Structuring Digital Platform Markets - Antitrust and Utilities' Convergence
Structuring Digital Platform Markets - Antitrust and Utilities' Convergence
Elettra Bietti1*
Abstract
Relying on the case of Google and its regulation between 1998 and 2022, the
Article situates antitrust and public utility efforts as part of a spectrum of
coextensive regulatory approaches to digital markets. It configures the space
of regulatory possibility across ex ante and ex post, centralizing and
decentralizing strategies. Its aim is to guide a move away from siloed or a-
1*
Joint Postdoctoral Fellow at NYU Law and Cornell Tech, S.J.D. Harvard Law School.
Table of Contents
Introduction ..................................................................................................................... 3
I. Digital Platforms, Antitrust Exceptionalism and The Regulatory State ............. 6
A. Digital Platforms: Definition, Evolution and the Role of Law ...................... 6
1. What is a ‘Digital Platform’? .................................................................... 8
2. The Role of Law in the Digital Platform Economy ................................ 10
3. Interpreting Convergence ........................................................................ 13
B. Conventional Accounts of Antitrust and Economic Regulation .................. 15
1. Competition, monopoly and consumer choice ........................................ 16
2. Antitrust and regulation as friends and foes ............................................ 18
C. The Public Utility as Exception to the Free Market Default ........................ 21
1. Infrastructure ........................................................................................... 22
2. Defining Public Utility Regulation.......................................................... 23
D. Conclusions to Part I .................................................................................... 24
II. Addressing Google’s Power: From Laissez Faire to Antitrust and Regulation 25
A. Introducing Google ...................................................................................... 26
B. Underenforcement ........................................................................................ 29
1. Advertising .............................................................................................. 31
2. Search ...................................................................................................... 33
3. Under-enforcement.................................................................................. 34
C. A Turning Point............................................................................................ 36
D. The Infrastructural Turn in Digital Antitrust ............................................... 37
1. Search ...................................................................................................... 37
2. Advertising .............................................................................................. 38
3. Is Antitrust Changing? ............................................................................ 40
E. The Pro-Competitive Regulatory Turn ........................................................ 41
1. Google as a Common Carrier and Utility? .............................................. 41
2. Toward Pro-Competitive Regulation ...................................................... 43
3. “Light-Handed Pro-Competitive Regulation” ......................................... 44
F. Conclusions to Part II ................................................................................... 45
III. Envisioning and Constructing The Convergence of Antitrust and Utilities in
Digital Platform Markets...................................................................................................... 46
A. Envisioning the Convergence of Antitrust and Utilities .............................. 47
1. The Convergence of Antitrust and Utilities ............................................ 51
2. Lessons from ARD .................................................................................. 52
3. Stretching ARD ....................................................................................... 54
B. Pragmatism in the Digital Platform Economy: Integrating Remedies and
Values ...................................................................................................................... 57
1. Integrating Means: Remedies, Processes, Institutions ............................ 57
2. Integrating Ends: Values and Goals ........................................................ 59
C. Pragmatism in Practice: Markets and Society’s Dynamic Co-Dependence 60
INTRODUCTION
2
See, e.g., Dipayan Ghosh, Don’t Break Up Facebook — Treat It Like a Utility, HARV.
BUS. REV., May 30, 2019, https://hbr.org/2019/05/dont-break-up-facebook-treat-it-like-a-
utility.
3 Frank Pasquale, Tech Platforms and the Knowledge Problem, Vol. II AMERICAN
CAL. L. REV. 1005 (1987) (distinguishing antitrust from the notion of economic
regulation); Herbert Hovenkamp, Antitrust and the Regulatory Enterprise, 2004 COLUMBIA
BUS. L.REV. 335, 336 (2004) (arguing that antitrust and regulation are “complementary
products”).
5
See, e.g., State of New York et al. v. Facebook Inc., No. 1:2020cv03589 (U.S. District
Court for the District of Columbia, filed December 9th, 2020); FTC v. Facebook Inc., No.
1:2020cv03590 (U.S. District Court for the District of Columbia, filed December 9th,
2020); United States of America v. Google LLC, No. DC/1:20-cv-03010 (US District
Court for the District of Columbia, filed October 20, 2020); State of Colorado et al v.
Google LLC, No. 1:2020cv03715 (US District Court for the District of Columbia, filed
December 17, 2020); The State Of Texas, et al v. Google, LLC, No. 4:2020cv00957 (US
District Court for the Eastern District of Texas, filed December 16, 2020).
6
American Innovation and Choice Online Act, S.2992, 117th Cong. (2021-2022)
[hereinafter AICOA].
7
BRETT M. FRISCHMANN, INFRASTRUCTURE: THE SOCIAL VALUE OF SHARED RESOURCES
3-4 (2012) (defining infrastructure).
antitrust and branches of law more attuned to the public dimension of digital
services.
Instead of focusing on doctrinal divides and endogenous disciplinary
concerns, asking for example whether antitrust is “the best tool for the job”
of promoting “competition in digital-platform markets,”8 regulators and
scholars should turn their attention to cross-cutting procedural and normative
questions: How to make sense of the convergence between a panoply of
remedies and resources available to courts and regulators in the digital
economy across and beyond disciplinary boundaries? What normative values
and social goals must drive regulatory design strategies in specific tech
platform contexts? Relying on antitrust and regulation’s ex ante and ex post
procedural affordances and their decentralizing and centralizing tendencies,
regulators might in practice opt for facilitating the decentralization of some
digital functions while centralizing other functions. They might act in both
an ex ante and ex post manner to capture the dynamic nature of digital
innovation. They might be faced with normative conundrums requiring that
they promote privacy, speech and security considerations which can
sometimes constrain competition, individual choice and innovation.9 The
task entails pooling from a range of different remedies and regulatory
resources at once and considering each digital function (e.g. “web search”)
as a situated problem that is not solved generically by appealing to one
remedy (“break-up”), body of law (“antitrust”), or goal (“promoting
competition”), and rejecting another. Further, an integrated approach
demonstrates that regulation does not simply disrupt competitive processes,
undermining choice and innovation. It in fact can promote and help them
flourish.
The Article presents a deconstructive argument followed by a
constructive one. Part I describes the arc of digital platform governance
efforts, offers a critique of the literature on the relation between antitrust and
regulation, and grounds an argument for greater regulatory experimentation
in the need to revisit the public utility as a more versatile concept. Part II
describes the evolution and convergence between antitrust and regulatory
efforts in digital settings, looking at the case of Google’s activities on web
8
Hovenkamp, Platform Monopoly, supra note 3.
9
These normative choices arise not only in relation to digital platforms like Google or
Facebook, discussed in this Article, but also as regards emerging technologies such as the
internet of things. See, e.g., Chris Jay Hoofnagle, Aniket Kesari & Aaron Perzanowski, The
Tethered Economy, 87 GEORG. WASH. L. REV. 782 (2019) (discussing, inter alia, data
flows in the Internet of Things); Peter Swire, The Portability and Other Required Transfers
Impact Assessment: Assessing Competition, Privacy, Cybersecurity, and Other
Considerations, Georgia Tech Scheller College of Business Research Paper No. 3689171,
https://ssrn.com/abstract=3689171 (discussing data portability and FRAND-like
obligations in the Internet of Things).
search and online advertising. It shows that antitrust and utility-like efforts
have not only always been intertwined, but they are also currently converging
in distinct new ways. In particular, existing lawsuits against Big Tech and
legislative proposals such as AICOA share a concern for pre-structuring
digital markets so as to make them more competitive and contestable. Part III
normatively evaluates the convergence of antitrust and regulatory strategies
in digital platform settings and starts the project of designing more integrated
policy efforts. After introducing a visual framework which illustrates how
antitrust and regulatory efforts are converging in digital settings, Part III
introduces a pragmatic methodology. This helps integrate goals and remedies
and cuts across legal domains such as antitrust, utilities and consumer
protection law. The Article concludes with two examples illustrating why the
design of more integrated institutional efforts is a normative imperative in the
digital economy.
coercive power of the state.10 Today, that early promise dating from the 1990s
is demonstrably shortsighted. The digital economy has become a collection
of ‘walled gardens’ dominated by a handful of platform companies such as
Google/Alphabet, Facebook/Meta or Amazon.11 These gatekeepers leverage
their privileged access to data, attention and infrastructural capability to
enclose users and competitors in relations of dependency while offering them
services that are increasingly core to modern life. The Internet of today is
therefore very different from the Internet of the 1990s. It is far less “open”
and decentralized, and far less facially competitive. Small entrepreneurs have
fewer opportunities to compete and create successful digital businesses and
consumers have a more difficult time switching from one platform to a
competing one for the same service.
Contrary to prevalent beliefs, the transition from a relatively utopian
internet of decentralized networks to a relatively dystopian internet of
enclosed platforms, which happened over the course of one, or at best two,
decades, was not the result of law’s absence.12 As Robert Hale explained, law
orders markets through private contract and property law rules.13 Contract,
10
See, e.g., Reno v. American Civil Liberties Union, 521 U.S. 844, 851 (1997) (“a unique
medium-known to its users as ‘cyberspace’ - located in no particular geographical location
but available to anyone, anywhere in the world, with access to the Internet”); John Perry
Barlow, Selling Wine Without Bottles: The Economy of Mind on the Global Net, WIRED
MAGAZINE (1994), https://www.eff.org/pages/selling-wine-without-bottles-economy-mind-
global-net (arguing that digital artifacts should be freed from the constraints of copyright
law); John Perry Barlow, A Declaration of Independence of Cyberspace, Electronic Frontier
Foundation (1996), https://www.eff.org/cyberspace-independence (arguing that cyberspace
must be free from the pressures and laws of states); Yochai Benkler, A Political Economy of
Utopia? 18 DUKE L. & TECH. REV. 78 (2019) (discussing Barlow’s two essays in a
contemporary light).
11
See JONATHAN ZITTRAIN, THE FUTURE OF THE INTERNET – AND HOW TO STOP IT
(2008), Introduction (describing the increasingly gated and enclosed evolution of the
Internet, and asks how we might stop such enclosure trend).
