07 Decision Analysis
07 Decision Analysis
Ata ul Musawir
• For example, suppose that after carefully considering all the factors
involved in the two job offers, you decide to accept the position with
company B. After working for this company for a few months, it suddenly
announces that, in an effort to cut costs, it is closing the office in which
you work and eliminating your job.
1. Problem Formulation
• We then identify:
• The decision alternatives
• The uncertain future events, referred to as chance events (or states of nature)
• The consequences (or payoffs) associated with each combination of decision
alternative and chance event outcome
• The financial success of the project depends upon the size of the
condominium complex and the chance event concerning the demand for
the condominiums.
1. Problem Formulation
PDC Example: Decision Alternatives
• The statement of the PDC decision problem is to select the size of the
new luxury condominium project that will lead to the largest profit given
the uncertainty concerning the demand for the condominiums.
• The states of nature are defined so they are mutually exclusive (no more
than one can occur) and collectively exhaustive (at least one must
occur); thus one and only one of the possible states of nature will occur.
• For the PDC problem, the chance event concerning the demand for the
condominiums has two possible states of nature:
• The figure below shows the payoff table for the PDC problem, which was
developed based on data collected and analyzed by the management.
1. Problem Formulation
PDC Example: Decision Tree
• A decision tree provides a graphical representation of the decision-making
process.
• Figure 4.2 presents a decision tree for the PDC problem. It shows the natural
or logical progression that will occur over time. First, PDC must make a
decision regarding the size of the condominium complex (d1, d2, or d3). Then,
after the decision is implemented, either state of nature s1 or s2 will occur.
The number at each endpoint of the tree indicates the payoff associated
with a particular sequence.
• The decision tree in Figure 4.2 shows four nodes: 1 to 4. Squares are used to
depict decision nodes and circles are used to depict chance nodes. Thus,
node 1 is a decision node, and nodes 2, 3, and 4 are chance nodes.
• The branches connecting the decision node (1) to the chance nodes (2, 3, 4)
correspond to the three decision alternatives. The branches leaving each
chance node correspond to the states of nature. The payoffs are shown at
the end of the states of nature branches.
1. Problem Formulation
PDC Example: Decision Tree
2. Decision Making without Probabilities
• In this section we consider approaches to decision making that do not
require knowledge of the probabilities of the states of nature.
• Thus, regret represents how much potential payoff one would forgo by
selecting a particular decision alternative given that a specific state of
nature will occur. This is why regret is often referred to as opportunity
loss.
|20 - 8| = |7 - 7| =
|20 - 14| = |7 - 5| =
|20 - 20| = |7 - (-9)| =
2. Decision Making without Probabilities
PDC Example: Minimax Regret Approach
2. Decision Making without Probabilities
Investments Example
• Khushkismat Khan has found a Rs. 1,000 note in his old shalwar. He has to
decide how to invest the money for one year.
• The payoff from each of these options will be affected by the performance of
the stock market over the coming year. The stock market’s performance can
be classified into five possibilities (states of nature):
1. Large Rise
2. Small Rise
3. No Change
4. Small Fall
5. Large Fall
2. Decision Making without Probabilities
Investments Example
• The table below shows the expected payoffs for the five potential
investment options under the five potential states of nature.
• Therefore, we can omit the stock option alternative from our calculations.
The
TheMaximin
MaximinCriterion
Criterion Minimum
Minimum
Decisions
Decisions Large
LargeRise
Rise Small
Smallrise
rise NoNoChange
Change Small
SmallFall
Fall Large
LargeFall
Fall Payoff
Payoff
Gold
Gold -100
-100 100
100 200
200 300
300 00 -100
-100
Bond
Bond 250
250 200
200 150
150 -100
-100 -150
-150 -150
-150
Stock
Stock 500
500 250
250 100
100 -200
-200 -600
-600 -600
-600
C/D
C/Daccount
account 60
60 60
60 60
60 60
60 60
60 60
60
2. Decision Making without Probabilities
Investments Example
• The minimax regret approach suggests that bond is the best alternative
as it has the lowest maximum regret of 400.
