Marketing of Agricultural Products: Rich Ar D L. K 0 HLS
Marketing of Agricultural Products: Rich Ar D L. K 0 HLS
Agricultural Products
RIC H A R D L. K 0 H L S, P II , D ,
PURDUE UNIVERSITY
A8GR \L
r J CCntral LI'b '
I aI'\,
HYdcrab:lCl '
G947
1/lIII/!11!I/lIIIIIiillllllllJ
FIRST PRINTING
MY GRANDPARENTS-
TO WHOM lOWE MY INTEREST
IN AGRICULTURE
PREFACE
4. Agricultural Production 49
The Production Plant: The Production Unit. Characteristics of the Prod-
uct: A Raw ;l,Iaterial; Bulky and Perishable Products. Characteristics of
Production: Total Output; Annual Variability in Production; Seasonal
Variability in Production; Quality Variation; Areas of Production; Adjust-
ment of Production to Changing Conditions.
8. Agricultural Prices
Agricultural and Nonagricultural Prices. Individual Commodity Prices:
Nature of Supply and Demand; Cyclical Price Fluctuaticns; Seasonal Price
Fluctuations.
..,../
10. Standardization and Grading
Importance of Standardization: 'Weights, Measures, and Containers; Quality;
Early History of Standards; Advantages of Standardization. Determina-
tion of Standards; Objective of Ideal Standards; Criteria for Good Stand-
ards. Problems of Agricultural Standardization: Lad: of Relationship
Between Price and Quality; Determining Consumer Preference; I\leasuring
Grade Factors; Determining the Limits of Grade; Quality Deterioration;
Health Regulations and Quality Standards. Farm Selling on a Graded
Basis. Place of Govemmel.~ in Standardization. The Consumer and Grad-
ing. The \Vholesale Trade and Grading.
12. Transportation
\Vho Does the Job? Trucking to Initial Markets; Trucking to Terminal
Markets; Rail Transportation; \Vater Transportation; Air Transportation.
Freight Rates: The Freight Rate Structure; :t\Iaking of Rail Freight Rates;
Freight Charges and Agricultural Prices. Reduction of Transportation
Costs: Rates and Methods of Transportation; Other Approaches to Cost
Reduction; The Transportation Bill Will Remain High.
13. Storage
Storage Operations: Seasonal Production and Storage; \Vhere Commodities
are Stored; Public \Varehouse Supervision. Costs of Storage. "'ho Should
Store? Reducing Storage Costs. Storage and Seasonal Price Variations.
INDEX
Part I
THE FRAMEWORK
OF THE
MARKETING PROBLEM
CHAPTER ONE
WHAT IS MARKETING?
Have you ever watched a housewife shop in a modern supermarket? As she
pushes her cart down the aisles, she casually picks and chooses from among
literally hundreds of different canned items. She may stop at the dairy case
and select her cheeses from among dozens of different varieties. At the meat
counter she must decide not only between the various cuts of fresh meat but
also from a tremendous array of all types of luncheon and precooked meats.
Continuing on, she may pick up a can of frozen orange juice and a carton of
frozen shrimp from the deep freeze cabinet. At another rack she may be
faced with perhaps hventy to thirty different kinds of fresh produce. On her
way out she may pick up a loaf of bread which was baked just today. Or she
may decide that she wants to do her own baking and can choose between
either ready-for-baking biscuits packed in a vacuum tin or a box which con-
tains all of the dry ingredients ready for mixing.
Then listen to this housewife at the check-out counter. She makes no
comment concerning the tremendous variety of goods at her disposal.
Rather, she is more likely to make some bitter remark about her favorite
brand of frozen peas being out of stock! Then, with perhaps a parting
remark about the high cost of food, she pays her bill and departs. This
scene could be one in Ne\v Yark City or in a small middle western town.
It could be happening in the heat of the summer or the cold of the
winter.
Here we see the end product-goods available for consumption-of the
tremendou:; marketing organization of the country. Here also, in the house-
wife's casual acceptance of this vast array of foods at her disposal, we have
t11e vote of confidence of the American consumer that the system \varks.
3
4 MARKETING OF AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS
Marketing Is Productive
Unfortunately many look upon those who are engaged in the many
marketing jobs such as grading, transporting, storing, arranging for the
transfer of title, and advancing and collecting credit, as being parasitic on
those who really "produce" the goods. Farmers often decry the "profits of
middlemen" because they think that farmers alone produce the food which
people eat. Of course, we realize that they produce only the raw materials
from which the consumer's food is finally made. The farmer who produces
a hog in Iowa has not produced pork for a housewife in New York. Many
things must be done to the hog before it is pork in New York. These other
The Marketing Problem 5
activities are the contributions which the packers, railroads, truckers, live-
stock commission men, and retail butchers make to pork production.
i Economists have defined production as the creation of utility-that
is, 'the process of making useful goods and services. The utilities created in
the productive processes are further classified into form utility, place utility,
time utility, and possession utility.
The farmer who produces "hogs adds form utility. The packer who
slaughters the hogs and cuts them into pork carcasses also adds form utility.
They change the form of raw materials and create something usefu1.
The railroad or trucker that moves the hogs from Iowa to the packing
plant, and then, after processing, moves the cuts of pork on to wholesalers,
retailers, and finally to consumers adds place utility. The product is more
useful because of the activities of these agencies in getting the product to
where it is most desired.
The packer furthermore may freeze some of the pork products for later
use. The pork is more useful by being held from periods of relative plenty
to periods of relative scarcity. Time utility is added to the product. Grain
elevator and warehouse operators and even the previously mentioned super-
ma,rket operator through his inventory holdings add time utility to products.
'"When the Iowa hogs are shipped to the terminal markets they prob-
ably ~re consigned to a commission man. This commission man seeks out a
packer who needs the hogs and helps transfer the hogs from the farmer to
the packer. A meat wholesaler facilitates the movement of meat to the
retailer for distribution to the final consumers. These people through their
efforts to transfer the product to those who could better use it add posses-
sion utility. Because of these actions the product is placed in the hands of
others who can add still other utilities to it.
Most people accept the activities of the farmer and the manufacturer
as being productive. They create visible changes in products. However, the
other individuals who see that the product is moved through the various
handlers, is sent to the needed place, and is available at the needed time
also are productive. All of their activities are necessary to produce the final
utility that the pork has for the New York housewife in feeding her family.
So those engaged in the marketing process, too, are producers in the sense
that they add usefulness or utility. To argue which group is more important
is rather senseless. Both groups, the producers of raw products and the mar-
keting agencies, are necessary to the creation of the final products for con-
sumption. Both create something useful for which society will pay a price.
Both groups are productive in the real sense of the word. Confusion arises
largely because of the different form of the output which stems from their
a:tivity. It is common practice to resen'e the term "producer" for those
6 MARKETING OF AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS
who are primarily engaged in the creation of form utility. \Ve, too, will
follow this practice. This, of course, does not mean that the other groups
are not productive.
Growth of Marketing
rvIarketing has developed in importance and complexity as specialization
of activities has increasingly separated producers of goods from the potential
consumers of those goods. The early pioneers of our country did not have to
concern themselves with marketing problems. Each family grew its own
food and fiber and built its own shelter. Producers and consumers, if not
actually the same individuals, lived next door to each other.
Very early in the development of any community, however, people
realized that some were better adapted to certain kinds of activities than
others. Thus, they specialized in their work. This specialization increased
the output of goods but it also broke down the self-sufficiency of the family
unit. As different people specialized in different activities, methods had to
be devised to exchange the surplus production for other desired goods which
other specialized workers produced. Here, then, was the beginning of the
marketing task and the group of people who specialized in its performance.
Another aspect of specialization is the growth of urban areas. 'Nith the
disappearance of the necessity of a man to produce all his basic needs, he is
able to leave the land and congregate in larger groups. Here his work may be
carried on more efficiently, and the remaining people on the farms can
more efficiently produce his food and fiber. Of course, this increasing urbani-
zation further complicates the task of those engaged in the marketing
process.
One of the limiting factors to the urbanization of our country has been
the development of adequate transportation and communication facilities.
Throughout most of our early history, one of the pressing agricultural
marketing problems was that of providing adequate transportation facilities
at a reasonable cost to move the increasing output of our farms to the
consumers in our growing cities. Here we find an early in~erest of govern-
ment in helping the marl:nting system function adequately. First turnpikes,
then canals, and then railroads were subsidized through government help.
This public concern has continued even to the present day as various gov-
ernmental units have actively pushed both highway and air transport de-
velopment.
]'vIarketing and mass production techniques have moved hand in hand.
A complex and costly marketing machinery is not necessary in situations
where the volume of production is limited. On the other hand, assembly
line mass production is not feasible until the marketing machinery opens
The Marketing Problem 7
the doors to the broad mass market. Many people have viewed with alarm
the impersonal relationships of our huge factories, the growing proportion
of our population living in cities, and the increasing numbers who are en-
gaged in the marketing trades and services. Such developments, however,
are usually the marks of the more productive countries with increasing
standards of living. It is the countries which are hovering near the subsist-
ence levels of living which have a relatively small proportion of their people
engaged in the job of marketing.
Table I shows the proportion of our working population employed in
the various areas. In 1950 over half were engaged in lines other than manu-
facturing and in the working of our land and natural resources. This was
a substantially larger proportion of our people than were so occupied fifty
years ago. As one views this fifty-year period, certainly he cannot conclude
we are now poorer in the good things of life. We have many problems, to
be sure! But certainly we cannot conclude that this increased portion of
our people working in the trades and services has been associated with a
declining standard of living.
APPROXIMATE PERCENT OF
OCCUPATION OR INDUSTRY TOTAL GAINFULLY EMPLOYED
rVlanufacturing 3:!
Trade, transportation, public utilities 34
Domestic, professional, public service 20
Forestry and mining 2 2
Agriculture 37 12
SOURCE: U. S. Census (differences in 1900 and 1950 data permit only approxi.
mations) .
Marketing Defined
As we have seen, marketing is essentially the production of time, plac;:e,
and possession utilities. vVith this in mind, then, marketing can be defined
as the performance of business activities that direct the flow of goods and
services from the producer to the consumer so as to reach the consumer at
the time, place, and in the form he desires at a price he is willing to pay.
In a society organized on a competitive framework such as ours, the final
consumer is the ultimate director of the process. The end product of all
productive processes is consumption. Each individual person who is engaged.
in marketing is interested in maximizing his own individual gain. However,
in a very real sense in the long run, he who serves the consumer best
plu£its most.
8 MARKETING OF AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS
Marketing Efficiency
Nearly all changes which are proposed are based upon the grounds of
increased efficiency or lower costs. Those who oppose these changes base
their opposition on the assumption that the change will decrease efficiency
The Marketing Problem 9
of farms increased from about 1.5 millions to 4 millions during the same
period. Outlets for this potential production bonanza had to be found in
both our own growing cities and in foreign countries.
About this time many of the large food industries were established.
In 1865, the Union Stockyards at Chicago were formed and soon were the
largest in the world. The Chicago Board of Trade was founded in 1848
and quickly developed into the nation's leading grain market. By 1870, ice
was being used to preserve meat, and by 1880 the use of the refrigerated
railroad car made the large national packers possible. In 1870, there were
only a few flour mills at r·vlinneapolis. By the late 1880'S, Minneapolis was
the milling center of the country, and the pattern of organization for the
modern giant milling and grain corporations was established. With the
introduction of tin cans and other canning equipment in 1880, large-scale
canning of fruits and vegetables got underway. The development of ciga-
rette-making machines in the 1880'S helped make possible the growth of
huge companies in the tobacco industry.
'Vhile these changes were occurring, transportation also expanded
tremendously. During the decade of the 1870'S, the mileage of railroads
almost doubled. The two coasts were joined and transcontinental shipments
became possible. Telegraph communications were rapidly expanded. Exten-
sive highway development, how~ver, was to await the automobile.
This was a turbulent period_The extraordinary expansion of the farm
production plant made suddenly available vast amounts of agricultural raw
materials. The many technological developments made possible the rapid
growth of a great number of processing firms. The marketing system was
put under great pressures to move this productive capacity into the hands
of consumers. The rapid growth of the food processing firms and their
search for outlets led to cries of monopoly and unethical practices. To this
situation was added a seve~e agricultural price depression during much of
the l~tter part of the century.
Farmers organized to --protest these situations. Railroads were bitterly
attacked for charging exorbitant and unfair rates. In 1889, one of the farm
organizations, the Farmer's Alliance, demanded government O\vnership of
the means of communication and transportation in order to correct alleged
abuses. Bitter attacks were made on the alleged evils of the middlemen.
Congressional investigations of the practices of the meat packing and other
companies were instigated. Demands were made for all kinds of corrective
and regulative measures. The immediate result of this agitation was federal
regulatory action. The Act to Regulate Commerce which, among other
things, authorized the Interstate Commerce Commission and the surveil-
hnce of interstate freight rates, was passed in 1887. In 1890, the passage
12 MARKETING OF AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS
of the Sherman Act laid the basis for our antimonopoly policies and made
private business activities a matter of public concern.
'Vith an improvement in general economic conditions, the tension
eased. And in the ensuing years until 'Vorld \Var I, the marketing system
was allowed time to grow up to its job. Agricultural production continued
to expand, but there were no upheavals of the cxtent of the post-Civil 'Var
period. This period was one of changing emphasis in marketing. Previously,
much of the effort of those working in agricultural marketing had been
directed toward developing foreign markets for our exportable surplus. Now
the emphasis was shifted toward developing the domestic outlets of our
growing country. Recognition of this changing emphasis came in 1908,
when the name of the Division of Foreign I'vIarkets in the USDA was
changed to the Division of Production and Distribution. In 1914, Congress
officially set up the Office of Markets to collect and disseminate information
concerning the marketing of farm products.
After World War I, the attitude toward agricultural marketing took a
still different perspective. It now appeared as if our production capacities
had outrun our consumption capabilities. Throughout the twenties, many
schemes were proposed to permit us to dump our excess production abroad.
Domestically, however, improvement in the marketing machinery was to be
the answer. Governmental blessings were given the cooperative movement
as one way for mOre effective and orderly marketing. Such regulatory laws
as the Packers and Stockyards Act and the Commodity Exchange Act were
passed to prevent abusive practices by the marketing agencies. Increased
marketing efficiency was the goal.
The depression decade of the 1930'S further increased the troubles of
moving the products of agriculture into consumption at satisfactory prices.
Attention was nOW turned away from marketing to production. Develop-
ments in the marketing area could not solve the problem. We simply pro-
duced too much. Public attention was now directed toward perfecting
various schemes which would reduce the amount of production.
With the demands of World War II, however, efforts were made to
produce all that our reSOl'Tces would permit. After the war-time demands
had receded, the marketing machinery again came in for increasing public
attention and criticism. There is now widespread belief that improvements
in production have outdistanced improvements in marketing. \Vays have
been found to make two blades of grass grow where one did before, but
no way has been found effectively to market the extra blade. The feeling
is that all that can be produced can be consumed at satisfactory prices jf
the marketing system is functioning well.
The current scene again is one of far-reaching changes in almost every
The Marketing Problem 13
phase of marketing. The technique of quick-freezing foods may revolution-
ize part of the food industry as much as the successful use of tin cans did
in the 1880'S. More and more processing is being done by the food indus-
try-less and less by the housewife. By 1948, more than a fourth of the
total consumer food purchases was in the form of completely or partially
prepared and ready-to-eat foods. The retail food industry has been drasti-
cally changed. By 1952, nearly half of the food was sold through self-service
supermarkets which were only in the experimental stages before World
\Var II. The emphasis has been on the mechanization or the distribution
system in §_uch a way as to reduce labor costs which have been proportion-
ately very high.
If the reader wiII stop and think of the changes which have occurred
in the decade of the 1940'S, he must conclude that we are again experienc-
ing revolutionary changes. The increasing concentration of population in
the urban areas and the increasing specialization of production have put a
still greater premium on a smooth-working and efficient marketing system.
Improved transportation and communication systems have changed most
marketing problems from ones of local or regional concern to those national
in scope. In 1946, Congress officially gave recognition to this new emphasis
on marketing when it passed the Research and Marketing Act. Under this
Act, additional funds for expanding research into all phases of marketing
were authorized. Once again the American people have thrown the chal-
lenge to those engaged in marketi~g~.
1. 'Vhat to produce. For example, some fruit varieties are more desired
than others. Some hog types wiII produce a more consumer-desired pork
than o~hers. Farmers who know these market desires can adjust their
production accordingly.
1 F. L. Thomsen, Agricultural Marketing (New York, McGraw-Hili, 1951), p. 4.
MARKETING OF AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS
Also, familiarity with marketing may help farmers make wiser decisions
as members of a group. Should a cooperative be formed to help do a market-
ing job? \\That part should government play in control and regulation?
\\That position should be taken toward a new method or development? A
broad knowledge of the objectives, organization, and operation of market-
ing is needed to judge wisely the proper actions which need to be taken.
These are just a few of the contributions which a knowledge of market-
ing can make toward more profitable farming. The objective of production
from the producer's standpoint is profit. And profit is not realized until the
product is sold. Coordination of those activities which occur within as well
as those which occur outside the farm fence is necessary for maximum
returns.
SELECTED REFERENCES
Agnew, H. E., H. A. Conner, and \V. L. Doremus, Outlines of !vIarketing, 3rd
ed. (New York, l'vIcGraw-Hill, 1950), Chap. l.
Black, John D., Introduction to Economics for Agriculture (New York, :tvIac-
millan, 1953), Chap. 2l.
Hotchkiss, G. B'., Milestones of Marketing (New York, :tVIacmillan, 1938).
Taylor, H. C., and Anne D. Taylor, The Story of Agricultural Economics in the
United States, 1840-1932 (Ames, Iowa State College Press, 1952), Parts 1
and 5.
Vaile, R. S., E. T. Grether, and Reaves Cox, iHarketing in the American
Economy (New York, Ronald Press, 1952), Chap. 32.
\Villiamson, Harold F., The Growth of the American Economy (New York,
Prentice-Hall, 1944)'
CHAPTER TWO
The difference between an orderly closet in which one can find what is
desired with a minimum of effort and a disorderly one in which nothing
can be easily found can often be traced to an adequate system of hooks,
hangers, and shelves. The study of a complex marketing problem can be
as frustrating as looking for a special item in the disorderly closet unless a
system of hooks and shelves is devised on which we can organize our
thoughts and ideas. It is to these organization devices that we now give our
attention.
out through the many wholesalers and retailers into the hands of con-
sumers. These activities make up the process of dispersion:
Perhaps the nature of these processes will be clearer if we follow a
commodity from its initia1 production through to its final consumption.
For example, let us examine these processes as they occur in the marketing
of wheat. Wheat is produced in amounts ranging from a few bushels to
thousands of bushels on thousands of farms scattered throughout the coun-
try. Farmers sell their wheat to country elevators. The elevators usually wait
until they have accumulated considerable volume and then ship the wheat
forward by the carload to larger terminal elevators, which are capable of
holding hundreds of thousand of bushels, located in our larger milling cen-
ters. This has been the concentration process-wheat has gradually been
assembled from widely scattered production points into large holdings
centrally located.
It will now remain in storage until it is needed by mi11ers. Or evcn
after milling, the flour may be stored for a short time. These activities are
part of the equalization process. Then the flour may be shipped in varying
quantities to bakers. Here, after baking, the bread will be sold to retailers.
These retailers will then sell the bread, loaf by loaf, to consumers. This
gradual breaking down into smaller and smaller units is dispersion. How-
ever, during this dispersion process equa1ization a1so was continuing as
some flour was probably held in stock by bakers and to a limited extent
so was some bread.
APPROACHES TO
MARKETING PROBLEMS
There are three major approaches to the analysis of marketing prob-
lems. These are ·the functional approach, the institutional approach, and
the commodity approach. All three are merely ways of breaking down a
complex marketing problem into its parts so that it can be better under-
stood.
A. Exchange Functions
1. Buying (assembling)
2. Selling
B. Physical Functions
3. Storage
4- Transportation
C. Facilitating Functions
5. Standardization
6. Financing
7. Risk-bearing
8. Ivfarket information
The exchange functions are those activities which are involved in the
transfer of title to goods. They represent the point at which the study of
price determination enters into the study of marketing. These functions are
never performed in our economy without a judgment of value, usually ex-
pressed at least partially as a price, being placed on the goods. Both the
buying and selling functions have as their primary objective the negotiation
of favorable terms of exchange.
The buying function is largely one of seeking out the sources of supply,
assembling of products, and the activities which are associated with pur-
chase. This can either be the assembling of the raw products from the
production areas or the assembling of finished products into the hands of
other middlemen in order to meet the demand'S of the ultimate consumer.
The selling function must be broadly interpreted. It is more than
merely passively accepting the price offered. In this function can be grouped
all of the various activities which sometimes are called merchandising. Most
of the physical arrangements of display of goods are grouped here. Adver-
tising and other promotional devices to influence or create demands are
also part of the selling function. The decision as to the proper unit of sale,
2 See, for example: P. D. Converse and H. \V. Huegy, The Elements of Marketing,
3rd ed. (New York, Prentice-Hall, 1946), p. 56; E. D. l\[CCurry, "Some Functions of
:t-.Iarketing Reconsidered," Theory in 'tIJarketing, ed. R. Cox and \V. Alderson (Chicago,
Richard D. Irwin, 1950), pp. 263-279.
Analyzing Marketing Problems 19
the proper packages, the best marketing channel, the proper time and place
to approach potential buyers-all are decisions which can be included in the
selling function. Here also might fall the market research activities which
are undertaken primarily to ascertain where an article can be sold and how
much will be taken.
The physical functions are those activities which involve handling and
movement of the actual comI~odity itself. They are involved in solving the
problems of when and where in marketing.
