VAT in Cross Lectures
VAT in Cross Lectures
Agenda
1. Course overview
2. Direct taxation vs indirect taxation: this is the only indirect tax course in our program
6. Structure of a consumption tax: the building blocks of a consumption tax for when you
would design such a tax from a global perspective, many of the difficulties would be the
same all over the world, in a different environment but from a tax design perspective there
are similar problems everywhere
Course overview
We will take the EU VAT system as an example, specifically and look at it from a global view. As of
the second week we will start looking at the EU VAT system – the building blocks from an EU VAT
perspective. Which country is entitled to tax revenue? We will get to the case studies that will
prepare us for after the graduation. We will also look at the digital economy in the VAT. The exam
consists of 2 parts, 1 part is the open questions, the more theoretical questions (40%). And part 2 is
about case studies (60%), the case studies will be EU VAT based case studies. With the case studies
we will look at what kind of indirect tax issues we see. The first case will focus on the basic stuff and
further on the course we will get into other stuff. The exam will be written, the resit is oral.
There is no syllabus available. Specifically for the selected topics they will select the articles, give you
directions to prepare for that lecture, in terms of the EU VAT lectures the structure of the book
follows the structure of the lectures so read those topics from the lectures in the book. You should
bring a copy of the EU VAT Directive. When you’re asked to do case studies on EU VAT law you will
be allowed to use the Directive, but it is not an open book exam. The exam will take place maybe
fully online or in a hybrid way depending on the situation.
• Direct taxes (corporation tax, payroll tax, private income tax etc)
– Tax base erosion: cutting on the base of the taxable amount, corporations have
designed tax friendly structures, businesses establish in tax havens for tax reasons,
topic on which a business tries to lower the tax base on which amount of profit they
have to pay tax, CIT has the flow that when you move stuff around you get different
results, you can’t play with consumer tax in a similar way, consumption takes place
at a consumption, you see a tendency towards more indirect taxes from a global
perspective
No gov. relies on a single tax, different taxes are used to collect gov. revenues, why? What happens
with income of private individuals when society is in an economic downturn? They cannot make
money, so there is no income, they cannot find a job or get fired or get paid less, their income
decreases, and the gov. might help them financially, so the tax revenues would decrease. In terms of
an aging society the society gets older and older. When people retire also less kids gets born and less
income is generated, so various factors may impact the tax. In the old days they used to have
window taxes, having a window was a sign of wealth. When gov. introduced window taxes, people
started putting bricks and closing windows to avoid paying taxes. Why would you have a tax mix as a
gov.? Because you want to have a stable income for the government. One would never ideally invest
in only one thing, you would diversify, and it is the same kind of comparison with taxes as well. What
other reasons could you have as a gov. to levy taxes apart from collecting money. Why do we levy
environmental taxes? Trying to influence certain behavior by punishing or by subsidizing, like excise
duty on cigarettes or alcohol. If you want to have a tax mix you need to have different sources to tax,
like windows, pollution, and you need to decide who you want to tax. Consumers pay the tax
eventually, but governments receive the money from defined tax subjects in law. People who are
liable to pay the government are not the same people who actually bear the burden of the tax
(consumers), because they eventually pay from their pockets. People do not really feel the pain of
paying taxes when consuming as when they have to bear it from their income and the gov. has
somebody to go after when there is a situation of fraud, tax subject are easier to find when they are
defined as businesses than if individuals had to give the tax to the gov. With payroll tax for example
which is a direct tax it is easier to go after to employers than to go after the employees, this is very
important to think about when designing a tax.
In a direct tax a person that feels the pain of the tax is the same person who is liable towards the
government for paying the tax. With indirect tax the consumer will bear the tax but the company is
liable towards the government. This is the summary but in real life it’s complicated.
Indirect taxes are everywhere, the only country that is not working with VAT is the US, working with
a special sales tax.
• Shift from direct tax to indirect tax: it is a trend that is happening across the globe, we have
just identified the difficulties and challenges, countries act upon those challenges, so there’s
a shift to indirect taxes, more effort to introducing indirect taxes in countries that did not
have these taxes, indirect tax rates increase slightly over the years, when you introduce a
new tax you have to go slowly, the EU average is now 21/22. It will be more than 5 % in
countries that introduced it, they will increase it later on but slowly, you do not need to feel
the pain of paying the tax. When you need to file a return of PIT and if you have to pay
10.000 euros of taxes – that is more difficult!