The
The Regret
RegretTable
Table Maximum
Maximum
Decision
Decision Large
Large rise
rise Small
Smallrise
riseNo
Nochange
change Small
Smallfall
fall Large
Large fall
fall Regret
Regret
Gold
Gold 600
600 150
150 00 00 60
60 600
600
Bond
Bond 250
250 50
50 50
50 400
400 210
210 400
400
Stock
Stock 00 00 100
100 500
500 660
660 660
660
C/D
C/D 440
440 190
190 140
140 240
240 00 440
440
2. Decision Making without Probabilities
• Ultimately, the decision maker will have to choose the most appropriate
approach and then make the final decision accordingly.
• Another example:
3. Introduction to Probability Theory:
Assigning Probabilities: Relative Frequency Method
• To illustrate the relative frequency method, suppose that in a test
market evaluation of a product, 400 potential customers were
contacted, where 100 purchased the product, but 300 did not.
• Assume that to obtain a passing grade, a student must pass at least one
of the two exams. Based on the data provided, what is the probability
that a student taking this course will pass at least one of the exams?
3. Introduction to Probability Theory
Computing Probabilities: Addition Law
• Using the addition law for the events A and B, we have:
• This result indicates an 88% chance of a student passing the course (not
considering any other factors) because of the 0.88 probability of passing
at least one of the exams.
3. Introduction to Probability Theory
Computing Probabilities: Addition Law
• Before proceeding, let us consider how the addition law is applied to
mutually exclusive events. Two or more events are said to be mutually
exclusive if the events do not have any sample points in common – that
is, there are no sample points in the intersection of the events.
• For two events, A and B, that are independent (i.e. the occurrence of
one does not influence the occurrence of the other), the multiplication
law is given as follows:
• For two events, A and B, that are dependent (i.e. the occurrence of one
influences the occurrence of the other), the multiplication law is given as
follows:
3. Introduction to Probability Theory
Computing Probabilities: Multiplication Law
• Thus, to compute the probability of the intersection of two independent
events, we simply multiply the corresponding probabilities.
• For example, a retail store manager knows from past experience that
40% of her customers use a credit card when making purchases. What is
the probability that the next two customers will both use a credit card?
• Let:
• This result tells us that 63% of the newspaper’s customers subscribe to both
the daily and Sunday editions.
3. Introduction to Probability Theory
Computing Probabilities: Multiplication Law
• Note: mutually exclusive events are always dependent. We know this is
true because if one event occurs, it means the other event(s) will not
occur. Thus the occurrence of each event affects the occurrence of all
other events.
• For example, assume there are two mutually exclusive events A = strong
market demand and B = weak market demand. Also, P(A) = 0.40 and P(B)
= 0.60. We know that if A occurs, then B cannot occur (i.e. P(A|B) = 0)
and vice versa (i.e. P(B|A) = 0). Therefore, P(A ∩ B) must be equal to 0.
For mutually exclusive events, these terms = 0. Hence, the entire expression becomes 0.
Exercises
Exercises
Exercises
Exercises
Exercises
4. Decision Making with Probabilities
The Expected Value Approach
• In many decision-making situations, we can obtain probability
assessments for the states of nature. When such probabilities are
available, we can use the expected value approach to identify the best
decision alternative.
• Let:
• Because one and only one of the N states of nature can occur, the
probabilities must satisfy two conditions:
4. Decision Making with Probabilities
The Expected Value Approach
• The expected value (EV) of decision alternative di is defined as follows:
where:
• di = decision alternative i
• P(sj) = probability of the state of nature j occurring
• Vij = payoff of the decision alternative i for the state of nature j
• Thus, using the expected value approach, we find that the large
condominium complex, with an expected value of $14.2 million, is the
recommended decision.
4. Decision Making with Probabilities
PDC Example: EV
• The calculations required to identify the decision alternative with the
best expected value can be conveniently carried out on a decision tree.
• Recall that in a decision tree, squares are used to depict decision nodes
and circles are used to depict chance nodes.