The storage function is primarily concerned with making goods avail-
able at the desired time. It may be the activities of elevators in holding
large quantities of raw materials until they are needed for further processing.
It may be the holding of supplies of finished goods as the inventories of
processors, wholesalers, and retailers.
The transportation function is primarily concerned with making goods
available at the proper place. Adequate performance of this function re-
quires the weighing of alternatives of routes and types of transportation as
they might affect transportation costs. It also includes the activities in-
volved in preparation for shipment such as crating and loading.
The facilitating functions are those which make possible the smooth
performance of the exchange and physical functions. These activities are
not directly involved in either the exchange of title or in the physical
handling of products. However, without them the modern marketing sys-
tem would not be possible. They might aptly be called the grease that makes
the wheels of the marketing machine go round.
The standardization function is the establishment and maintenance of
uniform measurements. These may be measurements of both quality and
quantity. This function simplifies buying and selling, since it makes the sale
by sample and description possible. It, therefore, is one of the activities
which makes possible mass selling, which is so important to a complex
economy. Effective standardization is basic to an efficient pricing process.
A consumer-directed system assumes that the consumer will make his wants
known largely through price differentials. These differentials must then be
passed back through the marketing channel so that marketing agencies and
producers can know what is wante_d. Only if a commodity is traded in well-
defined units of quality and quantity can a price quotation do this job effec-
tively. Standardization also simplifies the concentration process, since it per-
mits the grouping of similar lots of commodities early in movement from the
producing points. Besides their establishment, the use of standards must be
policed. Such :}ctivities as quality control in processing plants and inspec-
tions to maintain the standards in the marketing channel can be considered
part of this function.
20 MARKETING OF AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS
for new products, may be classified as part of the broad function of market
information. As with other functions, this function may be performed by
those who specialize in its performance. On the other hand, everyone in the
marketing structure who buys and sells products evaluates available market
data and therefore performs this function to some degree.
A. Merchant Middlemen
1. Retailers
2. \Vholesalers
3 The definitions that follow are substantially those as reported by the American
Marketing Association, Definitions Committee, Journal of Marketing, October, 1948,
p.211.
Analyzing Marketing Problems 23
B. Agent Middlemen
1. Brokers
2. Commission men
C. Speculative Middlemen
D. Facilitative Organizations
Merchant middlemen take title to, and therefore own, the products
they handle. They buy and selI for their own gain. The retailer buys prod-
ucts for resale directly to the ultimate consumer of the goods. He is the
producers' personal representative to the consumer. As such, his job is very
complex. From the functional viewpoint, the retailer may perform all of the
marketing functions. This group of middlemen, consisting of about 500,000
units, is the most numerous of the marketing agencies.
The wholesaler sells to retailers, other wholesalers, and industrial users,
but does not seH in significant amounts to ultimate consumers. \Vholesalers
make up a highly heterogeneous group of varying sizes and characteristics.
One of the more numerous groups of wholesalers (about 18,000 in 1948)
are the local buyers or country assemblers who buy goods in the producing
area directly from farmers and ship the products forward to the larger cities
where they are sold to other wholesalers and processors. In this group are
such agencies as grain elevators, poultry and egg buyers, and local livestock
buyers. Another group of wholesalers is located in the larger urban centers.
These may be "full-line" wholesalers who handle many different products
or those which specialize in handling a limited number of products. They
may be cash-and-carry wholesalers or service wholesalers who will extend
credit and offer delivery and other services. Such terms as "jobbers" and
"car-lot receivers" are often used synonymously with "wholesalers." In 1948,
there were approximately 31,000 merchant wholesalers of agricultural com-
modities (apart from country assemblers) and grocery products.
Agent middlemen, as the name implies, act only as representatives of
their clients. They do not take title to, and therefore do not own, the
products they handle. "'hile merchant wholesalers and retailers secure their
incomes from a margin between the buying and sel1ing prices, agent middle-
men receive their incomes in the form of fees and commissions. Agent
middlemen in reality sell services to their principals, not physical goods to
customers. In 1948, there were approximately 24,000 which could be classi-
fied as agent middlemen. In many instances, the principal stock in trade of
the agent middlemen is market knowledge and "know-how" which he uses
in bringing the buyer and seHer together. Their services are often retained
by a buyer or scHer of goods \vho feels that he does not have the knowledge
or opportunity to bargain effectively for himself.
Though the names may differ somewhat, agent middlemen can be
MARKETING OF AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS
broken down into two major groups, commission men and brokers. The
difference between these two types of agent middlemen is largely one of
degree. The commission man is usually granted broad powers by those who
consign goods to him. He normally takes over the physical handling of the
product, arranges for the terms of sale, collects, deducts his fee, and remits
the balance to his principal. The broker, on the other hand, usually does
not have physical control of the product. He usually follows the directions
of his principal closely and has less discretionary power in price negotiations
than commission men. In agriculture, livestock commission firms and grain
brokers are good examples of these two classifications of agent middlemen.
Speculative middlemen are those who take title to products with the
major purpose of profiting from price movements. All merchant middle-
men, of course, speculate in the sense that they must face uncertain con-
ditions. Usually, however, wholesalers and retailers attempt to secure their
incomes through handling and merchandising their products and to hold
the uncertain aspects to a minimum. Speculative middlemen seek out and
specialize in taking these risks and usually do a minimum of handling and
merchandising. Several names are given to these middlemen such as
"traders," "scalpers," and "spreaders." They often attempt to earn their
profits from the short-run fluctuations in prices. Purchases and sales are
usually made at the same level in the marketing channel. For example,
the livestock speculator may buy hogs today and sell them back either today
or tomorrow in the same yards. The grain scalper may buy and sell grain
futures seve~al times within the trading day. Speculative middlemen often
perform a very important job as a competitive force in the maintenance of
an adequate pricing structure.
Facilitative organizations aid the various middlemen in performing
their tasks. Such organizations do not, as a general rule, directly participate
in marketing processes either as merchants or agents. One group of these
organizations furnishes the physical facilities for the handling of products
or for the bringing of buyers and sellers together. They take no direct part
in the buying and selling of the products themselves. However, they estab-
lish the "rules of the game" which must be followed by the trading middle-
men, such as hours of trading and terms of sale. They may also aid in
grading, arranging and transmitting payment, and the like. They receive
their incomes from fees and assessments from those who use their facilities.
Examples ~f this group are the stockyard companies, grain exchanges, and
fruit auctions.
Another group of organizations falling in this general category is the
trade associations. The primary purpose of a large majority of these or-
ganizations is to gather, evaluate, and disseminate information of value to a
Analyzing Marketing Problems 2.5
particular group or trade. They may carry on research of mutual interest.
In many cases they also may act as unofficial policemen in preventing prac-
tices which the trade considers unfair or unethical. Though not active in
the buying and selling of goods, these organizations may often have far-
reaching influence on the nature of marketing.
Food processors, though not included in our list of marketing middle-
men, cannot be omitted from consideration. Apart from their manufac-
turing activities which one might classify as being outside the boundaries of
marketing, food processors do take an active part in marketing. Some, such
as meat packers, flour miilers, and fruit and vegetable canners often act as
their own buying agents in the producing areas. And on the other hand, it is
increasingly common for this group to undertake the wholesaling of their
finished products to retailers. Too, many of the processors through their
advertising sales work attempt to reach the ultimate consumer. So the
processing in itself is only part of the activities of food manufacturers. They
are also important institutions in marketing. As we shall see, the production
aspects and changes of the farm production unit itself have important bear-
ing on marketing. Similarly, the technology of food processing and its
changes have important influences upon the marketing processes. The
advent of frozen foods, for example, has had important effects on both
the performance of marketing functions and the institutions which perform
them. It will be recalled in this connection that the perfection of refrigera-
tor cars ,had important and far-reaching effects on the organization and
operation of the meat packing industry.
the marketing machine and the relative importance of its various parts.
Such data are presented in the various commodity chapters, since a grasp
of the basic movement pattern is one of the stepping stones toward better
understanding of marketing problems.
National flow charts for a commodity must be used only for what they
are-a generalized picture of the average channel at a given time. Marketing
channels of a commodity may also change over a period of time. New
technological developments, new products, and changing market institu-
tions are examples of many factors which may cause the old pattern to
change. The widespread ownership ~f trucks has been one of the factors
which have changed livestock marketing channels. The development of
the corporate grocery chain store along with its affiliated wholesaling and
processing agencies has been instrumental in changing old-established chan-
nels for both fresh and canned fruits and vegetables. The channel of a com-
modity may be considerably different in one region than in another. The
channel may also vary seasonally. If one is seeking answers to a specific
problem, these differences may be far more important than the aggregate
average.
USE 0 F THE INS TIT UTI 0 N A LAP PRO A C H The recogni tion
of the various kinds of marketing organizations and the way in which they
organize themselves furnishes another useful tool in analyzing marketing
problems. Very often, the why of certain marketing practices must be
answered in terms of the characteristics of who performed it. Such analysis
has the advantage of preventing the personal aspects of marketing from
being ignored.
Attitudes toward change or improvement must often be examined in
the light of the characteristics of the various marketing institutions. One of
the greatest hazards to market improvement comes from institutions with
large vested interests in the status quo. Marketing institutions give voice
to the marketing machinery. From them develop "pressure" and "educa-
tional" groups attempting to mold public opinion. One of the cardinal
rules to be followed in the analysis of any marketing controversy is first to
ascertain which groups are vocal in the controversy and what they might
stand to gain or lose.
MARKETING PRINCIPLES
The complex problems of marketing mean that many fields of study
can contribute to their ;:,olution. From economics we can utilize the large
body of theory which helps explain prices and price behavior. Firm analysis,
regulations of output, advantages of size and integration-all of these are
problems of economics. Also from the closely allied fields of business
management and cost accounting, marketing secures many of its useful
tools.
From psychology we can utilize the various theories of individual
behavior motivation. If marketing agencies are to influence demand suc-
cessfully, the knowledge of why people act as they do is of prime impor-
tance. From sociology we can utilize much of the body of knowledge
Analyzing Mctrketing Problems 29
which has been developed concerning populations, community growth and
relations, and so on to answer such marketing questions as proper location
and extent of trading areas.
The physical technological aspects of marketing are of great impor-
tance also. How cold should a warehouse be to store apples? What kind of
wrapping is best for prepackaged meat? What causes breakdown of canned
foods? How much strain must the crating for oranges be able to bear during
transit? For help in these areas, marketing people must turn to the various
physical sciences for aid and guidance.
Agricultural marketing and other marketing fields often have much
in common. Many of the results of industrial marketing studies may find
useful application in agriculture. Studies made of a problem in Illinois
may have full or partial application to problems in Ohio. We must not turn
up our nOses just because the study does not directly apply to our region
or product. As we shall see, the area of marketing study is really one of
coordination of many other areas rather than an isolated and specialized
area of its own.
SELECTED REFERENCES
Clark, F. E., and L. D. H. Weld, Marketing Agricultural Products (New York,
Macmillan, 1932), Chaps. 2 to 7.
Converse, Paul D., "Development of Marketing Theory-Fifty Years of Prog-
ress," in Changing Perspectives in Marketing, ed. Hugh \Vales (University of
Illinois Press, 1951).
Duddy, E. A., and D. A. Revzan, Marketing, 2nd ed. (New York, McGraw-Hill,
1953), Chaps. 1 and 2.
Vaile, R. S., E. T. Grether, and Reavis Cox, Marketing in the American Econ-
omy (New York, Ronald Press, 1952), Chaps. 2, 3, and 5.
CHAPTER THREE
800
400
o
PERCENT FOOD COSTS AS % OF DISPOSABLE
40
20
tion, but the per capita income is low. On the other hand, though the
income of the mountain regions is nearly that of the United States average,
the population is so sparse that it has a very low concentration of income
per square mile.
LAND INDIVIDUAL
REGION AREA POPULATION INCOME PAYMENTS
PERCENT OF U. S. TOTALS
PERCENT OF U. S. AVERAGE
Population Growth
The population of the United States has grown rapidly. It almost has
doubled during the first half of this century.
The fact that the country has been growing is an important one for
an expanding market for agricultural products. However, in this growing
process, the western regions have been growing much more rapidly than the
older eastern and southern regions. The Pacific coastal area has grown
phenomenally especially during the decade of the 1940's (Figure 2).
The changing population pattern means that the marketing machinery
also must change. Fifty years ago, almost all of the production of the West
had to look eastward for its market. Although, as we have seen, the eastern
area is still the principal market area, an increasing amount of western
Millions
140
U.S. Population
60
40
20~~ __~__~__~~~~__~__~
1870 1900 1950
Percent of U.S. Percent of U.S. Percent of U.S.
r-----..,
New England 16 10
14 8
8
12 6
6
10
14
12 §:====.x:><:::!
10
8
2 =..L.JL.-l............-J.-I
1870 1900 1950 1870 1900 1950 1870 1900 1950
FIG U R E 2. Total United States population and proportionate
distribution in different geographic regions, 1870-
1950. (Source: U. S. Census.)
LINE OF EAST-WEST MOVEMENT*
APPROXIMATE GEOGRAPHIC BOUNDARY TO WHICH WESTERN
PACKER BUYERS MUST COME INLAND TO BUY THE LIVESTOCK
SLAUGHTERED IN THE 12 WESTERN STATES
CATTLE
AND
CALVES
SHEEP
AND
LAMBS
HOGS
up chicken and turkey halves and quarters has come about largely through
the effort to satisfy the desire for a smaller purchasing unit. In one city, it
was found that 72 percent of the interviewed families said they would eat
turkey more often if it were available in smaller units.3 Such developments
usually neither simplify nor reduce the cost of marketing.
Income Distribution
Though some sections of the country have high average incomes and
others low, all families in each area do not have high or low incomes. Vvide
variation in incomes is characteristic of practically any particular place.
Table 2A indicates the wide range of incomes which exist. In the rela-
tively prosperous year of 1950, 13 percent of the spending units made less
than $1,000 annually. This group accounted for only 2 percent of the na-
tion's income. On the other hand, the 6 percent of the units which made
$7,5°0 or more accounted for over 20 percent of our total incomes. In 1950,
it required nearly three-fourths of the units to account for one-half of the
total income. As would be expected, incomes varied widely among the
various occupational groups (Table 2B). The median income of the pro-
fessional or self-employed person was over twice that of the unskilled
laborer.
These income differences are also reflected in the marketing structure.
Retail grocery stores adopt different practices and handle different items
in serving the different income groups. It has been estimated that food
expenditures take about half of the incomes of city families having less
than $2,000 per year. These people must watch what they buy very care-
INCOME AFTER
UNITS INCOME FEDERAL
INCOME TAX
AN:s'UAL INCOME PERCENT CUMULATIVE PERCENT CUMULATIVE PERCENT
BEFORE TAXES IN GROUP PERCENT IN GROUP PERCENT IN CROUP
Under $1,000 13 2 2
$1,000-1,999 17 3° 7 9 8
2,000-2,999 19 49 13 22 14
3,000-3,999 19 68 18 4° 19
4,000-4,999 12 80 16 56 16
5,000-5,999 14 94 23 79 23
7,5 00-9,999
10,000-over
3
3
97
100 }21 } 100 }IS
i\Iean Income $305 00
Median Income 3,000
537, 1949·
Consumers of Agricultural Products 37
TABLE 2B. Distribution of Spending Units and Income among
Occupational Groups, 1950
PERCENT OF UNITS
Under $1,000 4 5 2 2 11 36
$1,000-1,999 8 11 11 14 33 22
2,000-2,999 14 11 19 29 28 15
3,000-3,999 17 15 30 19 18 9
4,000-4,999 14 12 20 12 7 4
S,000-7,499 24 23 17 17 3 6
7,S°0-over 19 23 1 7 8
Median Income $.f,500 $4,SoO $3,660 $3,::00 $::,200 $1,900
Spending Unit: All persons living in same dwelling and belonging to same family,
who pooled incomes. Does not include armed forces on military reservations; hospital,
religious, or penal institutions; or people living in hotels, large boarding houses, etc.
Income: Sum of net money earnings from civilian emplo}ment; does not include
income received in kind, value of farm inventory changes, or capital gains or losses.
SOURCE: Federal Reserve Survey of Consumer Finance, August, 19S1.
fully and make every penny count. On the other hand, families having
incomes above $7,500 spend only 17 percent of their income on food. These
families can well afford the so-called food luxuries and fancy qualities.~
Generally, those stores serving higher income groups will stock more pre-
packaged and higher quality produce and meats. The stores of a New York
City grocery chain located in high income areas handled twice as many
fresh vegetable items as those in low income areas. 5 Also in New York City,
it was found that only 11 percent of the apples handled by retailers in low
income areas graded U. S. No. 1 or better. However, 80 percent of the
apples handled by retailers in the high income areas graded U. S. NO.1 or
better.6
Such income variation means there are always buyers for cheaper,
lower quality foods as well as for the more expensive, higher quality foods.
Commercial grade beef and bargain counter fresh vegetables have a market
as well as prime steaks and fancy vegetables. The job of the marketing
machinery is to assure that each kind finds its potential buyers.
Many who would improve marketing focus their attention only on
improving quality, providing more services, and making fancier packages.
4 Low Income Families and Economic Stability, Joint Committee on the Economic
Report, Slst Cungress, 1St Session, p. 5.
5 M. P. Rasmussen, Consumer Purchases of Fresh Vegetables at Retail, New York
Bulletin 849, 1948.
6 M. P. Rasmussen, F. A. Quitslund, and E. \V. Coke, Some Facts Concerning
Competition Between Apples and Other Fruits at Retail, New York City, 1939, Farm
Credit Administration, USDA Misc. Report 2S, 1940.
MARKETING OF AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS
Just as the market for mink coats is limited, so is the market for expensive
foods limited. One of the facts of agricultural marketing is that the bulk
of food products must be sold to the large group of low and middle income
people.
that different sections of the country prefer different weights in beef car-
casses. New York and Boston prefer the heavy animals weighing from
1,100 to 1,500 pounds. The Southeast, however, prefers animals which
weigh from 600 to 800 pounds; Chicago consumers like cuts from animals
which weigh from 750 to 850 pounds. Pacific Coast consumers prefer the
heavier animal weighing from 900 to 1,200 pounds.9 Lamb consumption
is very largely limited to the East and West Coasts with very little being
consumed in the interior areas. Boston housewives prefer brown eggs
while New York housewives prefer white ones.
Table 4 indicates consumption differences for persons of like incomes
in four cities in different regions of the country. Consumers in Birmingham
ate more pork and less beef than consumers in any of the other cities.
People in San Francisco were relatively heavy lamb and poultry con-
MINNEAPOLIS,
BIRMINGHAM, BUFFALO, ST. PAUL, SAN FRANCISCO,
ITEM ALABAMA NEW YORK MINNESOTA CALIFORNIA
125
75
50~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~
Beef 50 . 0 47-4 95
Lean pork 41.9 46 .1 110
Lamb ,·5 5·5 100
Chicken 19.0 24.6 13 0
Eggs 36 .4 42 .8 118
Fluid milk 26 3. 0 306 .0 116
Evaporated milk 3. 2 16·9 528
American cheese 2.8 4·4 157
Apples, fresh 56 .2 32·3 58
Oranges, fresh 14·4 37-4 260
Peaches, fresh 14·9 13.6 91
Snapbeans, fresh 6·9 " 8·9 12 9
Tomatoes, fresh 19. 6 " 23-3 119
Potatoes 155·4 116·9 75
Dry edible beans 6·3 8·4 133
\Vheat flour 194.0 147.0 76
Wheat cereal 3. 1 3.6 116
Rice 6.8 5·3 78
Sugar, refined 76 .5 87-7 115
Coffee 8·7 13. 8 159
" 19 2 0- 2 4.
SOURCE: Data computed from Consumption of Food in the United States, USDA
Misc. Publication 691.
80
60
40
20
4 OTHERS
i ~ I{MAJOR LIvESTOCK
~, ~:; j PRODUCTS*
3 1---1'/1------------ !% {FRUITS, VEG. e. -
. ,,~F, -- PREPARATIONS
2 --(S'I--------I'~--
~ _~ J~
;; U
_. . .
_
{TOBACCO (UIIMFD.)
COTTON AND -
~ ; Pi LINTERS
;; ~ r-
4~ {GRAINS AND
- ~ - - 1+-' PREPARATIONS-
these exports into major commodity groups. Our greatest individual agri-
cultural export commodities are cotton, tobacco, and wheat. During 1947-
1951, these commodities accounted for 56 percent of the value of agricul-
tural exports.
Figure 7 indicates the importance of the foreign markets in terms of
the total domestic production for agriculture. \Vhile foreign exports may
not be a major outlet for agricultural products in the aggregate, they are
of importance for many commodities. Producers of wheat, cotton, tobacco,
rice, and some fruits look upon the foreign market as a major outlet. From
this we can easily see why tariffs and export-import policies have always been
a major concern to agriculture. Sizable groups of politically powerful pro-
ducers, such as the wheat, cotton, and tobacco interests, find their markets
14 S. E. Johnson, "A !'.lid-Century Look at U. S. Agriculture," Journal of Farm
Economics, November, 1951, pp. 649-662.
Consumers of Agricultural Products 47
~~~~ ~mB
AV.
MILLED 1935-39
WHEAT
1935-39 DODI
1952 DDOO DOOO on
AV.
1935-39 ~ID~f§ ~~5&~ ~IDOO 19~IDJ?J ~
COTTON
1952 OO~j@ %7iJ~.w
AV.
~
TOBACCO 1935-39
(jJJfYCf)(jJ (/)~N)(/J rflfJ&¢ ~,
1952 rj)(jJJ(j)fJ rj)(!J(j)~
AV.
SOYBEANS935-39 ddd61
1952
AV.
dddd"
LARD
193!J-3 si3888J
RAISINS
1952
AV.
