
latory function of socialist countries, but also helpful in avoiding the trap of neo-
liberalism in the top-level design of economic policy.
Since the start of the twenty-first century, Western forces have strengthened the
dissemination and permeation of neoliberalism in China. Representatives of
Western forces cooperated with domestic neoliberals to vigorously propagate the
neoliberal thoughts of relying only on privatization, marketization, and liberaliza-
tion and continually sought to occupy the ideological front of China’s economic
theory and policy. In order to prevent, resist, and eliminate the infiltration of neo-
liberal thought, and to defend the reform and opening up of the new era against the
interference of the trend of “capitalist marketization,” Chinese scholars of the
“School of New Marxist Economics” continuously put forward policy suggestions
to improve the socialist market economy system.
The theoretical premise and core theories of neoliberalism (such as the theory of
selfishness of human nature, the theory of eternality of private ownership, the
theory of omnipotence of free market, etc.) are not applicable to socialist China as
a whole, hence cannot become the mainstream of China’s economics and
dominate China’s economic development and reform. The guiding ideology for
China’s economics teaching and decision-making on economic issues in China
can only be Marxism which advances with the times. (Liu 2006c, 637)
Liu criticized some economists who advocated “marketization reform” and delib-
erately declined to use the word “socialist” and the precondition of market econ-
omy, who declined to mention public ownership as the main component of the
Chinese economy and its rejection of polarization. He emphasized that China’s
market economy is “socialist,” and a “precondition” for it is being “under the
state’s macro-control”; “a market economy that does not speak of socialism is a
crony market economy” (Liu and Zhang 2006, 42). In “Adhering to the Right Path
of the Reform” in 2006, he thoroughly analysed the means by which bourgeois
liberalism misled China’s reform and opening up, “Once bourgeois liberalism
emerged in China, its battle in the name of reform and opening up with Marxism
and the correct view of reform, namely, Deng Xiaoping’s view of reform, began”
(Liu 2006d, 644).
In 2008, Liu argued that, although great achievements had been made in eco-
nomic development in 30 years of reform and opening up in China, the eco-
nomic system had seen the rise of the dangerous tendency to blind faith in the
market, with the development of resource factors and financial markets lagging
behind, especially with the problem of over-marketization in the areas of educa-
tion, medical care, housing, and so on. These lead to the imbalance of the
national economy, the deterioration of resources and environment, and the wid-
ening of the distribution gap. He believed that “The solutions to the problems
incurred in the aspects of the comprehensive balance, environment and resource
protection, and fair social distribution are not in the market economy per se in
China” (Liu 2008, 6). Therefore, “It is time to emphasize the guiding role of the
national plan in macro-control while continuing to adhere to market-oriented
reform” (Liu 2008, 7). In an interview on “The Directions, Goals and Core
Topics of China’s Economic System Reform” of 2018, Liu stressed that “failure
to adhere to the socialist direction of reform leads to a dead end” (Liu and Wang
2018). He also put forward suggestions on improving the socialist market econ-
omy system, such as strengthening and optimizing the state-owned and collec-
tive economy, strengthening the state’s macro-economic regulation and
regulation-oriented ability, and gradually solving the problem of wealth and
income polarization. Liu’s views have been highly valued and commented upon
by many leaders from the central government.
making the market play a decisive role in the allocation of resources and giving
better play to the role of the government. This is a major theoretical point put
forward by the decision of this plenary session. This is because the reform of the
economic system is still the focus of comprehensively deepening the reform, and
the core issue of the reform of the economic system is still to deal with the
relationship between the government and the market. (Central Literature
Research Office of the CPC 2014, 498)
There has been a debate in academic circles on “the decisive role of the market”
in the socialist market economy. Some scholars think that it leads to the road of
“market omnipotence” and capitalism. Enfu Cheng scientifically explained the
essential difference between the “theory of the decisive role of the market” of
socialism with Chinese characteristics and the “theory of market omnipotence” of
neoliberalism in 2014. “In China’s socialist market economy, although the condi-
tions for the market to play a role are different from those in a capitalist market
economy, the market similarly plays a decisive role in the allocation of resources
within a certain range” (Cheng and Gao 2014, 51). He pointed out that compared
with the neoliberal “theory of the decisive role of the market” which advocates
market fundamentalism, relying on marketization and minimization of govern-
ment functions, the “‘theory of the decisive role of the market’ of socialism with
Chinese characteristics should not only ensure the decisive role of the market in
the allocation of resources, but also emphasize national macro-control and micro-
regulation” (Cheng and Gao 2014, 56). He stressed that “‘the decisive role of
the market’ and the role of the government in planning and configuration are an
organic unity, in which both can achieve complementarity in function and synergy
in effect” (Cheng and Gao 2014, 56).
