Untitled
Untitled
Untitled
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and
facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected].
Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
https://about.jstor.org/terms
Brill is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Journal of the
Economic and Social History of the Orient
BY
JACK A. GOLDSTONE
(University of California-Davis)
1) For a sampling, see Brotton 1998; Cook 1994; Coward 1988; Goldston
and Pole 1987; Kirby 1990; Kunt and Woodhead 1994; McClain et al., 19
Ropp 1981; Schwartz 1994; Subrahmanyam 1990; Totman 1993; Wee 1993
the century-and-a half that followed the slow recovery from the Blac
By the beginning of the sixteenth century, market economies, state-li
cal structures dominated by a central government under a King, and
of serfdom had spread across most of Europe west of the Elbe. Yet it
until well after 1850 that a truly "modern society," with a work forc
nated by an industrial proletariat, and governments dominated by b
politicians rather than by titled nobles and aristocrats, was the norm
Western Europe. The period from 1500 to 1850 (or perhaps to 1832 in
1848 in France and Germany, and perhaps a bit later in Italy and Sp
thus neither clearly feudal, nor clearly modern, but an age of transiti
revolutions. Although some scholars, noting the consolidation of pow
monarchical central governments, called this the "Age of Absolutism,
far as it was a period of rising bourgeois power, of laying the founda
the "modern" world to come, it could with justification be labeled th
modern" period, and so it was.12)
Now the essence of "modernity" in this view lies in the mode of pr
of modern society, namely "capitalism." But since industrial capitalism
proletariat were not evident on a significant scale before 1850, what
mode of production that prevailed from 1500 to 1850, since classical
ism, with its local non-market economy, had also passed from the sce
answer was that a form of capitalism was growing from 1500 to 1850
"merchant capitalism," or "proto-industrial" production, in which goo
produced for markets, and in which profits were made by market tr
commodities, and accrued mainly to non-members of the dominant cla
latter were still feudal (e.g. mainly rentier) in their economic outlook a
tices."3) What was defined as characteristically "early modern," then
form of society in which markets were an active source of profits to mer
who ordered their affairs rationally in order to pursue profits, in a mann
ferent than the still "feudal" (e.g. concerned with rank and honor) n
Moreover, governance was neither "modern" (e.g. dominated by b
politicians) nor "feudal," (e.g. decentralized and dominated by ind
lords), but centralized and partly bureaucratized, albeit under the dire
traditionally-sanctified monarchies and their noble ministers and officers.
We thus come to one crucial problem in the use of the term "early
and its application to world history. "Early Modern" derives from a p
sociological theory of history that privileges modes of production in c
late Roman Empire, and again in Muslim Spain, but remained rar
late seventeenth century, when the Netherlands and England
American colonies enshrined freedom of religious practice. Still, de
gious freedom for individuals, no historians consider late Rome
Spain to be "modern," or "early modern." It is even difficult to co
Colonial America to be "early modern," in the sense of being clea
road to "modernity," for at the time of the Salem witchcraft tria
authority and the power of the King still remained paramount,
that the American colonists should write republican constitution
themselves free citizens were almost a century away. Finally,
made extensive use of coal in a variety of factory processes, to th
Hartwell speaks of an eleventh century "Industrial Revolution" in C
some scholars would push the origins of "early modern" China b
A.D.22) Yet here we would have an entire millennium between th
"early modernity" and the beginning of fully "modem" China c. 1
also note that although modern factory production powered by ste
road transportation appear in substantial degree in late Czaris
the grip of religion and traditional authority (as shown by the g
dependence on the personal whims of the Czar, and the Czar's
on the religious charlatan Rasputin) void any efforts to call pre-
Russia a truly "modern" country.
In addition, the modem Kingdom of Saudi Arabia offers an inter
ple of a country that clearly is technologically "modern," yet rema
wholly traditionally-sanctified modes of governance. Also in the
we find the Islamic Republic of Iran-again, a technologically adva
ety, and with a recently created constitutional government that aro
revolution against monarchical rule. Yet the dominant position of
and of the clergy in Iran has moved some scholars to declare that
a modernizing revolution, and that Iran is neither fully modern no
the clergy and Islamic law remain so dominant, on its way to bec
short we have in Saudi Arabia and Iran two countries that exploit
technology, yet are rarely considered to be fully modernized.
In sum, individual elements of "modernity" may appear in a sc
places, but such individual elements in isolation do not necessarily
ety "modern," or even "early modern." If by "early modern" we se
a society that was simultaneously progressing toward fossil-fuele
48) McNeill 1982; Rosenberg and Birdzell 1986; Landes 1969, 1983; Jone
1990; Hall 1985; Wallerstein 1980.
ripe for outsiders to exploit its internal rivalries, was weak enough to
European domination.