1935-39
i3~!38 0000 EI
$ ••• $$••
1952 ~$ ••
~ ••
• $.$ •• $$ $$$~
1935-3 9f3\3GG tJGGCJ tJ\3G'J Of:H:3~
AV.
PRUNES
1952 GGGG GOGO CJGGf
AV.
ORANGES 1935-3
9000
1952 OQa Each symbol represents
9fJ@~(H
AV.
1935-3
2i2 percent
APPLES
1952 ~
I I
PEARS
AV.
1935-3 9666d 666da MARKETING YEAR FOR THE RESPEcrlVE
COMMOOtrY, fEXCEPr LARO WHICH IS
011 CAUNOAR rEAR BASIS}.
1952 d I I I
closely tied to foreign conditions. \Vhile we shan not devote much space
to thi" problem, its importance is great and must not be overlooked in the
evaluation of marketing programs and policies.
SELECTED REFERENCES
Bay ton, J. A, "Consumer Preference Research in the Deparment of Agricul-
ture," Agricultural Economics Research, October, 1950.
MARKETING OF AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS
Agricultural Production
Land in fanns:
Cropland
Pasture
'Voodland, fannlots, etc.
Total in farms
49
,..
-"\ c111.2..
50 \_(;'~" ~:~;{A"RKETi-N~~O)F AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS
_v / " __ ,_ )~ \
receives lessv~han t\'.Tent);~"lnches of rainfall annually, and therefore has very
limited agriCultural potential from j:liat ,standpoint alone. The National
Resources Bba~ has estimat~d; th.a~'4T percent of our land area is non-
arable because1ott~~pgrai>llj:;- moisture, soil conditions, an~ so on, and
only 16 percent of the land "IS rated good or better for agrIcultural uses.
Table 1 shows the way our land is actually used. Only one-fourth of the
total is in cropland. About half is available for grazing.
PERCENT OF U. S. TOTAL
wide range of specialization. Some of the crop farms m,ay be wheat farms;
some of the livestock farms, hog farms. But many crop farms will raise
several types of crops-many livestock farms several kinds'QE~~nimals.
Another fact must bc added to this picture of many'rehi.tjvely small ---
and highly diversified production units. The amount of products 'sold in any
one year from the great majority of farms is very small (Table 3). In 1950,
less than one-fourth of the farm units sold products worth $5,000 or more.
In 1945, it was estimated that the top third of the farms accounted for
78 percent of the total value of farm production; the lower third, only 5
percent. The number of farmers who are actively interested in selling large
amounts of products is considerably less than the total number of farmers.
The near-subsistence farmers, though making up nearly one-fourth of the
farms, are not an important part of the commercial marketing machinery,
since they contribute only about 3 percent of the total product.
Commercial farms:
$25.000 and o\'cr 2.0
$10,000 to $24,999 7. 2
5,000 to 9,999 13·5
2,5 00 to 4,999 16·4
1,200 to 2,499 16.6
250 to 1,199 ,. 13.1
Total commercial farms 68.8
Part·time farms t 11.9
Residential and abnormal farms _:2:l_
All farms 100.0
'" Operator working off farm less than 100 days and farm sales greater than other
income.
t Operator working off farm 100 days or more and other income exceeding farm
sales.
SOURCE: "A Better Picture of Our ·Small·Scale Farms," Agricultural Situation,
}_iarch, 1952.
All of this adds up to two very important facts which have a great
impact upon the marketing of faml products. The first is that much of our
production is sold in relatively small lots from a large number of units. The
hog marketing machinery cannot get all the hogs from farm group "A"
and the poultry marketing machinery get all the poultry from farm group
"B." Some poultry must be assembled from "A" and some hogs from "B."
The marketing machinery must be set up to serve both groups for both
products.
MARKETING OF AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS
CHARACTERISTICS OF PRODUCTION
Total Output
The total output of the nation's farms has been gradually increasing
throughout the years (Figure 1). From 1910 to 1940 the trend in total
agricultural output was slowly upward with the exception of the drought
years of the mid-thirties. Since 1940, agricultural production has increased
as much as it did during the entire previous thirty years.
Percent of 1935-39
60
19~10~--~--~19~2~0----~---1~93-0----~--~1~94~0~--~--~19~5~0--~
FIG U REI. Total United States agricultural production, 1910-
1952. (Source: Bureau of Agricultural Economics,
USDA.)
PERCENT PERCENT
Total gross farm pro- Truck crops 5. 1
duction 5. 1 Vegetables, except truck 11.0
Product added by meat Tobacco 14·7
animals and animal Fruits and tree nuts 15.1
products 2·7 Feed grains 15-4
Total crops 8.0 Cotton 17·4
Food grains 1'2·7
'"U... ...<
U'l
"l
::0 Z
Q
< ::I ~ ~
00: Z H
CHANGES IN >< Z < '" <:>
u Z
'"0"'I
PRODUCTION
FROll! PRE·
'"'
;..
0:
""...
... U'l
<
!-<
<
!-<
<
I<l Z
......
'" <
~ "'I
u
< ......
0 !-<
<
...
0:
...'"
P '-' :z: P '-'
:;;Q 0'-' I>l 0 0 0 0
CEDING YEAR
'" ~ ::I ~ U 0: ;>
I'< '" u
'"
PERCENT NUMBER OF YEARS
Average change
in percent * 2.1 4. 1 5·9 13. 1 16.1 16.:: 15·3 16.2 14-5
'" The apparent disagreement of some of these data with those in Table 4 can be
explained by the difference in time period covered.
SOURCE: T. \V. Schultz, Production and \Velfare of Agriculture (New York, Mac·
millan, 1950 ), p. 73.
Agricultural Production 55
handlers and meat packers are only vaguely interested in the wheat crop.
Elevator operators, millers, and bakers spend very few sleepless nights over
the vegetable situation. It is the amount of production variation of indi-
vidual commodities which is of importance to marketing.
Table 4 shows that while aggregate production varies only about 5
percent on the average from year to year, production of the specific com-
modity groups has a much greater variability. Table 5 shows this variability
in greater detail for individual commodities.
There is stability in total agricultural production largely because of the
wide diversity of products and large area involved. vVhen one commodity
or area is down in production, the chances are that some other commodity
or area is up. The pattern of annual variability is different for various
commodities. The handlers and processors of dairy products are assured of
relatively minor annual change in volume. In contrast, the flour miller
found that in seven of the thirty-six years covered in Table 5, the wheat crop
varied more than 20 percent from the preceding year.
This production variation means that the marketing machinery must
be prepaJ;Cd to handle the varying volume. Referring again to our wheat
example, transportation and storage facilities must be available to handle
the big crops as well as the average ones. An organization which must be
ready to handle largely unpredictable variations in volumes cannot be as
fully utilized and efficient as one which has a large measure of control over
the volume handled.
!
/bCC: 1\! t) Z
II Dnte:
Ja=o==--.'-==...c:===~========::'
}'I ARK E TIN G 0 FAG RIC U L T U R ALP ROD U C T S
Quality Variation
The general quality as well as the total production of agricultural
commodities varies from year to year. During some years the growing con-
ditions are such that the crop in general is of high quality. In other years
unfavorable conditions prevail and the crop is of much lower quality.
Such variations in the quality of production make it very hard to apply
uniform standards for grades from year to year. If the quality of the apple
crop is uniformly high, the standards for top grade apples may be strictly
adhered to. On the other hand, if the quality of the apple crop is poor,
grading standards may be relaxed somewhat to permit some apples to be
marketed as top quality.
Variations in the quality also may change marketing patterns. For
example, during a year in which corn does not properly mature, large
amounts of "soft" corn are harvested. The corn will spoil if not used before
the following spring. Farmers then may buy additional feeder stock in
order to utilize this corn. The marketing pattern of these feeders, however,
will be different from the usual pattern as the feeding period is adjusted
tc the condition of the corn.
Areas of Production
It was found that there was a concentration of our domestic popula-
tion and income. Th(;re is also considerable concentration of agricultural
production. Figure 2 shows the national production picture as measured by
the value of farm products sold per square mile.
The eastern concentration is due largely to such intensive agricultural
crops as milk, eggs, broilers, and vegetables. The middle western area rep-
resents the highly concentrated agricultural region. There is considerable
justification for the claim of the central "corn-belr' region to the title of
food basket of the country. The twelve north central states account for
over two-fifths of the total farm marketings of the country.
Agricultural Production 57
HOGS SOLD
~8
CATTLE SOLD
SHEEP SOLD
FIGURE 3, (continued)
59
CHICKEN EGGS SOLD
FIG U R E 3, (continued)
60
VALUE OF ALL CROPS SOLD
FIG U R E 3. (continued)
61
ALL PURPOSES
CORN ~~~EAGE'1949
FIG U RE 3· ( continued)
62
HARVESTED FOR BEANS·
TOBACCO HARVESTED
conON HARVESTED
FIG U R E 3. (Continued)
market conditions and yields turns out correctly, he will pack and sell as
planned, But his market estimates could be wrong. The weather could be
unfavorable.
Aside from such short-run adjustment problems, it takes long periods
to change materially the production of some commodities. Fruit groves are
planted years in advance of their coming into production, The market
situation may change during this period, The expansion of milk production
is a slow process, Once investment is made in buildings, equipment, and
the herd, changes are very difficult and expensive to make.
This inability to adjust quickly to changing conditions creates a high
risk element in agriculture. The market for which a long-time production
plan is made may be nonexistent when the production is finally available.
Changes in consumer tastes may find large amounts of agricultural re-
sources being devoted to the production of something wl1ich is no longer
so greatly desired. High prices due to shortages of production may destroy
the consumer market for that good when it finally arrives in quantity. This
relative unpredictability and uncontrollability of production volume helps
explain many of the actions which have been taken to strengthen the posi-
tion of farmers. Some of the implications of this inability to adjust quickly
to changing conditions are taken up in the discussion of prices in Chap-
ter 6. The reader should compare the price theory developed there with
the practical problems outlined in this chapter.
Agricultural Production 65
SELECTED REFERENCES
Barger, H., and H. H. Landsberg, American Agriculture, 1899-1939, A Study of
Output, Employment and Productivity (New York, National Bureau of Eco-
nomic Research, 19.P).
Christensen, R. P., Efficient Use of Food Resources in the United States, USDA
Tcchnical Bulletin 9 63, 1948.
McElveen, J. V., "Changes in Production During \Vorld \Var II by Size of
Farm," Agricultural Economics Research, July, 1951.
Pearson, F. A., and Don Paarlberg, Food (New York, Knopf, 1944), Chaps. 4,
5,6, and 7·
\Vilcox, VI. \V., The Farmer and the Second \Vorld \Var (Ames, Iowa State
College Press, 1947).
CHAPTER F IV E
400Hr-----+------~
o Farmer's Share of Food
Dollar
o Family Markel
Basket
CONSUMER'S FOOD
DOLLAR
400
shows that the farmer's share moves up and down with changes in the
amount of the consumer's outlay at the retail level. The share has varied
from a low of 32 cents in the depression years of 1932 to a high of 54 cents
in the war year of 1945. In other words, when the retail expenditure is
reduced, the farmer receives a smaller percentage of the reduced consumer
outlay. 'Vhen the retail expenditure is increased, the farmer receives a
larger percentage of the increased consumer outlay.
The basic reason for this relationship is the relatively inflexible nature
of the marketing charges. Though it is true that these charges also move
up and down with changing business conditions, the change is relatively
quite small. :Marketing charges are "sticky." As the consumer outlay at the
retail level increases, the marketing charges do not increase as much. There-
fore, as a percentage of the consnmer dollar, marketing charges will de-
crease and the farmer's share will increase. The reverse situation will be true
when the retail expenditure declines. This relationship is illustrated in
Table 1.
This "sticky" nature of marketing charges also helps explain why the
farmer's share of some commodities fluctuates so much more than that of
others. Generally, the larger the marketing charges which must be sub-
tracted from the consumer's dollar, the greater the percentage change in
the farmer's share will be. A study of Table 2 shows the difference in share
change of a commodity with a relatively large marketing charge and one
with a relatively small marketing charge.
In both of these situations, the change of the share through a period
of time and the differences in the change of share among commodities, the
change can come about without any change in the physical organization of
the marketing system.
All foods
Beef
Eggs
Pork
Fluid milk
Potatoes
Evaporated milk
Tomatoes, fresh
Flour, white
Cabbage, fresh
Margarine
Oranges
Tomatoes, canned
Corn flakes
Bread, white
ing charges and farmer's share for several commodities and illustrates this
wide variation. For example, the farmer's share of the consumer's dollar
spent for beef is more than four times the size of the share received from
the sale of bread.
Upon a minute's reflection, however, the reason for these variations
becomes obvious. The marketing job for some products is more complex
MARKETING OF AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS
than for others. Only if all commodities were alike in all respects would the
marketing charges and farmer's share be alike. To a large degree, differences
in the size of the farmer's share reflect the effect of the product characteris-
tics on the complexity of the marketing functions which must be performed_
The major product characteristics which contribute to this difference might
be classified as fo11ows:
1. Processing. The more work which must be done in changing the form of the
product to satisfy the consumcr, the grcater the marketing charges will be.
... Perishability. The marketing of perishables is usually more costly than that
of nonperishables. Spoilage is greater. Expensive refrigeration may have to
be used both in transportation and in the various stages of the marketing
channel.
3. Bulkiness in relation to value. Some products will require more space in both
transportation and storage. This would tend to increase cost.
4· Extreme seasonality of production. Commodities which must come to
market within a very short time rcquire facilities to handle the peak period
of production. These same facilities may be only partially used during the
rest of the year. 1£ such commodities are also perishable, increased spoilage
costs also will result.
Other factors not attributable to the product itself may also cause
some of the differences. Institutional factors such as a high degree of ver-
tical integration or a highly organized system of accurate market informa-
tion might result in difference in the size of share. The demand by con-
sumers of a large amount of special services in some commodity areas may
result in higher costs. Of course, most commodities represent a combination
of these factors. It is the rare case where everything else would be the same
except perishability or amount of processing and the like. But a re-examina-
tion of Table 3 with these factors in mind will aid in explaining many of
the differences among the farmer's share of the various commodities. For
example, much of th;:: great difference between the beef and bread share
referred to before can be attributed to the difference in the amount of
processing done; much of the difference between the farmer's share received
from the sale of tomatoes and that from potatoes, to the difference in
perisha bili ty.
COMPOSITION OF THE
MARKETING MARGIN
The marketing margin can be broken down in many ways. Two of the
most common classifica tions are on the basis of specific cost items and on
the basis of jobs performed at the various levels in the marketing channel.
Tables 4 and 5 break down the marketing margins for several products on
these two classifications.
TAB L E 4. Breakdown of Marketing Margins for Farm Foods by
Various Services, 1939 (Arranged in Order of Process-
ing Necessary)
LOCAL TRANS-
PRODUCT RETAILING WHOLESALING ASSEMDLY PORTATION PROCESSING
1939 1947
PERCENT OF TOTAL MARGINS
Breakdown by services:
Retailing 50 .0 44·9
'Wholesaling 12.1 11.6
Processing 37-1
Local assembly 6,4
Breakdown by cost items:
\\'ages and salaries * 5302
Transportation * 11.2
Other costs 35. 6
* Not available.
SOURCE: Kathryn Parr, Farm to Retail Margins fOT Livestock and Meat, B.A.E.,
USDA,1949·
LOCAL TRANS·
PRODUCT AND AREA RETAILING WHOLESALING ASSEMBLY PORTATION
" H. 'IV. Bitting and H. T. Badger, f.,laTketing Charges for Apples Sold in Pitts·
burgh, USDA Agricultural Information Bulletin No. 47, 1951.
t H. H. Reizenstein and H. 'IV. Bitting, Farm to Retail !t.Jargins for Appalachian
Apples, USDA Agricultural Information Bulletin No. 44, 1951.
t H. H. Reizenstein and H. 'IV. Bitting, Farm to Retail IIIargins for \Vashington
Delicious Apples Marketed in Chicago, USDA Agricultural Information Bulletin No.6,
1949·
SJ. Foytik, California Celery-J\Iarketing Channels and Farm to Retail Margins
and Califomia Asparagus-Marketing Channels a1ld Farm to Retail Margins, California
t!imeographs 117 and 116, 1951.
II 'IV. P. l\!ortenson and T. F. Graf, Marketing Eggs in a Southern City, \Visconsin
Mimeograph, and Marketing Eggs in the Lake States, \\'isconsin Bulletin 168, 1950.
C[ J. O. Gerald, Farm to Retail Margins for Marketing \Vestern Turkeys, USDA
Agricultural Infornlation Bulletin No. )' 1949.
* * Transportation costs arc largely included in the wholesaling and assembly costs.
t t Includes dressing expenses.
7-+ ]II ARK E TIN G 0 FAG RIC U L T U R ALP ROD U C T :s
Profits in IVlarketing
No discussion of the composition of the marketing margin would be
complete without some reference to the profits taken by the various agencies
of the marketing system. Profits long have been used as a public "whipping
boy" not only by critics of marketing, but in all other fields of economic
endeavor.
It has become popular to treat profits as a "residual"-something which
is nice to have, but which can be reduced or eliminated without any effects
upon the business system. This ignores the function of profits in an econ-
omy such as ours. 3
:l\dodern accounting procedures often include the return to both capital
and management under the accounting breakdown of profit. Profits in this
2 The studies from which these examples were taken in the order mentioned are:
E. C. Byer, C. B. 'Wood, and C. S. Abshier, A Financial Business Analysis of Indiana
Grain Elevators, Indiana Bulletin 547, 1950; G. :tv1. Lewis, Financial Results of the Meat
Packing Industr)" 1950, American Meat Institute, Mimeograph, 1951; H. E. Ratcliffe,
Cooperative Marketing of Eggs and Poultry in Ohio, Farm Credit Administration, USDA
Bulletin 59, 195 0 ; J. K. Samuels and G. L. Capel, Citrus Packinghouse Costs in Cali-
fornia, Farm Credit Administration, C-q8, 195'1; K. Bjorka, t-.Jarketing Margins and
Costs for Livestock and Meat, USDA Technical Bulletin 932, 1947.
3 \Ve are not here concerned with profits as developed in the strict theoretical sense.
Those who wish to explore that area should tum to appropriate theory sources.
The Cost of Marketing 75
sense are as necessary in attracting capital for the maintenance and growth
of a company as wages are necessary to attract workers.
Profits are reported on varying bases. lvlost businesses like to present
their earnings on the basis of a percentage of total sales. This permits a
large dollar profit to appear infinitesimally small, especially if the sales vol-
ume of the firm is very large. For example, the meat packing industry earn-
ings in 1950 were 95 million dollars, but this was only 1.1 cents for each
dollar of sales. 4 This small figure can then be used to emphasize how unim-
portant profits are in the consumer cost of meat. It is possible that this
de-emphasis of the importance of profits on the part of business has con-
tributed to the widespread feeling of the unnecessary nature of profits.
Another way of presenting profits is on the basis of net worth. This
tends to give the more valid picture of returns on the capital which is at
work in the company. It is on this basis that the earnings are shown in
Table 8.The data in this table are for the '\Torld 'Var II and immediate
postwar period. This was a period when complaints about exorbitant profits
were commonplace. The earning records for these various food enterprises
4 Lewis, op. cit.
ff'I ~.... ~~ c:' ""'! ~ N 00 1""1
o
..... OM 0 O'o-o-n r-:..cO Mr.:...
....c ~ .-.I ,...;
o
u
u
-< '" o MO'Oc() '1""0 ""O"'Tt--
o,..
'" u0 <1- ... 00000000"';00-
...... '"'" ..... ..... ..... .-.4. .-t
-
'1""
o
'"
'»
~
~::c rr.. 7 C'CC ..... N N ..q- 0
0- 0- r:. r:. r:. r:.oo r:. '" -+- ~
.......... r"i ,...;
'"o;:l
.~
-
>
o tr\ U'\ ('(\
o cO 00 cO
0 Q\ 0- r;-..... ff\\,Q
r.:.. r.:... r1 ri cO r.:.. 0-
r---. .....
o \0 H\ f'('I.\CJ 0- N'\\O ~ ~~
u.r:..r:..r=...-.o,;",o.... ,..;.... U'\H\V\
'"
o
u
ooU N \0 N \0 ~ q r-\O '1-.... C1'
z r:....o 0 0 0'0 Q..mr.:...MM
:::.0: ..... ..... ..... ..... ..... ..... ~
'"
o ... M M;- 1..1"\\0 ["--.00 0' 0
'1"" '1""'1"" "'1"" '1"" '1""'1""'1"" '1"" T ' "
0'0"0"0'0'0'0'0"0'0'0-
..... .-.I ..... ,...; ,...; ,...; ~ ,...; ,...; .... ....
The Cost of Marketing 77
do not seem terribly out of line. Excessive profits of the marketing and
processing firms cannot be logically used as a major cause of excessive costs.
On the other hand, neither can the apparent reasonableness of the earning
record be used as the basis for arguing that the profit levels are "correct"
and that any lower level would invite disaster.
1,000 hogs on a day thcy arc sold at $25 as on the day thcy bring $10. It
takes substantially thc same plant and labor outlay to pack fruit at a time
whcn the value is high as when the valuc is low. It takcs the same amount
of transportation space to haul 1,000 cases of eggs at 25 cents a dozen as at
50 cents. This situation results in many markcting charges being levied on
a physical unit basis such as per bushel or per animal, instead of on a
percentage of dollar volume. Such charges become more difficult to adjust
to the changing value of the products handled.
