0% found this document useful (0 votes)
60 views58 pages

Ch4.2 Cost Minimization

The document discusses cost minimization and cost curves. It provides examples of how a firm determines its conditional input demands and total cost function given a production function and input prices. Specifically, it examines: 1) A Cobb-Douglas production function example where the firm's conditional input demands and total cost function are derived. 2) A perfect complements production function example where the firm's conditional demands and total cost function are found. 3) How returns to scale properties determine how average total costs change with output, and the implications for shapes of total cost curves.

Uploaded by

Uyên Trương
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
60 views58 pages

Ch4.2 Cost Minimization

The document discusses cost minimization and cost curves. It provides examples of how a firm determines its conditional input demands and total cost function given a production function and input prices. Specifically, it examines: 1) A Cobb-Douglas production function example where the firm's conditional input demands and total cost function are derived. 2) A perfect complements production function example where the firm's conditional demands and total cost function are found. 3) How returns to scale properties determine how average total costs change with output, and the implications for shapes of total cost curves.

Uploaded by

Uyên Trương
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 58

Chapter 4.

2
COST MINIMIZATION &
COST CURVES
Dr. Nguyen Bich Diep
[email protected]
THE COST-MINIMIZATION PROBLEM

• Consider a firm using two inputs to make one output.


• The production function is y = f(x1,x2).
• Take the output level y  0 as given.
• Given the input prices w1 and w2, the cost of an input bundle (x1,x2) is
w1x1 + w2x2.
THE COST-MINIMIZATION PROBLEM

• For given w1, w2 and y, the firm’s cost-minimization problem is to solve


min w 1x1 + w 2x 2
x1 , x 2  0

subject to f ( x1 , x 2 ) = y.
THE COST-MINIMIZATION PROBLEM

• The levels x1*(w1,w2,y) and x1*(w1,w2,y) in the least-costly input bundle


are the firm’s conditional demands for inputs 1 and 2.
• The firm’s cost function describes the minimum costs necessary to
achieve the desired level of output:
*
c( w 1 , w 2 , y ) = w 1x1 ( w 1 , w 2 , y )
*
+ w 2x 2 ( w 1 , w 2 , y ).
CONDITIONAL INPUT DEMANDS

• Given w1, w2 and y, how is the least costly input bundle located?
• And how is the total cost function computed?
ISO-COST LINES

• A curve that contains all of the input bundles that cost the same
amount is an iso-cost curve.
• E.g., given w1 and w2, the $100 iso-cost line has the equation

w 1x 1 + w 2 x 2 = 100 .
ISO-COST LINES

• Generally, given w1 and w2, the equation of the $c iso-cost line is


w 1x 1 + w 2 x 2 = c
i.e. w1 c
x2 = − x1 + .
w2 w2
Slope is - w1/w2.
ISO-COST LINES
x2 Slopes = -w1/w2.

c”  w1x1+w2x2

c’  w1x1+w2x2
c’ < c”

x1
THE Y’-OUTPUT UNIT ISOQUANT

• All input bundles yielding y’ units of output. Which is the cheapest?


x2

f(x1,x2)  y’

x1
THE COST-MINIMIZATION PROBLEM

• All input bundles yielding y’ units of output. Which is the cheapest?


x2

x2*

f(x1,x2)  y’

x1* x1
THE COST-MINIMIZATION PROBLEM

At an interior cost-minimization input bundle:


x2
* *
(a) f ( x 1 , x 2 ) = y  and
(b) slope of isocost = slope of isoquant
w1 MP1
− = TRS = − at ( x*1 , x*2 ).
w2 MP2
x2*

f(x1,x2)  y’

x1* x1
A COBB-DOUGLAS EXAMPLE OF COST
MINIMIZATION
• A firm’s Cobb-Douglas production function is
1/ 3 2 / 3
y = f ( x1 , x 2 ) = x1 x 2 .
• Input prices are w1 and w2.
• What are the firm’s conditional input demand functions?
A COBB-DOUGLAS EXAMPLE OF COST
MINIMIZATION
• At the input bundle (x1*,x2*) which minimizes
the cost of producing y output units:
(a) y = ( x* ) 1 / 3 ( x* ) 2 / 3
1 2
and