• Governance, risk and control: businesses and tax authorities spend more time on managing
and require businesses to manage their tax, how they deal with taxes and how they ensure
that tax is sufficiently paid and how you use technology that way with for example digital
reporting
Taxing consumption
Consumption tax (is intended to tax consumption) is a big part of indirect tax, but they’re not
synonyms. What would you do if you would want to try to levy consumption taxes? That is the main
question right now. If we would have a bottle of wine and we buy the bottle and then someone
drinks the wine, wine bottles are made from glass. If you look at it from a consumption perspective,
if you drop the bottle and it breaks you would not be able to consume anymore, how do you deal
with this issue in the consumption tax? A government needs to define consumption.
You need to move from the conceptual idea of consumption to a model in which you can tax
something you can manage and control efficiently. Private consumption is a very broad concept. You
need to look at expenditures by private persons, because you cannot consume the broken bottle of
wine but you have purchased. Do we want to tax all expenditures of private individuals? No, we
would want to tax the taxable transactions. If you buy something from a friend or a neighbor, C2C
transactions (consumer to consumer) are expenditures but are not taxable transactions, also for
efficiency reasons governments do not want to bother to tax those expenditures. In terms of
consumption if your neighbor has knitted a sweater and you wear it, then this is consumption, but
you do not want to tax this as a gov. Definition of C2C depends on the definition of B, what a
business defines as, and then that excludes the C2C, so who is seen as a business? The internet
makes C2C very easy nowadays.
General vs specific
– Excises (e.g. alcoholic beverages, tobacco, gasoline) -> on very specific products
When designing consumption tax systems you have to keep in mind a way a country is structured
governmentally. Single state vs multiple states. Single level vs multiple levels of gov. You need to
make choices. EU VAT is harmonized for the most part. From a gov. perspective there are much
more elements that play a role than you might consider at first. Depending on whether you are a
federal state of a single state you may have attributed taxing powers to different levels, to states
(that form a national state together) or to the federal state.
Consumption
If Google buys a laptop, is that a transaction that should be taxable with consumption tax? Why
should Google pay consumption tax when it’s a business, consumption tax was created for private
consumption tax. At least we would expect a mechanism which relieves businesses from the
consumption tax. This is a B2B transaction, it does not make sense to tax, but basically in all
consumption we tax but we also have a deduction to ensure that Google does not pay consumption
tax (bear the burden of that tax) at the end. It pays tax to the shop where it buys the laptop from,
pays 100 consumption tax and then gets it back from gov. (100), so balance = 0. Why would
countries have chosen for this stupid model then and why do we not simply say that we do not
charge consumption tax in a B2B transaction? This is an example of creating efficiency, stability in a
tax. In orde to keep the tax efficient in most countries the shops will charge VAT, in terms of
crediting the tax then the tax authorities are in control and not the shops. It’s better to control this.
Conceptually it does not make any sense because we only want the tax consumption, and we do that
buy relieving businesses from the burden.
– Legislative intent
– Case law
• ECJ 24 November 1996, Case C-317/94, Elida Gibbs: “intended to tax only
the final consumer”
Taxing consumption
vs
Social balancing argument, ability to pay, we want to achieve a situation that people who make
more money contribute more such as in income tax? But that is more difficult with consumption tax,
is it as relatable to the ability to pay as income tax? No, but there are ability to pay elements in
necessity goods such as food and the other luxury goods and services that are at a higher tax rate.
– taxing the benefit one has from consumption (expenditure), which is an indicator of
the economically relevant activity of a person
Do we want to tax each and every business or selective businesses or only a certain type of
businesses? We see historically that in a simple value chain like here on the slide, if we introduce a
single stage tax only tax the manufacturer or the wholesaler of the retailer. You do not see this often
globally, especially nowadays, what are the differences between wholesalers and retailers for
example, you would have to define these words again.
This is a single stage tax, you only choose to tax the retailer.