From these original contributions of the scholars of the “School of New Marxist
Economics” to the scientific establishment and healthy development of the social-
ist market economy theory, it can be seen that, since the reform and opening up,
scholars of the “School of New Marxist Economics” have carried forward the
theoretical quality of Marxist economics, keeping pace with the times, and have
summarized and refined new concepts and categories from abundant practical
experience in reform. They developed the socialist political economy with Chinese
and the market. Traditional socialist theory that regards the national plan as the
only operating mechanism of the socialist economy has been changed, and a vari-
ety of models have been explored that combine the plan and the market, centrali-
zation and decentralization, efficiency and fairness. The study of socialist economy
model by scholars in the world can be divided into six categories, with a total of
17 models. The first category is the decentralized socialist economic model, spe-
cifically including Virlyn W. Bruse’s “planned economy model with market
mechanism,” Ota Sik’s “planned market economic model,” Janos Kornai’s “model
of introducing market mechanism into planned economy,” Alec Nove’s “feasible
socialist economic model.” The second is the autonomous socialist economic
model, including Edvard Kardelj’s “autonomous socialist economic model,”
Edward van Nike’s “workers’ autonomous economic model,” and Tony Andreani’s
“enterprise autonomous socialist model.” The third is the socialist economic
model which emphasizes efficiency and maximization of benefits, including John
E. Roemer’s “bank-centered socialist model” and James Juncker’s “practical mar-
ket socialist model.” The fourth is a socialist economic model which emphasizes
equality, including David Miller’s “model of cooperative market socialism” and
Dean Elson’s “socialist model of market socialization.” The fifth is the new model
of socialist economy which advocates democracy, including Thomas Weisskopf’s
“democratic market socialist model based on enterprise,” David Schweickart’s
“socialist model of economic democracy,” and Robin Archer’s “socialist eco-
nomic model based on economic democracy.” The sixth is the socialist economic
model against the market, specifically including Maurice Herbert Dobb’s “planned
economic model with the central authority providing centralized solutions,” Ernest
Mandel’s “no price economic model,” and Bertell Ollman’s “democratic planned
socialist economic model.”
In China, the theory of the socialist market economy constructed by the schol-
ars of the “School of New Marxist Economics” not only advocates that China at
the primary stage of socialism needs to use the market mechanism to develop
productive forces, but also emphasizes the need to regulate the entire socio-
economic operation through state adjustment to further regulate the market.
Scholars of the “School of New Marxist Economics” believe that after socialism
with Chinese characteristics enters the new era, we should be more vigilant about
the phenomenon of neoliberal economics insidiously masquerading as the theory
of the socialist market economy and causing serious damage to the cause of social-
ist modernization. On the whole, China’s socialist market economy is fundamen-
tally different from full marketization reform under the guidance of neoliberal
economics. The key is to give full play to the benign and efficient regulatory func-
tions of socialist countries. In short, the theory of the socialist market economy
constructed by scholars of the “School of New Marxist Economics” who can
represent the “Chinese School” can be summarized as “the market socialist econ-
omy model with the principal position of public ownership and the dominant role
of the state,” This is an important theoretical achievement of developing Marxism
and building socialism in the twenty-first century, which is conducive to enriching
the model of socialist market economy worldwide and its school of thought.