12
See, generally, SHOSHANA ZUBOFF, THE AGE OF SURVEILLANCE CAPITALISM (2019)
(arguing that the growth of companies like Google was the result of an absence of law,
rather than the result of specific legal choices). For critiques of this perspective on law in
digital markets see, e.g., Amy Kapczynski, The Law of Informational Capitalism, Review
of Shoshana Zuboff, The Age of Surveillance Capitalism and Julie Cohen, Between Truth
and Power, The Legal Constructions Of Informational Capitalism, 129 YALE L. J. 1460
(2020), Evgeny Morozov, Capitalism’s New Clothes, THE BAFFLER, February 4, 2019,
https://thebaffler.com/latest/capitalisms-new-clothes-morozov.
13 See Robert L. Hale, Coercion and Distribution in a Supposedly Non-Coercive State, 38
POLITICAL SCIENCE QUARTERLY 470 (1923) (expanding the notion of coercion to show that
it is ubiquitous in property and contractual relations and is an often desirable way to
structure marketplaces). Also see BARBARA FRIED, THE PROGRESSIVE ASSAULT ON
LAISSEZ FAIRE: ROBERT HALE AND THE FIRST LAW AND ECONOMICS MOVEMENT (1998)
(describing Hale’s work and context). And see Yochai Benkler, An Unhurried View of
Private Ordering in Information Transactions, 53 VANDERBILT L. REV. 2063 (2000)
property and other laws and regulatory modalities indeed shape digital
markets constantly and in a durable way. Faith in individual choice, freedom,
market efficiency, openness and decentralization have not led to less law; in
practice they helped build the legal and intellectual case for new forms of
control.14 New experimental ways to enclose people as assets emerged
around the early 2000s, in response to new financial and legal requirements.
As a result of the dot-com bubble bursting, for example, open platforms such
as Google began to rely on decentralized information sharing infrastructures
to make money from advertising.15 Between 2000 and 2020, the internet then
grew increasingly concentrated, with the most successful platform models –
Google, Facebook, Amazon, Apple to name a few – benefiting from a
virtuous cycle of winner-take-all dynamics and vertical integration. Many of
these companies have become unparalleled transnational powers, deserving
the title “new governors.”16
This evolution prompts two questions. First, what are digital platforms?
And second, what role did law play in digital platforms’ growth and what is
law’s role today? Answering these two questions will surface some
complexities around the antitrust-regulation polarity and prepare the ground
for an experimental approach to integrating antitrust, regulation and utility
regulation in the digital economy.
(arguing that enclosing information goods is not per se desirable); Julie E Cohen, Lochner
in Cyberspace: The New Economic Orthodoxy of “Rights Management”, 97 MICH. L. REV.
462 (1998) (showing the distributive politics of rights over information); Margaret J. Radin
& R. Polk Wagner, The Myth of Private Ordering: Rediscovering Legal Realism in
Cyberspace, 73 CHICAGO-KENT L. REV. 1295 (1998) (discussing the limits of laisser faire
and private ordering in digital settings).
14
See JULIE E. COHEN, BETWEEN TRUTH AND POWER 23 (2019) (hereafter TRUTH AND
POWER).
15
ZUBOFF, supra note 12, discussing this shift, however without emphasizing the role of
law.
16
Kate Klonick, The New Governors: The People, Rules, and Processes Governing Online
Speech, 131 HARV. L. REV. 598, 598 (2018). Also see, e.g., Anupam Chander,
Facebookistan, 90 NORTH CAROLINA L. REV. 1807 (2012) (arguing that platforms should
be considered self-standing jurisdictions with a power equivalent to that of states).
17
Julie E. Cohen, Tailoring Election Regulation: The Platform is the Frame, 4 GEO. L.
TECH. REV. 641, 656 (2020). Also see José van Dijck et al., Platformisation, 8 INTERNET
POL’Y REV. 1 (2019) (platforms are “digital infrastructures that facilitate and shape
undermine each other’s ability to compete, raise barriers and costs to entry or
otherwise conclude mutually beneficial but competitively dubious
agreements among themselves. Fourth, platform gatekeeping companies rely
on the capture, use, creation and monetization of data and its algorithmic
processing. This core reliance on data and algorithmic processing raises novel
surveillance issues.21 Fifth, these businesses create and leverage opacity as a
core business strategy.22 Opacity, in turn, can have implications from a
surveillance and non-discrimination perspective. Sixth, platform business
models transform infrastructural resources into markets and vice-versa.
Platform companies manage markets and infrastructures and leverage data,
asymmetries of knowledge and opacity to make money while offering critical
services to the public. They are simultaneously market-makers and
infrastructure providers.23
Each of these characteristics is highly relevant not only to an
understanding of how the platform economy evolved in the way it did, but
also to how one should regulate platforms today.
21
See generally Shoshana Zuboff, Big other: surveillance capitalism and the prospects of
an information civilization, 30 JOURNAL OF INFORMATION TECHNOLOGY (2015) (coining
the term surveillance capitalism to describe the exploitative practices of data-driven
business models); SAFIYA UMOJA NOBLE, ALGORITHMS OF OPPRESSION: HOW SEARCH
ENGINES REINFORCE RACISM (2018) (describing the discriminatory impacts of data-driven
recommender systems on people of color); Jose van Dijck, Datafication, dataism and
dataveillance: Big Data between scientific paradigm and ideology, 12 BIG DATA
SURVEILLANCE (2014) (introducing the ideas of dataism and dataveillance to explain the
phenomenon of ubiquitous data collection and life tracking and its discontents).
22
Johanna Gunawan et al., A Comparative Study of Dark Patterns Across Web and Mobile
Modalities, 5 PROC. ACM HUM.-COMPUT. INTERACT. (2021),
https://doi.org/10.1145/3479521 (mapping the use of dark patterns across 150 platforms on
the web and mobile); Gregory Day and Abbey Stemler, Are Dark Patterns
Anticompetitive? 72 ALA. L. REV. 1 (2020) (arguing that digital manipulation and opaque
design should constitute anticompetitive behavior)..
23
José van Dijck, David Nieborg & Thomas Poell, Reframing Platform Power, 8 INTERNET
POLICY REVIEW (2019), https://policyreview.info/articles/analysis/reframing-platform-
power (describing platform power in terms of infrastructural power and co-ependencies);
Elettra Bietti, Self-Regulating Platforms and Antitrust Justice, 101 TEXAS L. REV. 165, 173
(2022) (arguing that platforms are both monopolistic actors, marketplaces and market
makers).
being the immoveable object.24 Yet, as Cohen demonstrated, law is far from
immoveable; it has been there all along, it enables new technologies and
marketplaces to emerge and evolves with them.
The story of law and digital platforms’ (co-)evolution is often told in the
following way.
24
TRUTH AND POWER, Introduction, at 1.
25
Werbach, supra note 18, at 17.
26
Hal R. Varian, Computer Mediated Transactions, AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW:
PAPERS & PROCEEDINGS 100 (May 2010) (showing that computer-mediated transactions
create efficiencies); Hal R. Varian, Beyond Big Data, 49 BUSINESS ECONOMICS (2013)
(exploring market changes due to big data developments); Hal R. Varian, Intelligent
Technology, 53 FINANCE & DEVELOPMENT (September 2016) (celebrating the virtues of
advances in AI and data-driven technologies). Also see VIKTOR MAYER-SCHONBERGER &
THOMAS RAMGE, REINVENTING CAPITALISM IN THE AGE OF BIG DATA (2018)(arguing that
big data brings about an era of perfect information and ideal marketplaces).
27
See Yochai Benkler, Siren Songs and Amish Children: Autonomy, Information, and Law,
76 N.Y.U. L. REV. 23 (2001); YOCHAI BENKLER, THE WEALTH OF NETWORKS (2006) (each
presenting an optimistic, yet cautious, view of the potential of networks to enhance
autonomy). Also see Kiel Brennan-Marquez & Daniel Susser, Privacy, Autonomy, and the
Dissolution of Markets, KNIGHT FIRST AMENDMENT INSTITUTE, August 11, 2022,
https://knightcolumbia.org/content/privacy-autonomy-and-the-dissolution-of-markets (a
revised account of digital markets’ capacity to foster autonomy).
28
See House Committee on the Judiciary, Investigation of Competition in the Digital
Marketplace: Majority Staff Report and Recommendations, October 6th, 2020,
https://judiciary.house.gov/news/documentsingle.aspx?DocumentID=3429 (hereafter
House Report).
b. To ‘break-up’ or to ‘regulate’?
It is in this context, and as a sequel to this story, that views on the role of
antitrust and regulatory intervention in the digital platform economy have
recently developed. Law is plural, it comes in many forms. There are many
legal doctrines that can be relied on to regulate digital businesses. Among
these methods and strategies, however, two paths have been singled out as
particularly promising for fighting the growing and threatening power of tech
platform giants. The first consists in returning to the decentralized roots of
the digital economy, disaggregating and breaking-up platforms and enforcing
competition rules so that the digital economy can return to its natural, pre-
legal, and decentralized state, fostering innovation and choice without
requiring durable government involvement. The second consists instead in a
change of course. The deregulatory attitude of the 1990s contributed to a
centralized economy. Re-decentralizing platforms today could lead to
another wave of centralization. Thus, what is needed is a more hands-on
durable form of intervention that takes digital markets as structurally fragile.
Adequate levels of choice, innovation and competition can only be ensured,
under this view, through strong and durable regulatory structuring.
These two approaches seem antithetic because they entail two different
attitudes to digital markets. The first is friendly to the idea of self-correcting
digital markets, the other is skeptical of it. The disagreement on whether to
“break-up” or “regulate” Facebook or Google, at bottom, is a disagreement
on whether self-correcting competitive markets can alone or through punctual
facilitative interventions produce the benefits economic theorists impute to
them.29 The identification of antitrust with a deregulatory digital market
ideology has led technology scholars to cautious skepticism on antitrust and
“break-up” remedies. Scholars have claimed that “splitting Instagram and
WhatsApp off from Facebook… will not solve the most intractable issues
about how to moderate speech...”30 or that “antitrust-based approaches do not
align well with surveillance abuses.”31 One media scholar has even warned
“don’t expect American antitrust to accomplish anything to limit the power
29
See below discussion on perfect competition at I.B.