(Retail) sales tax – US example
– E.g. food for preparation and consumption at home and prescribed medication
All stage taxation system is the leading taxation system. This is all stage taxation in which you tax all
of the stages in the value chain. If you do not introduce a refund mechanism than the manufacturer
would not be able to deduct the tax and raise its price to the wholesaler with the tax in the price
included, that is tax on tax. And it goes on to the retailer this way etc. If I would be Apple I would go
for direct sales instead of to retailers, because if the consumer prices stay the same than Apple could
lower the prices or the prices and the profit could stay the same. Otherwise there would be
distortion in economic context.
• Value added taxes (VAT) (belasting toegevoegde waarde): VAT system with a tax credit
method/ deduction of input is the leading system
– Addition method
– Subtraction method
– Tax credit method / deduction of input VAT * EU, Australia, Malaysia etc. Sometimes
the name is different it can be called GST (but it’s just VAT) -> Australia. Because
when they started the introduction of tax, in most instances people do not respond
very enthusiastically so the gov. has to sell this tax to the people which is not so
popular (totally new branded tax which seems different than VAT because VAT had a
negative impact -> UK).
* E.g. EU VAT, but also Australia, Canada, New Zealand and Singapore where it is called a
Goods and Services Tax (GST)
• 8 US states
– Arizona, Delaware, Hawaii, Kentucky, New Mexico, Ohio, Texas and Washington
• Different names:
– Transaction Privilege Tax (TPT), Commercial Activities Tax (CAT), GRT and Business
and Occupations Tax
• All elements of turnover are taxed insofar they have not been taxed at previous stages of the
distribution chain
– E.g. medical services, certain real estate transactions, insurance, certain financial
services, specified social welfare services
• Simplified rules for SME’s for deduction in case of taxed and exempt without credit supplies
– Fixed credit rates: manufacturing (70%), wholesalers (90%), retail (80%), services
(50%), other (60%)
In terms of legal technique, we have private consumption – expenditures and then taxable
transaction, but if we look at that from a legal technique perspective, how do we define taxable
transactions typically? Supplies of goods and services for consideration, but the difference between
C2C and B2C is that in order to come to taxation as such, it should be supplies of goods and services
for consideration by taxable persons (so not a neighbor, friend or stranger). For consideration =
onder bezwarende titel (tegen betaling, tegenprestaties over en weer).
Example of what we discussed before, how do we exclude on balance B2B taxation? The Google
example. If we want to relieve the retailer than the retailer needs to get back the tax it has paid to
the wholesaler (20), so the tax received by the government is 40 and that equals the tax on private
consumption. Advantage for gov. to tax B2B as well, tapping tax through the supply chain (from each
tax payer), if there’s a fraudulent tax payer than you do not lose out on all the money, it would be
only one part of the whole supply chain.
Structure of a consumption tax / VAT
1. Who
2. What
3. Where
5. Exemptions
6. Liability
7. When
9. Administrative obligations
We are going to look at the building blocks we would need in order to build a consumption tax
system or even just any tax. Let’s assume we lease a home, we have the owner of the home and
leases the home to us and there is a window tax that needs to get paid, there are two potential tax
payers, we would need to define in the windows tax law who would need to pay the tax. And what
do we need to tax, we would need to define what is a window. In a CIT business income has to be
taxed but what should be included for example? Define where and what is the taxable amount and
the rate. Imagine if you live in Spain and you move to the NL and you buy an online game, which
country should get the taxing rights? You may have to use exemptions, we do not want to levy
windows on every 2 windows of the house for example. Who should be liable and should you make
somebody else liable, if the person living in the house does not pay windows tax maybe we can tax it
from the owner. When does it need to get paid, each year/every first of the month? Tax crediting is
number 8. And how is the filing of returns or objections? It is the structure of any tax actually.
Always go back to these basics!