there seems to be a danger judged by the responses of the internet. This danger is
that this debate has made this nationalism gain more advantages, that is, to
support China’s related industries with greater administrative power. For example,
there is a slogan of “developing the chip industry at all costs.” (Wu 2018, 60)
Wu’s fear is obviously contrary to the position of the Chinese government, indus-
tries, academics, and citizens. In July 2018, Xi Jinping stressed,
We must give full play to the unique role of the socialist market economy, give full
play to the advantages of China’s socialist system, and give full play to the role of
scientists and entrepreneurs in innovation to form a system to solve the key and
core technological problems. (Xi 2018a)
Jinglian Wu opposed Chinese cadres and the masses when they demanded the
strengthening of the centralized and unified leadership of scientific and tech-
nological work, and work to form a strong synergy and system to surmount
key technological difficulties. Wu’s extremist misinterpretation of his oppo-
nents as representing the “danger” of “nationalism” in order to make his own
market fundamentalism appear more moderate reflects his adherence to the
laissez-faire ideology of developing a market economy and of reliance on core
technology from the West. In addition, Weiying Zhang of Peking University
has always opposed the national industrial and technological policies. As he
himself emphasized, “I advocate the abolition of any form of industrial policy”
(Zhang 2016, 13).
In response to such views, Enfu Cheng wrote an article in 2018 which, starting
from the theory of socialist market economy combining market regulation and
national control, emphasized that intellectual property advantage brought by inde-
pendent innovation should be highlighted in the new era.
Under the circumstances that key and core technologies are blocked by the
developed countries, only by means of education reform and cultivation and
introduction of the talents, breaking the commanding height occupied by developed
countries by accelerating the independent research and development and
dominating step by step the international industry chain, changing China’s passive
position to an active one, can we fundamentally promote the transformation of
China from a large economy to a strong economy and realize the high-quality
development of the national economy. (Cheng 2018a, 2)
And Zuyao Yu also has stressed that “If we reject entirely the function of the
state in the allocation of resources, and depend purely on the market, the process
for realizing the economic take-off will be slow and the cost will be huge” (Yu
2005c, 50).
In conclusion, as China handles the “economic and trade war,” “technology
war,” and “financial war” waged by the United States, the socialist market econ-
omy theory constructed by the scholars of the “School of New Marxist Economics”
helps to give full play to the positive role of the state, the unique function of the
socialist market economy, and the institutional advantages of China’s socialism,
forming a system to solve core technological problems.
We should have the courage to deepen the reform in an all-round way, consciously
stimulate the vitality of the development of social productive forces through
adjusting relations of production, and consciously adapt to the requirements
of economic base development by improving the superstructure, and make
socialism with Chinese characteristics move forward in accordance with regular
rules. (Xi 2018b)
However,
Scholars of the “School of New Marxist Economics” in China agree with the cen-
tral government’s decision to deepen reform in an all-round way, actively offer
plans and policies, promote the continuous improvement of the socialist market
economy system with Chinese characteristics in the deepening of reform in an all-
round way, and facilitate the self-improvement and development of the socialist
system (He 2018).
However, in the process of comprehensively deepening reform in China, some
academic views catered to the market logic of Western neoliberalism, separating
the relation between “state and market” from that between “government and mar-
ket.” In essence, these views preach taking the “Western model” as a prototype for
the reform of the market economy system and following the development path of
relying on Western capitalism. They advocate the reform plan of unrestrained pri-
vatization, relying purely on marketization and liberalization, emphasizing one-
sidedly the important role of private ownership economy and marketization
reform, and further rejecting the model of the economic system with domiant pub-
lic ownership, denying the institutional advantages of socialist countries in gather-
ing resources for grand undertakings, and negating the path of socialism with
Chinese characteristics via self-dependence and opening-up. Jinglian Wu made
this case in his book 50 Chinese Economists on China’s Economy in the Past 30
Years: Review and Analysis published in 2008. He argued that
economists tend to take the government as the provider of public goods instead
of a market player supplying goods and services and they believe that too much
government intervention hinders market operation and leads to corruption.
Therefore, they are more inclined to prefer the Western type of market economy,
namely, the liberalized market economy system. With more and more scholars
mastering modern economics, the influence of this kind of thinking is on the rise.
(Wu et al. 2008, 10–11)
The idea of “market economy” in Weiying Zhang’s 2012 book The Logic of the
Market echoes Jinglian Wu’s views. Zhang deemed himself one of the representa-
tives of Property-Right Economics and argued that
the market economy could not be built on the basis of state ownership, and only
the market economy based on private property system can operate efficiently!