30
Evelyn Douek, Breaking Up Facebook Won’t Fix Its Speech Problems, SLATE, May 10,
2019, https://slate.com/technology/2019/05/chris-hughes-facebook-antitrust-speech.html.
31
Julie E. Cohen, How (Not) to Write a Privacy Law, KNIGHT FIRST AMENDMENT
INSTITUTE, March 23, 2021, https://knightcolumbia.org/content/how-not-to-write-a-
privacy-law.
c. A convergence?
Recognizing the limits of these understandings of antitrust law means
coming to terms with the regulatory state in its complexity and perceiving the
beginnings of a third approach that sits between decentralizing and
centralizing, between antitrust and utility regulation, between bottom-up
competition and top-down regulation. Two parallel moves characterize it. On
the one hand, antitrust lawsuits, which for long were hands-off and timid in
tech platform markets, are increasingly aimed at Big Tech’s infrastructural
power and are designed to attract quasi-regulatory remedies such as
interoperability, break-ups, and non-discrimination obligations. On the other
hand, far from the monolithic conceptions of utilities law that prevail in
energy or transportation industries, regulation in digital markets is being
envisioned as “light-hand” and “pro-competitive.”33 Policy makers seek to
structure digital markets through sectoral law so that they can become more
decentralized, horizontal, and conducive to competition and consumer
choice.34 The convergence between antitrust and regulatory attitudes is both
a response to narrow conceptions of antitrust law and the symptom of a
transformed ‘free markets’ mentality in digital settings, one that recognizes
the imperative to structure markets to enable competitive disruption.
3. Interpreting Convergence
32
Siva Vaidhyanathan, So the government’s antitrust lawsuit against Facebook failed.
Where now?, THE GUARDIAN, June 30, 2021,
https://www.theguardian.com/commentisfree/2021/jun/30/facebook-antitrust-lawsuit-big-
tech?ref=upstract.com&curator=upstract.com&utm_source=upstract.com.
33
See Rogerson & Shelanski, supra note 3.
34
Id.
35
15 U.S.C. § 1 & 2.
36
15 U.S.C. § 13 and following.
37
15 U.S.C. §§ 41 to 58.
38
15 U.S.C. § 18(a).
39
Amending section 2 of the Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C. §§ 13(a) to (f).
40
Some public utility statutes include various Post Office Acts, the Pacific Railroad Act of
1862, the Telegraph Act of 1866, the Federal Reserve Act of 1913, the Federal Water
Power Act, the Radio Act of 1927, the Communications Act of 1934, the Public Utility
Holding Company and the Federal Power Acts of 1935, the Federal Aviation Act of 1958,
the Telecommunications Act of 1996. “Regulation” can also be construed differently and
more expansively. See, e.g., Lawrence Lessig, The New Chicago School, 27 J. LEGAL
STUD. 661, 662 n.1 (1998) (“[By regulation] I mean the constraining effect of some action,
or policy, whether intended by anyone or not. In this sense, the sun regulates the day, or a
market has a regulating effect on the supply of oranges.”).
41
See TRUTH AND POWER (articulating the role of law in structuring and reacting to
technological phenomena in platform settings). Also see Kapczynski, supra note 12; Elettra
Bietti, A Genealogy of Digital Platform Regulation, 7 GEO. L. TECH. REV. 1, 1 (2022)
(describing the evolution of legal attitudes in platform markets).
42
See Sanjukta Paul, Antitrust as Allocator of Coordination Rights, 67 UCLA L. REV. 378
(2020) (framing antitrust law as a body positively shaping markets); Nathan Tankus &
Luke Herrine, Competition Law as Collective Bargaining Law, in CAMBRIDGE HANDBOOK
OF LABOUR IN COMPETITION LAW (2022) (arguing that competition law encompasses labor
laws).
Over the last 40 years economists and economic law scholars’ attention
has been on pursuing efficiency, competitiveness, innovation and choice.
This ‘free markets’ rationality has led to a decline in utility and sectoral
regulation.45 It has also led to the privatization of numerous industries, e.g.
airlines.46 In this context, antitrust and regulation have been frequently
construed as separate legal domains operating in separate descriptive and
43
Bietti, Self-Regulating Platforms, supra note 23, at 190 (showing that Chicago School
antitrust law in particular is committed to the separability of market efficiency and
distributive considerations).
44
Rogerson & Shelanski, supra note 3; Hovenkamp, Platform Monopoly, supra note 3.
45
WILLIAM NOVAK, NEW DEMOCRACY: THE CREATION OF THE MODERN AMERICAN STATE
112 (2022), (hereafter NEW DEMOCRACY) (“[T]he last half century or so has witnessed a
sustained effort … to undermine and undo the public utility idea. Perhaps aware of the
intimate connection between public utilities and the rise of the regulatory state, two
generations of critics of regulation have taken direct aim at almost every aspect of the
progressive public utility paradigm.”).
46
PAUL SABIN, PUBLIC CITIZENS: THE ATTACK ON BIG GOVERNMENT AND THE REMAKING
OF AMERICAN LIBERALISM (2021) (tracing the roots of 1980s Reaganism in earlier liberal
attitudes to institutions); PAUL STEPHEN DEMPSEY & ANDREW R. GOETZ, AIRLINE
DEREGULATION AND LAISSEZ-FAIRE MYTHOLOGY 179-87 (1992) (criticizing Alfred
Khan’s approach to airline deregulation). Also see Paul Stephen Dempsey, The Rise and
Fall of the Civil Aeronautics Board - Opening Wide the Floodgates of Entry, 11
TRANSPORT. L. J. (1979)(discussing the CAB’s role in the history of airline deregulation).
normative ways, over separate objects, and often having separate goals.
Dominant conceptions have interpreted antitrust in competitive markets and
privatized industries as a preferred default, and regulation as an exception to
be justified only in rare circumstances. Revisiting the plausibility of some of
these tendencies has significant repercussions for how we might regulate
digital platform ecosystems today and in the future.
47
William J. Baumol, On the Proper Cost Tests for Natural Monopoly in a Multiproduct
Industry, 67 THE AM. ECON. REV. 809 (Dec., 1977) (defining natural monopoly).
48
ADAM SMITH, THE WEALTH OF NATIONS (1776), Book I Chapter VII (describing the
“invisible hand” mechanism). Also see ADAM SMITH, THE THEORY OF MORAL SENTIMENTS
(1759), Part IV, Chapter 1.
49
HAL R. VARIAN, INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS: A MODERN APPROACH, 1 (8th Ed,
2010); and see generally CRANE & HOVENKAMP, infra note 51 (illustrating contestations on
the relationship between state and market as regards competition over the last century).
50
See, e.g., MASSIMO MOTTA, COMPETITION POLICY: THEORY AND PRACTICE 75-89 (2004)
(discussing network effects, non-physical barriers to entry and other characteristics that sit
in-between competitive markets and natural monopolies). WILLIAM BAUMOL, JOHN C.
PANZAR AND ROBERT D. WILLIG, CONTESTABLE MARKETS AND THE THEORY OF
INDUSTRIAL STRUCTURE (1982) (on the contestation of monopolies over time).
51
DANIEL A. CRANE AND HERBERT HOVENKAMP, THE MAKING OF COMPETITION POLICY:
LEGAL AND ECONOMIC SOURCES 1, 71, 125 (2013) (describing the influence of neoclassical
and other economic theories on competition policy over time).
52
Id. See also Sanjukta Paul, Beyond Neoclassical Antitrust, BOSTON REVIEW, June 23,
2022, https://bostonreview.net/forum_response/beyond-neoliberal-antitrust/ (denouncing
the over-emphasis on perfect competition economic law and policy).
53
N. Pac. Ry. Co. v. United States, 356 U.S. 1, 4 (1958).
54
FRIEDRICH A. HAYEK, THE CONSTITUTION OF LIBERTY 29-30 (1960) (making the case
for deregulation).
55
Id.
56
For a different use of the word “frenemies,” see ARIEL EZRACHI & MAURICE E. STUCKE,
VIRTUAL COMPETITION, THE PROMISE AND PERILS OF THE ALGORITHM-DRIVEN ECONOMY
1, 147 (2016).
57
See ALFRED KHAN, THE ECONOMICS OF REGULATION: PRINCIPLES AND INSTITUTIONS, 2
(Vol. 1, 1970). However, see NOVAK, NEW DEMOCRACY, at 123, (citing Bruce Wyman,
The Law of Public Callings as a Solution to the Trust Problem, 17 HARV. L. REV. 157
(1904): “monopoly was just one of many important factors that could justify a public
utility”) in .
58
Breyer, supra note 4, at 1007. Also see Hovenkamp, supra note 4, at 339 (noting
information asymmetries as a key case of externality justifying regulatory intervention).
The case of digital markets seems a case in point, see Rogerson & Shelanski, supra note 3,
at 1914 (arguing for supplementing general purpose digital antitrust actions with sectoral
regulation).