And why should it have been otherwise? After all, the Chinese an
civilizations had been advanced organic societies for many centuries, f
than most European states, which emerged from feudal chaos on
fifteenth and sixteenth centuries. By 1750, what British visionary wo
foreseen their nineteenth century queen as Empress of India? Half a
before Napoleon's exploits in Egypt, and even longer before steam-p
gunboats or railways, what European strategist would have foreseen a
coalition imposing humiliating terms of defeat on the Emperor of Chi
carving up Mesopotamia and the Middle East into European protectora
In short, something dramatic happened in a very short time, such t
tween 1750 and 1850, the global balance of power dramatically altere
"happened" is that most western European countries, exploiting the r
a peculiar set of chance results, occurring mainly but not wholly in
became "modern;" and against such societies the advanced organic soc
Asia were simply overmatched.
Modern societies not only enjoyed the significant technical advant
steam-powered warships and locomotives, built with cheap steel, but
nearly unlimited cheap energy for production. Using that energy to turn
umes of cheap cotton goods and metal tools, England and later Europ
invaded that of Asia, first in the Ottoman Empire and India, and later
Yet this was not their only advantage. In the course of the seventeen
eighteenth and nineteenth centuries, most European countries had gre
formed or revolutionized their governments, reducing the power of th
and traditional elites and increasing that of both the secular governm
independent entrepreneurs. The pursuit of rational means to increase p
the opening of state and business careers to talent, rather than the fo
of traditional government and economic practices by elites with old-f
training and largely hereditary recruitment, meant that Western nati
more efficiently led, more creative, and more flexible in the confron
Western and Asian powers. In the nineteenth and twentieth centurie
major Asian power either underwent a modernizing revolution, or b
subject territory of modern Western (or in the case of Korean and T
modern Asian) nations.
What was this transition to modernity, and how was it accomplish
53) For a good survey of the difficulties of the explaining the Industrial Revolution, see
Mokyr 1985.
By contrast, China's coal was concentrated in the north and was far inland.
Though this coal had been used extensively during the northern Song, these
regions were lost to China when the northern portion of the empire was con-
quered. The shift of China's cultural and commercial centers to the south and
east during the Southern Song era was never fully reversed, and by the time
China recaptured its rich coal lands, they were so far from the main commer-
cial centers of Chinese society that their massive exploitation would have been
hopelessly expensive.
Once cheap coal became ever more plentiful in England, as deep mining was
extended, a revolution could be extended to the production of metals. Although
the value of iron and steel as tools and weapons had been recognized for mil-
lennia, as long as the smelting of ore depended on using wood or charcoal for
fuel, iron would remain expensive and scarce. Wrigley points out that "as long
as the production of 10,000 tons of iron involved the felling of 100,000 acres
of woodland, it was inevitable that it was used only where a few hundred-
weight or at most a few tons of iron would suffice for the task at hand."59) The
tensile strength of steel makes it not only a fine weapon, but a fine material for
tools, and for products ranging from watch springs to building construction. But
where the use of steel is enormously restricted in an organic economy by its
cost, the use of coal to produce iron and steel from ore allows the production
of such materials cheaply and in bulk, to the point where construction of rail-
way systems or fleets of ships weighing thousands or even millions of tons can
be undertaken without fiscal or ecological disaster.
Cheap heat from coal does more than drastically increase the production of
metals; cheap heat allows brick-making, brewing, glass-making, and a hundred
other industrial processes to be carried on with large supplies of cheaper fuel.
And cheap bricks and cheap glass make for far cheaper construction of homes
and factories, while cheaper metal tools of all sorts aid even traditional craft
processes, at the same time that metal and metal-reinforced machinery aid in
factory production. Even agriculture is affected, as the use of tile drainage (the
The other possibility is that these societies had a normal impetus to gro
but that something in them was "blocking" that capacity; a lack of capit
science, of markets, of agricultural productivity, or perhaps an excess of
lation, or of government regulation and interference. Unfortunately (or f
nately for non-European societies), none of these blockages can be docume
as sustained. China and India had great concentrations of capital in the h
of merchants; both had substantial accomplishments in science and techno
both had extensive markets. Eighteenth century China and Japan had agr
tural productivity and standards of living equal or greater than that of con
porary European nations. As to excesses of population, Japan clearly contr
its population, as (we now know) did China; the vast "overpopulation" of
sical Asia is an anachronism from the late nineteenth and early twentieth
turies.60) Government regulation and interference in the economy were m
in Asia, for the simple reason that most economic activity took place in
markets run by merchants and local communities, and was beyond the rea
the limited government bureaucracies of advanced organic societies to reg
in detail. Cultural conservatism did keep economic activities in these soc
on familiar paths, but those paths allowed considerable incremental inno
tion and long-term economic growth.61) Although neither hypothesis now
empirically solid, for a long time, Europe's development was seen as "norm
and non-Europe as pathologically "stagnant" or "blocked."