The relative degree of competition or monopoly control in the market-
ing structure also has a bearing on inflexible margins. Increased unioniza-
tion of labor will probably lead to greater rigidity both in wages and em-
ployment practices. Though probably a more flexible cost structure in the
marketing system would be desirable, there seems to be little reason to
believe that much improvement in this area will be made.
haye pointed out the possible cost savings through increased size and fewer
and integrated firms, there has been very little work toward determining
the optimum number of firms for effective competition. In the modern
business world there may have to be some compromise between secming
the maximum economies of scale and maintaining an effective competitive
structme. Undiscriminating worship at the shrine of the economies of
scale may bring still greater costs by fostering weak and impotent com-
petition.
Another major approach toward increased efficiency is in the improv-
ing of the operational methods and layouts of individual firms. The end
product of such improvements can be the more efficient utilization of
labor. The same study on citrus packing house costs reported that the
number of men needed for operation could be reduced through the use
of proper machinery. A study of the operations of the receiving rooms in
milk plants concluded that with an improved arrangement, the job which
previously had taken four or more men could be done either with one or
two men. 7 Through the proper training of peelers in tomato canning fac-
tories it was possible to increase productivity 20 percent.s Examples of
possibilities of improving the way labor is used, the handling of materials,
and the layout of plants are numerous.
That efficiency of labor with resulting reduction in costs can be im-
proved in marketing is demonstrated by Figme 2. Unit labor costs have not
risen as mnch as have wage rates. Hourly earnings increased 125 percent
from 1940 to 1950; unit labor cost increased 100 percent. This means that
the output per man of the marketing labor force has been increased.
PERCENT CHANGE
r:-;nUSTRY 1949 FROM 1939
Flour and grain mill products +::0·5
Condensed and evaporated milk + ::.8
Sugar + 1,4
Beet sugar - +3
Confectioncn' -r.p
l\IaJt liquors" -20.2
Canning and preserving
Ice cream
SELECTED REFERENCES
"Beha"ior of Marketing Margins" (series of papers), Journal of Farm Eco-
nomics, December Proceedings, 1952.
Lazo, H., and Ivl. H. BIetz, \Vho Gets Your Food Dollar? (New York, Harper
and Brothers, 1938).
"An Outline of Distribution Costs" (Committee Report), Journal of Ivlarket-
il1g, July, 1951.
Report on Distribution AJethods and Costs, Part 1, Important Food Products,
Federal Trade Commission, 1944.
Stewart, P. 'V., and J. F. Dewhurst, Does Distribution Cost Too Much? (New
York, Twentieth Century Fund, 1939)'
Part II
SOME FUNCTIONAL
PROBLEMS
CHAPTER SIX
The exchange functions of marketing. bll~'ing and selling. are the heart
of marketing. As goods 1110\'e through the many hands before reaching the
final user, title changes several times. Each time title changes, a price must
be decided upon. This means that pricing is an integral part of marketing.
Price analysts claim that marketing is an important branch of the study of
prices. Marketing people claim that pricing is a major branch of the study
of marketing. Regardless of viewpoints, the study of marketing and of
prices go hand in hand. One really cannot adequately understand market-
ing without some grasp of the fundamentals of pricing.
It is the objective of the next few pages to prescnt briefly some of the
basic concepts which arc needed for price understanding. For many of you,
this will be merely review. For those of yon who have not come in contact
with these concepts before, more careful study will be appropriate.
'ion prt:scnt in the marketing of agricultural products will be dilcmscd in the next
chapter.
86 MARKETING OF AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS
sumers must have information on the relative costs that producers incur
in snpplying them with different goods so they can make their decisions
on how to allocate their limited incomes on a basis of more than sheer
desire. In a competitive economy the pricing machinery is expected to
transmit these orders and directions. Briefly, then, fluctuating competitive
prices have the following three major jobs to perform:
1. They are to guide and regulate production.
2. They arc to guide and regulate consumption.
3. They are to guide and regulate the distribution of goods both over a
period of time and from place to place.!!
Economies organized in some other fashion-such as socialistic and
communistic organization-still must find some way to give direction to
the workings of the system. The area of disagreement is not over what
orders are necessary, but rather over how and who should give them.
If a competitively functioning price system is allowed to give the direc-
tion, it has the advantage of being impartial. The idea of "fair treatment" is
left to the composite judgment of the market place rather than to the
decisions of individuals in positions of political power. Such a system of
direction also has the advantage of being in continuous operation-there
is a continuous adjustment to changing conditions. This is in contrast to
the sluggish "after-the-fact" type of direction which usually occurs when
the direction job is delegated to various public agencies.
The heart of price formation under competition is the supply-and-
demand analysis. There is probably no more overworked and misunder-
stood phrase in economics than the "law of supply and demand." To some
it is a form of magic or divine guidance \vhich is invoked to explain away
any major problem or dilemma. To others it is something which can be
used or ignored depending upon the desires of the moment. It is to these
fundamental ideas of supply and demand that we shall now apply ourselves.
.\MOUNT PURCHASED
PRICE PER DUSHEL (lIIILLIO:-; BUSHELS)
$1.60 1,5°0
1.5 0 1,570
1.40 1,660
1.3 0 1,75 0
1.20 1,9°0
1.10 2.,030
1.00 2.,190
.9 0 2.,4°0
bushels would be purchased; if the price were $1.40, 1,668 million bushels
would be purchased and so on for any other possible prices assuming that
all other things remained unchanged. The demand schedule and curve do
not indicate what the price and quantity are but only what the effect of
different prices will have on the quantity purchased. The price which will
exist has not yet been established and demand alone cannot establish it.
Several important points, then, must be kept in mind if the idea of
demand is to be llsed correctly. First, it is a series, or schedule. of amount-
price relationships. To forget this will lead often to the very common
error of associating a price change or a consumption change alone with
demand.
Secondly, demand indicates the differing amounts that will be pur-
chased at differing prices, and not simply the amounts needed by pur-
chasers. The demand which is important in marketing is what is often
termed effective demand. Effective demand is the desire of the consumer
for the commodity backed up by purchasing power. Effective demand,
then, is the quantity that would be purchased at the existing price. The
people of China both need and desire many things-more rice, better
clothing, better homes, and so on. However, the Chinese demand for these
things is very limited, since they do not have the purchasing power to make
their needs and wants effective. The pertinent marketing question is always,
"How much will be bought at a price?" and not, "How much will be
needed or desired?"
$1.60 2,030
1.50 2,000
1.-1 0 1,980
1.3 0 1,94 0
1.10 l.g00
1.10 1,860
1.00 1,79 0
.9 0 ____________________1~,7°0______________
160
14D
120
100
80
1500 1700 1900 2100
Millions of Bushels Sold
FIG U R E 2. Hypothetical supply cun'e for COTII.
should not influence price. However, replacement costs and storage costs
may influence the seller's judgment and therefore influence the supply
schedule.
It is the interrelationship with future time that brings cost into the
supply picture. \Vhen the given time period is future time, analysts usually
consider two additional periods, the short mn and the long mn. The short
run is that time during which goods can be produced only with existing
production facilities. The long run refers to that time during which the
production facilities themselves may be expanded or contracted. In the
short run the cost of the existing facilities is not an element influencing
the seller's decisions with respect to supply. In the long-mn period, how-
eyer, the costs of all things used in production enter into the determination
of supply.
Since the supply schedule of amounts to be produced refers to a period
involving the passage of time, it must take into consideration the time
necessary to initiate and complete the production process. For some com-
modities like broilers, this may be only a period of weeb; for others like
cattle, it may be a period of several years. And as we shall point out later
and as is obvious from the preceding discussion of time and cost, the
supply curve for the same commodity will be different for the different
periods of time under consideration.
The time element greatly complicates the analysis of agricultural
supply. Unwary observers who notice that large receipts on today's market
move at lower prices, or that a large crop brings lower average prices, con-
clude that the law of supply is not valid. However, these situations point
up the problem of determining the proper time lag between the price
stimulus and the quantity response. High livestock prices on the market
today will result in larger receipts one and two days later because of the
time necessary to initiate the shipment from the farm. The proper supply
schedule in this instance would probably be one which related to day's
prices with receipts two days later. The hog production coming to market
during the fall monLllS is in response to conditions which existed far
enough in the past that hog producers changed their breeding plans. The
supply schcdule in this case would relate current prices with the level of
production forthcoming at least twelve months later.
the demand schedule of Table 1 and the supply schedule of Table 2. The
question is what will be the price of corn, given these two sets of conditions.
As we run down the list of prices we find that at $1.20 per bushel, buyers
will take 1,900 million bushels. At this same price sellers will produce and
offer for sale 1,900 million bushels. At $1.20 buyers will take all that sellers
\vill offer. There will be no unsold corn-the market will be cleared. This,
then, will be the price which will be established if the forces of competition
are allowed to function. This is the equilibrium price-the point where
demand and supply are equal. Figure 3 graphically presents the same pic-
ture. '\There the demand (d-d) and supply (s-s) curves intersect, (p) is
the equilibrium price.
Cents per
Bushel
1500
I
1700 1900
I
2100 2300
I II
Millions of Bushels
FIGURE 3· Hypothetical supply and demand curves for corn,
illustrating the equilibrium price.
~{ ARK 10 TIN G 0 FAG RIC U L T U R .\ L PRO Due T S
\Vhy must the price come to rest at $1.::0 in this illustration? Suppose
prices tried to come to rest at $1.30' At this price sellers would be willing
to sell more corn than buyers would purchase (Table 3: 1,940 compared
to 1,75° million bushels). The desire of these extra sellers to sell at some
price above $1.::0 would result in price concessions to attract buyers. Any
price lower than $1.20 \vol1ld find additional buyers but fewer sellers. In this
situation the desire of eager buyers to secure corn at what they considered
advantageous prices would result in the bidding up of prices. At $1.::0 both
the buyers and sellers who are willing to enter the market at all would be
satisfied, and 1,900 million bushels would change hands. This price would
be an equilibrium price.
The equilibrium price is not a point readily found nor easily main-
tained. Rather, prices are always overshooting the mark in their search for
the price which will clear the market. Changes may be small but they occur
frequently as buyers and sellers search for the market-clearing price. It is
more correct to say that the equilibrium price is that price toward· which
actual prices will tend to move.
The first two factors would generally either increase or decrease de-
mands for all products. The next two factors would largely affect shifts in
demand among individual commodities. The last factor could affect either
the general or the specific demand situations. As we shall see later, the
most important single factor influencing demand for agricultural products
is a shift in the general income levels of the country.
Supply may also increase or qecrease. If more of a product is offered
for sale at the same or lower prices than before, supply will increase. Refer
to our corn example in Table 2. If 2,200 million bushels are offered at $1.60,
2,100 at $1.;0, and so forth, supply will increase. If this new schedule were
plotted on Figure 2, the increased supply curve would fall to the right of
the original. \\Then less of a commodity is offered for sale at the same or
higher prices than before, supply will decrease. The curve for this decreased
supply would fall to the left of the original curve.
As is the case for demand, many factors can combine to increase or
decrease supply. Generally, they may be classified as follows:
1. In the very short period, there may be a change in the various factors
which would induce sellers to offer their available stock of goods at a
different schedule of prices. These would include such factors as costs
of storage, the sellers' need for cash, and the general expectations as to
the future situation.
" In the short run, there may be a change in the cost of production of
the commodity itself based upon the availability of various resources
for production as well as the degree of competitiveness of other firms.
3. In the long run, there may be changes in all of the factors mentioned in
(1) and (2) plus changes in the availability of resources for altering
productive facilities and the ease of making these changes.
Price Price
Quantity Quantity
A. Demand increases B. Supply increases
Supply remains unchanged Demand remains unchanged
Result: Increased quantity Result: Increased quantity
moves at a higher price moves at a lower price
Price
sIs'
Quantity Quantity
C. Demand decreases D. Demand increases
Supply increases Supply increases
Result: The same quantity Result; Increased quantity
moves at a lower price moves at the same price
Demands with unit elasticity are those in which the changes in quan-
tity taken are of the same magnitude as the changes in price. The elastic
demands are those in which the changes in quantity taken are proportion-
ately greater than the changes in price. The inelastic demands are those
in which the changes in quantity taken are proportionately less than the
changes in price. For example, let us assume price has decreased by 10 per-
cent. The law of demand indicates that the quantity taken will increase.
But how much will it increase? The changes in quantities taken for com-
modities with demand curves of different elasticities would be as follows;3
Commodities with inelastic demands are often those \vhich fall into
the classification of necessities and which have few substitutes. Consumers
want them and are relatively insensitive to price changes. Commodities
with elastic demands are often those whose use is not directed by necessity
or habit and which have several close substitutes. Consumer response for
such products is more sensitive to price changes.
Price per
Unit
20 40 60 80 100120
Quontity
A. Unit elosticity
FIG U R E 5. Demand curves of B. Inelostic
C. Elostic
different elasticities.
Elasticity can be mathematically calculatcd. \Vhcn so p.resent<;d, unit ela~ticity is
3
-1; an elastic demand is something more than - 1 ; and an mclastlc demand IS some-
\y.
thing less than - 1 . For a more complete discussion of elasticity analysis see C. \Vaite
and H. C. Trelogan, Agricultural flfarket Prices, 2d ed. (New York, John \\"lley, 195 1 ),
cD. 3.
'>1.\ It " E T 1 :\ COl· .\ C RIC U L T U R.\ 1. I' ROD U C T S
On graphs of the same scale, the more inelastic the demand, the
steeper is its plotted curve (Figure 5). The most important implication of
demand elasticity is its effect on the total amount of money received from
selling different quantities at varying prices. \Ve can easily see this by study-
ing the results of a 10 percent cut in prices on three hypothetical com-
modities of different elasticities. For a commodity with a demand of unit
elasticity, the quantity taken would increase 10 percent and the total re-
Total
Ret,#"ns
500 f-
:r ~/
2oof- ~
100f- / "
I I I I
o 20 40 60 80 100 120
Quantity
FIe U R E 6. Total retuT11 Clln'es fOT
A. Curve for unit elasticity the demand curves of
B. Curve for inelastic demand different elasticities
C. Curve for elastic demand
shown in Figure 5.
turns from sales under thc new situation would be exactly the same as be-
fore the price cut. For a commodity with an clastic demand, the quantity
taken would increase more than 10 percent and the new total returns from
sales would be greater than before. However, for a commodity with an in-
elastic demand, something less than 10 percent more of the commodity
would be taken and the total returns would be less. The total return curves
which would be derived from demand curves of different elasticities arc
shown in Figure 6.
Demand curves for the same product often are not of the same
elasticity throughout the entire curve. For example, demand for an agricul-
tural commodity may be inelastic when the price is very high, elastic when
the price is in the middle ranges, and inelastic again when the price is
extremely low. Such a situation would mean decreasing returns through
part of the curve, increasing returns through the middle section, and de-
creasing returns again through the lower part of the curve as quantities and
prices change. Elasticity may also change over a period of time. Thus.
many things which were once luxuries with elastic demands may shift into
the necessity category with inelastic demands.
The Exchallge FUllction-Pricc Discol'c1'Y 97
\Vill a largc crop return Illore money to grow~rs than a small one even
though prices are lower? \\That will be the effect of restricting output on the
total returns from sales? Should a store seek to lower its prices to sell more
goods? Knowledge of demand elasticity and its relationship to total returns
is the key to the answers to such questions as these.
Thc same elasticity framework also can be applied to supply. Com-
modities which are very responsive to price changes have elastic supply
curves. Those which respond relatively little to price changes ha\'e inelastic
supplies. As for the different elasticities of demand, on graphs of the same
scale the more inelastic the supply the steeper the plotted curve.
Quantity
A Short-run, within
Quantity
/ Quantity
B. Intermediate, C. long-run. extending
a given production extending over two over several
period or three production production
periods periods
Price Price
Quantity Quantity
A. With inelastic supply B. With more elastic supply
price change is great price change is less
The probability that there will be perfectly inelastic supplies for many
agricultural products in the very short period has two major implications.
First, it means that changes in demand are of tremendous importance in
changing the equilibrium price. Secondly, it means that price fluctuations
resulting from changes in demand are much more severe than when the
supply curve is more elastic. Figure 8 illustrates the effect of an equal de-
crease in demand in tv:o situations-one with a perfectly inelastic supply
(A) and the other with a somewhat more elastic supply (B). Notice the
difference in the degree of price change (p and p') as the demand changes.
SUMMARY
Vie may now briefly summarize the major points in the fundamentals
of price determination under competition as follows:
1. The law of demand is a statement of consumers' tendencies to buy
less as prices increase.
The Exchange FU1lctio1l-Price Discovery 99
2. The law of supply is a statement of the producers' tendencies to sell
more as prices increase.
3. The equilibrium price is the result of the interaction of supply and de-
mand. It is that price at which buyers will take all that producers will
offer.
4. Demand and supply may change independently. A change in demand
or supply or both will result in a new equilibrium price.
5. Demand-and-supply curves have different elasticities. Elasticity dif-
ferences will affect the total returns secured from selling different
amounts at different prices. They also will influence the degree of
change in equilibrium price as demand and supply shift.
SELECTED REFERENCES
References for this Chapter and Chapters 7, 8, and 9 are listed at the end of
Chapter 9.
CHAPTER SEVEN
The cffecti\'C working of mllch which was discussed in the previolls chapter
assumcs perfect competition. Under this assumption. prices will not onl~'
do the threefold job laid out for them, but they \vill also assure an efficiently
functioning economic system. Businesses will operate 'It their optimum
size, neither smaller nor larger. New technologies and other improvements
will be snapped up and adopted immediately by all firms if they arc to
remain in business. The benefits from such improvements would also be
quickly dispersed throughout society because of the pressure of the com·
petiti\'e pricing mechanism. \Ve must assess hO\v closely the existing'
marketing machinery approximates the ideal of perfect competition. The
first part of this chapter will outline the assumptions and results of the
competiti"e system. The second part will attempt to assess the extent and
kind of competition operating in the actual marketing system.
PERFECT COMPETITION
costs and the prices received in the market. In agriculture, the perishable
and seasonal nature of production makes these very short run profit and
loss possibilities quite likely.
In the short run, it will be recalled, production can be altered within
existing firms with existing technology. If demand is high, producers may
expand production up to the point where rational conduct tells them to
stop-that is, where the additional cost of another unit is equal to the price.
At this output profits will be maximized. If the level of demand is so low
that prices will not cover the direct costs of production such as seed and
fertilizer, the producer may not produce at all. Or if the price will cover
the direct proportion of his costs but not his fixed costs, he may produce
up to a point where his losses are minimized. In either case under the
assumptions of perfect competition, no one producer by his individual
decision to produce or not to produce can influence price. Price is imper-
sonal and competition is a ruthless distributor of rewards and penalties.
No man can change the relationships between cost and price that result.
In the long run, however, new firms may enter an industry or old
ones leave it. Existing firms can change their size and seek the most efficient
technology. Under such a long-run consideration, if demand and prices are
high and high profits are being enjoyed, production will be increased as
more firms enter the industry and existing firms expand. Thus, prices will
be under pressure from the increased production and eventually a profitless
situation will result for all firms in a competitive industry. Similarly, if
firms are operating at a loss, eventually enough firms will be forced out
so that the remaining ones will share in the industry demand under con-
ditions where there no longer are losses, but also no profits. Therefore in
the long run, production will adjust so that average prices will tend to equal
average costs.
The problems facing an apple orchard operator offer a good illustra-
tion of these different time period relationships. Once fruit is harvested
the operator has the alternative of either selling at the market price or not
selling at all. The demand situation may be such that he may enjoy large
profits or suffer substantial losses, but he cannot alter his previously made
decision to produce. And with so many other se1lers, he cannot influence
price by withholding part of his apples from the market.
In the short run as the harvest season approaches, the orchard operator
can take certain actions if the price appears too low. He may cut out part
of his spraying activities. He may decide to pick and pack only the better
fruit-or in an extreme case, none at all. Or if the prices are high he may
c;·;~rt every effort to handle his crop so that he can harvest as many high
quality apples as possible.
I-.1 .\ R h E T I :-; C 0 F :\ C It leu L T U R :\ L PRO Due T S
In the long run, if the prices have been persistently very low, he may
abandon his orchard completely or reduce his tree replacement program.
Or if the prices have been very high, new orchards may be started for
production. As has been mentioned previously, the length of the long-run
period varies depending upon the nature of the costs and equipment in-
volved. In some cases it may be only a few years. Or as in the case of
apple production it may be ten or more years.
DEPARTURES FROM
PERFECT COMPETITION
It doesn't take a particularly astute observer to recognize that the
assumptions necessary for perfect competition are not fully attained in the
real world of business activities. Furthermore, the natural tendency of men
is to try to escape from the ruthlessness of the mechanism of perfect com-
petition into some situation in which they have some control over their
destinies as economic beings. In fact, it seems doubtful whether the per-
fectly competitive situation has ever existed except upon the pages of
economic texts.
There are two major categories of departure from perfect competition.
On the one hand is monopoly. In this situation, the control of production
of an industry is by a single firm. Similar to monopoly in many of its
effects is oligopoly. In an oligopolistic situation such a significant propor-
tion of the production of an industry is controlled by a few firms that at
least one of these dominant firms can influence price by changing its
production. In the case of pure monopoly or simple oligopoly, no attempt
is made by the firm to control demand. Demand is accepted and the firm
determines the quantity which can be offered at prices which will maximize
profits.
On the other hand is imperfect competition with product differentia·
tion. In this situation a firm strives to make its product different in some
respects from the products of other firms of the industry. In this way the
firm attempts to achieve some influence over the demand for its own
products regardless of what other firms in the industry do. Each firm
attempts by differentiation to create a monopoly for its own product. But
the demand for this product is very elastic since there are many close sub-
stitutes from the other firms in the industry.
prepared to increase its output ~nd if its competitors did not retaliate. The
firm is also usually forced into extcnsive expenditures to maintain the level
of its demand. These expenditures may take the form of advertising,
product improvement, offering of additional serviccs, and so forth. These
costs of maintaining its differentiated product exist regardless of changes
in the level of raw material costs and tend to make cost and price structures
somewhat inflexible.