59
The relationship is governed by three main legal regimes in the United States. First, the
so-called Noerr-Pennington doctrine immunizes petitioners of legislation from antitrust
scrutiny. See R.R. Presidents Conference v. Noerr Motor Freight, Inc., 365 U.S. 127
(1961); United Mine Workers v. Pennington, 381 U.S. 657 (1965). Second, the state action,
or Parker, doctrine immunizes conduct governed by state and local regulations from
federal antitrust law. See Parker v. Brown, 317 U.S. 341 (1943). See also Hovenkamp,
supra note 4, at 347. (“[i]f the state passes a statute that unambiguously calls for potato
price regulation, and a potato agency created for this purpose actively administers the rate-
making process, then the antitrust court has no choice but to find the regulation immune
from the antitrust laws.”) Third, federal law can expressly exempt conduct in a given
industry from antitrust scrutiny through a preemption or immunity clause (e.g. Webb-
Pomerene Act, 15 U.S.C. §62 (2006), exempting collective export associations from
antitrust liability), it can expressly preserve antitrust scrutiny through a savings clause
(Telecommunications Act of 1996, 47 U.S.C. § 152 expressly preserving antitrust law), or
it can impliedly exempt antitrust. Regarding implied exemption, until 2004 the law
interpreted antitrust and regulation as compatible unless there was “plain repugnancy
between the two.” See United States v. Philadelphia Nat'l Bank, 374 U.S. 321, 350-1
(1963) (“repeals of the antitrust laws by implication from a regulatory statute are strongly
disfavored, and have only been found in cases of plain repugnancy between the antitrust
and regulatory provisions.”); and Otter Tail Power Co. v. United States 410 U.S. 366
(1973) (where the objectives of the Federal Power Act and of antitrust law were held to be
aligned). However, as argued in Howard Shelanski, The Case for Rebalancing Antitrust
and Regulation, 109 MICH. L. REV. 683 (2011), Trinko and Credit Suisse loosened the
standard of implied immunity making the joint application of antitrust and regulation more
difficult to justify. See Verizon Commc’ns Inc. v. L. Offs. of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP 540
U.S. 398 (2004); Credit Suisse Sec. LLC v. Billing, 551 U.S. 264 (2007).
60
See Trinko, 540 U.S. 398 (2004); Credit Suisse, 551 U.S. 264 (2007).
61
Breyer, supra note 4, at 1006.
When the government makes rules about price or output, market forces no longer
govern. To that extent antitrust is shoved aside. A corollary is that as an industry
undergoes deregulation, or removal from the regulatory process, antitrust re-enters
as the residual regulator. … .67
62
Id.
63
Id.
64
Id, at 1007.
65
Hovenkamp, supra note 4, at 336; Herbert Hovenkamp, Antitrust and Regulation Over
Time, The Regulatory Review, Oct 1, 2020,
https://www.theregreview.org/2020/10/01/hovenkamp-antitrust-regulation-over-time/. Also
see Howard Shelanski, The Case for Rebalancing Antitrust and Regulation, 109 MICH. L.
REV. 683 (2011) (arguing against exemptions of antitrust in regulated sectors); Rogerson &
Shelanski, supra note 3, at 1914 (arguing for supplementing general purpose antitrust with
sectoral regulation in technology markets).
66
Hovenkamp, The Regulatory Enterprise, supra note 4, at 336.
67
Id. at 341.
Antitrust law takes a market's regulatory structure as given, warts and all, and tries
to prevent injuries to competition that the regulatory process leaves untended. …
[A]ntitrust's role is "residual." It picks up only where regulation leaves off.68
(emphasis added)
68
Id. at 342.
69
WILLIAM NOVAK, NEW DEMOCRACY, at 121. Also see JOHN DEWEY, THE PUBLIC AND
ITS PROBLEMS 109 (1927) (the democratic state is dedicated to “the utilization of
government as the genuine instrumentality of an inclusive and fraternally associated
public.”); FELIX FRANKFURTER, PUBLIC AND ITS GOVERNMENT 81 (1930) (emphasizing the
importance of government’s role “in securing for society those essential services which are
furnished by public utilities.”).
70
William J. Novak, The Public Utility Idea and the Origins of Modern Business
Regulation, in N. R. LAMOREAUX AND W. J. NOVAK (EDS.), THE CORPORATION AND
AMERICAN DEMOCRACY (2017), at 170 (presenting a history of utilities as paradigms of
regulatory experimentation).
71
Munn v. Illinois, 94 U.S. 113 (1876).
Property does become clothed with a public interest when used in a manner to make
it of public consequence and affect the community at large. When, therefore, one
devotes his property to a use in which the public has an interest, he, in effect, grants
to the public an interest in that use, and must submit to be controlled by the public
for the common good, to the extent of the interest he has thus created.72
1. Infrastructure
72
Munn, at 126.
73 NEW DEMOCRACY, at 112 (“[T]he last half century or so has witnessed a sustained effort
… to undermine and undo the public utility idea. Perhaps aware of the intimate connection
between public utilities and the rise of the regulatory state, two generations of critics of
regulation have taken direct aim at almost every aspect of the progressive public utility
paradigm.”).
74
Posner, infra note 154, at 635-6.
75
Id. at 638.
76
Harold Demsetz, Why Regulate Utilities?, 11 J. OF L. AND ECON. 55, 61 (1968) (the case
against utility regulation).
77
Rick Geddes, Public Utilities, in ENCYCLOPEDIA OF LAW AND ECONOMICS: THE HISTORY
AND METHODOLOGY OF LAW AND ECONOMICS 1162, 1163 (2000).
78
BRETT M. FRISCHMANN, INFRASTRUCTURE: THE SOCIAL VALUE OF SHARED RESOURCES
3 (2012) (defining infrastructures).
79
Id. at 4.
80
TRUTH AND POWER, at 23.
81
Standard Oil Co. v. FTC, 340 U.S. 231, 249 (1951) (“Congress was dealing with
competition, which it sought to protect, and monopoly, which it sought to prevent.”).
82
Frank H. Easterbrook, Limits of Antitrust, 63 TEX. L. REV. 1, 1 (1984) (delineating
antitrust law’s under-enforcement virtues and limits).
83
MOTTA, supra note 50, at 30.
84
See note 40.
85
Thomas P. Hardman, Public Utilities: I. The Quest for a Concept, 37 W. VA. L. REV. 250
(1931) (defining public utilities).
D. Conclusions to Part I
The analysis in Part I shows that the relationship between antitrust law
86
Id. at 251.
87
Id. at 251.
88
See, e.g., Pub. Util. Comm’ v. Texas Tel. Ass’n., 163 S.W.3d 204 (Tex. App. 2005)
where a “public interest” determination was held to be necessary to receive public funding
but not to compete in an industry. There are many non-naturally monopolistic industries
that are nonetheless the subject of heavy government regulation that serves public
purposes. Similarly, there are limits to what “public interest” regulation entails in a
naturally monopolistic industry, see, e.g., NAACP v. Federal Power Comm’n, 425 U.S.
662 (1976), New York Cent. Sec. Corp., v. U.S., 287 U.S. 12 (1932).
89
FPC v. Hope Nat. Gas Co., 320 U.S. 591 (1944); William Boyd, Just Price, Public
Utility, and the Long History of Economic Regulation in America, 35 YALE J. ON REG. 721
(2018) (a genealogy of price-setting and utilities law).
90
New State Ice v. Liebmann, 282 US 262 (1932).
91
See, e.g., American Hoechest Corps. v. Dept. of Pub. Utils., 379 Mass. 408 (1980).
Mountain States Legal Foundation v. Utah Pub. Serv. Comm’n, 636 P.2d 1047 (1981).
92
MORGAN RICKS, GANESH SITARAMAN, SHELLEY WELTON & LEV MENAND, NETWORKS,
PLATFORMS, AND UTILITIES LAW AND POLICY (2022), Chapter 1 (textbook on regulation).
Some of these remedies are discussed in greater detail below.
A. Introducing Google
service that would soon become the backbone of its business model.95
Between 2000 and 2020, Google acquired more than 260 companies,96
including user-generated video company YouTube in 2006,97 adtech player
DoubleClick in 2007,98 Motorola Mobility in 2011,99 Waze100 and
DeepMind.101 In 2015, Google became a wholly owned subsidiary of its
parent company Alphabet.102 Today Google counts at least nine products with
more than a billion users each: Search, Gmail, Android, Chrome, Maps,
Drive, Photos, Play Store and YouTube.103 In 2019, Google reported a total
revenue of $160.7 billion, 83% of which was derived from ads.104 These
revenues were as high as Hungary’s GDP that same year, according to the
World Bank indicator,105 and have continued to grow in 2021.106
95
House Report, supra note 28, at 174.
96
Id. See also an updated list of publicly known acquisitions here:
https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/List_of_mergers_and_acquisitions_by_Alphabet#cite_note-1.
97
Andrew Ross Sorkin and Jeremy W Peters, Google to Acquire YouTube for $1.65
Billion, THE NEW YORK TIMES, October 9, 2006,
https://www.nytimes.com/2006/10/09/business/09cnd-deal.html.
98
Louise Story and Miguel Helft, Google Buys DoubleClick for $3.1 Billion, THE NEW
YORK TIMES, April 14, 2007,
https://www.nytimes.com/2007/04/14/technology/14DoubleClick.html.
99
Hayley Tsukayama, Google agrees to acquire Motorola Mobility, THE WASHINGTON
POST, August 15, 2011, https://www.washingtonpost.com/blogs/faster-
forward/post/google-agrees-to-acquire-motorola-
mobility/2011/08/15/gIQABmTkGJ_blog.html.
100
Ingrid Lunden, Google Bought Waze For $1.1B, Giving A Social Data Boost To Its
Mapping Business, TECHCRUNCH, June 11, 2013, https://techcrunch.com/2013/06/11/its-
official-google-buys-waze-giving-a-social-data-boost-to-its-location-and-mapping-
business/.
101
Kwame Opam, Google buying AI startup DeepMind for a reported $400 million, THE
VERGE, January 26, 2014, https://www.theverge.com/2014/1/26/5348640/google-
deepmind-acquisition-robotics-ai.
102
Letter from Larry Page, CEO, Alphabet Inc., and Sundar Pichai, CEO, Google LLC
(2015), https://abc.xyz/investor/founders-letters/2015/index.html#2015-larry-alphabet-
letter.
103
Harry McCracken, How Google Photos joined the billion-user club, FAST CO, July 24,
2019, https://www.fastcompany.com/90380618/how-google-photos-joined-the-billion-
user-club.
104
Alphabet Inc., Annual Report (Form 10-K), February 3, 2020, at 26–30,
https://www.sec.gov/Archives/edgar/data/1652044/000165204420000008/goog10-
k2019.htm.