BIBLIOGRAPHY
Abu-Lughod, Janet
1989 Before European Hegemony: The World System, A.D. 1250-1350
Oxford University Press).
Arjomand, Said
1984 The Shadow of God and the Hidden Imam (Chicago: University o
Press).
Baker, Keith, ed.
1987 The French Revolution and the Creation of Modern Political Culture. 2 vols.
(Oxford: Pergamon Press).
Beloff, May
1962 The Age of Absolutism, 1660-1815 (New York: Harper & Row).
Bentley, Jerry
1996 "Cross-Cultural Interaction and Periodicization in World History." American
Historical Review 101: 749-770.
Berg, Maxine
1985 The Age of Manufactures, 1700-1820 (London: Fontana Press).
Bix, H.
1986 Peasant Protest in Japan, 1590-1884 (New Haven: Yale University Press)
Brady, Thomas A.
1991 "The Rise of Merchant Empires, 1400-1700: A European Counterpoint
James Tracy, ed. The Political Economy of Merchant Empires (Cambrid
Cambridge University Press), pp. 117-160.
Brenner, Reuven
1983 History: The Human Gamble (Chicago: University of Chicago Press).
Brotton, Jerry
1998 Trading Territories: Mapping the Early Modern World (Ithaca, N.Y.: Co
University Press).
Christie, Jan Wisseman
1998 "Javanese Markets and the Asian sea Trade Boom of the Tenth to Thirteenth
Centuries A.D." JESHO 41.3: 344-381.
Cook, Westin
1994 The Hundred Years' War for Morocco: Gunpowder and the Military Re
in the Early Modern Muslim World (Boulder, CO: Westview Press).
Copplestone, Trewin
1985 Modern Art (New York: Exeter Books).
Coward, Barry
1988 Social Change and Continuity in Early Modern England 1550-1750 (London:
Longman).
Curtin, Philip D.
1984 Cross-Cultural Trade in World History (Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press).
DeVries, Jan
1974 The Dutch Economy in the Golden
versity Press).
Diehl, Charles
1957 Byzantium: Greatness and Decline (New Brunswick: Rutgers University Press).
Doyle, William
1990 The Oxford History of the French Revolution (New York: Oxford University
Press).
Eisenstadt, S.N., ed.
1986 The Origins and Diversity of Axial Age Civilizations (Albany, N.Y.: State Uni-
versity of New York Press).
Elvin, Mark
1973 The Pattern of the Chinese Past (Stanford: Stanford University Press).
1996 "Skills and Resources in Late Traditional China." In M. Elvin, Another History:
Essays on China from a European Perspective (Sydney: University of Sydney
East Asian Series No. 10, published by Wild Peony Press), pp. 64-100.
Eyre, Christopher J.
1997 "Peasants and 'Modern' Leasing Strategies in Ancient Egypt." JESHO 40.4:
367-390.
Fairbank, J.K. and Edwin O. Reischauer
1989 China: Tradition and Transformation (Boston: Houghton-Mifflin).
Feuerwerker, Albert
1992 "Presidential Address." Journal of Asian Studies 51.4: 757-769.
Forrest, W.G.
1966 The Emergence of Greek Democracy 800-400 B.C. (New York: McGraw-Hill).
Frank, Andre Gunder
1998 Re-Orient: The Silver Age in Asia and the World Economy (Berkeley: University
of California Press).
Fu Chu-fu and Li Ching-neng
1956 The Sprouts of Capitalistic Factors within China's Feudal Society (Program in East
Asian Studies, Western Washington State University, Occasional Paper no. 7).
Furet, Frangois
1981 Interpreting the French Revolution. Translated by E. Forster. (Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press).
Goldstone, Jack A.
1987 "Cultural Orthodoxy, Risk, and Innovation: The Divergence of East and West
in the Early Modern World." Sociological Theory 5: 119-135.
1991 Revolution and Rebellion in the Early Modern World (Berkeley: University of
California Press).
1996 "Gender, Work, and Culture: Why the Industrial Revolution came Early to
England but Late to China." Sociological Perspectives 39.1: 1-21.