• Figure 4.3 shows the decision tree for the PDC problem with state-of-
nature branch probabilities. Working backward through the decision
tree, we first compute the expected value at each chance node. That is,
at each chance node, we weight each possible payoff by its probability of
occurrence.
Work backwards from the branch levels to determine the EV of each decision alternative.
4. Decision Making with Probabilities
PDC Example: Decision Tree Solution
When the final level is reached, we have the expected value of each decision alternative.
This is the solution of the decision tree using the expected value approach, which
suggests that alternative d3 has the highest expect value of $14.2 million.
4. Decision Making with Probabilities
Expected Value of Perfect Information (EVPI)
• The expected value of perfect information (EVPI) is computed as follows:
• Note the role of the absolute value in equation (4.5). For minimization
problems, the expected value with perfect information is always less
than or equal to the expected value without perfect information.
• Note that, if PDC knew for sure that state of nature s1 would occur, the
best decision alternative would be d3, with a payoff of $20 million.
Similarly, if PDC knew for sure that state of nature s2 would occur, the
best decision alternative would be d1, with a payoff of $7 million. Thus,
we can state PDC’s optimal decision strategy when the perfect
information becomes available as follows:
4. Decision Making with Probabilities
PDC Example: EVPI
• What is the expected value for this decision strategy using perfect
information?
• Thus, from equation (4.4) the expected value of the decision strategy
that uses perfect information is 0.8(20) + 0.2(7) = 17.4. We refer to the
expected value of $17.4 million as the expected value with perfect
information (EVwPI).
4. Decision Making with Probabilities
PDC Example: EVPI
• Earlier in this section we showed that the recommended decision using
the expected value approach is decision alternative d3, with an expected
value of $14.2 million. Because this decision recommendation and
expected value computation were made without the benefit of perfect
information, $14.2 million is referred to as the expected value without
perfect information (EVwoPI).
• The expected value with perfect information is $17.4 million, and the
expected value without perfect information is $14.2; therefore, the
expected value of the perfect information (EVPI) is $17.4 - $14.2 = $3.2
million.
SilverDecisions: http://silverdecisions.pl/
Exercises
Exercises
Exercises
Exercises
Exercises
5. Risk Analysis and Sensitivity Analysis
Risk Analysis
• Risk analysis helps the decision maker recognize the difference between
the expected value of a decision alternative and the payoff that may
actually occur.
• Risk analysis helps decision makers to look beyond the expected value of
a decision alternative and also take into consideration the level of risk
involved, in terms of variations in the potential payoffs.
• The payoffs for each decision alternative by developing risk profile graphs for the
decision alternatives of interest
5. Risk Analysis and Sensitivity Analysis
PDC Example: Risk Analysis
• Let us demonstrate risk analysis and the construction of a risk profile by
returning to the PDC condominium construction project.
• The 0.8 probability for the $20 million payoff and the 0.2 probability for
the -$9 million payoff provide the risk profile for the large complex
decision alternative. This risk profile is shown graphically in Figure 4.5.
5. Risk Analysis and Sensitivity Analysis
PDC Example: Risk Analysis
5. Risk Analysis and Sensitivity Analysis
PDC Example: Risk Analysis
• Sometimes a review of the risk profile associated with an optimal
decision alternative may cause the decision maker to choose another
decision alternative even though the expected value of the other
decision alternative is not as good.
• For example, the risk profile for the medium complex decision
alternative (d2) shows a 0.8 probability for a $14 million payoff and a 0.2
probability for a $5 million payoff. Because no probability of a loss is
associated with decision alternative d2, the medium complex decision
alternative would be judged less risky than the large complex decision
alternative.
• As a result, a decision maker might prefer the less risky medium complex
decision alternative even though it has an expected value of $2 million
less than the large complex decision alternative.
5. Risk Analysis and Sensitivity Analysis
Sensitivity Analysis
• Sensitivity analysis also helps the decision maker by describing how changes
in the state-of-nature probabilities and/or changes in the payoffs affect the
recommended decision alternative.
• If a small change in the value of one of the inputs causes a change in the
recommended decision alternative, the solution to the decision analysis problem is
sensitive to that particular input. Extra effort and care should be taken to make sure
the input value is as accurate as possible.