Some succcssful firms may perpctually enjoy large profits. Other firms
may not be so successful and barely hang on in the industry. Firm mortality
rates may be high. However, firms in such circumstances are likely to be
quite progressive in their search for and application of new techniques and
improvements. The successful "differentia tor" must continually keep per-
snading the consuming public that his product is better than ever before.
The market acceptance of a differentiated product is likely to be quite
dynamic, and for a firm to lag behind its competitors is to die.
Trade barricrs havc often laid the groundwork for competitive imper-
fection. \Vhether by intent or not, many regulatory actions by states or
local units have the effective result of restricting freedom of entry and the
free flow of goods. In this way some degree of monopoly power is obtained
by the favored firms. City milk ordinances, state grading regulations, and
truck size regulations which vary widely from state to state are merely
examples of these artificial barriers.
Howevcr, probably the greatest amount of competitive imperfection
stems from product differentiation either real or assumed, from various
kinds of serviccs offered with the product, from locational advantages, and
from the power of habit and ignorance. These arc neither illegal nor spec-
tacular, and often arc ignored.
Product differentiation in agricultural marketing has on occasion been
de-emphasized because effective branding of farm products themselves is
very difficult. However, we have seen that farm products are raw materials
for the food marketing machinery. The great majority of our food by the
time it reaches the consumer has been differentiated by brands and pack-
aging. Even meat and fresh fruits and vegetables are not completely
immune. Packers work hard on the public to build acceptance for their
particular brands of ham and bacon. The label "Sunkist" is stamped on
oranges. Canners attempt to make their various labels synonymous with
different kinds of packs and qualities.
Effective differentiation is not limited to products alone. Marketing
concerns make every attempt to separate their particular firms from others
by offering special services, easier credit, and so on. This is done by retailers.
wholesalers, and even commission men.
As we have indicated above, the end product of most differentiation is
to remove the emphasis from price. The purpose of much advertising is to
associate the name of a product or firm with the buying urge and reducc
association with the price. \Ve are urged to buy from a particular store
because the clerks are friendly, because it is sparkling clean, or because it
stays open after 6:00 P.M. \Ve are told to buy bread "X" because it is made
by a company which bakes only "quality goods." How do the prices in
this particular store or of this particular bread compare with other stores
or breads? \Vhat a question! \Ve should trust the store and the baker
always to treat us fairly!
Locational advantage furnishes thc foundation for many departures
from competition. Spatial monopoly need not be regional or nation-wick
to be effective. :i\Iany country buyers of farm products can pay lower prices
because of their location. \'lan1' retail outlets can charge higher prices
because of their location. Some 10cational advantage arises because CllS-
Competition in Food fo..JarketilIg 10C)
tomers are willing to pay extra for convenience. Other locational advan-
tages arise because of the limited area over which products can be trans-
ported. But some of the competitive power of location arises because of the
lack of nearby competitors. Such firms have limited monopoly power in
exploiting their limited territory. A baker in a very small town or an isloated
livestock buyer in the country may have more effective monopoly power
than a huge baking concern or the agencies in a large central market. One
should not make the mistake of associating power to exploit only with size.
Habit can lead to imperfection in competition. The power of habitual
action can take many forms. For example, at one time the quality of cotton
coming from southeastern :Missouri was quite poor, and this therefore
became a low price area. However, buyers continued to bid low in this
area long after the quality problem had been corrected. Similarly, a section
of Iowa historically was associated with low quality butter and low prices.
After the quality differences disappeared, however, the price structure re-
mained below that paid for similar quality in similar locations.
Habit can also be a factor in establishing the general pricing structure.
The pricing of butter is an example. Originally a large amount of the
nation's butter was marketed through the Chicago and New York ex-
changes. The quotations of these exchanges were widely accepted as cor-
rect indicators upon which to base butter prices throughout the country.
\Vith the passing of time, the marketing structure of butter has changed
and now only a very small amount is sold through these exchanges. Trade
pricing habits have not changed in step, however, and country buyers still
rely heavily on the old quotation patterns.
:i\Iargins taken by various marketing agencies often become habitual.
In time, a given margin receives trade acceptance as being "fair." The "fair"
margin often tends to exist long after the marketing activities and structure
which gave rise to it have changed. It was partly the resistance to changing
margins in line with changed practices which led processors and retail chain
organizations to by-pass the service wholesaler and set up their own whole-
saling agencies (see Chapter 24).
Product differentiation, location. and habit can gain monopoly ad-
\',mtages largely because of the lack of knowledge on the part of buyers
and sellers. \Vith a lack of standardization and poor informational services.
buyers and sellers cannot fully appraise alternative opportunities. It is often
suggested that when alternative opportunities arc available to the buyer
or seller, competition must be effective. TIlis need not be so. Numbers
themselves do not fully prevent collusion or the tacit adoption of a live-and-
let-live policy among rival firms. Neither do numbers assure that buyers
and sellers will have the necessary facts to appraise alternatives adequately.
110 MARKETING OF AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS
USEFULNESS OF THE
C 0 l\I PET I T I V E 1vl 0 DEL
As one becomes marc familiar with the agricultural marketing ma-
chinery, it is evident that dcpartures from the model of perfect competition
arc the rule rather than the exception. Diagrammatically, the marketing
structure can be represented as in Figure 1. At one extreme is perfect
competition and at the other is perfect monopoly. ·With the possible
Perfect Competition
Monopolistic
and
Imperfect
Competition
1 . Diagrammatic distribu-
tion of conditions under
which agricultural mar-
Perfect Monopoly keting occurs.
PP·9- 10 •
11: .\[ .\ R K E T I" G 0 FAG HIe U L T U HAL l' ROD U C T S
both price and non-price competition is used, and that large firms will
develop as they exploit the" economies of scale which are the result of
modern technology.
There will be the continuous problem of evolving and maintaining
an effective competitive situation. The conditions which may result in
effective competition for one industry may not give the desired results in
another. How many buyers and sellers are required for an "appreciable num·
ber"? How powerful must the trader be to be able to "coerce effectiyely" his
rivals? \Vhat handicaps are "automatically created" by established firms
and what are not? \Vhat is "substantial" preferential treatment? These are
difficult questions-many would say questions which are impossible to
answer. But such an ostrich, head-in-the-sand attitude will only ignore
some of the most difficult marketing problems.
CHAPTER E I G H T
Agricultural Prices
The preceding two chapters have set forth some of the rudiments of the
price making forces and a general appraisal of the competitive structure
of the marketing machinery. This chapter will briefly outline some of the
characteristics of agricultural prices. This is not a text of agricultural prices,
and the student who wishes to study that field in detail will find several
books completely devoted to the subject. However, some understanding of
the nature of farm product prices is necessary background to the following
chapter on government farm price and marketing policies and programs.
J\Iany of the attitudes of agricultural people toward the rest of the economy
find their origins in the relationship of agricultural prices to nonagricultural
price3. 1\l3ny of our more serious marketing problems are those which stem
from the price aspects.
AGRICULTURAL AND
NONAGRICULTURAL PRICES
One of the outstanding characteristics of the American economy has
been the wide fluctuations in its business health. Periods of depression,
recovery, boom, and recessions in prices and business activity have becn
the historic norm. Long periods of stability in prices and busincss activity
have been rather unusual. As the general price level of the country has
moved up and down, so have agricultural prices.
A study of Figure 1 will show that with each major war the level of
prices has tended to almost double. This sharp increase has been followed
by sharply falling prices. Agricultural prices, too, have been pulled up and
down in thi5 general sweep.
Such :,weeps in prices would not necessarily adversely affect the pros-
perit)· of farmers or :my other group if all clements of the costs and returns
of different industries adjusted themselves quickly to the changing level.
113
MARKETING OF AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS
Wf-lOlESAlE PR ICES
% OF 1910-14
100
~l
o
1800 1840 1880 1920 1960
SOURCE, WARREN AND PEARSON, 1798·1889, BLS, 1890 TO DATE
DATA FOR 1953 ARE PREliMINARY
the 1930's. Figure 2 shows how agriculture and industry reacted to these
changes. \Vhen these two industries are compared, a major difference be-
comes evident. Agricultural production rose gradually throughout the
period with only very minor short-run changes. Agricultural prices fluctu-
ated violently. Industrial production, too, has tended upward throughout
the period. But it was reduced substantially during the early thirties and
rose sharply during \Vorld War II. \Vhen industrial prices are compared
to agricultural prices, we see that they did not fluctuate as violently. The
difference, then, can be summed up quite briefly. Agriculture reacts by tak·
Agricultural Prices 115
ing nearly all of the impact in the prices for its product while maintaining
production without much change. Industry attempts to lessen its price
fluctuation by adjusting production.
This difference does not mean that the industrial segment profits
from depressed conditions. Incomes in both agriculture and industry are
a result of both prices and the volume of goods sold at those prices. Sus-
tained output with very low prices in agriculture and reduced output at
sustained prices in industry both result in low incomes and profits. Part
taliation from other firms or_ of spoiling the customary relationships of the
market. In agriculture the many producing firms have no power over price.
The farm firm also has a large portion of its costs fixed and a smaller portion
which are variable. Under these circumstances, it continues to produce in
order to recover as much of its costs as possible and will not withdraw
from production until after a very long-run period of losses.
FARMERS' PRICES
% OF 1910-14
300r-------4--------r------~------
2001----
% OF PARITY
150 f------I--
100
50 ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~
paid and prices they received. \\Then the level of business activity rises,
the prices farmers receive for their products rise faster than those they pay.
Gross farm income rises more than production expenses and so net income
to farmers also rises. '\Then business activity falls, the prices farmers reo
ceive decline more than the prices they pay. Gross farm income falls more
than production expenses, and net income therefore declines even more
sharply.
til
~
r< en ~
OJ ...l
0 0:
::> z -< r<
0
0 -< :;; 0
CHANGE IN 0:
Po
><
0:
z-< ...-<
Z
-<
0
Z
to
~
0
PRICE FROM
PRECEDIXG
~
0: "'
...l '"
...-< ::: Z
s,_. '"~
OJ
u
-< ...
0
'"
-<
::> '-' ,:;
YEAR <
0
0,-,
Po ~
~
~ ~ '"
0
OJ '" ::>
~ Z ...
0 '"
0
u '"
0
p,
---
Agricultural Prices 119
PERCENT OF
PRODUCTION
lIiOST 11liPORTANT PERCENT OF ACREAGE ,'ARIATION
FACTORS RELATED VARIATION EXPLAINED EXPLAINED
CROP TO ACREAGE BY FACTORS BY ACREAGE
CHANGE
siderable evidence that the consumer demand for food and services at
retail levels may approach unity. (Recall that consumers spend a percentage
of their income for food which is remarkably stable from year to year-
Chapter 3, Figure 1.) The value of the raw commodity at the farm
level is derived from the value of that commodity at the consumer level.
Farm value is substantially consumer value minus the marketing charges.
These marketing charges, it will be recalled, tend to be on a fixed dollar
amount rather than on a percentage basis. Such a situation would result
in demands which are more inelastic as one moves from the retail level
back through the marketing channel to the farm leveJ.2
Even though there is considerable disagreement among researchers
as to the exactly correct figures, there is wide agreement that the demand
curves for a great many farm products tend to be inelastic-some of them
highly so. Only a relatively few products have been found to have elastic
2 For a more complete discussion of derived demands and elasticities see F. L.
Ti,omsen and R. J. Foote, Agricultural Prices, :d ed, (New York, i\fcGraw-Hill, 195:),
eh. ).
120 !-.I ARK E TIN G 0 FAG RIC U L T U R ALP ROD U C T S
demands at the farm level. This means that a 10 percent change in farm
prices will result in substantially less than a 10 percent change in amount
taken. And more importantly it means that a small crop or reduced pro·
duction will bring higher total returns than a large crop or high production.
(See Chapter 6, Figure 6.)
\Vith wide variations in incomes and purchasing power as the economy
moves through its wide swings, the demand curve for agricultural products
shifts sharply. \Vith production dependent on factors beyond man's con-
trol, supply of individual commodities also will shift from year to year.
\Vith the inelastic nature of the two curves, such shifts will give wide
variations in farm prices. (See Chapter 6, Figure 8.)
to earlier has only partial control over his wheat crop, and therefore cannot
respond with regularity to price encouragement. The cattle cycle has
averaged about fifteen years in length (from peak to peak or from trough
to trough), with individual cycles varying from twelve to twenty years.
Since the middle twenties there appears also to be a cycle in dairy cow
60 9
50 7
40 5
30 14 3
HOGS 9
100
8
80
7
5
40
7--:l 4
numbers and prices which move with the total cattle cycle. The hog cycle
has averaged about five to seven years in length. Some writers also list a
poultry cycle of two to three years.
A study of Figure 4 and Table 3 will show that cycles are not highly
regular either in amount or length of their fluctuations. Extraordinary con-
ditions such as a sharp reduction in feed supplies because of droughts may
extend a contraction or stifle an expansion in numbers which may have
been undemay. Sharply expanding demand during wars may prolong an
expansion or cut short a contraction phase of a cycle which is undenvay.
At best, cycles are important "tendencies." Turning points are evident in
many cases only after they have been reached and passed. Such limitations,
however, do not prevent them from being useful tools for the market
analyst.
CATTLE HOGS
18 90 18 96 6 19 00 19 02 2
19 04 19 1Z 8 8 19 08 19 10 2 6
19 18 19:. 8 10 6 19 12 19 14 2 2
1934 193 8 -4 6 19 16 19 17 ::
1945 194 8 4 7 19 19 19 21 2 ::
19 23 19 26 3 2-
19 28 1931 3 ::
1933 1935 :: ::
194 0 1941 r
-'
1944 1945 3
194 6 194 8 2
r-.f\f'\CO rlCCCOc()
o 0
........ C1' 0
.... 0' O'CO
most food is relatively constant year around. Table 4 gives the long-time
average seasonal pattern of prices for selected commodities. Most students
will want to substitute the seasonal patterns for the commodities in which
they are particularly interested and which apply to their particular area.
However, patterns for different areas will usually differ only in degree.
Seasonal prices reach their low points during harvest or peak produc-
tion periods. TI1en they will begin a slow rise until just before the next
peak production period. For example, the low period for wheat is in July,
for corn in November, and for cotton in October. TI1e peak period for
wheat prices is reached during IvIarch and April, for corn during August,
and for cotton during July. Hog prices have two periods of high and low
prices during the year corresponding to the two-litter farrowing system.
The amount of seasonal price fluctuation is the combined result of
the violence of the seasonal production plus the storability of the com-
modity. Reference again to Table 4 will help illustrate this. Certainly the
production pattern of grains is a violent one. An the wheat is harvested
within a period of a few summer months. The peak harvest time of snap
beans and tomatoes also occurs during a brief period of late summer.
However, wheat prices fluctuate only about 10 percent from low to high
while snap bean prices are three times as high during the peak price period
as in the low period. The principal reason for this difference is that wheat
is storable while snap beans are not. Theoretically, the perfect seasonal
variation will just cover the cost of storage if the product is storable.
Like cyclic patterns, seasonal patterns are not 100 percent accurate.
The average pattern is just an average of many observations. The average
represents the pattern most likely to occur if history repeats itself. Too,
all seasonals are not of equal reliability. Neither are all months of the
seasonal price pattern of equal reliability. Generally, the average can be
relied upon to point up correctly the direction of price movement but not
the amount. Seasonal patterns may also change over the years. New pro-
duction patterns or improved storage techniques would affect changes.
For example, as better Fork production methods have shortened the time
necessary to produce a market hog, the peak in the seasonal price pattern
has changed. It once was in October and now in many states it occurs in
August. Knowledge of these patterns, even with their limitations, is among
the most useful of marketing facts available to farmers. Every worker in
agricultural marketing should be thoroughly familiar with them. However,
he should also use them in relation with other pertinent facts which may
be known about the current supply-and-demand picture.
CHAPTER NINE
they receive the most severe jolts as the price and business levels zoom
up and down over the years. Prices they receive are much more sensitive
than those they pay. Depressions of the whole economy appear to have
accounted for a much greater amount of agricultural failure than either
poor husbandry or management. Vlith increasing industrialization and
urbanization, agriculture finds itself less and less self-sufficient and more
and more closely tied to the general economy.
3. Prices of individual commodities are extremely unstable. \Vide fluctua-
tions both within the year and from year to year are the normal pattern.
And since many farnlers produce only one major product, such as wheat,
cotton, tobacco, cattle, and so on, what these individual prices do is
a matter of great concern. \X/ith the inelastic demands for many com-
modities, shifts in supply have resulted in wide sweeps in prices. And
what is more, high levels of production have often been associated
with low total returns from sales. The logical question then arises
as to whether controlled production will net greater income than full,
uncontro1led production.
4. The individual farm is a small competitive unit operating in a general
structure of larger units with varying degrees of market control. Full pro-
duction to the individual farmer is logical since, being so small, he can
sell all of his output at the same price. He, acting alone, has no eco-
nomic power to affect prices. In contrast, the farmer has always be-
lieved that the marketing machinery does have some degree of control
over prices and takes advantage of him. He looks upon the large share
of the consumer's doBar taken by marketing agencies as evidence of
this. How to meet "power with power" in the market place has become
a major issue.
Corn $ ·32
Oats .16
\Vheat .3 8
Cotton .07
1ililk 1.28
Hogs 3·34
Cattle +25
Though we are here concerned with agricultural developments, we
must not overlook that the whole country was on its economic knees.
Businesses failed; banks shut their doors; one out of every four workers
was without a job. The agricultural program which developed was only a
part of a broad program which included social security and unemployment
insurance for workers, special legislation for banks, and the National Indus-
trial Recovery Act for other businesses. The latter, NRA as it was widely
known, was designed to control "bad" competition and foster "good"
competition. The bad competitor was in reality one who competed on the
basis of prices. The good competitor was one who largely restricted his
efforts for securing more business to the more gentlemanly non price
techniques. NRA encouraged industries to join together and formulate
"fair" trade codes and to take cooperative action to police their trade
against "unfair" competition. After a short life NRA was declared uncon-
stitutional but the issues it raised left its mark both on the marketing
structure and the men who operate it.!
The legislative development of the 1930'S signaled a change in the
basic approach to the problems of a depressed agriculture. During the
192.0'S the two-price system was offered as a device by which our agricultural
production could have a protected domestic market and yet secure what
1 See A. J. Eddy, The New Competition (Chicago, A. C. McClurg, 1915), and
O. F. Rost, Distribution Today (New York, Whittlesey House, 1933), for interesting
contemporary writing in this arca.
-----------,---~--
Governmental Price and fvIarheting Programs 129
it could get from the world market. The Federal Farm Board proposed to
solve the problem by helping farmers to level out the peaks and valleys of
their marketings and thereby stabilize the prices of agricultural products.
The basic approach which was now to be followed was to reduce produc-
tion. In this manner, demand and supply were to be brought into balance
at prices which were "fair" to farmers. Though many camouflaging terms
were used, the basic concept of curtailing production prevailed.
The pressure for all-out production during \Vorld War II halted the
desire to restrict output. Agriculture during this war period experiencerl
unprecedented prosperity. However, with the growing agricultural prob-
lems in the postwar period, the old question again came to the fore. And
this question simply stated is: ':ViII consumers absorb the fun productive
capacity of the agricultural plant at prices which wi11 give agriculture a
reasonable degree of prosperity? It is to the definition of the fair price and
the mechanics for securing it that we now give our attention.
Development of Parity
The Agricultural Adjustment Act of 1933, established the criterion
for a fair price for agriculture. Parity, or fair price, was that price which
would give agricultural commodities the equivalent purchasing power over
articles which farmers bought that they had in the base period. The base
period for the great majority of products was established as the five-year
period from August, 1909, to July, 1914-
To find the parity ratio for agriculture as a whole was then a simple
process as fo11ows:'~
Current index of prices received (1910-14 base) p"
C urrent III
'dex 0 fpnces
' pal'd (1910-14 base) X 100 = anty rabo.
Obviously, the parity ratio for 1910-1914 would be 100. \Vhenever prices
receivcd by farmers did not rise as much-or fell more-than prices paid,
the ratio would fall. Conversely, when prices received rose more-or fell
less-than prices paid, the ratio would rise.
The parity price for an individual commodity also could be calculated
as follows:
Average price current
recei\'ed for index of
X
the commodity prices
during 1910-14 paid
--=---'----=--=---- = Current parity price.
100
'Vhen the actual current price was below the price obtained from the
above calculation, the commodity was below parity. The market price was
MARKETING OF AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS
not one which would give the commodity the same purchasing power as it
had in 1910-1914.
As time passed, it became obvious that such a formula had a great
shortcoming. There was no provision for taking into account any changes
which had taken place since 1910-1914 in either the demand or the supply
of the commodity. For example, the parity or fair price of horses in 1953
under the above formula would still be the price which would be com-
parable to the purchasing power which horse prices represented in 1910-
1914. But with modern mechanized farming and the reduced demand for
horses this was a ridiculous goal for a fair price. The example is an extreme
one, but it shows the problem of handling change when only a fixed period
in the past is used.
In 1948 the parity formula for individual commodities was changed.
Though the desired purchasing pO\ver was still tied to the 1910-1914 base,
the base period for prices of a commodity was to be calculated for the
most recent ten years. Therefore, the formula for calculating the current
parity price of a commodity would be as follows:
Average price of
commodity, most
recent 10 years Current index ..
-o----:---,-d--f~- X f ' 'd = Current panty pnce.
Average in ex 0 0 pnces pal
all prices received,
most recent 10 years
Support Programs
Here then is a formulized method for arriving at the "fair" price.