* −2 / 3 * 2 / 3
(b) w1  y /  x1 ( 1 / 3)( x1 ) (x2 )
− =− =−
w2  y /  x2 ( 2 / 3)( x*1 )1/ 3 ( x*2 ) −1/ 3
*
x2
=− .
*
2x1
A COBB-DOUGLAS EXAMPLE OF COST
MINIMIZATION *
w1 x 2
* 1/ 3 * 2 / 3 (b)
= .
(a) y = ( x1 ) ( x 2 ) w 2 2x*1
* 2w 1 *
x =
From (b) 2
x1 .
w2 2/ 3 2/ 3
* 1/ 3  2 w 1 *   2w 1 
Now substitute into (a) to get
y = ( x1 )  x1  =  x*1 .
 w2   w2 
2/ 3
*  w2 
So x1 =   y is the firm’s conditional demand for input 1.
 2w 1 
A COBB-DOUGLAS EXAMPLE OF COST
MINIMIZATION
2/ 3
2w 1 * *  w2 
*
Since x 2 = x1 and x1 =   y
w2  2w 1 

2/ 3 1/ 3
* 2w 1  w 2   2w 1 
x2 =   y=  y
w 2  2w 1   w2 
is the firm’s conditional demand for input 2.
A COBB-DOUGLAS EXAMPLE OF COST
MINIMIZATION
So the cheapest input bundle yielding y output units is

( x*1 ( w 1 , w 2 , y ), x*2 ( w 1 , w 2 , y ) )
  w  2/ 3  2w  1/ 3 
=  2  y,  1
 y .
  2w 1   w  
 2 
A COBB-DOUGLAS EXAMPLE OF COST
MINIMIZATION
So the firm’s total cost function is
c( w 1 , w 2 , y ) = w 1x*1 ( w 1 , w 2 , y ) + w 2x*2 ( w 1 , w 2 , y )
2/ 3 1/ 3
 w2   2w 1 
= w1   y + w2  y
 2w 1   w2 
2/ 3
 1
=  w1/ 3 2/ 3
w y + 21/ 3 1/ 3 2/ 3
w1 w 2 y
 2 1 2

1/ 3
 w 1w 2 
2
= 3  y.
 4 
A PERFECT COMPLEMENTS EXAMPLE OF
COST MINIMIZATION
• The firm’s production function is
y = min{ 4 x 1 , x 2 }.
• Input prices w1 and w2 are given.
• What are the firm’s conditional demands for inputs 1 and 2?
• What is the firm’s total cost function?
A PERFECT COMPLEMENTS EXAMPLE OF
COST MINIMIZATION
x2 Where is the least costly input bundle
4x1 = x2
yielding y’ output units?

x2* = y min{4x1,x2}  y’

x1* x1
= y/4
A PERFECT COMPLEMENTS EXAMPLE OF
COST MINIMIZATION
The firm’s production function is y = min{ 4 x 1 , x 2 }
and the conditional input demands are
*
*
x1 ( w 1 , w 2 , y ) =
y and x 2 ( w 1 , w 2 , y ) = y.
4
*
So the firm’s total cost function is c( w 1 , w 2 , y ) = w 1x1 ( w 1 , w 2 , y )
+ w 2x*2 ( w 1 , w 2 , y )
y  w1 
= w1 + w 2y =  + w 2  y.
4  4 
AVERAGE TOTAL PRODUCTION COSTS

For positive output levels y, a firm’s average total cost of producing y


units is

c( w 1 , w 2 , y )
AC( w 1 , w 2 , y ) = .
y
RETURNS-TO-SCALE AND ATC

• The returns-to-scale properties of a firm’s technology determine how


average production costs change with output level.
• Our firm is presently producing y’ output units.
• How does the firm’s average production cost change if it instead
produces 2y’ units of output?
CONSTANT RETURNS-TO-SCALE AND ATC