Therefore, for the successful establishment of the market economy system,
economic privatization is unavoidable. (Zhang 2012, 52)
Evidently, the “market economy model” advocated by Wu and Zhang is the “liber-
alized market economy model” based on neoliberal theories, namely, the “Western
model.” The comprehensive deepening of the “market-oriented” reform they
referred to is in fact the path of Western “liberalized market economy,” even if
disasters such as financial crises, fiscal crises, economic recessions, and polariza-
tion result, it means a “true success” of the reform.
Guoguang Liu distinguished between the two views on reform:
There are significant differences between neoliberal capitalism and socialism with
Chinese characteristics in respects of economic systems, economic theories and
policy ideas. . . . Major failures have occurred in neoliberal economies and social
democratic economies against the criteria of improving the overall strength of the
country and the wellbeing of the people in accordance with the essential
requirement of the people, which makes the socialist market economy with Chinese
characteristics as a new mode of economic civilization of mankind more outstanding
in comparison. Marxism, Leninism and the sinicized political economy theories and
policy suggestions have effectively promoted the improvement of the overall
strength of China and the wellbeing of the people in accordance with the people-
centered principle and the community of human interests. (Cheng 2018b, 58)
Acknowledgements
This article is translated from Chinese by Dr. Xiaoran Gong at the Shanghai University of International
Business and Economics.
Notes
1. See Cheng (2009). He introduced eight important theoretical innovations of modern Marxist
economists, of which this paper only expounds specifically on the significant contributions of
Guoguang Liu, Zuyao Yu, and Enfu Cheng to the socialist market economy theory due to the length
and demonstration perspective of this paper.
2. Jinglian Wu, a neoliberal economist from the Development Research Center of the State Council,
still criticized “the transition from planned economy to market economy” in 1983 (Zhou and Wu
1983, 48). He stated that
However, after learning about the central government’s intention to adopt the wording of “socialist
market economy,” Wu shifted to suggest in an article published in 1992 to “establish the wording of
‘socialist market economy’” (Wu 1992, 3). Shortly afterwards, he no longer insisted on the socialist
market economy with public ownership taking the dominant position, but stated that “the fundamental
characteristics of socialism are social justice plus market economy, rather than other thoughts” (Wu
1997). Later on, he preferred the wording of “good market economy” and “bad market economy.”
3. Guoguang Liu made the following comment on the book titled Study on Enfu Cheng’s Academic
Thoughts (Economic Science Press 2015, 1):
As one of the major academics of the school of innovative Marxism, there is a great deal of
academic and practical significance in the ideological principles of “the adoption of world situation
as the reference, national condition as the grounds, Marxism as the base, Western thoughts as the
tool, national legacy as the root, making comprehensive innovations” that Professor Enfu Cheng
proposed.
References
Central Literature Research Office of the CPC. 1996. Selected Important Documents since the 14th
National Congress (I). [In Chinese.] Beijing: People’s Publishing House.
Central Literature Research Office of the CPC. 2014. Selected Important Documents since the 18th
National Congress (I). [In Chinese.] Beijing: Central Party Literature Press.
Chen, J., and H. Hu. 1988. “Guoguang Liu on Economic Development Strategy in Hainan.” [In
Chinese.] Outlook Weekly, no. 13: 20–21.
Cheng, E. 2009. “The Reform and Opening-Up and the Innovation of the Marxist Economics.” [In
Chinese.] Journal of South China Normal University, no. 1: 5–15.
Cheng, E. 2010a. “On the Basic Standards for Demarcating Socio-economic Formations and Social
Development Stages.” [In Chinese.] In Enfu Cheng Selected Works, 172–181. Beijing: China
Social Sciences Press.
Cheng, E. 2010b. “Drawing on the Experience of the Western Countries and Establishing the Market
Economy System Dominated by Planning.” [In Chinese.] In Enfu Cheng Selected Works, 642–648.
Beijing: China Social Sciences Press.
Cheng, E. 2010c. “Construction of a New Type of Regulation Mechanism ‘Based on Market Regulation
and Dominated by State Regulation.’” [In Chinese.] In Enfu Cheng Selected Works, 611–621.
Beijing: China Social Sciences Press.