But merely doing the calculations does not make the price on the market
equal parity!
The Commodity Credit Corporation (CCC) was set up in 1933 to
take over the activities of the old Farm Board in supporting prices. Two
broad programs have been undertaken by the CCC to support prices. In the
case of most storables, the nonrecourse loan was used. Under this system,
the farmer "seals" his commodity in acceptable storage. He then obtains
a loan reRecting the amount of the support price. If the market price rises
above the loan rate, the farmer may sell and repay the loan. If the market
_-
Governmental Price and Marketing Programs 131
price never reaches the loan rate, the farmer delivers the commodity to
the government and thereby fulfills his obligations. This has been the basic
program used to support prices for most grains, tobacco, and cotton.
The other major program has been one of direct market purchase.
In this case, the government buys directly from processors and handlers
at prices reflecting the desired levels of support prices. The CCC then
attempts to dispose of these commodities through other "noncompeting"
outlets. If they cannot be disposed of, it either stores them if possible
or, as a last resort, destroys them. This program has been used for a wide
variety of products such as eggs, turkeys, butter, and beef.
Until 1937, the levels of support were at the discretion of the admin-
istration. In 1938, support levels as definite percentages of parity for a few
products were written into law. After our entry into \Vorld \Var II, the
Steagall Amendments set the support level at 90 percent of parity for a
wide range of products. One might say that the "90 percent," which later
was to become so controversial, was a war baby!
The level of support-not the parity idea-has become the contro-
versial issue. In 1948, Congress passed a new law which provided for
flexible support levels instead of the fixed 90 percent. Under its provisions,
the support level was on a sliding scale which varied inversely with the
production of a commodity. If the production was below the average of
a recent period of years, the support price would be at a higher percent of
parity. If the production was above this average, the support level would
be at a lower percent of parity. A fixed high level of support ignored the
fact that it would take lower prices to move a large supply into consump-
tion. It also ignored whatever effect prices might have on guiding future
production. The flexible provisions were an attempt to provide support
and yet recognize the economic jobs that fluctuating prices are presumed
to perform.
The law of 1948 never was al10wed to become effective, as it was
superseded by a new law passed in 1949. In the Agricultural Act of 1949,
the "basic commodities"-corn, cotton, wheat, tobacco, rice, and peanuts-
were to be mandatorily supported at a fixed 90 percent of either parity
formula, which ever was higher. This was to be in effect for a limited
period of time after which the revised parity formula and the flexible
support provisions were to become effective. A few other commodities
were to be mandatorily supported at flexible levels ranging from 75 to 90
percent of parity. The great bulk of perishables and nonbasic storables were
left without any definite support provisions. The Secretary of Agriculture
!Could support these latter commodities at his discretion and in light of
funds available to him. Succeeding amendments, however, have extended
MARKETING OF AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS
the 90 percent support provisions, and the flexible support provisions for
basic commodities did not become effective.
In each of the laws, provision was made for compulsory production
controls when production exceeded a predetermined level. The controls
were of two levels in severity. In instances of moderate overproduction,
farmers would receive an acreage allotment which would reduce the acres
planted. Compliance with these allotments would be voluntary, but only
those farmers who did comply would be eligible for price support loans.
In years of severe oversupply, however, marketing quotas would be used.
Under marketing quotas, the extent of necessary reduction would be an-
nounced and a referendum of affected farmers held. If a majority of the
farmers voted in favor of the scheduled restriction, compliance with its
provisions would be compulsory for all farmers. Penalties then could be
inflicted on those farmers who did not comply. If a majority did not favor
the restriction, it would not go into effect and the support prices would
be sharply dropped to lower levels.
bc legally sold on thc domestic:; in-shcll markct. Thc surplus percentagc is eithcr
shellcd or exported. Grmvcrs normally gct a grcatcr rcturn from walnuts sold
in-shell than from thosc sold in thc shcllcd markct. Thc perccntage of diversion
from the domestic in-shell markct has ranged from 9 to over 30 percent of the
total crop over the years.
Such allocation increases total returns, since shellcd walnuts arc a year-
round itcm and customers do not shift from in-shell to shellcd purchascs
because of small price changes. Also percentage changcs in supplies in the two
markets do not cause cqual percentage changcs in their prices. T1le control pro-
gram does not materially affect the total supplies of walnuts available to con-
sumers, but it docs control the form in which they are sold in order to get
maximum returns for growers. \Vithout these allocations, prices of walnuts of
comparable quality in the two outlets would tend to be the same; however, the
program controls thc supply going into each outlet which results in a two-price
market.
Under such unified action, producers-cooperatively organized for
order participation-may have the pmver to affect the price they receive.
They now have the prerequisite control over production for securing
monopoly returns. Ivluch of the justification of such control rests upon
the assumption that there is not one demand curve of a given elasticity
for the commodity, but several curves of different elasticities. There may
be different curves for different cities, different qualities, different uses, and
different times of the year. By controlling the amounts offered each outlet,
different prices may be established which will maximize the total returns
trom all. Generally it is the two-price system of foreign and domestic
markets proposed in the twenties applied at home and carried to much
greater refincments.
Basically, the technique involved here is one of price discrimination.
\Vithin the framework of whatever other goals the discriminator may
have in mind, profit maximization will be striven for by following two
lines of action. First, the general market must be divided into two or more
submarkets. 111is subdivision must be made in such a manner that sales
at a low price in one market will not attract buyers away from the other
higher priced market or result in resales out of the low price market
into the higher priced market by other groups seeking to take advantage
of the several price situations. 111is is quite possible whenever one of the
markets is a domestic market protected by tariffs, quotas, or transportation
cost barriers which prevent re-entry of the exported portion. It is also
possible whenever the product itself is so differentiated in the several
markets that consumers actually consider it as two different products. Such
evidently is the case in the above illustration of the markets for in-shell
and shelled walnuts. Such also is the case in the techniques of pricing milk
according to its use which will be discussed later.
Governmental Price and IvIarketing Programs 135
Secondly, the different elasticities of demands in each market must
be considered in adjusting prices in order to maximize profits. If demand
is relatively inelastic in one market, limited quantities will be withdrawn,
bringing about a proportionately higher price and therefore a greater total
dollar return. These amounts taken from the market of inelastic demand
will be added to the offerings in the market of more elastic demand without
much reduction in the price so that total dollar returns will be increased.
This substitution between markets will be carried to the point where the
addition to net revenue (after costs have been met) obtained from selling
one more unit will be the same in each submarket. Here net returns or
profits will be maximized and any further shifting of products from one
submarket to the other will only result in profit reduction. Of course, such
exact adjustments for maximum profit can rarely be achieved with the
imperfect knowledge and limitations of the real market. But some advan-
tage can be acquired whenever such discriminative monopolistic practices
can be employed.
Price Controls
Practically all agricultural legislation has dealt with how to raise prices.
During war periods, however, the problem has been how to keep prices
from rising too fast or too high. The Office of Price Administration (OPA)
during 'VorId 'Var II and the Office of Price Stabilization (OPS) during
the Korean vVar are the two most recent direct attempts to control rising
prices.
In initiating a control program, prices are "frozen" as of a given date
by government order. From these freeze points, adjustments up or down
are made as needed. The enforcement technique is simply to make it illegal
to charge above the legal levels. The simplicity of the technique, however,
belies the simplicity of the job. Effective price control is immeasurably
complex. Agricultural products have presented real headaches in efforts
to control them. vVith wide annual and seasonal variation in production,
differences in quality, and numerous and small producers, price ceilings
always seemed to be out of adjustment at some place or time. To secure
their operation, a rationing and subsidy system had to be devised. A con-
tinuing flow of orders from the central control agency was necessary to
allocate available supplies among those who needed them. Though break-
downs and confusion occurred, price control will probably remain a much
Llsed technique in times of inflationary duress.
1)6 1\1 ARK E TIN G 0 FAG RIC U L T U R ALP ROD U C T S
EFFECT OF PROGRAMS
ON MARKETING
'\Thether or not such programs as the above are socially desirable is
not of particular concern here. Neither need the consideration of such
program details such as fixed versus flexible supports receive our attention
as such. VVe are interested in the impact of these various programs on the
marketing of farm products. And they do have important effects. These
we will attempt to summarize briefly.
one must have the necessary-data to analyze the situation and estimate the
curves.
Again, little generalization can be made as to the effects of these
various programs on marketing. Cost reducing as well as cost increasing
effects are possible. Again the effects must be analyzed commodity by
commodity, program by program.
SELECTED REFERENCES
Black, J.D., and :tvI. E. Kiefer, Future Food and Agricultural Policy (New
York, ~IcGfa\v-Hill, 1948).
Gray, R. \V., V. L. Sorenson, and \Y. \V. Cochrane, Price Supports and the
Potato Industry, Minnesota Station Bulletin "p+ 1954-
HaIerow, H. G., Agricultural Policy of the United States (New York, Prentice-
Hall,1953)'
Hedlund, F. F., "The Impact of Marketing Agreements Upon the Marketing of
Fruits and Vegetables," Journal of Farm Economics, November Proceedings,
1951.
Hotchkiss, G. B., Milestones of Marketing (New York, Macmillan, 1938),
Chap. 15.
Jesness, O. B., ed., Readings on Agricultural Policy (Philadelphia, Blakiston,
1949) .
Larson, A. L., Agricultural Marketing (New York, Prentice-Hall, 1951),
Chap. 19.
Naden, K. D., "Price Policy of the Challenge Cream and Butter Association"
(2 parts), Journal of Il'1arketing, April, 1948, and January, 19-1-9.
Nichols, \V. H., Imperfect Competition \Vithin Agricultural Industries (Ames,
Iowa State College Press, 19.f1).
Oxenfeldt, H. R., Industrial Pricing and Marketing Practices (New York,
Prentice-Hall, 1951).
Price Policy Award Papers, Journal of Farm Economics, November, 1945.
Saloutos, T., and J. D. Hicks, Agricultural Discontent in the Middle \Vest,
19°0-1939 (Madison, University of \Yisconsin Press, 1951).
Shepherd, C. S., Agricultural Price and Income Policy, Vd ed. (Ames, Iowa
State College Press, 1951).
Stocking, C. VI., and M. \Vatkins, Monopoly and Free Enterprise (New York,
Twentieth Century Fl'nd, 1951).
Study of },lonopoly Power, Committee on the Judiciary, House of Representa-
tives, 81st Congress, 1949.
\Vaite, \V. C., and H. C. Trelogan, Agricultural Market Prices, 2nd ed. (New
York, \Viley, 1951).
CHAPTER TEN
~tainers for n~I1Y itGms in the wholesale trade are also standardized
with the -aid or-federal ~~~d state legislation. Howcver, there is little con-
tainer standardization at the retail level, with the result that consumers
arc often confused and misled. Federal law requires that quantities must
be plainly marked 011 food packages entering intcrstate commcrce. How-
ever, packages are often designed to deceive the purchaser. Examples of
this can bc found in any grocery store by comparing the size of the package
with its weight or volume. Many bottles are made to appe'!_~J<l_!:g~Lby the
tlse of extra thick or false b;ttoms or by the design of the sides. Many
packages are intentionally designed to be larger than necessary for its
contents.
,/"
Quality
It is in the area of quality that some of the greatest standardization
problems of agriculture arise. \Vhat should be the criteria for various
grades of quality? How many grades should there be? How uniformly
interpreted and widely accepted are the standards for grading from one
area to another or from one grader to another? 'Vhat terminology should
be used? Should the standards be compulsory or permissive?
All of these are questions which arc important to agriculture and
agricultural marketing agencies. In many instances, they are questions
which are currently answered unsatisfactorily. But the fact remains that
workable answers are necessary if the marketing machinery is to function
smoothly and efficiently. It is this area of quality standardization and
grading which will be discussed in the remainder of this chapter.
The early cotton trade was also plagued by grade confusion. The term
"middling" apparently was adopted from its use in England. Such terms as
"good," "fair," and "ordinary" were in general use about 1th5. In 1847,
efforts were made to adopt a standard classification system, but this failed
within a few years.
Livestock once were sold on the basis of the girth of the belly. In the
literature of the 18:;0's, hogs were sometimes classified as "fat disti1Iery-
fed" hogs and "fat corn-fed" hogs. In most of the early market reports, the
point of origin was indicated as one method of classifying the animals. Such
terms as "prime," "choice," and "good" were not uniformly used either
within an individual market or between two different markets. 3
The lack of accepted fruit and vegetable standards resulted in especial1y
chaotic trade conditions. These very perishable products were shipped long
distances, and there was no intel1igible basis for price comparison and the
settlement of damage claims. Some growers attempted to secure recogni-
tion by placing their names on a11 shipments. In this way, they hoped to
establish a reputation which would give them market premiums. 4
Such situations resulted in many unfair practices and abuses. Not only
did producers suffer, but the middlemen of the trade also were often de-
frauded. In most instances, pressure developed for reform of the grading
system from within the trade itself. Trade groups and organizations at-
tempted to systematize nomenclature and grades. Generally, however, real
permanent progress was not made until the federal government stepped in
to coordinate the efforts to improve the grading system. In 1907, Congress
appropriated funds to study federal standardization. The passage of the
Cotton Futures Act in 1914 and the Grain Standards Act of 1916 initiated
a series of laws which have gradually broadened the area of federal respon-
sibility in promulgating uniform standards.
Advantag?~_gf Standardization
The use of uniform standards for setting up the different grades of
quality by the trade has many advantages to offer. These may be enumerated
as fol1ows:
1. It results in more meaningful price quotations. The consumer is as-
sumed to direct production through the pricing mechanism. This is not
possible if prices do not have specific meanings throughout the market-
3 A mc"e complete discussion of the progress of livestock grading can be found in
:\. A. Do\':dl and Knutc Bjorka, Livestock 1\larketing (New York, l\lcGraw-Hill, 1941),
eh. XIV.
4 See Raymond L. Spangler, Standardi;:ation and Inspection of Fresh Fruits and
\' egetablcs, USDA, Production Marketing Administration, .Misc. Publication 604, 1946,
for a more complete discussion of these early problems.
l\fARKETING OF AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS
PROBLEMS OF
AGRICULTURAL STANDARDIZATION
Much of the grading system for agricultural production needs critical
examination. In a recent report of the Agricultural Research Administra-
tion, which is in charge of administering federal marketing research funds,
it was reported that about 12 percent of the nearly 6 million dollars spent
in marketing research was used for consumer preference and grades and
stan da rds stu dies. 7
CENTS PERCENT
Fancy 1::·5 20 61 19
Extra standard 9·9 6 63 31
Standard 8,4 4° 59
SOURCE: F. D. Gaylord and K. 1. Fawcett, A Study of Grade, Quality and Price of
Canned Tomatoes Sold at Retail in Indiana, Indiana Bulletin 495, 1944.
11 For more detail 011 these developments, see the Report of the 1951 r-,[arketing
Research \Vorkshop, op. cit., and also the following __alti(:les in.l\Jarkcting _i\ctiyitie~,
USDA, Production and 11arkcting Administration: "Better Than the Human Touch,"
July, 1950; "Simple Refractometer Developed," July, 1950; "Technical Research to Back
Tobacco Standards," 1\la1', 1949; and "Good Butter Tastes Good," r-,'1arch, 1949.
Standardization and Grading 147
DeterminingJhg_I,.i1Pits of Grades
How many grades should there be? This is an extremely important
question since it can influence the total amount received from the total
production. \Vithin limits of the consumer's willingness to pay premiums
for certain qualities, the amount which wiII fall in each grade can be
changed. However, agricultural products do not fall into classifications
with definite "breaks" between them. Instead, the quality of agricultural
products varies throughout a wide range. It has been suggested that most
pro~d_lJ..cJsJ~~_a_ qu_ality_distribution very similar to the normal frequency
distri~u~io_~_surve.l~ This can be illustrated by the hypothetical situation
shown in Figure 1.
_ •• , _ ' _r~' •
Amount of Production
One of the criteria for good grades is that there be enough of the
llorm_aJFiod~~tion falling in each grade to make it a meaningful market
category. How many grades should there be and where should the
boundaries of the grades occur in the commodity illustrated in Figure I?
TJ1_ere are-some products of very low and some of very high quality. r-Iost,
however,
~-- ....---
fall --_somewhere between these two extremes.
'~., ".
It also is evident from this illustration that the grade boundaries will
be ~'~_on_e_( rather than clear-cut lines. The more the grade factors are meas-
12 H. E. Erdman, "Problems in Establishing Grades for Fann Products," Journal of
Farm Economics, Febr\lary, 1950, p. 15.
MARKETING OF AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS
uredsubjectively, the wider will be the zone of indecision. This has led to a
system of tolerances in standards. F:_orexample, grades of fruits and, yege-
tables usual1y provide for 5 to 10 percent of off-grade specimens.
There are situations in which the grade designations appear too re-
strictive. Eggs appear to be an example. A study showed that housewives,
when faced with a choice between "A" and "B" quality eggs, actual1y
chose about as many "B" eggs as the better egg "A." '''hen faced with the
choice between "A" and "e" quality eggs, however, most chose the "A." 13
Have the grade boundaries been incorrectly chosen in this case?
The quality of the production of a commodity also changes from year
to year: The curve in Figure 1 might shift either to the right or to the left.
One year might find a larger amount of higher quality products and a
smal1er amount of lower quality products. Or the situation might be re-
versed. Such conditions make it extremely difficult to maintain consistent
standards. Ag~in, this is particularly true when grade factors depend upon
5.l1bjective measurement. For example, if the apple crop is very poor in
quality, very few apples would meet the top grade requirements if the
standards were rigidly adhered to. Under these circumstances, the pressure
is strong to "reach a little farther down" for the top grade apples.
This tendency to "up-grade" or "down-grade" means that the cQmposi-
tion of particular grades will vary from year to year. Under such circum-
stances, the consumer is faced with a product of a given grade that will not
be the same product even though the grade is the same one time as com-
pared with another. It has been suggested that preference studies which
conclude that consumers are not discriminating as to grades do not neces-
sarily mean that the standards are incorrectly measuring consumer quality
preferences. On the contrary, they may indicate that consumers have found
the stated grades an unreliable measure of actual product quality and there-
fore ignore them.
One thing seems clear. Agricultural products, cannot hope for the
precise standardization that is possible with -~~ny industri~l_ prgdllcts.
Nature presents agriculture with a product which varies too widely in
quality to secure this kind of standardization.
_--
QualitlPeterio!:ation
__ -
-.
The problem of quality loss during marketing brings ,up. th~ ql,!~stio_Jl
of where ion the mar~eting channel should grading be done. If grades are
to fulfill their objective of telling producers what consumers consider de-
sirable, grading first must be done when the farmer sells his commodities.
Only then will he know what the quality and actual worth of his product
was. However, if quality deteriorates during the marketing process, this
grade will not remain accurate. ~h~r.efore, grading must be done as often
as needed t!Jr_oughout the marketing process to assure accurate grade when
it reaches the finaruser.
\
Sometimes there is confusion between the requirements for sanitation
and e~ibility and those for. ~.a!i_ty. For example, meat entering into inter-
state commerce must be federally inspected to make sure it is fit for human
consumption. The packing plants themselves must also meet certain
sanitary requirements. But such inspection has nothing to do with th_~
grading of meat for quality.
On the ot:her' hand, sanitary requirements are sometimes written into
the gradir.g standards. ~'lilk quality standards are a case in point. Though
the graue standards consider bacteria count, they also may ,prescribe the
ron~itj,o'~s_l1E9.er_\vhich cows mllst be hOllsed and milked, the ~ilk co~led,
14 Childress, op. cit., p. 75.
MARKETING OF AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS
and so forth. Regardless of bacteria count, milk cannot meet the grade re-
quirements unless it has been produced and handled under the designated
conditions. Such practices confuse the issue. Often, instead of facilitating
marketing processes, such standards turn into practical trade barriers and
techniques to control production.
PLACE OF GOVERNMENT
IN STANDARDIZATION
One of the prerequisites for an adequate grading system is a uniformity
of the standards and terminology to be applied throughout the market area
in question. In the United States this area for most commodities is the en-
tire country. Standards which are used in one state but not in others cause
confusion. In many cases, such differences may act as effective trade barriers
between states or regions.
As has been pointed out, real improvement in correcting this confusion
did not come until the federal government entered the picture. The
enabling legislation which was passed during the first two decades of this
century permitted the United States Department of Agriculture to enter
actively into the field of unifying standards of quality.
Federal standards for farm products fall into three classifications-
mandatory, permissive, and tentative. Mandatory standards are those whose
use is compulsory under certain conditions. Permissive standards are those
which are officially recommended but whose use is not compulsory. Tenta-
tive standards are those which are offered for use but are still subject to
further study before becoming permissive or mandatory. It is mandatory
that grains and cotton which move into interstate commerce and also those
which are traded on the futures exchanges be graded according to federal
standards. Apples and pears sold in the export trade, tobacco, and naval
stores also have mandatory standards. A list of the tentative and permissive
standards as of early 1952 listed some 136 standards for fresh fruits and
vegetables, some 110 for canned, dried, and frozen fruits and vegetables,
and some 59 for dairy and poultry products, livestock, meats, and miscel-
laneous other commoditiesY3
16 Check List of USDA Standards for Farm Products, USDA, Production and
lvlarketing Administration, 1952.
MARKETING OF AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS
Many states have adopted federal standards and have often made
them mandatory under certain circumstances. In some instances, states
have promulgated their own standards which differ from the federal stand-
ards and from other state standards. Such circumstances cause confusion
and often add to marketing costs through encouraging delays, waste, and
regrading. Many examples of these grade differences may be cited. Table 3
summarizes the differences in standards as set up for eggs.
Standards for milk are also an example of the variation which can
exist when various governmental units promulgate individual standards.