105
See the World Bank Indicator here:
https://data.worldbank.org/indicator/NY.GDP.MKTP.CD?year_high_desc=true.
106
Google/Alphabet’s total revenues in 2021 were 257.637 billion dollars. Google’s
Annual Report explains the figures as follows: “Revenues were $257.6 billion, an increase
of 41%. The increase in revenues was primarily driven by Google Services and Google
Cloud. The adverse effect of COVID-19 on 2020 advertising revenues also contributed to
the year-over-year growth.” Alphabet Inc., Annual Report (Form 10-K), Feb. 1st, 2022, at
32, https://abc.xyz/investor/static/pdf/20220202_alphabet_10K.pdf?cache=fc81690.
107
Which includes ads, Search, Android, Chrome, Gmail, Maps and YouTube.
108
Sergey Brin & Larry Page, The anatomy of a large-scale hypertextual Web search
engine, 30 COMP. NETWORKS AND ISDN SYSTEMS (1998),
http://infolab.stanford.edu/pub/papers/google.pdf (detailing what would subsequently
become the Google "Search Rank” algorithm).
109 Id.
110
Charlie Warzel, The Open Secret of Google Search, THE ATLANTIC, June 20, 2022,
https://www.theatlantic.com/ideas/archive/2022/06/google-search-algorithm-
internet/661325/ (criticizing Google Search).
111
It is worth noting that Brin and Page themselves recognized that advertising would favor
economic interests over the interests of users. See Brin & Page, supra note 108, Appendix
A (“The goals of advertising business models do not always correspond to providing
quality search to users. … we expect that advertising funded search engines will be
inherently biased towards the advertisers and awat from the needs of consumers. … we
believe that [advertising] causes enough mixed incentives that it is crucial to have a
competitive search engine that is transparent and in the academic realm.”).
112
Second Amended Complaint at 7, In re Google Digital Advertising Antitrust Litigation,
State of Texas AG et al. v. Google LLC, No. 1:21-md-03010-PKC (S.D.N.Y. 2021).
B. Underenforcement
Until recently, U.S. regulatory attitudes vis-à-vis Google were timid and
113
CMA, Online platforms and digital advertising market study, FINAL REPORT, July 1st
2020, at 222, https://www.gov.uk/cma-cases/online-platforms-and-digital-advertising-
market-study, [hereafter CMA Report].
114
This is thanks to a series of acquisitions including the acquisition of DoubleClick in
2007, of AdMob in 2009, of Invite Media in 2010, of AdMeld in 2011, and of Adometry in
2014. For more detail see CMA Report, at 272.
115
See Dina Srinivasan, Why Google Dominates Advertising Markets, 24 STAN. TECH. L.
REV. 55 (2020), https://ssrn.com/abstract=3500919 (an analysis of Google’s
anticompetitive behavior on ad-tech markets).
116
Chand Narendra-Colucci & Ethan Zuckerman, Forgetful Advertising: Imagining a More
Responsible Digital Ad System, ESSAYS ON A HEALTHY DIGITAL PUBLIC SPHERE ,
INFORMATION SOCIETY PROJECT, September 2022,
https://law.yale.edu/isp/publications/digital-public-sphere/healthy-digital-public-
sphere/forgetful-advertising-imagining-more-responsible-digital-ad-system (arguing that
advertising is infrastructure, and introducing a model for responsible online advertising).
117
These cases ended in decisions many years later. See Google Search (Shopping), Case
AT 39740, Commission Decision C/2017/4444 (2018) OJ C 9/11 (fining Google and
Alphabet €2.42 billion); Google Search (AdSense), Case AT 40411, Commission Decision
C/2019/2173 (2020) OJ C 369/04 (fining Google and Alphabet €1.49 billion); Google
Android, Case AT.40099, Commission Decision, C/2018/4761 (2018) OJ C 402/08 (fining
Google and Alphabet €4.34 billion).
118
Case 131/12, Google Spain SL, Google Inc. v. Agencia Española de Protección de
Datos and Mario Costeja González [2014] ECR I-000, nyr.
119
With some exceptions. I discuss antitrust below. On the consumer protection front, in
2002, the FTC’s Consumer Protection Bureau sent search engines letters asking them to
distinguish clearly between organic search results and paid search results or ads to avoid
misleading consumers. (FTC, Commercial Alert Response Letter, June 27, 2002,
https://www.ftc.gov/legal-library/browse/cases-proceedings/closing-letters/commercial-
alert-response-letter.) The guidance was then updated in 2013 when it was found that paid
results had become confusing and indistinguishable from organic results. (FTC Consumer
Protection Staff Updates Agency's Guidance to Search Engine Industry on the Need to
Distinguish Between Advertisements and Search Results, June 25, 2013,
https://www.ftc.gov/news-events/news/press-releases/2013/06/ftc-consumer-protection-
staff-updates-agencys-guidance-search-engine-industry-need-distinguish.) See also Data
Brokers: A Call For Transparency and Accountability: A Report of the Federal Trade
Commission, May 2014,
https://ec.europa.eu/commission/presscorner/detail/en/IP_18_4581.
120
Amanda Shanor, The New Lochner, WIS. L. REV. 133 (2016) (arguing that First
Amendment doctrine excessively constrains the administrative state); Genevieve Lakier,
The First Amendment's Real Lochner Problem, 87 U. CHICAGO L. REV. 1243 (2020)
(arguing that First Amendment doctrine advances a narrow conception of negative liberty).
121
Search King v. Google No. Civ-02-1457-M, 2003 WL 21464568 (W.D. Okla. May 27,
2003).
122
Id. See also Eric Goldman, Search Engine Bias and the Demise of Search Engine
Utopianism, 8 YALE J.L. & TECH. 188, 189 (2006) (arguing that search engines make
editorial choices); Eugene Volokh & Donald M. Falk, Google First Amendment Protection
for Search Engine Search Results, 8 J.L. ECON. & POLY 883, 886-894 (2012) (arguing that
search engine results are speech and as such protected under the First Amendment). Though
see more recent developments: Eugene Volokh, Social Media Platforms as Common
Carriers?, Draft Presented at Freedom of Expression Scholars Conference, April 2021
1. Advertising
(arguing that social media platforms should be regulated as neutral carriers of speech); Biden
v. Knight First Am. Inst. at Columbia Univ., __ S. Ct. __ (2021) (Thomas, J., concurring,
stating, obiter, that Twitter should be considered a common carrier); Netchoice LLC. v.
Paxton, 596 U.S. ___ (2022) (Justice Alito, with whom Justice Thomas and Justice Gorsuch
join, dissenting, arguing that Facebook ought to be regulated as a neutral carrier of speech).
123
Geoffrey Manne and Joshua D.Wright, Google and the Limits of Antitrust: The Case
Against the Antitrust Case Against Google, 34 HARV. J. OF L. AND PUB. POL.’Y (2011)
(arguing that Google Search does not violate antitrust); Geoffrey A. Manne and William
Rinehart, The Market Realities that Undermined the FTC’s Antitrust Case Against Google,
HARV. J. OF L. & TECH. OCCASIONAL PAPER SERIES (2013), (describing some errors on the
part of the FTC); Michael A. Salinger & Robert J. Levinson, Economics and the FTC’s
Google Investigation, 46 REV. IND. ORGAN. 25 (2015). But see Mark R. Patterson, Google
and Search Engine Market Power, Fordham Law Legal Studies Research Paper No.
2047047 (2012), https://ssrn.com/abstract=2047047 (arguing that asymmetries of
knowledge and control over information constitutes Google’s market power); JOHN E.
KWOKA JR. AND LAWRENCE J. WHITE, THE ANTITRUST REVOLUTION: ECONOMICS,
COMPETITION, AND POLICY (2018) (discussing the political context and history of the
FTC’s Google investigation).
124
Eugene Volokh & Donald M. Falk, First Amendment Protection For Search Engine
Search Results, April 20, 2012, https://volokh.com/wp-
content/uploads/2012/05/SearchEngineFirstAmendment.pdf (paper commissioned by
Google).
125
See ZUBOFF, supra note 12; Zephyr Teachout & Lina Khan, Market Structure And
Political Law: A Taxonomy Of Power, 9 DUKE J. OF CON. L. & PUB. POL.’Y 37 (2014)
(discussing industry lobbying and other forms of government capture by large firms).
126
Leah Nylen, Meta Seeks Recusal of FTC Chair Khan in Within Deal Challenge,
BLOOMBERG, Sept 23, 2022, https://www.bloomberglaw.com/bloomberglawnews/privacy-
and-data-security/XQFOEVO000000?bna_news_filter=privacy-and-data-security#jcite
(discussing Meta’s attempts to recuse Chair Khan).
127
Statement of the Federal Trade Commission Concerning Google/DoubleClick, Case n.
0710170, December 20, 2007, at 2.
128
Id. at 10.
129 Concurring Statement of Commissioner Jon Leibowitz in Google/DoubleClick, FTC
FTC could take privacy and consumer choice considerations into account, the
majority concluded that data and privacy harms did not warrant intervention
or investigation from a competition law perspective. Privacy harms were of
no interest to regulators concerned with “unfair methods of competition”
only.
The FTC’s assumptions about the separateness of competition and the
free and competitive nature of advertising markets, the large diversity of
choices these markets afford and the need to let them operate autonomously
are illustrative of the early 2010s. Google’s speculations about its future post-
merger conduct, for example, were given weight in spite of their subsequently
demonstrated flaws.