Cheng, E. 2010d. “Different Approaches and Schools to Reform, Opening-up and Development.” [In
Chinese.] In Enfu Cheng Selected Works, 601–610. Beijing: China Social Sciences Press.
Cheng, E. 2010e. “The Indispensable ‘Economic System Ensuring Four Principal Positions’ in a
Harmonious Society.” [In Chinese.] In Enfu Cheng Selected Works, 141–144. Beijing: China
Social Sciences Press.
Cheng, E. 2010f. “Reformulation of Chinese Economics: Beyond Marx and Western Economics.” [In
Chinese.] In Enfu Cheng Selected Works, 195–216. Beijing: China Social Sciences Press.
Cheng, E. 2010g. “A Discussion on the Academic Principles Promoting the Modernization of Chinese
Economics: Focusing on the Relation between Marxism, Western Economics and Chinese Studies.”
[In Chinese.] In Enfu Cheng Selected Works, 217–237. Beijing: China Social Sciences Press.
Cheng, E. 2010h. “Eight Dialectical Thoughts of Deng Xiaoping’s Economic Theory.” [In Chinese.] In
Enfu Cheng Selected Works, 65–75. Beijing: China Social Sciences Press.
Cheng, E. 2018a. “Enhance the Self-Confidence in Foreign Economic Competition.” [In Chinese.]
Guangming Daily, August 7.
Cheng, E. 2018b. “The Acceleration of the Process of Enriching the People and Strengthening the
Nation of the New Era under the New Normal.” [In Chinese.] Journal of the Central Institute of
Socialism, no. 1: 51–58.
Cheng, E., and J. Gao. 2014. “On the Decisive Role of the Market in the Allocation of Resources.” [In
Chinese.] Studies on Socialism with Chinese Characteristics, no. 1: 51–57.
Cheng, E., and H. Xu. 1987. “Economic Characteristics and Reform at the Primary Stage of Socialism.”
[In Chinese.] Ganjiang Economy, no. 12: 26–28.
Deng, X. 1983. Deng Xiaoping Selected Works, vol. 2. [In Chinese.] Beijing: People’s Publishing
House.
Economic Science Press. 2015. Study on Enfu Cheng’s Academic Thoughts. [In Chinese.] Beijing:
Economic Science Press.
Gu, H. 2018. “‘Chinese Wisdom’ of Contemporary Marxist Political Economy.” [In Chinese.]
Economics Study of Shanghai, no. 2: 13–21.
He, G. 2018. “The Significant Role of the Constitution on the Economic Reform.” [In Chinese.]
Journal of Management, no. 10: 1–10.
Jian, X. 2018. “Innovation and Development of the Socialist Political Economy with Chinese
Characteristics.” [In Chinese.] Studies on Marxism, no. 3: 4–19.
Liu, G. 2005a. “On the Relationship between Planning and Market in the Socialist Economy.” [In
Chinese.] In Guoguang Liu Collected Works, 60–88. Beijing: China Social Sciences Press.
Liu, G. 2005b. “One More Discussion on the Relationship between Planning and Market.” [In Chinese.]
In Guoguang Liu Collected Works, 127–138. Beijing: China Social Sciences Press.
Liu, G. 2005c. “On Several Issues concerning the Theory of Socialist Market Economy.” [In Chinese.]
In Guoguang Liu Collected Works, 199–216. Beijing: China Social Sciences Press.
Liu, G. 2006a. “A Brief Discussion on the Transformation of the Dual Models.” [In Chinese.] In
Guoguang Liu Selected Works, vol. 4, 188–192. Beijing: China Social Sciences Press.
Liu, G. 2006b. “On the Transformation of Dual Models of China’s Economy.” [In Chinese.] In
Guoguang Liu Selected Works, vol. 4, 206–213. Beijing: China Social Sciences Press.
Liu, G. 2006c. “Rethinking the Reform Is Not Equal to Anti-Reform.” [In Chinese.] In Guoguang Liu
Selected Works, vol. 4, 629–639. Beijing: China Social Sciences Press.
Liu, G. 2006d. “Adhering to the Right Path of the Reform.” [In Chinese.] In Guoguang Liu Selected
Works, vol. 4, 640–645. Beijing: China Social Sciences Press.