She is a resident in Canady, she lives in the NL now, she purchased the ticket when she was in
Germany and the carousel is in Germany and she used a US credit card, we have 5 potential
countries which may claim taxing rights to this transaction, there’s no global consumption tax so
each of these countries have their own rules. What would conceptually be the best country to
allocate the taxing rights to? This is a service that she consumes physically in France. The place of
residence of the business that sold her the tickets (the carousal works through this company to sell
online tickets) and this company is in the UK. She purchased the tickets from a UK company. What is
the complexity here? From a gov. perspective, if we represent the French gov., the UK company
should be the tax payer because it sold the ticket to the consumer, and pay French VAT. Double
taxation would mean if the UK wants VAT and France wants French VAT. If there’s double non-
taxation and UK would not tax and point to France and vise versa. The latter does not occur very
often.
Some general difficulties in consumption taxes in any jurisdiction you would encounter these
questions and problems, topics and issues are the same
• Scope of taxable person concept (who is a taxable person -> specifically in this digital area
C2C this is an important questions)
• Goods vs services (jurisdictions have different rules for goods and services, is 3d printing a
good or a service?)
• Financial services (for example Islamic banking, it focuses on the supply of goods model)
• Abusive practises
Example: government bodies, how do we deal with gov. bodies? The government does a lot of stuff
like picking up the trash and selling passports. The government asks for a payment of a passport, is
this an expenditure? Yes, so conceptually we need to think of a way of dealing with this, you end
with the questions of how to deal with government bodies. The government is a taxable person,
should it be taxed for the sale of passports? Many countries did not want to achieve this, they did
not want to levy taxes on government goods and services. You could think of many solutions such as
exempting the sale of passports or exclude government bodies from taxable person concept
straightaway so that there is no tax. In the EU typically we exclude gov. bodies from being taxable
persons. IN AUS the sales are not subject to tax but gov. bodies are taxable persons and gov. bodies
can get VAT back on purchases.
Sale of passport:
• taxable?
• exempt?
Difference between supplies of goods and services. The question is what defines a good and what
defines a service? Various countries treat intangible service differently than in the EU. Book vs. e-
book -> depending on how the definition is and how you attach preferential rates, would you treat
them alike or differently? Would we consider an e-book the same as a physical book? EU
perspective: rules were changed by member states, they should be allowed to apply equal
treatment.
If you are a consumer in Japan and I buy certain music from a provider, if I purchase that locally we
have local tax, you could buy it from spotify for local tax but if you buy it from the US, what are the
problems you would encounter? What are the problems the gov of country X would encounter?
From a neutrality and competition perspective, if you do not want your local entrepreneurs to lose
businesses you will need to find a way to apply equal treatment. Either spotify is more expensive
than apple or if they apply the same price than apple’s profit would be higher because they do not
have to pay tax in the example. The solution to this problem to get equal treatment: charge same tax
to the us firm. We need to apply tax in a similar way but how, because how can country x ensure
that apple pays the same tax in country x? The purchasers of the services would have to be obliged
to the gov (reverse charge mechanism) consumers gets the obligation to pay the tax to the gov. This
would not be effective, more effective is that Apple needs to register in country X for taxes and you
will have to go only after Apple as country X. The issue is that companies do not want to go to those
countries to register. How do you enforce that and ensure that businesses from the US/China or
somewhere else follow those rules? What % is actually going to be a good taxpayer? One of the
great solutions: legislation allows if the tech companies do not pay the taxes they shut down their
websites, than they cannot generate businesses (turkey). Big businesses are relatively easy to catch
but the difficulty lies in the small businesses, they’re more difficult to go after. Governments have
accepted an 80/20 rule -> you can only adapt rules for 80% of the market and the other 20% also
needs to follow the rules but the gov. accepts that the 20% does not follow the rules, it may seem
unfair.
Each consumption tax system is dealing with how to treat financial services.
Who
We need to define who we will have as a taxable person, who will be the taxpayer for example the
window tax in our example? There are some basic elements you would see typically across the
globe, they may use different definitions but the concept is quite similar.
– Any person: Because it’s a consumption tax you want to ensure that the definition of
taxable person is as neutral as possible. No difference between any legal format,
because you want to tax the consumption no matter the legal form. That is different
in CIT (you only want to tax legal entities) in PIT only private individuals.
– Economic activities: You need to run a business, only then consumption tax should
apply. (not friends and neighbors selling stuff to each other).