• If a firm’s technology exhibits constant returns-to-scale then doubling


its output level from y’ to 2y’ requires doubling all input levels.
• Total production cost doubles.
• Average production cost does not change.
DECREASING RETURNS-TO-SCALE AND ATC

• If a firm’s technology exhibits decreasing returns-to-scale then


doubling its output level from y’ to 2y’ requires more than doubling all
input levels.
• Total production cost more than doubles.
• Average production cost increases.
INCREASING RETURNS-TO-SCALE AND ATC

• If a firm’s technology exhibits increasing returns-to-scale then


doubling its output level from y’ to 2y’ requires less than doubling all
input levels.
• Total production cost less than doubles.
• Average production cost decreases.
RETURNS-TO-SCALE AND ATC
$/output unit

AC(y)
decreasing r.t.s.

constant r.t.s.

increasing r.t.s.

y
RETURNS-TO-SCALE AND TOTAL COSTS

• What does this imply for the shapes of total cost functions?
RETURNS-TO-SCALE
$
AND TOTAL COSTS
c(y)

c(2y’) Slope = c(2y’)/2y’


= AC(2y’).

Slope = c(y’)/y’
= AC(y’).

c(y’)

y’ 2y’ y

ATC increases with y if the firm’s technology exhibits decreasing RTS


RETURNS-TO-SCALE
$
AND TOTAL COSTS
c(y)
c(2y’)
Slope = c(2y’)/2y’
c(y’) = AC(2y’).

Slope = c(y’)/y’
= AC(y’).

y’ 2y’ y

ATC decreases with y if the firm’s technology exhibits increasing RTS


RETURNS-TO-SCALE
$
AND TOTAL COSTS
c(y)
c(2y’) =2c(y’)
Slope = c(2y’)/2y’
= 2c(y’)/2y’
= c(y’)/y’
so AC(y’) = AC(2y’).
c(y’)

y’ 2y’ y

ATC is constant if the firm’s technology exhibits constant RTS


TYPES OF COST CURVES

• How are these cost curves related to each other?


• How are a firm’s long-run and short-run cost curves related?
AFC, AVC & ATC CURVES

• What does an AFC curve look like?


F
AFC( y ) =
y
• AFC(y) is a rectangular hyperbola so its graph looks like ...
$/output unit

AFC(y) → 0 as y → 

AFC(y)

0 y
AFC, AVC & ATC CURVES

• In a short-run with a fixed amount of at least one input, the Law of


Diminishing (Marginal) Returns must apply, causing the firm’s average
variable cost of production to increase eventually.
Since AFC(y) → 0 as y → ,
$/output unit ATC(y) → AVC(y) as y → 

And since short-run AVC(y) must


eventually increase, ATC(y) must
eventually increase in a short-run.

ATC(y)

AVC(y)

AFC(y)

0 y
MARGINAL COST FUNCTION

• Marginal cost is the rate-of-change of variable production cost as the


output level changes. That is,

 cv ( y)
MC( y ) = .
y
MARGINAL COST FUNCTION

• The firm’s total cost function is

c( y ) = F + c v ( y )
• and the fixed cost F does not change with the output level y, so

 c v ( y )  c( y )
MC( y ) = = .
y y
• MC is the slope of both the variable cost and the total cost functions.
MARGINAL & VARIABLE COST FUNCTIONS

• Since MC(y) is the derivative of cv(y), cv(y) must be the integral of


MC(y). That is,
 cv ( y)
MC( y ) =
y
y
 c v ( y ) =  MC( z) dz.
0
MARGINAL & VARIABLE COST FUNCTIONS
$/output unit

y
c v ( y  ) =  MC( z) dz
0
MC(y)