Liu, G. 2006e. “Which Path Is and Which Path Is Not the Right Direction: A Brief Discussion on
the ‘Marketization of Reform.’” [In Chinese.] In Guoguang Liu Selected Works, vol. 4, 646–652.
Beijing: China Social Sciences Press.
Liu, G. 2008. “Summary of 30 Years of Reform and Opening-Up by Marxist Philosophical Method.”
[In Chinese.] Social Sciences in China, no. 6: 4–15.
Liu, G., and J. Wang. 2018. “The Directions, Goals and Core Topics of China’s Economic System
Reform.” [In Chinese.] Reform, no. 1: 5–21.
Liu, Y., and D. Zhang. 2006. A Swift Memoir of Guoguang Liu: The Reform and Opening-Up Must
Take Marxism as the Guideline. [In Chinese.] Beijing: China Economic Publishing House.
Stiglitz, J. 2007. Stiglitz Collected Works on Economics, vol. 6. [In Chinese.] Beijing: China Financial
Publishing House.
Wu, J. 1992. “Suggestions on the Establishment of the Wording of the ‘Socialist Market Economy.’”
[In Chinese.] Finance and Trade Economics, no. 7: 3–6.
Wu, J. 1997. “Answers to Reporters’ Questions: Social Justice Plus Market Economy Are the Basic
Characteristics of Socialism.” [In Chinese.] Economic Daily, August 5.
Wu, J. 2018. “Can It Be a Guaranteed Success to Develop Chip Manufacturing at All Costs?” [In
Chinese.] China Weekly, no. 5: 60–61.
Wu, J., G. Fan, Y. Lin, and G. Yi. 2008. 50 Chinese Economists on China’s Economy in the Past 30
Years: Review and Analysis. [In Chinese.] Beijing: China Economic Publishing House.
Wu, J., and S. Zhou. 1983. “On the Regulation Mode of the Socialist Planned Economy.” [In Chinese.]
Social Science Journal, no. 5: 48–56.
Xi, J. 2017. Secure a Decisive Victory in Building a Moderately Prosperous Society in All Respects and
Strive for the Great Success of Socialism with Chinese Characteristics for a New Era. [In Chinese.]
Beijing: People’s Publishing House.
Xi, J. 2018a. “Improve the Innovation Capability for Key Technologies to Provide Powerful
Technological Support for China’s Development.” [In Chinese.] People’s Daily, July 14.
Xi, J. 2018b. “Speech at the Conference Commemorating the 200th Anniversary of Marx’s Birth.” [In
Chinese.] People.cn. http://cpc.people.com.cn/n1/2018/0504/c64094-29966126.html.
Yu, Z. 2002. “China’s Economic Concerns at Home.” [In Chinese.] Strategy and Management, no. 4:
41–50.
Yu, Z. 2005a. “A Discussion on Socialist Market Economy.” [In Chinese.] In Zuyao Yu Selected
Works, 3–32. Shanghai: Shanghai Lexicographical Publishing House.
Yu, Z. 2005b. “On the Fundamental Role of Market in Optimizing Resource Allocation.” [In Chinese.]
In Zuyao Yu Selected Works, 228–235. Shanghai: Shanghai Lexicographical Publishing House.
Yu, Z. 2005c. “China’s Market-Oriented Reform: A Hard Path after Ridding of Bewilderment.” [In
Chinese.] In Zuyao Yu Selected Works, 49–65. Shanghai: Shanghai Lexicographical Publishing
House.
Yu, Z. 2005d. “Solving the Conundrum: Causes of China’s Economic Worries.” [In Chinese.] In
Zuyao Yu Selected Works, 129–161. Shanghai: Shanghai Lexicographical Publishing House.
Zhang, W. 2012. Logic of the Market. [In Chinese.] Shanghai: Shanghai People’s Publishing House.
Zhang, W. 2016. “Right and Wrong of Industrial Policy.” [In Chinese.] Business Observation, no. 11:
12–13.
Zhou, S., and J. Wu. 1983. “On the Attributes of Planned Economy and Commodity Economy of the
Socialist Economy.” [In Chinese.] Industrial Economy Management, no. 9: 157–179.