• Sometimes dependent on tax registration (that is very easy, you are a taxable person if you
are registered for taxes but it also means that people who do not register are not taxable
and they need to design rules when to register and when not to register. You don’t get born
with a consumption tax registration, there is a revenue threshold in many countries that if
you have this amount of revenue you become a taxable person and you register and below
that you do not have to register because you are not a taxable person.)
• Group taxation regimes: Different than the group taxation in CIT, this one is specifically for
consumption tax. Designed to simplify taxation for businesses and for tax administration.
What are we going to tax? We need to define the taxable events that lead to tax liability. In a
window tax that would be having a window and then you would have the issue of defining a window
(with or without glass). A very important additional taxable event: if we want to buy really rare
sneakers we could go to a local shop -> it would be taxable. Order the sneakers online from an
online dutch company -> sales would be taxable. What if you would go to a different website and
order the shoes from the US? What are the choices in terms of equal treatment for the government?
US ships the sneakers to the NL, from a consumption point of view it should be paid in the NL. You
need o find a way to create a taxable event when good enter in your country, in consumption taxes
there’s an additional taxable event: import is a separate taxable event. It is to achieve tax neutrality
and equal competition. We care about the local economy and all countries want to assure a level
playing field between foreign companies and local companies. In terms of sovereignty, you also want
to be charge of your own country concerning the VAT. We need the taxable event of import to fix
that.
What is the transaction that the US business is carrying out/doing? From a legal perspective what
does the US business do? It’s a sale, there’s a transaction, you deliver the sneakers for the consumer
to own the sneakers, the US company is supplying a good. The problem if we would put US tax on
the sneakers is double taxation -> we would need to come up with a mechanism whereby the export
of the goods is exempt or 0% rated. -> These two are not the same thing.
If we run a vineyard and sell wine to a person, what would we do in terms of taxing rights? Which
country should be able to tax these transactions, the supply of this wine? In country Y the
consumption takes place. It should only be country Y tax from a global point of view, how do we deal
with that? In certain occasions country x would also claim taxing rights (not in an ideal world) and
then there would be double taxation.
If you look at it from a principle perspective, if you step away a bit from the goal of taxing
consumption, for cross-border trade there are 2 principles:
1. Origin principle
2. Destination principle
Destination principle is the leading principle for the vast majority of the cases, because it meets
the consumption goals the best. However, in consumption taxation depending on certain
situation the origin principle is sometimes applies. Why would that be a driver to apply the origin
principle? To make sure the VAT is paid, because you may not know what happens on the other
side of the transaction. If you use resources of your country and you only export, you do not pay
any tax in your country. It would give the country more money if you simply tax all the
transactions. Origin principle is applied sometimes for tax efficiency in B2C type of transactions,
taxes get paid in the country of business and the and the business does not have to do
everything abroad and the private individual does not have to do anything, principle to apply for
tax efficiency reasons. Getting a piece of the tax pie is also a reason. But from a conceptual point
of view there is no reason to apply the origin principle.
Week 4
The arm’s length principle: come up with a commercial market price as if it would be a transaction
between non-related parties if the transacting parties are related to each other, for the calculation
of taxation this is fair. This is the working field of going from an agreed price to what should be the
price in a non-related situation. From a consumption tax perspective, we would see that the
principle is not really present, it’s a key item in direct taxation but not so much in indirect taxation.
Why does it not play such a big role in consumption tax? We have chosen to tax the consumption by
expenditures, you should not be forced to pay more tax than the expenditure.
Exemptions
Exemptions exist because of policy reasons, tax relief reason, exemption only means that the VAT on
your supply is removed, if exemption is used -> business ic not charging VAT to the costumer.
Typically applied on transaction and not on the level of the tax subject (taxpayer), we want to relive
tax on certain transactions. For example medical services are exempt usually. In a lot of countries
education is exempt. The other end of the spectrum is input side of the businesses (buying), there
you could make a policy choice. If you exempt you allow the VAT to be recoverable that is an
exemption with credit, if you do not allow a refund on VAT that is an exemption without credit.
