Dornbsuh Model Exercice
Dornbsuh Model Exercice
Problem Set 3
1 Delegated control over monetary policy
(This question is based on K. Rogoff, QJE 1985; D. Romer, q. 9.12)
Suppose that output is given by the Lucas supply function
y = ȳ + b(π − π e). (1)
The social welfare function is
a
S = γ̃y − π 2. (2)
2
The coefficient γ̃ is a random variable with mean E[γ] = γ̃¯ and variance
Var(γ̃) = σ 2. This reflects the fact that political objectives can vary, de-
pending on the political process and a change of goals. It would be nice
to have a flexible central banker who could quickly adjust to the needs of
the situation, that is a central banker who would pursue a relatively more
expansionary policy whenever the realization of γ̃ is high, and a relatively
strict low-inflation policy whenever γ̃ is low. What is the best choice of a
central banker?
Let the central banker follow the objective function
a
S CB = cγ̃y − π 2, (3)
2
where c ∈ R.
The timing of the model is as follows. The private sector decides π e
without knowledge of γ̃. The central banker, however, chooses π after γ̃ is
known.
a) What is the central banker’s choice of π given π e , γ̃, and c?
b) What expectation of inflation, π e , does a rational private sector choose?
c) What is the expected value of the true social welfare function (2)?
d) What value of c maximizes expected social welfare? Is the ‘optimal’
central banker more or less conservative (inflation averse) than the
private sector? Interpret your result.
1
2 A simple model of overshooting
Suppose money demand takes the Cagan form
where mdt denotes the logarithm of nominal money demand, pt the logarithm
of the price level, ytd the logarithm of aggregate demand and it+1 the nominal
interest rate (≈ ln(1 + it+1)). The coefficients φ and η are assumed to be
positive. Money supply is constant,
where et denotes the logarithm of the nominal exchange rate. In this form, a
high value of et means a weak currency. The logarithm of the real exchange
rate is qt = et + p∗t − pt , so that a high value coincides with a depreciated
real exchange rate.
Suppose that aggregate demand depends on the real exchange rate. It is
high, whenever the real exchange depreciates (because exports benefit):
Finally, suppose in Keynesian style that prices are not immediately set to
the expected equilibrium level, but adjusted slowly. In particular, let prices
obey the response function
In order to further simplify the model, let’s standardize all foreign vari-
ables to constants p∗t = i∗t+1 = 0, and let’s suppose that money markets
2
are always clearing immediately, mdt = mst = m̄. Then a simple Dornbusch
model of overshooting can be built as a system in three equations:
m̄ − pt = φytd − η(et+1 − et ), (10)
1
ytd = δ(et − pt ) δ ∈ (0, ), (11)
φ
3
1
ytd = δ(et − pt ) δ ∈ (0, ), (14)
φ
a) Using (14) and the steady-states of ē and p̄ that you found in question
2a), express ytd − ȳ as a function of et − ē and pt − p̄.
b) Using (13) along with the results in 2a) and 3a), express et+1 − ē as a
function of η1 (et − ē) and η1 (pt − p̄).
c) Using (14) and (15) along with the results in 2a), express pt+1 − p̄ as a
weighted sum of et − ē and pt − p̄.
1
From now on, assume that π = η
and φ = 3 for simplicity.
d) Write your findings from 3b) and 3c) into a system of two difference
equations that takes the form
et+1 − ē et − ē
= A· . (16)
pt+1 − p̄ pt − p̄
Find the eigenvalues and eigenvectors of the system (you may, of course,
simply plug your previous results into the formulas from section.)
2(δ+η)
[Hint: An intermediate result is tr(A) = η
and det(A) = 1 −
(1−2η)δ
η2
.]
e) Is the system stable? That is, do the exchange rate and price levels
converge to the steady-state?
If not, set the coefficient of the unstable root to zero. Then, using
the simplified system (16) and the results from 2a), express pt+1 as a
function of et+1 and exogenous variables. Draw this function into the
phase diagram from question 2 (Remember that δ < φ1 .)
What did you just find? What is the intuition for the fact that the
economy obeys this relationship?