Greene, Jack, and J.R. Pole
1987 Colonial British America: Essays in the New History of the Early Modern Era
(Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press).
Hall, John A.
1985 Powers and Liberties: The Causes and Consequences of the Rise of the West
(Berkeley: University of California Press).
Hanley, Susan
1983 "A High Standard of Living in Nineteenth Century Japan: Fact or Fantasy?"
Journal of Economic History 43: 183-192.
Hanley, Susan and K. Yamamura
1977 Economic and Demographic Change in Preindustrial Japan 1600-1868
(Princeton: Princeton University Press).
Hartwell, Robert
1962 "A Revolution in the Chinese Iron and Coal Industries During the
Sung, 960-1126." Journal of Asian Studies 21.1: 153-162.
1966 "Markets, Technology, and the Structure of Enterprise in the Dev
the Eleventh Century Chinese Iron and Steel Industry." Journal of Econom
26: 29-58.
Hazard, Paul
1963 The European Mind (1680-1715). Translated by J.L. May (London: Hollis a
Carter).
Hill, Christopher
1961 The Century of Revolution, 1603-1714 (New York: Norton).
Hilton, R.H.
1990 Class Conflict and the Crisis of Feudalism: Essays in Medieval Social History.
Rev. 2nd ed. (London: Verso).
Hirst, Derek
1986 Authority and Conflict: England 1603-1658 (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard Uni-
versity Press).
Ho, Ping-ti
1967 "The Significance of the Ch'ing Period in Chinese History." Journal of Asian
Studies 26: 189-196.
Hobsbawm, Eric
1962 The Age of Revolution, 1789-1848 (New York: Mentor Books).
Hodgson, Marshall G.S.
1974 The Venture of Islam, vol. III: The Gunpowder Empires and Modern Time
(Chicago: University of Chicago Press).
Huang, Philip
1985 The Peasant Economy and Social Change in North China (Stanford: Stanfor
University Press).
1990 The Peasant Family and Rural Development in the Lower Yangzi Region, 135
1988 (Stanford: Stanford University Press).
Huang, Ray
1981 1587, A Year of No Significance: The Ming Dynasty in Decline (New Haven:
Yale University Press).
Hunt, Lynn
1984 Politics, Culture, and Class in the French Revolution (Berkeley: University of
California Press).
Jones, Eric L.
1981 The European Miracle (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).
Karpat, Kemal
1974 "The Stages of Ottoman History: A Structural-Comparative Approach." In
K. Karpat, ed., The Ottoman State and Its Place in World History (Leiden: E.J.
Brill) pp. 79-98.
Kirby, D.G.
1990 Northern Europe in the Early Modern Period (London: Longman).
Kishlansky, Mark
1986 Parliamentary Selection (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).
1996 A Monarchy Transformed: Britain, 1603-1714 (London: Allen Lane).
Kriedte, Peter, Hans Medick, Jurgen Schlumbohm, with Herbert Kisch and Franklin Mendels
1981 Industrialization before Industrialization: Rural Industry in the Genesis of Capi-
talism (New York: Cambridge University Press).
Kunt, Metin and Christie Woodhead
1994 Suleyman the Magnificent and his Age: Ottoman History in the Early Modern
World (London: Longman).
Landes, David S.
1969 Prometheus Unbound (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).
1983 Revolution in Time: Clocks and the Making of the Modern World (Cambridge,
Mass.: Belknap Press of Harvard University Press).
Lee, James and Wang Feng
1997 Malthusian Mythology and Chinese Reality: The Population History of One Quar-
ter of Humanity 1700-2000. Unpublished ms, California Institute of Technology.
Liu, Kwang-Ching
1990 Orthodoxy in Late Imperial China (Berkeley: University of California Press).
McClain, J.L., J.M. Merriman, and U. Kaoru, eds.
1994 Edo and Paris: Urban Life and the State in the Early Modern Era (Ithaca,
N.Y.: Cornell University Press).
McNeill, William
1982 The Pursuit of Power (Chicago: University of Chicago Press).
Marx, Karl and Friedrich Engels
1967 The Communist Manifesto (Hammondsworth, U.K.: Penguin Books).
Mokyr, Joel
1976 Industrialization in the Low Countries 1795-1850 (New Haven: Yale University
Press).
1985 "The Industrial Revolution and the New Economic History." In Joel Mokyr,
ed., The Economics of the Industrial Revolution (Totowa, NJ: Rowman and
Allanheld), pp. 1-52.