When you look at exports of goods you would exemption with credit, if you do not allow that then
the consumption tax would be part of the overall price on the sneakers -> tax on tax, the tax would
be moved to the consumer not charged as a tax but it would be tax part pf the pricing, only way of
solving that is allowing exemption with credit.
A is Nike US, B is Footlocker US and C is the consumer. Without credit Nike would tax to footlocker
and footlocker would sell with tax included to consumer. We solve this with a credit.
Why we would not apply a credit mechanism, you do not charge the tax to consumers but the supply
of medical equipment increases the cost base of the hospital, here you can argue whether you
would not allow credit to the hospital, if your goal is to lower the price of medical care then you
would allow exemptions, but around the globe we have said that this is a choice of governments a
policy choice. Input VAT is then a cost to the business.
Liability = choice of who needs to pay a tax. If you buy a bread from the bakery the bakery, would we
liable to pay the tax, but on certain occasions it would not be handy to do that. Then the liability
would get shifted to the consumer.
Shifted liability from supplier to customer.
Assumption: somebody in UK gives legal advice to someone in France, France needs the taxing rights
(B2B, consumption in France) who would be liable to pay the VAT normally? We have introduced the
concept of shifting the liability so the French business needs to pay the French tax instead of the Uk
business having to pay the French tax -> for efficiency reasons we use reverse charge. Tax liability
shifted from supplier to costumer.
• The deduction system is meant to relieve the trader entirely of the burden of the VAT
payable or paid in the course of all his economic activities, provided that such activities are
themselves, in principle, subject to VAT
– E.g. ECJ 14 February 1985, Case 268/83, Rompelman, ECJ 15 January 1998, Case C-
37/95, Ghent Coal Terminal and ECJ 8 June 2000, Case C-98/98 Midland Bank
– several methods
• turnover based
• actual use
The common issue is the same but it depends on what choice the government has made.
The final building block is what we will not focus on in this course, the administrative obligations,
vital in terms of businesses and governments dealing with this.
Customs union - Abolished quotas and customs duties between the Member States
• Common market - four freedoms: free movement of persons, services, goods and
capital
• Customs union
• EU treaties, principally:
Secondary law
• Decisions taken by the institutions entitled under the treaties. Among which:
• The Council
The Council
• E.g. Preliminary rulings (binding for all Member States –explaining the law as it
always has been), infringement procedures launched by the Commission
• Assisted by Advocates General which submit opinions to the Court (non-binding proposals)
National law
ECJ, 5 February 1963, Case 26/62, Van Gend & Loos, and 15 July 1964, Case 6/64, Costa v. ENEL
Direct vertical effect of Primary law (but first check national Law with secondary law)
• Principle of neutrality
Principle of neutrality
• Legal neutrality – the equal must be treated equally, VAT must be exactly
proportional to the price
• Economic neutrality – taxes should not damage economic interest (by price
increase)
Equal treatment of taxable persons, transactions, goods & services local and abroad
Competition neutrality – cascading tax would be distorting (tax burden would depend on extent of
vertical or horizontal integration)
Principle of neutrality
• Tax on importation should not exceed internal tax and refund on exportation cannot
be more that levied
• ‘The factual economic state of affairs as they take place between parties’
• As a starting point the legal reality (e.g. contractual relationships) dictates the appropriate
VAT treatment
1. Who
2. What
3. Where
5. Exemptions
6. Liability
7. When
9. Administrative obligations
Agenda
2. Any person
3. Independent
4. Economic activities
5. Holding companies
6. VAT grouping
7. Public bodies
Taxing consumption
Taxable person (paying tax to government) -> art. 9 VAT Directive defined
vs
– ECJ 4 December 1990, Case C-186/89, Van Tiem: ECJ is a court on EU level that needs
to interpret questions that arise from EU perspective.
VAT Directive is blueprint EU directive, there is a blueprint rule at European level but
national governments all need to look at this blueprint VAT directive and implement it to
national law and that will be the local VAT local, all the local VAT laws should be in line with
the VAT Directive, because in the EU we have a single market concept and VAT should not be
distortive in that market, should not be an obstacle for EU market trade. All the important
rules are the same in every country to have an equal playing field, key concept in EU vat is
that a meaning of a word such as taxable person is a EU VAT meaning which should have the
same meaning in all the countries, you cannot be a taxable person in Spain and not be a
taxable person in Germany. It must be applied in the same world in the whole EU. In the
design the dynamic is that everything must be applied equally in the EU
The concept of taxable person has a very wide scope. You need to interpret the term taxable person
quite widely, the idea behind that is that we want to tax consumption, if we want to tax
consumption the government goes to the level of businesses, we want to be able to tax (not from
friends or neighbors) but widen the scope.
