Bayesian Games
Bayesian Games
Bayesian Games
Abhinash Borah
In order to choose her action, player 1 (when her cost is low) must
try to predict player 2’s behavior, which, in turn depends on 2’s
prediction of 1’s behavior and how this behavior in influenced by
1’s private information about her cost.
1 1
Don’t Don’t
Build Build
Build Build
2 2 2 2
Don’t Don’t
Enter Enter
Enter Enter
Don’t Don’t
Enter Enter
Enter Enter
Equilibrium
Normal-form representation and Nash Equilibrium
E DE
DB,B 1.75, 0 3.25, 0
DB,DB 2, 1 3, 0
B,B .75, −1 2.75, 0
B,DB 1, 0 2.5, 0
Modeled what a player does not know about the other player in
terms of probabilistic beliefs
Assumed that players’ probabilistic beliefs are common knowledge
Constructed an extensive game of imperfect information with
corresponding normal form representation and used standard
equilibrium analysis
In the process, constructed “meta player(s)”
1
This normal form is referred to as the Bayesian normal form in Watson
Incomplete Information & Bayesian Games 16 / 22
Example (Watson, figures 24.3, 24.4)
C D
A x, 9 3, 6
B 6, 0 6, 9
100 − q1 − θ2 − 2q2 = 0
1 q1 θ 2
q2 (θ2 ) = [100 − q1 − θ2 ] = 50 − −
2 2 2
That is,
q1
q2 (70) = 15 −
2
q1
q2 (50) = 25 −
2
For type of applications we will deal with in this course, there are two
equivalent ways of computing equilibrium in Bayesian games.
1 Compute Nash equilibrium using the normal form. This is
recommended for any game that can be represented in matrix
form.
2 The second method entails treating the types of each player as
separate players. Treating types separately often simplifies the
analysis of infinite games, where calculus may be required