2. Search
In the early 2010s, the FTC and various state AGs started an antitrust
investigation alleging Google self-preferencing on search results. The FTC
dropped the case in 2013 and did not start formal proceedings, in spite of 19
months spent reviewing over nine million pages of documents from Google
and others.132 The original allegation was that “Google unfairly preferences
its own content on the Google search results page and selectively demotes its
competitors’ content from those results.”133 To have a claim under section 2
of the Sherman Act, the FTC had to show an intent to acquire or maintain
monopoly power through exclusionary conduct.134 The question was thus
framed as “whether Google changed its search results primarily to exclude
actual or potential competitors and inhibit the competitive process, or on the
other hand, to improve the quality of its search product and the overall user
experience.”135 The FTC found that although Google effectively harmed and
demoted potential competitors, “in the main, [it] adopted the design changes
… to improve the quality of its search results, and … any negative impact on
132
Id. See also Leah Nylen, How Washington fumbled the future, POLITICO, March 16,
2021, https://www.politico.com/news/2021/03/16/google-files-ftc-antitrust-investigation-
475573#:~:text=The%20FTC%20spent%2019%20months,%2C%20Tripadvisor%2C%20F
acebook%20and%20Amazon.
133
Statement of the FTC Regarding Google’s Search Practices - In the Matter of Google
Inc.; January 3, 2013, at 1, https://www.ftc.gov/legal-library/browse/cases-
proceedings/public-statements/statement-federal-trade-commission-regarding-googles-
search-practices-matter-google-inc.
134
To state a monopolization claim under § 2 of the Sherman Act, a plaintiff must allege
that (1) the defendant possessed monopoly power in the relevant market; (2) the defendant
willfully acquired or maintained that power through exclusionary conduct; and (3) the
defendant's conduct caused antitrust injury. MetroNet Servs. Corp. v. Qwest Corp., 383
F.3d 1124, 1130 (9th Cir. 2004).
135
FTC, supra note 133, at 2.
3. Under-enforcement
136
Id.
137
Manne & Rinehart, Market Realities, supra note 123, at 9.
138
Patterson, supra note 123; Marshall Steinbaum, Establishing Market and Monopoly
Power in Tech Platform Antitrust Cases, THE ANTITRUST BULLETIN 1, 9 (2022) (describing
market power in platform markets and critiquing the analysis in Ohio v. American Express,
585 U.S. ___ (2018)); Daniel Francis, Making Sense of Monopolization: Antitrust and the
Digital Economy 84 ANTITRUST L.J. (2022) (theorizing monopolization in a digital
context); John M. Newman, Antitrust in Digital Markets, 72(5) VAND. L. REV. 1497 (2019)
(arguing that dominant monopolization paradigms in antitrust law do not fit digital
markets).
139
But see John M. Newman, The Myth of Free, 86 GEO. WASH. L. REV. 513 (2018)
(rebutting that assumption).
140
United States v. Grinnell Corp., 384 U.S. 563, 570-71 (1966) (stating that a
monopolization offence requires improper conduct-as opposed to superior skill, foresight,
or industry).
141
THOMAS RAMGE AND VIKTOR MAYER-SCHÖNBERGER, REINVENTING CAPITALISM IN
THE AGE OF BIG DATA (2018) (celebrating the potential of data-driven markets). Also see
VILI LEHDONVIRTA, CLOUD EMPIRES: HOW DIGITAL PLATFORMS ARE OVERTAKING THE
STATE AND HOW WE CAN REGAIN CONTROL (2022) (discussing the early Internet as a
locus of promise and free interaction).
142
This confirms the thesis of sociologist Neil Fligstein, Markets as Politics: A Political-
Cultural Approach to Market Institutions, 61 AM. SOCI. REV. 656, 662, 664 (1996) (“Law
and accepted practices often reflext the interests of the most organized forces in society” at
662. “At the beginning of a new market, the largest firms are the most likely to be able to
create a conception of control and a political coalition to control competition” at 664).
C. A Turning Point
143
United States v. Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d 34 (D.C. Cir. 2001).
144
United States v. Microsoft Corp., 97 F. Supp. 2d 59, 64-65 (D.D.C. 2000) (the District
Court for the District of Columbia issued an order requiring Microsoft to submit a proposed
plan of divestiture, with the company to be split into an operating systems business and an
applications business).
145
Microsoft, supra note 143. Department of Justice, Reach Effective Settlement on Antitrust
Lawsuit, PRESS RELEASE, November 2nd, 2001,
https://www.justice.gov/archive/atr/public/press_releases/2001/9463.htm; U.S. v. Microsoft
Corporation Information on the Settlement, November 6th, 2001,
https://www.justice.gov/atr/usdoj-antitrust-division-us-v-microsoft-corporation-
information-settlement.
146
Microsoft, supra note 143, at 91 (citing N. Pac. Ry. Co., 356 U.S. at 5).
1. Search
Soon after the 2020 Report came out, the Department of Justice (DOJ)
accused Google of maintaining an anticompetitive monopoly in search and
search advertising through exclusionary agreements with actors controlling
devices, web browsers, and other search access points.149 In December of the
same year, several state attorneys general, including Colorado, started a
similar case against Google for alleged anticompetitive behavior on search
and search advertising markets.150 In both cases, antitrust plaintiffs go beyond
the 2013 focus on content rankings, and instead investigate a series of
exclusionary distribution agreements with Apple, Mozilla and others that
maintain Google’s dominance by ensuring that it remains the default on web
browsers, mobile and other devices, often in exchange of a share of
advertising profits. The complaints allege that, through these agreements,
Google achieved an overall 60% coverage of all general search queries, and
that nearly half the remaining queries (about 20% more) are funneled through
Google owned-and-operated properties such as Chrome.151 The complaint
147
House Report, supra note 28.
148
Id. at 20.
149
United States v. Google LLC, No. DC/1:20-cv-03010 (D.D.C. 2020); Department of
Justice, Justice Department Sues Monopolist Google For Violating Antitrust Laws, PRESS
RELEASE, October 20th, 2020, https://www.justice.gov/opa/pr/justice-department-sues-
monopolist-google-violating-antitrust-laws. Also see Cecilia Kang, David McCabe &
Daisuke Wakabayashi, U.S. Accuses Google of Illegally Protecting Monopoly, THE NEW
YORK TIMES, October 20, 2020, https://www.nytimes.com/2020/10/20/technology/google-
antitrust.html.
150
State of Colorado et al v. Google LLC, No. 1:2020cv03715 (D.D.C. 2020).
151
See, e.g., United States v. Google LLC, No. DC/1:20-cv-03010 (US District Court for
the District of Columbia, filed October 20, 2020), Amended Complaint, January 15, 2021,
para 5, at 4, https://www.justice.gov/atr/case-document/file/1428271/download.
also highlights that Google and Apple concluded a deal whereby Apple
agreed to preset Google as its default general search engine on Safari and
across Apple devices in exchange for a large percentage of Google’s
advertising revenues.152
Although the outcome of this case is uncertain, court documents already
reveal where antitrust enforcement in this area might be heading. First, the
focus of regulators between 2013 and now has moved from a concern with
discrimination on the content layer, at the level of search rankings, to an
infrastructural concern, i.e. worry about concentrated control over
infrastructural bottlenecks and awareness that search competition cannot be
achieved without contestability over search infrastructure. It must, in other
words, become possible for new entrants to build a competing ecosystem or
tap into the dominant ecosystem in a fair and transparent way. This goes
hand-in-hand with an emerging view that antitrust cannot merely intervene
ex post to correct self-preferencing behavior and deter future behavior. It
must help reconfigure the structure of search markets in a dynamic before-
the-fact way. Competitive processes, in other words, are not simply
something to constrain from the outside; they are processes constructed
through durable remedies over time.
Second, the focus in the 2013 case was not on antitrust law’s role in
enabling search diversity and including new entrants. The FTC and the States
failed to imagine effective remedies to such bias. Even if the case had been
successful, interventions targeting self-preferencing algorithms, alone, would
unlikely have displaced Google’s dominant position on search.153 The DOJ’s
current linking of search to advertising conduct instead denotes a better grasp
of the multi-sidedness of Google’s business model. In this sense, it seems that
antitrust is evolving toward a greater sensitivity for infrastructure and concern
for distrupting vertical integration, away from the prior tolerance of vertical
agreements and efficient monopolies – often imputed to Chicago School
antitrust.154
2. Advertising
152
Id. para 86, at 28.
153
Google Search (Shopping) and Google Search (AdSense), supra note 117.
154
Richard A. Posner, Natural Monopoly and Its Regulation, 21 STAN. L. REV. 549, 564
(1969) (“the effort of a businessman to monopolize a market by producing at a cost so low
as to drive out his competitors and deter new entry or, the monopoly achieved, to improve
his return by lowering his costs still further is not at all reprehensible.”).
155
Complaint, Texas et al. v. Google LLC, Case No. 4:20cv957 (E.D. Tex. Dec. 16, 2020);
Complaint, United States et al. v Google LLC, Case 1:23-cv-00108 (E.D. Virg. Jan. 24,
2023). (Note to editors: this paragraph will need to be amended in light of the new DOJ
complaint.)
156
Second Amended Complaint at 4, Texas et al. v. Google LLC, Case No. 4:20-CV-957-
SDJ (E.D. Tex. Aug. 4, 2021). Taylor Hatmaker, Google asks a judge to dismiss Texas
antitrust lawsuit about its ad business, TECHCRUNCH, January 21st, 2022,
https://social.techcrunch.com/2022/01/21/google-asks-a-judge-to-dismiss-texas-antitrust-
lawsuit-about-its-ad-business/.
157
Id. at para 117.
3. Is Antitrust Changing?
158
Reuben Binns & Elettra Bietti, Dissolving Privacy One Merger at a Time: Competition,
Data and Third Party Tracking, 36 COMPUTER LAW & SECURITY REVIEW (2020) (showing
that agencies in the US and EU have not paid sufficient attention to data-sensitive mergers).
159
See Rory Van Loo, The Missing Regulatory State: Monitoring Businesses in an Age of
Surveillance, 72 VAND. L. REV. 1563 (2019) (arguing that online platforms need the kind
of regulatory monitoring seen in other industries); Rory Van Loo, Digital Market
Perfection, 117 MICH. L. REV. 815, 824 (2019) (suggesting friction for digital markets
analogous to that which exists in stock markets); Caleb Griffin, Systemically Important
Platforms, 107 CORN. L. REV. 445 (2022), (arguing for a broad array of oversight
mechanisms that would complement existing antitrust remedies including greater
regulatory access to middleware).