Any person
• Neutrality of legal form
Art. 9 VAT Directive -> we have this element of any person because we want to achieve neutrality,
catch all businesses, independent of the legal form. If two private individuals run a partnerships, like
a joint venture than the joint venture would be the taxable person.
• Entity
• Own name
Independent
• a contract of employment, or
• any other legal ties creating the relationship of employer and employee as
regards working conditions, remuneration and the employer’s liability
• ‘Taxable person’ shall mean any person who, independently, carries out in any place any
economic activity, whatever the purpose or results of that activity
• Any activity of producers, traders or persons supplying services, including mining and
agricultural activities and activities of the professions, shall be regarded as ‘economic
activity’
– supply, before first occupation, of a building or parts of a building and the land on
which the building stands
• The exploitation of tangible or intangible property for the purposes of obtaining income
thereform on a continuous basis shall in particular be regarded as an economic activity
Illegal activities – (no) economic activity
– Economic activity
– ECJ 28 May 1998, Case C-3/97, Goodwin/Unstead
– Persons
– Legally independent
– Ratio legis
– administrative simplification
– combat of abuse (e.g. splitting up of one undertaking among several taxable persons
so that each may benefit from an SME scheme)
VAT grouping – consequences (2)
– derogation from the definition of “taxable person” and thus should be interpreted
restrictively
– Head offices and fixed establishments within the territory of a Member State may be
included in a VAT group
– Foreign fixed establishments and head offices may not
– Not contrary to FCE Bank as that case did not involve a VAT group
• Taxable services between head office (country A) and fixed establishment included in a VAT
group (country B)
• Freedom of establishment?
– Art. 49 TFEU
– Financial link
– Economic link
• one member of the group carries out activities which are wholly or
substantially to the benefit of the other members
– Organizational link
• Commission implicitly takes the view that each of the three links must be tested separately
• Allocation of 3G licenses
– Public body
– Distortion of competition
• Public bodies are regarded as taxable persons in respect of the activities listed in Annex I,
unless they are negligible
1. Telecommunications services;
3. transport of goods;
5. passenger transport;
9. warehousing; cont’d
Cont’d
4. activities carried out by radio and television bodies in so far as these are not
exempt pursuant to Art.132(1)(q) VAT Directive
• Tendency to ‘in-source’ public body activities due to lack of input VAT deduction
– Canada / Norway
Week 3 Taxable transactions
Structure of EU VAT
1. Who
3. Where
5. Exemptions
6. Liability
7. When
9. Administrative obligations
1. Introduction
2. Supplies of goods
4. Supplies of services
5. Importation of goods
6. Composite supplies
a) Supply of goods for consideration within the territory of a Member State by a taxable person
acting as such
c) Supply of services for consideration within the territory of a Member State by a taxable
person acting as such etc.
• Place of supply
• Exemptions
• Rate
• Liability
• Supply/lease immovable property in principle VAT exempt (Art. 135(1)(j), (k) & (l) VAT
Directive)
• Immovable property
b. rights in rem giving the holder thereof a right of use over immovable property;
c. shares or interests equivalent to shares giving the holder thereof de jure or de facto
rights of ownership or possession over immovable property or part thereof
• Twofold test
– de jure (on the basis of the contract) – one party should actually empower the other
party to dispose of the property as if he were the owner of that property
• relevant whether the purchaser at any time obtains the right to decide in
what way the goods must be used or to what end
c. Commission agents
Hire purchase and sale on deferred terms
• Civil law
• VAT
– Application by a taxable person of goods forming part of his business assets for
• more generally, their application for purposes other than those of his
business
– where the VAT on those goods or the component parts thereof was wholly or partly
deductible.