VC of making y’ units

0 y y
MARGINAL & AVERAGE COST FUNCTIONS

• How is marginal cost related to average variable and average total


costs?
MARGINAL & AVERAGE COST FUNCTIONS

• The short-run MC curve intersects the short-run AVC curve from


below at the AVC curve’s minimum.
• Similarly, the short-run MC curve intersects the short-run ATC curve
from below at the ATC curve’s minimum.
$/output unit

MC(y)

ATC(y)

AVC(y)

y
SHORT-RUN & LONG-RUN TC CURVES

• A firm has a different short-run total cost curve for each possible short-
run circumstance.
• Suppose the firm can be in one of just three short-runs;
x2 = x2
or x2 = x2 x2 < x2 < x2.
or x2 = x2
SHORT-RUN & LONG-RUN TC CURVES

• In the long-run the firm is free to choose amongst these three since it
is free to select x2 equal to any of x2, x2, or x2.
• How does the firm make this choice?
$
For 0  y  y, choose x2 = x2. cs(y;x2)

For y  y  y, choose x2 = x2.

For y < y, choose x2 = x2.


cs(y;x2)

cs(y;x2)
c(y), the
F firm’s long-
run total
cost curve.
F
F

y y
0 y
SHORT-RUN & LONG-RUN TC CURVES

• The firm’s long-run total cost curve consists of the lowest parts of the
short-run total cost curves. The long-run total cost curve is the lower
envelope of the short-run total cost curves.
SHORT-RUN & LONG-RUN TC CURVES

• If input 2 is available in continuous amounts then there is an infinity of


short-run total cost curves but the long-run total cost curve is still the
lower envelope of all of the short-run total cost curves.
$
cs(y;x2)

cs(y;x2)

cs(y;x2) c(y)

F

F
F

0 y
SHORT-RUN & LONG-RUN ATC CURVES

• For any output level y, the long-run TC curve always gives the lowest
possible total production cost.
• Therefore, the long-run ATC curve must always give the lowest
possible average total production cost.
• The long-run ATC curve must be the lower envelope of all of the firm’s
short-run ATC curves.
SHORT-RUN & LONG-RUN ATC CURVES

• E.g. suppose again that the firm can be in one of just three short-runs;
x2 = x2
or x2 = x2 (x2 < x2 < x2)
or x2 = x2
then the firm’s three short-run average total cost curves are ...
$/output unit

ACs(y;x2)

ACs(y;x2)

ACs(y;x2)

y
SHORT-RUN & LONG-RUN ATC CURVES

• The firm’s long-run average total cost curve is the lower envelope of
the short-run average total cost curves ...
$/output unit

ACs(y;x2)

ACs(y;x2)

ACs(y;x2)

The long-run av. total cost


curve is the lower envelope AC(y)
of the short-run av. total cost curves.

y
SHORT-RUN & LONG-RUN MC CURVES

• Q: Is the long-run marginal cost curve the lower envelope of the firm’s
short-run marginal cost curves?
• A: No.
SHORT-RUN & LONG-RUN MC CURVES

• In the discrete case, the firm’s three short-run average total cost
curves are ...
$/output unit MCs(y;x2) MCs(y;x2)

ACs(y;x2)

ACs(y;x2)

ACs(y;x2)

MCs(y;x2)

MC(y), the long-run marginal


cost curve.

y
SHORT-RUN & LONG-RUN MC CURVES

• For any output level y > 0, the long-run marginal cost of production is
the marginal cost of production for the short-run chosen by the firm.
• This is always true, no matter how many and which short-run
circumstances exist for the firm.
• So for the continuous case, where x2 can be fixed at any value of zero
or more, the relationship between the long-run marginal cost and all of
the short-run marginal costs is ...
SHORT-RUN & LONG-RUN MC CURVES
MC(y)
SRMCs
$/output unit

AC(y)

For each y > 0, the long-run MC equals the MC for the short-run chosen by the firm.

You might also like