160
Note that the American Innovation and Choice Online Act (AICOA) discussed in this
Article failed to be passed in Congress.
161
These include the cases mentioned supra at note 5.
162
Gigi Sohn, Another Red Herring, PUBLIC KNOWLEDGE (June 5, 2006), cited in Frank
Pasquale, Internet Nondiscrimination Principles: Commercial Ethics for Carriers and
Search Engines, 2008 UNIV. OF CHI. LEG. FORUM (2008), at fn 47.
163
Oren Bracha & Frank Pasquale, Federal Search Commission – Access, Fairness and
Accountability in the Law of Search, 93 CORNELL L. REV. 1149 (2008) (suggesting an
agency for regulating search engines); Frank Pasquale, Internet Nondiscrimination
Principles: Commercial Ethics for Carriers and Search Engines, 2008 UNIV. OF CHI. L.
FORUM 263 (2008) (suggesting common carrier principles for holding search engines to
account). See also FRANK PASQUALE, THE BLACK BOX SOCIETY: THE SECRET
ALGORITHMS THAT CONTROL MONEY AND INFORMATION 98–100 (2015) (discussing
Google and the analogy to Robert Hale’s writing on utilities).
164
Frank Pasquale, Rankings, Reductionism, and Responsibility, 54 CLEV. ST. L. REV. 115,
135 (2006) (showing that search rankings can be biased).
165
Id.
179
Id.
180
Rogerson & Shelanski, supra note 3, at 1924.
181
Id.
182
Id. at 1925.
183
Pierre Larouche, Foreword: Legislation on digital platform giants: The future of
competition law? 1 CONCURRENCES 2 (2022) (arguing that the DMA is a competition law
framework). Also see Schweitzer, infra note 186 (also arguing that the DMA is a pro-
competitive regulatory framework).
184
Id.
185
AICOA.
F. Conclusions to Part II
186
DMA. For commentary, see, e.g., Heike Schweitzer, The Art to Make Gatekeeper
Positions Contestable and the Challenge to Know What is Fair: A Discussion of the Digital
Markets Act Proposal, 3 ZEUP (2021) (arguing that the DMA should be interpreted as a
competition policy measure).
187
Digital Services Act Package: https://ec.europa.eu/digital-single-market/en/digital-
services-act-package; Natasha Lomas, EU’s new rules for Big Tech will come into force in
Spring 2023, says Vestager, TECHCRUNCH, May 5, 2022,
https://techcrunch.com/2022/05/05/digital-markets-act-enforcement-margrethe-vestager/.
188
See DMA, Art. 3.
189
DMA, Art. 1.
190
Up to 10% of global turnover.
191
DMA, Art. 6.
192
DMA, Recital 10 (draft dated May 11, 2022) (“since this Regulation aims to
complement the enforcement of competition law, it should apply without prejudice to
Articles 101 and 102 TFEU, to the corresponding national competition rules and to other
national competition rules regarding unilateral conduct.”)
https://www.consilium.europa.eu/media/56086/st08722-xx22.pdf.
antitrust, utilities and other areas of law and regulation. Part II described a
shift in digital markets from a regulatory default which consisted in avoiding
interferences with digital platforms’ activities to a current phase of light-
handed regulation which addresses big tech platforms’ infrastructural
dominance while restoring competition through behavioral and structural
remedies. The shift from a deregulatory conception of digital markets as
naturally competitive and innovative to an institutionalist conception of
digital markets as spaces that require legal structuring suggests the need to
revisit the way scholars theorize antitrust’s relation to utilities and other
regulatory regimes in digital platform markets, descriptively and
normatively.
193
Note that the history of antitrust law is replete with examples of overlaps between
sectoral and utility-like legislation and antitrust. See, e.g., AT&T, infra note 201; Microsoft,
supra note 143; Trinko, supra note 60.
The relationship between antitrust and regulation has a long history. Until
the 1970s and 1980s, US scholars saw the two as complementary and
emphasized antitrust’s decentralizing effects, and utilities’ centralizing
effects.195 Today, in spite of 50 years of neoclassicist antitrust law which
tolerated ‘efficient’ market concentration, the emphasis on decentralization
and market structure remains pervasive among laypeople, but also lawyers
and scholars.196 Frank Pasquale describes the crossroads of antitrust and
regulatory visions of the internet as a tension between the decentralizing
“Jeffersonian” antitrust path and the centralizing “Hamiltonian”
regulatory/utilities path:197
Populist localizers want a new era of antitrust enforcement to break up giant firms.
These Jeffersonian critics of big tech firms, megabanks, and health care behemoths
are decentralizers. They believe that power is and ought to be distributed in a just
society. They promote strong local authorities to counterbalance the centripetal
accumulation of wealth and power in multinational firms.
Others have promoted gigantism as inevitable or desirable, and argue that we simply
need better rules to cabin abuses of corporate power. Today’s Hamiltonians argue
that massive stores of data are critical to the future of artificial intelligence—and
thus to the productive dynamism of the economy. They focus on improving the
194
The term “pragmatic” refers to John Dewey’s approach to regulation which consists in a
contextual definition and tailoring of means and ends. See DEWEY, supra note 69.
195
See ROBERT BORK, THE ANTITRUST PARADOX (1978) (arguing in 1978 that antitrust’s
“populist” goals of structural decentralization and protecting small firms should be
revisited).
196
Also see PHILLIP E. AREEDA AND HERBERT HOVENKAMP, AN ANALYSIS OF ANTITRUST
PRINCIPLES AND THEIR APPLICATION (2021), Chapter 1 (“When laypersons, including some
lawyers, speak of “competition” they think of a market containing numerous firms…
Protecting “competition” may then mean preserving a market structure that permits small
firms to enter freely and profit, even if this entails forcing larger firms not to compete too
strenuously lest the smaller ones be unable to survive.”).
197
Pasquale, supra note 3.
Figure 1
The remedies traditionally associated with antitrust law and public utility
regulation can be represented along ARD’s two axes. The x axis is horizontal
and represents a spectrum of approaches to law that go from decentralizing
to centralizing. From legal interventions that directly aim to protect and
correct decentralized productive processes and individual transactions, or that
have this effect, to modes of intervention that intentionally preserve more
centralized infrastructures, such as utility regulation, or that have this effect
through court enforcement, such as copyright law. The x axis thus goes from
policy action that promotes uncoordinated invisible hand transactions and
preferences (e.g. some antitrust remedies) to action that preserves more
concentrated structures. These can include more structured coordination of
productive decisions, infusing pre-determined purposes directly into
198
Id.
199
OECD, supra note 3, at 4 (“Competition law … is fundamentally a case-by-case
instrument that focuses on one individual situation with a specific set of facts where one
specific undertaking—or a few undertakings in the case of an anti-competitive
agreement—is found to be in violation of competition rules. … Although the adoption of a
decision should have a precedent and deterrent effect on other undertakings not involved in
the specific case and discipline their future behaviour, this is far from certain and is
unlikely to be as effective as ex ante rules that can tackle recurrent and systemic problems
affecting a sector.”).
Figure 2
200
Microsoft, supra note 143. AT&T, infra note 201. On settlements more generally see
Douglas H. Ginsburg & Joshua D. Wright, Antitrust Settlements: The Culture of Consent,
in WILLIAM E. KOVACIC: AN ANTITRUST TRIBUTE 177 (2013) (articulating the virtues of
antitrust settlements); Joshua D. Wright & Douglas H. Ginsburg, The Economic Analysis of
Antitrust Consents, EURO. J.L. & ECON. (2018) (a tentative case against settlements);
Jonathan M. Jacobson, Issues in Antitrust Consent Decrees, Presented to the Department of
Justice Antitrust Division, April 26, 2018 (practicalities related to antitrust settlements).
201
See United States v. AT&T Co., 552 F. Supp. 131, 201, 224 (D.D.C. 1982).
202
See, e.g., Google Search (Shopping), supra note 117 (imposing a fine on Google of
EUR 2.42 billion for preferential treatment in comparison shopping). Google LLC,
Figure 3
Lawsuits against Google and other big tech companies challenge power
over vertically integrated platform models such as the combination of
Android, Chrome and YouTube, and networks of agreements between
providers of upper-layer functionality (e.g. Google Search) and of lower-
layer operating systems (e.g. Apple’s iOS). These cases seek to impose
obligations and structural remedies on companies to enable long-term
competition. At the regulatory level, sectoral Bills such as AICOA or the
208
See, e.g., the Hepburn Rate Act of 1906. Section 1(4) imposed a common carrier
obligation on pipelines to “provide . . . transportation upon reasonable request therefor” and
section 1(5) required common carriers to publish their rates, which must “be just and
reasonable; and every unjust and unreasonable charge for such service or any part thereof is
prohibited and declared to be unlawful.”
209
See the Communications Act of 1934, as amended by the Telecommunications Act of
1996, (regulating telcos but not information-service providers as common carriers. Also
see Nat’l Cable & Telecomm. Assn. v. Brand X Internet Servs., 545 U.S. 967 (2005).
210
Communications Act of 1934, Pub. L. No. 73-416, para 1, 48 Stat. 1064, 1064 (the
industry should be regulated “so as to make available, so far as possible, to all the people of
the United States a rapid, efficient, Nation-wide, and world-wide wire and radio
communication service with adequate facilities at reasonable charges”).
Open App Markets Act advanced a vision of digital platform markets as more
competitive and contestable by default. They imposed statutory obligations
and liability on large bottlenecks and incumbents.
In the past, too, antitrust remedies have had long-lasting structural effects.