Cities as well as states are active in establishing milk standards. The ordi-
nances of eighty-four cities of 100,000 or more in population were studied
in 1949. It was found that of these eighty-four cities, twenty-three followed
the standards suggested by the states in which they were located, twenty
had prepared their own local regulations, and forty-one followed the basic
pattern of the United States Public Health Service Ordinance. Table 4
illustrates the range of bacterial count which was permitted in the best
grade of milk.
These two examples illustrate one of the important functions of the
federal government in s~andardization. Both in the case of eggs and milk,
the standards established by federal agencies act as a model for the stand-
ards which are established by other governmental units. In this way, the
tendency is toward uniformity even though wide differences continue to
exist.
Changes in federal standards, or the development of new ones, come
about slowly. Generally, the initial suggestions for changes come from the
trade or from research findings. Conferences are then held with industry
groups to obtain suggestions. Out of the research and suggestions grow
tentative grades which are tried out. Finally, after it appears that the stand-
Standardization and Grading 153
ards meet as many of the criteria for good standards as possible with current
knowledge and are usable by the trade, they are issued as the federal
standard. This process may extend over a period of several years.
SOURCE: Sanitary Milk and lee Cream Legislation in the United States, National
Research Council of the National Academy of Sciences, Bulletin 121, 1950.
SELECTED REFERENCES
Coles, J. V., and H. E. Erdman, "Some Aspects of the Arguments Against
Grade Labeling," Journal of l'vlarketing, January, 1945.
Juran, J. M., Quality-Control Handbook (New York, i'vleGraw-Hill, 1951).
Shepherd, G. S., Marketing Farm Products (Ames, Iowa State College Press,
1946), Chap. 14.
CHAPTER ELEVEN
Price Jnformation
Accurate and meaningful price information is very difficult to obtain.
Price has meaning only in reference to the product itself. The great dif-
ferences in quality and trade practices complicate the picture. The ac-
MARKETING OF AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS
Discount * 2 0 0 3
Premium:
~ I 0 3
Yz 2 0
9 I 12
% 0 0 2 0 2
1 0 1 5 1 7
I~ 0 0 0 1 1
lYz 0 0
9 10
Varying with grade 0 4 8
No premium or discount II °6 6
4
24
Total 16 9 28 17 70
* These three creameries sold butter Lo.b. factory; all others paid shipping costs to
market.
SOURCE: A. G. tvlathis and D. E. Hirsch, Butter Pricing by Iowa Creamerics, Farm
Credit Administration, USDA Circular C-136, 1950, p. 20.
Information Dissemination
If information is to be useful it must be timely. 'Vhat is considered
timeliness will vary with the different types of markets and different ways
in which information is used. Information which is to be used on the ex-
changes of the country is needed almost every minute during the trading
day. The li\'estock markets need information for each day's activities. Coun-
try markets for fruits and vegetables need rapid and detailed information
1 R. 1. Kohls and T. C. \Valz, Broiler Trucker-Buycrs in Indiana, Indiana Bulletin
=80, 195:::.
160 MARKETING OF AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS
during the production season~ but very little during the remainder of the
year. Reports on the retail trade may be issued weekly or even less often
and still be quite useful, since the retail price structure is slow to change.
Much useful information is not tied to the day-to-day workings of the
market and short-run price determination. Total production figures, reports
of products in storage, utilization patterns, and so on are useful longer-run
marketing information. The usefulness of much of the marketing data de-
pends not so much upon speed in dissemination as upon accuracy and
completeness. Probably as many important decisions hinge upon the
analysis of historical data as upon the receipt of immediate short-run in-
formation.
COLLECTION AND
DISSEMINATION AGENCIES
Private Agencies
l'iluch information is collected either formally or informally by busi-
nesses for their own use. Large food processors maintain large staffs to
collect and evaluate information usable to the company in the production
and marketing of its products. Much of this information, however, is not
available for others to use. In a sense, large companies obtain still stronger
bargaining positions because of their superior information facilities.
To offset this situation, trade organizations of different industries
compile market information for general use by their trade. Organizations
like the American Meat Institute, the National Grocery Manufacturers of
America, and the various trade organs of the wholesale and retail trade all
continually compile pertinent information. Much of this data is available
to those who wish to use it.
Some newspapers operate primarily as market information agencies.
General newspapers and radios also retain the services of farm editors,
financial editors, and others whose job it is to keep their public informed.
To this must be added the growing group of private research agencies which
perform specialized jobs for a fee. They may evaluate the market potential
for a new product, study how an old product may secure an expanding
market, or do any of a wide variety of informational tasks upon request.
Though much of the remainder of this chapter will discuss the activities of
governmental agencies, the importance of the private information services
must not be minimized.
Public Agencies
In the field of agricultural information, public agencies playa major
role in the collection of information. To a considerable extent, this job has
Collection and Use of Market Information 161
ccnsuses furnish the basic data and bench marks for much of the statistical
work done in the United States.
The Department of Agriculture is thc sourcc of the vast majority of
market and economic information pertinent to agricultural producers and
the food industry in general. I'vIuch of this information work is centered in
the Agricultural :Marketing Service (AMS), one of the major subdivisions
of the department.!!
The purpose of the Federal Market News Service operating within the
Agricultural l\Iarketing Service is to collect and distribute information on
prices, supply, and demand conditions which exist at the various marketing
points throughout the country.3 The service was established in 1913 by an
appropriation to aid in information collection. The first market report
issued was that covering the movement and prices of strawberries at Ham-
mond, Louisiana, in 1915. From this, the service has developed into its
current six branches for cotton, dairy and poultry, fruit and vegetables,
grain, livestock, and tobacco. In many instances the federal agencies have
entered into cooperative agreements with the individual states in order to
expand the coverage of the service.
l\1arket news reporters stationed at the various important markets and
production areas of the country collect much of the data for the market
news reports. These men are specialists in their individual fields. The
market information must be collected from the various individuals and
agencies actively marketing the product. The information which agencies
give might be incorrect or biased. The news reporter must be thoroughly
acquainted with the market and the product so as to appraise the accuracy
of the information obtained. For example, a livestock news reporter must
be able to grade livestock and be thoroughly acquainted with the method
of the livestock trad~. The same is true for the news reporter for each of the
other commodities.
The various offices are tied together by leased wire and telephone
services as shown in Figure 1. \Vith this communication system, informa-
tion can be exchanged almost instantaneously with all other points in the
country. Messages placed on the wire at anyone point reach all other points
on the circuit and, when desired, can be relayed to offices on other circuits.
Speed is of major importance in making such market information
2 Prior to the reorganization of the department in November, 1953, the market news
work was centered in the Production and fvlarketing Administration (Pl\'lA) and the
estimating work in the Bureau of Agricultural Economics (BAE). Most of the activities
of these two organizations were collected in the AMS, and the PMA and BAE as such
were abolished.
3 Much of the following concerning the operation of the Market News Service has
been taken from Agricultural Estimating and Reporting Services, USDA Misc. Publica·
tion 703.
Collection and Use of Market Information 163
useful to the trade. Agencies or individuals can subscribe to the Com-
mercial News Dispatch Service of the \Vestem Union Telegraph Company
which obtains information directly from the Market News Service. Radio
is widely used in distributing the market reports. Nearly 1,100 radio stations
throughout the country regularly broadcast market news information. The
information is also made available to the press services of the country. Most
of the daily newspapers carry market news either completely or in part as
collected by the federal and state agencies.
Daily, weekly, and monthly mimeograph reports and summaries are
available free of charge from the markets covered by the service. Such re-
ports arrive by mail and are usually too late to be of use in evaluating imme-
diate market conditions, but they are useful in evaluating the trends which
are developing. The following illustrates the type and extent of the infor-
mation available from the various offices of the Market News Service:
Cotton:
1. Prices on lint cotton, cotton linters, and cottonseed.
2. Daily price quotations on ten principal markets.
3. Quality data during the ginning season.
Dairy and Poultry:
1. Prices, receipts, dealer's stocks, cold storage holdings, and retail move-
ments are reported for butter, cheese, fluid milk, cream, dried milk and
products, condensed and evaporated milk, shell, frozen, and dried eggs,
live and dressed poultry.
Fruits and Vegetables:
1. Prices and supply movements for the large city markets.
2. Shipping area data on prices, volume of loadings, quality, and market
trends.
3. Cold storage holdings in principal centers.
Grain:
1. Daily grain prices and supply movements (both cash and futures) for the
principal markets.
2. Prices, market movements, and production data of feedstuffs.
3. Country shipping point prices of hay, beans, hops, and some others.
Livestock:
1. Prices and supply movements on the principal livestock markets.
2. vVholesale meat prices and information on large consuming centers.
3. Feder livestock prices and supplies.
4. Cold storage holdings.
Tobacco:
1. Prices and supply movements on important auction markets.
2. Piices, supplies, and relatcd data for the growing area.
MARKET NEWS OFFICES AND
SEASONAL OFfiCES
82 SO\,;T)o!(RN i>1N[ S, N C ... S 90 W.CON. ";A .. $ 9:1 PLAN! ClfT, FLA" S 106 L[ES6\JR:;. n .. A S
• C;Cno... 6 COTTONSE [0
• (lA\"-' eo PQ\,)\,.TRl'
.a. FRUITS a Ve:CETASl(S
a GRAW, HAT, FE [0. S[[O, RIC' • ..cPS, StAHl
• Lt\lESTQCIC, ~(ATS a "'OOL
EI MOI.l.SSES Ii SUGARClJojE SlF1~~
e N:'V~ STeR£:;
H~ P.c.U5AC£. CCl.O .. S
",..,
II6~AJoCO fALJ••S,lQAl-(l4 os
111PATETTE,IOAHO. S
Ii3LOCl.tJ.ll'" S
1r9s.:.I..I~~A-S. e"L.I' .. S
1?\)!oAh"'A"~lA..t.to",lJ= "'$
.;>. 8P,~""lET. CALli .. 5
1~1 Tl~A. ~IZ ... S
IZl PH-.;O.;T LRII ... S
Livestock:
1. January 1 numbers, value per head, and total value, by states, of livestock
on farms and ranches; published every February.
2. January 1 cattle, sheep, and lambs on feed; published in January. Reports
on development of feeding situation are issued in October, November,
and December.
3. Sow farrowings and pigs saved in the spring and fall season along with
sow breeding intentions; released in June and December.
4- Report on the early lamb crop issued in March and on total lamb crop in
July; lamb crop development reports are also released in April and May.
5. Estimates of wool and mohair production; issued in IVIarch.
6. Condition of western range feeder cattle and sheep; reported monthly.
7. Shipments of stocker and feeder cattle and sheep into eight leading feed-
ing states; reported monthly. Shipments of lambs from western feed lots;
reported weekly from January through May.
8. Meat animal farm production, disposition, and cash receipt estimates by
states; issued every April.
9. L;vestock slaughter and meat production estimates; published monthly.
Dairy:
L Number of milk cows on farms; released January 1 and monthly.
2.Milk production per cow; released monthly.
3. AnTIual production of milk and butterfat on farms.
4. Annual farm disposition of and income from milk.
5. Rations fed to milk cows; published monthly.
pret and appraise current market information and make predictions con-
cerning future trends. These publications often report research findings
of special interest. Some of the more important of these reports, in most
instances available free, are as follows:
The Agricultural Situation. A popular type of monthly publication which con-
tains brief reviews of current economic developmcnts affecting farmers. Short
articles also report new findings and conditions of special interest.
The Demand and Price Situation. This monthly publication reports the more
technical details, analyzing the demand and price prospccts for agriculture.
Thcre are brief outlook reviews for each of the major commodity groups.
This is probably thc best publication for those who wish to keep abreast of
the general trends of the markets. The Agricultural Outlook Digest is a single
page summary of the general and specific commodity situations. It also is
issued monthly.
The Marketing and Transportation Situation. This monthly publication con-
tains statistical tables showing price spreads between the farmer and the
consumer. It also includes summary reports of some of the latest develop-
ments in the field of agricultural marketing. The publication, Marketing
Activities, also is issued monthly. This also reports results of marketing re-
search and current developments in the field of standardization, grading, and
price support activities.
Commodity Situation Reports (the cotton, dairy, fats and oils, feed, fruit, live-
stock and meat, poultry and egg, tobacco, vegetable, wheat, wool, world sugar,
national food, and farm cost situations). Some of these are issued monthly;
others periodically. Each appraises the current market situation and future
prospects for the respective commodity. Articles of special interest in the par-
ticular commodity groups are also carried. In all of the Situation reports, one
issue in the fall, usually October, is devoted to the analysis of the outlook for
the next year.
The above illustrates the scope and type of information available. In
spite of the availability of such information, many producers and marketing
agencies are notoriously uninformed. Ignorance is not a passive situation.
Information is a strong competitive weapon. To assemble and properly
evaluate pertinent information is one of the most difficult jobs facing
marketing personne1. In this work even the most astute make costly mis-
takes. However, to remain voluntarily uninformed when so much informa-
tion is available is the most costly mistake of all.
Extension of Coverage
More specific information is needed. ,\Vith the wide range of qualities
that are involved, price, supply, and demand information will have its
maximum use only if it is related to specific grades and conditions. Since
many agricultural products have several uses, information needs to be
specific as to use. For example, price quotations for the fruit which is to
be used fresh cannot be interchanged with those quotations for the fruit
which is to be used for processing. Feeder livestock conditions need to
be reported separately from slaughter livestock market conditions. Informa-
tion needs to be more detailed and specific as to the level of the marketing
channel being reported, such as f.o.b. prices at the country elevators,
prices in the terminal market, and retail prices.
There is a need for additional regional or local data. Much of the
information is collected on a state or national basis. Political subdivisions,
however, do not necessarily correspond with the areas which are economi-
cally homogeneous. For example, local and regional data of the broiler
chick placement statistics are gathered and reported for our major broiler
areas. Some of these areas, such as the Del-Mar-Va peninsula, northern
Georgia, and northwestern Arkansas, represent highly specialized regions
for which state-wide data would not be adequate.
There is a need to fill the large gaps in which no information is now
available. One of these blank areas is that of the retail trade. Information
which would permit consumers to compare prices and products more
rationally should enhance competition at this level of the marketing
system. There are many commodities about which very little information
is available. Such commodities are often considered "minor" when viewed
from the national viewpoint. However, to the specialized producers, in-
formation for such products is of major importance. Naval stores and black-
strap molasses are examples of this type of product. Gum turpentine and
rosin are distilled from crude pine gum which is produced by over 8,000
farmers. Nearly three-fourths of the total production is in Georgia. As an
industry it has an annual gross value of many millions of dollars. To the
Georgia producers it is a product of major importance. Yet there is nothing
available from the federal services in the way of market information.5
services which once were adequate may not meet the requirements of a new
situation.
One of the important causes of information problems is the decentrali-
zation of the marketing processes which has taken place for many products.
The large central wholesale markets which once handled the bulk of the
products now may be largely by-passed. The principal level of initial trans-
actions is now in the production area, and the transactions at large whole-
sale terminals may no longer be a representative picture. The growth of
direct marketing of livestock means that other coverage than that of the
terminal market must be devised if the information is to be representative
of the livestock being marketed. The informational services for butter were
set up to cover the large central exchanges which originally handled the
great majority of the butter transactions. However, during 1949 it was
estimated that the butter sold on the Chicago Exchange represented only
I } percent of all the butter received in Chicago and less than two-tenths of
1 percent of all the butter produced in the United States. 6 Examples of
Methodology of Collectio1l
Above we have pointed up the need for more i~formational services.
However, there is also a need for more accurate coverage. Questions of
accuracy arise with regularity. Some are sure the estimates for the pig crop,
the corn crop, or the cotton crop are too high or too low. Many times the
estimates prove to be correct, but in a few cases they have been decidedly
6 Hugh L. Cook, "Central Market Quotations and Country Buying," Journal of
Dissemination of Information
As pointed out in the discussion of usable information, timeliness
is of great importance. \Vith the development of modem communications,
the demand for speed has increased. The mail and press were aided by
the telephone and telegraph. To these methods were added radio and more
recently television. \Vith each new method of communication, the empha-
sis on speed has increased. Also, the area over which the information is
used has broadened.
Much of the information of a more basic character does not require
such speedy dissemination. In this area, the mails remain the most im-
portant method of dissemination. Even here, however, there is a need for
more uniform terminology in describing marketing conditions as the area
of use grows larger. l'vlarket reporters no longer can use their own peculiar
teminology in explaining marketing conditions. The preparation of press
and radio releases in language which cannot be misunderstood is important.
In this important field, many of our informational agencies need much
more experience.
An educational program for the users of the information is also needed.
Onl~' in this way will data be used for the purpose for which they were
Collection and Use of Market Information 173
intended and nothing more. The use of price ranges instead of single
specific prices is an example of the misunderstanding and misuse of infor-
mation. In many markets, because of the number and variation of the
transactions, the reporting of a specific meaningful price is not possible.
Only a price range represents the true picture. However, some of the users
of the information desire a single quotation and criticize the use of price
ranges. This demonstrates misunderstanding of the mechanics of the
marketing and price making process. All considered, the securing of ade-
quate dissemination and wise use of information present problems no less
difficult than those involved in collection.
SELECTED REFERENCES
Agricultural Economic and Statistical Publications, USDA, Bureau of Agricul-
tural Economics, 1952.
Clark, F. K, and L. D. H. \Veld, Marketing Agricultural Products (New York,
lvlacmillan, 1932), Chap. 15.
Shepherd, G. S., Marketing Farm Products (Ames, Iowa State College Press,
1946), Chap. 6.
Taylor, A. C., and Ann D. Taylor, The Story of Agricultural Economics (Ames,
Iowa State College Press, 1952), Chaps. 12, 13, and 17.
Thomsen, F. L., Agricultural Marketing (New Yark, McGraw-Hili, 195 1 ),
Chap. 14.
CHAPTER TWELVE
Cfransportation
Products must be moved from where they are produced into the areas
where they will be consumed. As we have seen from our study of the
relationship of production and consumption areas of agricu1tural products,
this is no simple task. Adequate and efficient transportation is a cornerstone
of our modern marketing system. The wide variety of food available in
our grocery stores at all times of the year would not be possible without
modern transportation. How this moving job is done and some of its major
problems are discussed in the pages that follow.
PERCENT PERCENT
Grains 91 9
Fruits 83 17
Vegetables 82 18
Livestock 88 12
Milk 97 3
Cotton 96 4
Poultry and eggs 96 4
Tobacco 99 1
i\Iiscellaneous crops 85 15
All commodities 89 11
Grains 54 34 12
Fruits 40 20 40
Vegetables 59 20 21
Livestock 21 61 18
Milk 30 41 29
Cotton 7° 28 2
Poultry and eggs 27 13 60
Tobacco 44 52 4
Miscellaneous crops 46 24 30
All commodities 45 33 2:?
A'1arkets by Rail and Motor Truck, 1939-50, Bureau of '\gricultural Economics, USDA
Mimeograph, 1951.
PERCENT OF FOOD RECEIPTS
BY RAIL AND TRUCK
Major Markets, Selected Commodities, 1950
COMMODITY PERCENT OF TOTAL RECEIPTS
o 25 50 75 100
LI V E PO U L TRY ......... I - - - - - - , - - - - - : - - - - _ - - - . J I
5 HELL EGG 5 ...•.•..... I--_ _--,-_ _ _-:--_ _ _ _ _~
1 77
MARKETING OF AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS
2. Commodities which hav~ a high value per pound or are bulky have
comparatively high rail rates while those which have low value or are
less bulky have relatively low rail rates.
3. Some commodities are more susceptible to damage in transit. Shipment
by rail freight is frequently considered to be more damaging than ship-
ment by truck because of more jolting and handling.
4- Shippers which need speedy or more "door-to-door" service prefer the
truck over the rail shipment.
Rail Transportation
Even though the inroads of the truck have been severe, the railroad is
still a very important agency for moving agricultural products. Agricultural
\Vater Transportation
\\Then compared to the volume hauled by truck and rail, the volume
of agricultural commodities carried on the inland and coastal watenvays
of the country is small. However, where speed is not important and the
commodity has great bulk and weight, water transportation is often the
cheapest method of transportation. For example, in early 1953 the rail
freight rate for hauling wheat, corn, and oats from Minneapolis to New
Orleans was $10.30 per ton. The barge rate for the same trip was $4.50
per ton.
The Great Lakes and Mississippi River system are the most important
arteries of waler commerce in the United States. \Vith the development
of Diesel towboats, the barge traffic on the rvIississippi system jumped
from 5.5 billion ton-miles in 1931 to 36 billion ton-miles in 1951. Grain is
the principal agricultural product which is transported by water. One out
of every five barges hauls grain. Some of the larger barge tows will now move
200,000 bushels of grain. In 1951, 46 percent of the corn and 30 percent
of the wheat exported from New Orleans arrived by barge. 5
Air Transportation
Agricultural air freight is still in its infancy. The quantities of agricul-
tural commodities which are moved by air freight are very small indeed. Cut
5 Stanley Phillips. "Grain Traffic of the ;\lississippi River and Its Tributaries,"
::- ;,'rketing and Transportation Situation, USDA, April, 1953; also, the \Vall Street
/oumai, ;\lay :!.7, 1952.
180 MARKETING OF AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS
flowers and nursery products are the biggest single agricultural users of air
freight. Some fruits have been moved in limited quantities on an experi-
mental basis. In a few instances, some of the very early season produce is
rushed to market by air in order to secure premium prices.