1990 The Lever of Riches (New York: Oxford University Press).
Needham, Joseph
1954- Science and Civilisation in China (New York: Cambridge University Press).
Nef, J.U.
1932 The Rise of the British Coal Industry (London: Routledge).
North, Douglas
1990 Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance (New York:
Cambridge).
Owens, J.B.
1997 "Castilian Monarchical Authority and Urban Patrician Power." Proceedings of
the American Historical Association, 1997 (Ann Arbor, MI: University Microfilms).
Parker, Geoffrey
1988 The Military Revolution: Military Innovation and the Rise of the West, 1500-
1800 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).
1991 "Europe and the Wider World, 1500-1750; the Military Balance." In James D.
Tracy, ed. The Political Economy of Merchant Empires (Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press), pp. 161-195.
Parsons, Talcott
1937 The Structure of Social Action (New York: Free Press).
1977 The Evolution of Societies (Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall).
Pomeranz, Kenneth
1993 The Making of a Hinterland: State, Society, and Economy in Inland North
China, 1853-1937 (Berkeley: University of California Press).
Reid, Anthony
1993 Southeast Asia in the Early Modern Era: Trade, Power and Belief (Ithaca,
N.Y.: Cornell University Press).
Ropp, Paul
1981 Dissent in Early Modern China (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press).
Rosenberg, Nathan, and L.E. Birdzell
1986 How the West Grew Rich (New York: Basic Books).
Runciman, Steven
1956 Byzantine Civilization (Cleveland: Meridian Books, World Publishing
Russell, Conrad
1990 The Causes of the English Civil War (New York: Oxford University
Said, Edward
1978 Orientalism (London: Routledge and Kegan Paul).
Schwartz, Stuart, ed.
1994 Implicit Understandings: Observing, Reporting, and Reflection
counters between Europeans and other Peoples in the Early Mod
(Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).
Smil, Vaclav
1994 Energy in World History (Boulder, Colo.: Westview Press).
Soboul, Albert
1975 The French Revolution, 1789-1799: From the Storming of the B
Napoleon. Translated by A. Forrest and C. Jones. (New York: Vinta
Subrahmanyam, Sanjay
1990 Merchants, Markets, and the State in Early Modern India (Delhi
University Press).
Swift, Jonathan
1909 The Battle of the Books (London: Cassell).
Thompson, E.P.
1963 The Making of the English Working Class (New York: Pantheon B
Tocqueville, Alexis de
1955 The Old Regime and the French Revolution. Translated by S. Gil
York: Doubleday).
Totman, Conrad
1989 The Green Archipelago: Forestry in preindustrial Japan (Berkeley:
of California Press).
1993 Early Modern Japan (Berkeley: University of California Press).
Tracy, James D.
1976 Early Modern European History 1500-1715: A Bibliography of Se
Literature. Unpublished ms.
Tsukahira, T.G.
1970 Feudal Control in Tokugawa Japan (Cambridge, Mass.: East Asian
Center, Harvard University Press).
Veenhof, Klaas
1997 "'Modern' Features on Old Assyrian Trade." JESHO 40.4: 336-366
Vlastos, S.
1986 Peasant Protests and Uprisings in Tokugawa Japan (Berkeley: Un
California Press).
Wallerstein, Immanuel
1980 The Modern World System, vol. 2: Mercantilism and the Consolida
European World Economy, 1600-1750 (New York: Academic Press).
Washbrook, David
1997 "From Comparative Sociology to Global History: Britain and India
History of Modernity." JESHO 40.4: 410-443.
Wee, Herman van der
1993 The Low Countries in the Early Modern World (Brookfield, VT: Va
Wigen, Karen
1995 "Bringing the World Back In: Meditations on the Space-Time of Japanese Early
Modernity." Research Papers in Asian/Pacific Studies. (Durham, NC: Asian/
Pacific Studies Institute, Duke University).
Wong, R. Bin.
1994 "Dimensions of State Expansion an
37.1: 54-66.
Wrigley, E.A.
1988 Continuity, Chance, and Change: The Character of the Industrial Revolution i
England (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).
Yoffee, Norman
1995 "Political Economy in Early Mesopotamian States." Annual Review of Anthro-
pology 24: 281-311.
Zilfi, Madeline C., ed.
1997 Women in the Ottoman Empire: Middle Eastern Women in the Early Modern
Era (Leiden: Brill).
Zurndorfer, Harriet
1997a "China and 'Modernity': The Uses of the Study of Chinese History in the Pas
and the Present." JESHO 40.4: 461-485.
1997b "From Local History to Cultural History: Reflections on Some Recent Pub
lications." T'oung Pao 83: 386-424.