The Microsoft settlement is one example.211 The corpus of essential facilities
and duty-to-deal exceptions in antitrust is also forward-looking: it imposes
quasi-regulatory duties on certain firms.212 It has been argued that there are
reasons to revive the essential facilities doctrine in technology markets.213
Duties to license key telecommunications patents on “Fair Reasonable and
Non-Discriminatory” terms are another example of pre-emptive
procompetitive measure. These open the market to competitors and promote
the development of innovative products based on these patents.214 Overall,
ARD highlights that regulatory attitudes in digital markets are far from
“laissez-faire.” The core contestation is around the form that ex ante
procompetitive measures must take. This finding is significant for reasons I
now explain.
left quadrant of ARD illustrates a growing appetite for hybrid approaches that
combine faith in competition and consumer choice with recognition of the
public value of infrastructure. It carries more than one lesson.
First, perhaps most obviously, the convergence toward ex ante
decentralizing legal intervention in digital markets shows that antitrust and
utility regulation are not the polar opposites they are sometimes claimed to
be in popular or policy discourse. Instead, they are best understood as points
on a common spectrum or map. Both antitrust and regulatory measures can
centralize and decentralize, both can act in structuring or reactive ways, and
they can be combined in creative ways.
Second, the convergence toward ex ante decentralization crystallizes an
existing normative consensus in policy circles around promoting competition
and consumer choice in digital markets. This broad consensus is significant
in two ways. On the one hand, it crystallizes a recognition that markets, and
in particular competitive markets, are made and not found. Perfect
competition lives in textbooks. In real digital markets, competition requires
more than minimal ex post correction; it requires durable pre-emptive
structuring.215 This seems particularly salient in platform ecosystems where
markets are formed through conscious infrastructural choices. Without
holding those who control platform ecosystems in check, and ensuring
contestability over digital bottlenecks, digital markets cannot be
“competitive.” Competition requires creating options and standards,
imposing interoperability and non-discrimination obligations, it requires
enabling new entrants to compete with incumbents, and enabling the exercise
of individual choice and switching.
On the other hand, the overlap is also reflective of – one might say
“neoliberal” – faith in individual preferences in markets. Indeed, the vision
motivating reforms such as AICOA, as well as the vision underlying some
antitrust lawsuits, is one of perfect competition and contestability in digital
markets: a scenario where a multiplicity of platform providers can co-exist
and offer services to users and customers who in turn can switch iteratively
between platforms. The hope is that a mix of antitrust lawsuits and regulatory
reforms might create a radically more decentralized platform economy
governed by individual preferences and entrepreneurial freedoms, instead of
the whims of platform giants.
Structuring markets this way reflects the same faith in autonomous self-
correction that pervades the literature discussed in Part I. It reflects a
normative consensus between progressives and conservatives that
autonomous competitive markets must be shielded from social and political
pressures including questions of privacy or equality in an economy. This
215
But see Easterbrook, supra note 82, (arguing in favor of underenforcement and the ex-
post nature of antitrust).
3. Stretching ARD
216
Note that a similar point is made by Filippo Lancieri & Caio M.S. Pereira Neto,
Designing Remedies for Digital Markets: The Interplay Between Antitrust and Regulation,
J. OF COMP. L. & ECON. 1 (2021) (arguing for synergies between antitrust and regulatory
methods).
217
Trinko, at 407.
218
ROBERT BORK, THE ANTITRUST PARADOX (1978) and see Posner, supra note 154, at 564
(“the effort of a businessman to monopolize a market by producing at a cost so low as to
drive out his competitors and deter new entry or, the monopoly achieved, to improve his
return by lowering his costs still further is not at all reprehensible.”). For a critical analysis
of this view see Rudolph J. Peritz, A Counter-History of Antitrust Law, 1990 DUKE L. J.
263 (1990) (an alternative to Chicago’s history of antitrust) and see Sanjukta Paul, Antitrust
224
California Consumer Privacy Act, section 1(d), Cal. Civ. Code. § 1798.100. (d)
(hereafter CCPA). The California Privacy Rights Act of 2020, coming into force in January
2023, has added protections to the CCPA.
225 Elettra Bietti, Explainer: Competition, Data and Interoperability in Digital Markets,
Filippo Lancieri and Caio Mario Pereira Neto have provided a helpful
error-cost framework which guides the adoption of remedies across different
areas of economic regulation including antitrust and utility-like regulation.231
They argue that “[r]emedy design […reflects] a continuum distribution of
possibilities that can and should be modulated in intensity: authorities must
choose one or a couple of solutions from a range of available
interventions.”232 They see regulation as a “learning process that enables the
reduction of over- and under-enforcement errors in remedy design and
230
The term “pragmatic” refers to John Dewey’s approach to regulation which consists in a
contextual definition and tailoring of means and ends. See DEWEY, supra note 69.
231
Lancieri & Neto, supra note 216.
232
Id. at 30.
233 Id.
234
Rogerson and Shelanski, supra note 3.
235
Id. at 1917-21.
236
Id. at 1923-24.
237
Id. at 1924.
239
15 U.S.C. § 45.
240
Bureau of Competition, https://www.ftc.gov/about-ftc/bureaus-offices/bureau-
competition.
241
Federal Trade Commission Act, Pub. L. No. 63-203, 38 Stat. 717, 719 (1914)
(empowering the FTC to prevent “unfair methods of competition” through regulation); and
see J. Howard Beales, The FTC's Use of Unfairness Authority: Its Rise, Fall, and
Resurrection, Speech at the Marketing and Public Policy Conference, Washington, D.C.,
May 30, 2003, https://www.ftc.gov/news-events/news/speeches/ftcs-use-unfairness-
authority-its-rise-fall-resurrection (on the FTC’s unfairness authority).
242
Bureau of Consumer Protection, https://www.ftc.gov/about-ftc/bureaus-offices/bureau-
consumer-protection.
243
See Luke Herrine, The Folklore of Unfairness, 96 N.Y.U. L. REV. 431, 454 (2021)
(describing the origins of “unfair methods of competition” as part of a longer history of
“unfair competition”).
244
Id.
construction that extends beyond the current bounds of the Sherman and
Clayton Acts and justifies reforming the existing antitrust laws.245 As argued
by Sandeep Vaheesan, in their antitrust caselaw “courts do not
indiscriminately protect competition, but rather restrict certain forms of
competition they deem unfair” meaning that they rely on a moral
understanding of unfairness as a guiding principle for enforcement.246
Reliance on unfairness as a moral principle suggests that antitrust and
consumer protection law are not so separate in their purposes. In Europe,
scholars have also argued that the concept of “fairness” is a point of
normative connection between disjointed branches of legal enforcement in
markets including competition and consumer protection law.247
Other normative synergies between consumer law and antitrust can be
articulated through the notion of consumer choice. Together, antitrust and
consumer law ensure that consumers have options and that they have the
ability to make active choices among them without being impaired in their
choosing by unfair or deceptive commercial practices.248 Competition and
antitrust law have as their mission “to protect the array of options in the
marketplace.”249 As noted by Robert Lande, “[t]he antitrust laws are intended
to ensure that the marketplace remains competitive so that worthwhile
options are produced, and this range of options is not to be significantly
impaired or distorted by anticompetitive practices.”250 Antitrust cases and
other procompetitive regulatory frameworks in the digital economy regularly
245
Sandeep Vaheesan, The Morality of Monopolization Law, 63 WILLIAM & MARY L. REV.
ONLINE 119 (2022) (layering a moral lens on competition law).
246
Sandeep Vaheesan, Antitrust Law’s Unwritten Rules of Unfair Competition,
PROMARKET, November 17, 2021, https://www.promarket.org/2021/11/17/antitrust-
enforcement-unfair-competition-ftc/ (discussing unfair competition as a normative guide
for antitrust).
247
Inge Graef, Damian Clifford & Peggy Valcke, Fairness and enforcement: bridging
competition, data protection, and consumer law, 8 INT. DATA PRIV.’Y L. 200 (2018)
(fairness as a common root of three legal areas); Francisco Costa-Cabral and Orla Lynskey,
Family Ties: The Intersection between Data Protection and Competition in EU Law, 54
COMM. MARKET L. REV. 11, 18 (2017) (synergies between antitrust and data protection
law).
248
Neil W. Averitt & Robert H. Lande, Using the “Consumer Choice” Approach to
Antitrust Law, 74 ANTITRUST L.J. 175, 182 (2007); Neil W. Averitt & Robert H. Lande,
Consumer Sovereignty: A Unified Theory of Antitrust and Consumer Protection Law, 65
ANTITRUST L.J. 713 (1997); Neil W. Averitt & Robert H. Lande, Consumer Choice: The
Practical Reason for Both Antitrust and Consumer Protection Law, 10 LOY. CONSUMER L.
REV. 44 (1998) (grounding antitrust and consumer protection law in consumer choice).
249
Neil W. Averitt & Robert H. Lande, Using the “Consumer Choice” Approach to
Antitrust Law, 74 ANTITRUST L.J. 175, 182 (2007) (defending a conception of antitrust
grounded in consumer choice).
250
Robert H. Lande, Consumer Choice as the Ultimate Goal of Antitrust, 62 U. PITT. L.
REV. 503, 503 (2001) (defending a conception of antitrust grounded in consumer choice).
251
First Complaint, FTC v. Facebook Inc., No. 1:2020cv03590 (D.D.C. 2020) (defining
harms to consumers in social media markets in terms of loss of consumer choice, and
harms to advertisers in terms of loss of advertising options).
252
Howard Shelanski discusses the distinction between two conceptions of the public
interest along these same lines in Howard A. Shelanski, Antitrust Law and Mass Media
Regulation: Can Merger Standards Protect the Public Interest? 94 CAL. L. REV. 371, 399
(2006) (arguing that “antitrust has no mechanism by which to evaluate or prioritize variety
and quality to suit particular social goals over the diversity and quality levels that
consumers demand”).
253
As regards rulemaking, see Rohit Chopra & Lina M. Khan, The Case for “Unfair
Methods of Competition” Rulemaking, 87 UNIV. CHI. L. REV. 357 (2020) (the case for the
FTC’s rulemaking authority)
to enforce consumer standards in digital markets in ways that could erode the
differences between antitrust and consumer protection while focusing
enforcement on the question of “fairness” in markets.
CONCLUSION