• On the other hand, if a modest-to-large change in the value of one of the inputs does
not cause a change in the recommended decision alternative, the solution to the
decision analysis problem is not sensitive to that particular input. No extra time or
effort would be needed to refine the estimated input value.
5. Risk Analysis and Sensitivity Analysis
Sensitivity Analysis
• Sensitivity analysis may be conducted for:
• The payoffs for each decision alternative under each state of nature by
calculating the range of payoffs within which the particular decision alternative
remains optimal (for two states of nature only)
• For example, suppose that in the PDC problem the probability for a
strong demand is revised to 0.2 and the probability for a weak demand is
revised to 0.8. Would the recommended decision alternative change?
• Using P(s1) = 0.2, P(s2) = 0.8, and equation (4.4), the revised expected
values for the three decision alternatives are
5. Risk Analysis and Sensitivity Analysis
PDC Example: Sensitivity Analysis by Changing Values
• With these probability assessments, the recommended decision
alternative is to construct a small condominium complex (d1), with an
expected value of $7.2 million. The probability of strong demand is only
0.2, so constructing the large condominium complex (d3) is the least
preferred alternative, with an expected value of -$3.2 million (a loss).
• Thus, when the probability of strong demand is large, PDC should build
the large complex; when the probability of strong demand is small, PDC
should build the small complex. Obviously, we could continue to modify
the probabilities of the states of nature and learn even more about how
changes in the probabilities affect the recommended decision
alternative.
• For the special case of two states of nature, a graphical procedure can
be used to determine how changes for the probabilities of the states of
nature affect the recommended decision alternative. To demonstrate
this procedure, we let p denote the probability of state of nature s1; that
is, P(s1) = p.
• With only two states of nature in the PDC problem, the probability of
state of nature s2 is:
• Using equation (4.4) and the payoff values in Table 4.1, we determine
the expected value for decision alternative d1 as follows:
5. Risk Analysis and Sensitivity Analysis
PDC Example: Sensitivity Analysis for Probabilities of States of Nature
• Thus, we have developed three equations that show the expected value
of the three decision alternatives as a function of the probability of state
of nature s1.
• For each equation, we can obtain the line by identifying two points that
satisfy the equation and drawing a line through the points.
• The value of p for which the expected values of d1 and d2 are equal is the
value of p corresponding to the intersection of the EV(d1) and the EV(d2)
lines. To determine this value, we set EV(d1) = EV(d2) and solve for the
value of p:
5. Risk Analysis and Sensitivity Analysis
PDC Example: Sensitivity Analysis for Probabilities of States of Nature
• Sensitivity analysis calculations can also be made for the values of the
payoffs. In the original PDC problem, the expected values for the three
decision alternatives were as follows: EV(d1) = 7.8, EV(d2) = 12.2, and
EV(d3) = 14.2.
• Let:
• Using P(s1) = 0.8 and P(s2) = 0.2, the general expression for EV(d3) is:
5. Risk Analysis and Sensitivity Analysis
PDC Example: Sensitivity Analysis for Values of Payoffs
• Assuming that the payoff for d3 stays at its original value of -$9 million
when demand is weak, the large complex decision alternative will
remain optimal as long as:
• Assuming that the payoff for d3 when demand is strong stays at its
original value of $20 million, we can make a similar calculation to learn
how sensitive the optimal solution is with regard to the payoff for d3
when demand is weak. Returning to the EV calculation of equation
(4.10), we know that the large complex decision alternative will remain
optimal as long as:
• Based on this sensitivity analysis, we see that the payoffs for the large
complex decision alternative (d3) could vary considerably, and d3 would
remain the recommended decision alternative. Thus, we conclude that
the optimal solution for the PDC decision problem is not particularly
sensitive to the payoffs for the large complex decision alternative.
• Note that similar sensitivity analysis calculations can be made for the
payoffs associated with the small complex decision alternative d1 and
the medium complex decision alternative d2.
Exercises
Exercises
Exercises
Decision Analysis vs.
Other DM Tools & Techniques
Qualitative Quantitative