• Intra-Community acquisition in Member State of arrival of the goods (Art. 20 VAT Directive)
(g) temporary use of goods within the territory of the Member State in which dispatch or
transport of the goods ends, for the purposes of the supply of services by the taxable person
established within the Member State in which dispatch or transport of the goods began
• Conditions no longer met, transfer is deemed to take place at the time when conditions
cease to be met
Supplies of services
• of his staff or
• Member States may derogate from this provision, unless distortion of competition (Art.
26(2) VAT Directive)
Optional supply of services - internal supply
• The supply by a taxable person of a service for the purposes of his business, where the VAT
on such a service, were it supplied by another taxable person, would not be wholly
deductible
• Aim is to prevent distortions of competition that are due to business without a right to full
deduction of input VAT “in sourcing” certain activities
Opinion of Advocate General Trstenjak of 9 December 2008, Case C-572/07, Tellmer Property, para
36: In determining the essential features of a composite supply there are two opposing aims.
• Lease of dwelling (exempt) + parking space (VAT) = single supply of services (VAT exempt
lease of dwelling)
ECJ 13 July 1989, Case 173/88, Morten Henriksen
1 supply of goods and 1 supply of services according to Hof Amsterdam 5 juni 1996, nr. 94/4854, V-N
1996, p. 4313.
For consideration
• Tit-for-that principle
– Person to whom the goods are transferred is to be treated as the successor to the
transferor
2. What
3. Where
5. Exemptions
6. Liability
7. When
9. Administrative obligations
Agenda
d) Import
a) Chain transactions
• (…) deemed to be the place where the goods are located at the time when the supply takes
place
• (…) where the goods are located at the time when dispatch or transport of the goods to the
customer begins
• However, if dispatch begins in a third territory or third country (…) deemed to be within the
MS of importation of the goods
E.g. B is a representative of A in IT
0% VAT rate / exemption with a right to deduct may apply e.g. to:
• Intra-Community supply
• Temporary use of the goods in MS of destination for the purposes of the supply of
services
• (…) where the goods are located at the time when dispatch or transport of the goods to the
customer ends
(a) the place of supply of intra-Community distance sales of goods shall be deemed to be the
place where the goods are located at the time when dispatch or transport of the goods to
the customer ends;
(b) the place of supply of distance sales of goods imported from third territories or third
countries into a Member State other than that in which dispatch or transport of the goods to
the customer ends, shall be deemed to be the place where the goods are located at the time
when dispatch or transport of the goods to the customer ends;
(c) the place of supply of distance sales of goods imported from third territories or third
countries into the Member State in which dispatch or transport of the goods to the
customer ends shall be deemed to be in that Member State, provided that VAT on those
goods is to be declared under the special scheme of Section 4 of Chapter 6 of Title XII.
Importation
• MS within whose territory the goods are located when they enter the community
Intra-Community acquisition
• (…) deemed to be the place where dispatch or transport of the goods to the person
acquiring them ends
• Deemed to be within the MS which issued the VAT identification number under which the
goods were acquired, unless VAT has been applied in accordance with Article 40
ABC-transactions:
• Multiple parties
Several undertakings from two or more MS’s successively conclude contracts for the purchase of the
same goods which are then performed by means of a single transfer of goods from the supplier to
the last customer
Goods transported by forwarding agent on K’s instructions.
Two successive supplies give rise to only a single movement of goods – must be regarded as having
followed each other in time
Intra-Community movement can only be ascribed to one of the two successive supplies
EXW
Under specific conditions where person acquiring the goods has obtained right to dispose as owner
in MS of first supply, expressed intention to transport goods to other EU country and presented VAT
number of that country, intra-Community movement ascribed to first supply IF the second person
acquiring the goods has obtained right to dispose as owner in MS of destination
Triangulation
Triangulation is a supply chain involving:
Problems arise for the intermediate supplier (B) if the 3 parties are in different countries due to:
• Acquisition deemed where dispatch or transport of the goods to the person acquiring them
ends
• B must notify C (via the sales invoice) that C is liable to pay the VAT due on
B’s supply
• ECJ 22 April 2010, Case C-536/08 and C-539/08, X and Facet / Facet Trading