The future of air transportation cannot be evaluated on the basis of
current freight rates alone. Substantial economies may be forthcoming
in other ways. Lighter containers may be used. Some packing and other
marketing costs may be largely eliminated. For example, the usual methods
of handling off-season tomatoes is to pick them green and ripen them after
they reach the consumption centers. If tomatoes were picked when vine-
ripened and shipped by air overnight to the markets, the ripening costs of
2 to 3 cents per pound might be eliminated. The air shipment of lettuce
from California might substantial1y reduce the icing costs. Under normal
rail shipment, icing costs are about 50 cents per crate; this cost could be
largely eliminated with air shipment.6
In addition to these possible savings in current marketing costs, there
is the unknown factor of the effect upon demand. Many believe that if con-
sumers were supplied with tree-ripened fruit they would buy more at the
same or higher prices. Perhaps it is in this area of increased consumer
acceptance that the real net gain from air transportation may develop.
The potential for air transportation of selected high value, perishable,
and seasonal products appears considerable. However, the impact upon
marketing methods and costs will be great. Changes probably will have to
be made in harvesting, processing, packaging, and the assembly of the
commodity.
FREIGHT RATES
The level of and changes in freight rates have always been a matter'
of concern to agricultural producers. 'Vith the inelastic nature of agri-
cultural supply, at least in the short run, changes in the freight rate struc-
ture are absorbed by agricultural producers through lower farm prices.
Also, changes in rates which are unequal for various sections of the country
may change the competitive advantage of producers in one section com-
pared with those in another section. It was the rural agitation of the Grange
movement of the 1870'S which is credited with laying the groundwork for
the creation of the Interstate Commerce Commission in 1887-
The Freight Rate Structure
The railroad freight rate structure of the United States is a very
complex, and often irrational, thing. In general there are two basic types
6 R. \V. Hoecker, et al., Air Transport of Agricultural Perishables, USDA Misc.
Publication 585, 1946.
Transportation 181
of rates, the class rates and the commodity rates. Class rates are those
which are estab1ished for a 1imited number of broad categories into which
thousands of different products can be placed. This eliminates the necessity
of establishing individual rates for each different product. Commodity
rates are those which are established specifically for an individual com-
modity considering the needs and problems of shippers. Such rates are
established for large·volume, low-valued items such as coal, ore, and grain.
j\,Iost agricultural products move under commodity rates. Over four-fifths
of the total carloads of all products is moved under commodity rates.
In establishing the class rates, the country is divided into five rate
territories each with different rates. These regional differences in rates have
resulted in continual controversy. It is claimed that rate differentials have
encouraged industrial development in the northeastern region of the
United States, and discouraged such development in the southern and
western regions. This situation results in the long hauls to move raw
products eastward for manufacture.
Just how much the differential freight rate structure has retarded the
industrial development of some sections of the country is a matter of
debate, but there is general agreement that regional rate differences cannot
be entirely justified on the basis of cost difference. 7 Many contend that
changes in the freight rate structure would encourage industrial develop-
ment in the areas near the raw materials. Since most manufacturing and
precessing generally result in less bulky and higher-valued products than
the original raw material, this could mean substantial savings in the trans-
portation costs.
Commodity rates are generally lower than class rates. These rates vary
somewhat in line with the "cost of service." Some of the factors considered
here are the length of haul, weight that can be shipped in a car, and the
risk of loss and damage. The great variation in distance and bulk among
commodities can be seen from studying Table 4- The effect of the length
of haul can be seen in the cost per hundredweight. Sugar beets which
are shipped for only a very short distance cost much less per hundred-
weight than apples or lettuce which travel long distances. However, the
bulk weight of commodities also affects the cost as can be seen from
variations in the revenue per ton-mile.
There are also rate differences depending upon whether the shipment
is in carlot (c.1.) or less than carlot (l.c.l.) amounts. The rate is generally
lower on the carlots than the less than carlot shipment. This preferential
rate for carlots was one of the-reasons for the development of early coopera-
tivc livestock shipping associations. As the railroad was the only method
of moving livestock to major markets, the association assembled small lots
from individual farmers so they could ship into the terminal markets at
carlot rates.
REVENUE
* Short-line mile is the shortest practicable railroad distance between origin and
destination; actual haul usually is somewhat longer.
SOURCE: Donald E. Church, Effect of Increases in Freight Rates in Agricultural
Products, USDA Circular 847, 1950.
It is the job of the Commission to see that tIle rates are "reasonable
and just." \\That are the standards for such rates? Some measuring sticks
for answering this question have been laid down by legislative action and
are continually being revised by court decisions. The Commission was
directed originally by Congress to provide for an adequate railroad net-
work. The first basis for making decisions was that rates should give a
fair return upon the property value of the railroads. In a resolution passed
by the Congress in 1925, the Commission was further directed to consider
"the conditions which at any time prevail in our several industries . . . ."
In the 1930's, the emphasis shifted from a fair return upon property value
to a return which would enable the carriers to attract additional capital
from investors. The Commission was then given the additional directive
to give consideration to the effect which the rates would have. on the
movement of traffic.
The Commission, then, is faced with the dilemma of establishing
rates which will yield un adequate return (as measured against some
standard) on the one hand, but which will consider the economic "ability
to pay" of the shipper on the other. This is the heart of the modem rail
rate problem. Diversion to trucks is cutting into rail volume. Operating
costs of railroads may rise, or remain stable, when other prices are falling.
To provide revenue which will maintain an adequate rail system may
require rate increases at the very time when shippers need a downward
revision in rates. The Commission has answered this situation on various
occasions in the past by exempting some commodities from rate increases
and by giving special treatment to others.
Transportation 185
o
1910 1920 1930 1940 1950
YEAR BECfNHING JULY' 1.1911·'''; CALEHDA.R YEJ.R. 19"'$.Sl
generalizations. First, rates remain relatively stable during the first stages
of a rise in agricultural prices, but they finally increase sharply. This increase
may occur even after the rise in farm prices is over and has turned down-
\vard. Secondly, once the rate increase is accomplished, the new level tends
to become permanent even though other prices decline sharply.
111ese relationships mean that during rising prices, freight rates de-
cline relative to farm prices. But during falling prices, the rates rise relative
to farm prices. The data on wheat prices and freight rates presented in
Table 6 illustrates this. The selected years given show the major changes
,,·hich have occurred in prices for wheat. In the immediate postwar years
MARKETlNG OF AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS
of 1919 and 1946, wheat prices had risen from prewar levels, but the freight
rate had increased only slightly. During those years, it required only 4.4
and 6.9 bushels to pay the freight on 100 bushels. However, in 1921 and
1932, prices broke sharply. In 19:n, freight rates actually increased and in
1932 they remained unchanged. The results were that it required 11 bushels
in 1921 and 24 bushels in 1932 to pay freight on 100 bushels of wheat.
This frcight-price relationship becomes particularly critical for those
shippers located long distances from markets. The inflexibility of the
rates often explains why a sharp market price decline for perishables, for
example, will result in California growers either destroying or leaving crops
unharvested. After freight and harvesting costs are met, the result may be
an actual net dollars loss to the grmver. He logically attempts to minimize
his losses by not incurring these expenses by not harvesting either part or
all of his crop.
SOURCE: i\dapted from data in Chief Factors Undcrl;.-ing General Changes in Rail
Freigizt Hates by Ezekiel Limmer, Bureau of Agricultural Economics, USDA 1'.limeo·
graph, 1951.
REDUCTION OF
TRANSPORTATION COSTS
Rates and Methods of Transportation
There appears to be little justification for basing hopes of reducing
transportation costs on lowcr truck and rail freight rates. Past history offers
little encouragemcnt that ra tcs can be reduced substantially. Rather, the
future'probably holds increased rates. Also, competition between the trucks
and railroad carriers cannot be cQunted upon to accomplish any major re-
Transportation 187
duction in costs. Though the diversion of business from railroad to truck
will probably continue, there will always be a place for both types of carriers.
The principal advantage of trucks lies in their speed, versatilil:jr, and con-
venience in short hauls and to small shippers. The advantage of rail carriers
is their ability to carry huge volumes over long distances with dependability
and regularity.
'Vith the increased development of the larger truck and nation-wide
trucking companies, the trucking industry will probably be subjected to
more and more regulations similar to those covering railroads. There is
a growing tendency for greater state taxation on trucking. \Vith ever-
grovving highway maintenance problems, states are insisting that trucks
pay a larger share of the road costs. Both trucks and railroads will probably
improve the efficiency of their operations with the passing of time. These
improvements cannot be depended upon to do more than hold down the
pressure for higher rates. It also seems likely that the rate advantages now
held by some segments of the truck industry will gradually disappear.
Unit costs of operation of the transportation agencies also are rela-
tively fixed. This means that in good or poor times for the economy as a
whole, there is only a very sluggish change in operating expenses. Because
of this, there is little hope for increased flexibility of rates. This means
that in periods of low prices, transportation rates will continue to be rela-
tively high. In times of prosperity, they will be relatively lower. Some sort
of public subsidization is probably the only way in which any considerable
flexibility could be obtained in rates.
Part of the cost of truck transportation arises from the barriers which
individU<i1 states have erected in the form of varying regulations on \veight
and dimensions (Table 7). Such regulations make it impossible for trucks
to pass freely from state to state. Loads often must be changed or rerouted
if the truck passes over state borders. There is a movement among states
188 MARKETING OF AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS
Bu1letin 479,1945.
Transportation 189
loads. The average daily load in February for some routes studied was less
than half of practical capacity. One study summarizes the savings possible
through combinations as follows:
For example, two haulers collecting milk in adjacent country areas 40 miles
or more from the city could save about 80 miles daily. At variable costs of 6,54
cents per mile, savings would be $5.23 or about $2.60 per hauler per day. On
many routes such temporary consolidations would be possible from 60 to 120
days each year. 1 !!
Farm assembly of products is not the only area where poorly planned
and underutilized transportation facilities exist. The pressures to conserve
tires and gasoline during World 'Var II exposed many other areas in the
marketing system where the same type of savings could be made. Every-
other-day delivery of bottled milk to consumers was substituted for daily
delivery. Better planning found return loads of fertilizer and other needed
supplies for the trucks which transported livestock to central markets. Often
many of these trucks previously had made the return trip empty.
(2) Reduce the spoilage, damage, and breakage during transportation.
This is an area which offers considerable opportunity to reduce real trans-
portation costs. Many of the remedies to reduce spoilage and breakage are
remarkably simple. Three factors account for much of the wide variation
in damage claims presented to railroads. These are differences in the value
of the carload because of the density and bulk of the product, types and
suitability of the containers, and the degree and efficiency of the loading
and bracing methods used in preparing the car for shipment,13
Nearly three-fourths of the total damage claims for fruits and vege-
tables occurs because of unsuitable and faulty containers and poor loading
practices (Table 8). These are factors subject to control and improvement.
For example, it was found that cantaloupe crates loaded on end had only
about one-third the breakage as when the crates were loaded on their sides
and lengthwise of the car. Also, a new method of bracing the crates in the
car was found to be superior to the one commonly used.14 The tying of a
single wire around lettuce crates was found to reduce crates damaged in
shipment from 11.5 percent to 6.2 percent,15 Experimentation is now going
12 N. T. Pritchard and \V. H. Cope, l\filk Assembly in the Fort \Vaync Milkshed,
on with new containers and new packing methods for many commodities.
::\Iany of the methods and containers used have not changed from the early
days of railroad transportation. Imagination coupled with a lack of rever-
ence for the status quo can produce cost-saving results.
PERCENT PERCENT
* Includes breakage of containers, loss and damage due to excessive rough handling
in transit, faulty or improper methods of packaging, loading, and bracing.
(3) Change the product itself. In this area probably are some of the
greatest potentialities for attacking the transportation cost problem. High
damage claims, to a substantial extent, hinge around the nature of the
product itself. The product should not be accepted as a given, unchange-
able fact. It, too, can be changed.
High perishability is one of the basic reasons for expensive transporta-
tion. But poor quality products are more perishable than top quality
products. An expanded program of farm selling on grades might result in
products being more c10sely graded before shipment. Only those products
best able to stand up during movement then would move long distances.
Those which might deteriorate more quickly would be sold in the nearby
markets.
Bulky, low-valued shipments can also be changed. The shipment of
frozen, concentrated orange juice in place of the whole fruit is an example
of one type of possible change. The production-area slaughter of livestock
and the shipment of carcasses rather than the live animals is another
example of product change which can be made. In general, production-
area processing win result in a less bulky, higher-value-and oftentimes less
perishable-product for shipment to consumption areas.
(4) Reduce barriers to interstate shipment. As has been pointed out,
the various states have different truck weight limits, licensing regulations,
and so forth. Such differences often cause costly rerouting or reloading.
A "truckload" in one state may be an illegal "overload" in another. One
Transportation 191
has only to notice the weigh stations that exist at the state borders to
realize that there are barriers to movement. An eliminaion of these barriers
through increased uniformity of regulations could reduce transportation
costs.
Storage
STORAGE OPERATIONS
There are two general types of normal storage operations. One is that
which equalizes seasonal production to the pattern of demand. The other
is the storage at all times within trade channels which is necessary to keep
the marketing system operating without interruption. The first type of
storage operation is undertaken by elevators, warehouses, and other places
of mass accumulation. The latter type of storage operation is largely the
operating inventories of the various manufacturers, wholesalers, retailers,
and to a small extent consumers of the nation.
1600
1400
Dec.
FIG U R E 1. Relations of monthly storage holdings to the sea-
son~l pattern of production, 1946-1950 average.
storage. In this way, the amount available for current consumption is re-
duced. Then, as production declines, stocks move out of storage and into
consumption. During this latter period amounts available for consumption
are maintained at levels above current production. For example, total meat
production starts increasing about September and reaches its peak levels
during December and January. Starting about October, cold storage
holdings increase and continue to grow until about March. From March
on through the summer, when meat production is low, meat moves out of
storage and into consumption.
In the case of storable crops which are harvested during a very short
time of the year, the entire production must be stored and doled out for
consumption throughout the remainder of the year. Table 1 shows the
amount and place of storage of two crops as we move through the year.
Corn is harvested during October and November, therefore January 1
storage holdings are the largest of the year. Then they work down to the
c:any-over levels of October. Wheat storage is highest during the quarter
MARKETING OF AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS
INTERIOR GOVERN-
QUARTER MILLS, MENT
AND ON TERMINAL ELEVATORS, MERCHANT OWNED TOTAL
COMMODITY FARM MARKETS WAREHOUSES MILLS STOCKS * STORAGE
MILLION BUSHELS
Corn:
January 1 2,042 31 ;1 50 2,174
April 1 1,287 29 47 48 1,411
July 1 766 17 37 47 86 7
October 1 366 13 34 64 447
\Vheat:
January 1 373 137 15 6 106 7 77 8
April 1 206 88 102 71 5 472
July 1 62 73 51 32 4 222
October 1 53 1 20 4 24 8 13 0 5 1,118
Com:
January 1 93. 0 1.4 2·4 2·3 100.0
April 1 91.3 2.0 3·3 H 100.0
July 1 88,3 2.0 4·3 5·4 100.0
October 1 75. 2 2·9 7·5 14·4 100.0
\Vheat:
January 1 47. 8 17.6 20.1 13.6 0·9 100.0
April 1 43·7 18,7 21.7 14·9 1.0 100.0
July 1 27. 8 33. 2 22·9 14·4 1.7 100.0
October 1 47·5 18.2 22.2 11.6 0·5 100.0
* This is not too representative, for the government is in and out of the market
picture as the price support program is brought into play some years more than others.
SOURCE: USDA statistics.
COSTS OF STORAGE
It is extremely difficult to isolate realistica11y the cost of the storage
function from the costs of the functions of financing and risking. With the
3 H. S. Yohe, "Storage Under License," Marketing Activities, USDA, December,
194 8 .
Storage 197
hoMing of goods, one either foregoes possible money income or borrows
money against the goods. Also, with the holding of goods one incurs various
kinds of risk. In determining the total costs of holding commodities, five
possible categories of costs must be considered as follows:
1. The costs necessary to provide and maintain the physical facilities for
storage. These costs would include such items as repairs, depreciation,
and insurance against loss.
2. The interest on the financial investment in the product while it is in
storage. Whether money is actually borrowed or not, this is a cost
which should be assessed at the rate of interest which would have to
be paid if money were borrowed during the storage period.
3. The cost of quality deterioration and shrinkage during storage. Most
commodities either deteriorate in quality or shrink in volume-or
both-while in storage. In a few cases, some commodities, such as corn,
may increase in quality while shrinking in volume. In such cases, storage
may result in a net gain instead of a net loss for this particular factor.
4. The loss which may result from poor consumer acceptance of the stored
as against the "fresh" product. Packing companies maintain that frozen
meat will be accepted by consumers only at a price discount, even
though quality as measured by the grading system has not deteriorated.
There is consumer resistance to storage eggs compared to fresh eggs,
though the quality as measured by the grading system may be the same.
This is not a problem in all commodities. Nor do such consumer pref-
erence patterns remain unchanged. For example, there is evidence that
the widespread acceptance of food lockers and home freezers is over-
coming the resistance to frozen meats.
5. The risk that general business conditions might deteriorate and the
general level of prices decline. Under these circumstances, the product
might have to be sold at less than its into-storage value. The possibility
of a favorable movement in prices, on the other hand, is a major factor
in encouraging speculative storage.
Technology in Food Marketing, USDA, Agricultural Monograph No. 14, 1952, espe-
cially ch. 4.
Storage 199
chemical when placed in storage will not sprout readily. Another ex-
ample is the use of "modified atmosphere" wherein proportions of
various gases are controlled in gas·tight rooms to retard deterioration.
Practices followed in preparing products for storage have an im-
portant effect on their storability. The deterioration rate of many prod-
ucts can be reduced if the temperature is reduced as soon after harvest
as possible. The discovery that cuts and bruises received during harvest-
ing reduce storage life has led to redesigning of machinery to reduce
sharp edges and dropping distances. The proper farm use of insecticides
and fungicides has reduced storage rotting which follows insect injury.
The degree of ripeness at harvest has also been related to length of
storage life. In grains, this has led to experimentation on various
methods of quick drying immediately after harvest. It is not too great
a dream to imagine that the combines of tomorrow will both harvest
and flash dry the grain in one operation.
2. Reduction of the costs of the physical facilities used for storage. The
most fruitful possibility here seems to be that of increasing the labor
efficiency in handling through reorganization and additional mechani-
zation. Often a by-product of such work is an increase in effective
storage capacity of a given area.
The concept that storage is not static but is instead an integral part
of the movement of goods has directed increasing attention toward
handling problems of all types. Much of the work and expense of ware-
housing occurs during the unloading and loading operations. Attention
to this idea of movement has led to the construction of one·story ware-
hOllses with ample loading facilities in contrast to the old multiple-story
buildings. The use of pallet storage along with the fork-lift truck, con-
veyor systems, automatic dumping devices, and other mechanical de-
vices is giving some storage operations a long-needed face lifting. One
multiple-story warehouse originally handled a maximum of five trucks a
day and 40,000 cases a month with a work force of fourteen. After rede-
signing and installing new eqUipment it could handle ten trucks a day
and 50,000 cases a month with a work force of seven. 5 The same dra-
matic changes were accomplished when the design and methods of
many grain elevators were changed.
Developments in ventilation and insulation are making both cold
and general nonrefrigerated storage possible in the same space. New
advances in the science of refrigeration are both reducing the cost and
increasing the dependability of refrigerated storage. Study is undenvay
on the problem of odor contamination of one product by another. If
5 Technology in Food Marketing, op. cit., p. 60.
200 MARKETING OF AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS
odor controls can be worked out, commodities which now must be kept
separated in different facilities may be stored together. This would
greatly increase the flexibility of storage space.
3. Reduction of consumer resistance to storage products. Change here will
come slowly and with difficulty. In many instances resistance rests upon
prejudice instead of fact. In other cases, poor consumer acceptance has
carried over from a past period when storage did result in a poorer
quality product. \Vith the increasing use of frozen food lockers and
home freezers, many consumers are demonstrating to themselves that
refrigeration and storage need not harm the product. The real problem
in this area may be the resistance to change of many marketing and
processing agencies and not of consumers themselves.
+ Changing the product or the pattern of production. Many of the real
improvements in the storage problem can be classified here. Since part
of the storage problem rests upon the production pattern, some of the
cost reduction practices must be initiated on the farm or in the
factory.
In some commodities, such as eggs and hogs, production has grad-
ually shifted to a more uniform year-round pattern. Such changes reduce
the amount of storage needed. (For example, see the discussion on egg
production changes in Chapter 17.) In other cases, product develop-
ments have changed the nature of storage operation. The rapid devel-
opment of the frozen orange juice concentrate has shifted the emphasis
from that of maintaining fresh fruit to that of properly maintaining the
frozen product. If the experimentation with powdered orange juice
produces a practical market product, the storage considerations will
again be different. The trend toward more processed, table-ready meats
has changed some of the meat storage requirements. The development
of frozen and dried eggs in addition to shell eggs has increased the flex-
ibility of egg storage operations. Some varieties of crops have been found
to be better for storage than others.
5. Reduction of the sp.::culation in the storage operation resulting from
changes in the general level of prices. Perhaps this should not be listed
here since its implications are much broader than that of reducing
storage costs. This is part of the larger price policy question. Speculative
implications are important in orderly storage. The amount and timing
of this year's into-storage movement of many products often are affected
by last year's profit experiences. The level of farm prices during these
into-storage periods of the year may be particularly sensitive to the level
of demand for storage. Therefore, this year's price experiences may carry
over into next year. Though over the years storage must be done, this
Storage 201
does not prevent high risk and speculation from affecting a particular
year's storage volume and its cost.
Our study of storage has demonstra ted how difficult it is to isolate one
of the marketing functions from others. The cost of holding goods, it wiII
be recalled, really incorporates the costs of the storage function as well as
costs related to the financing and risking functions. Now, we shall further
consider the risk-bearing function in marketing along with a brief survey
of an important specialized marketing institution, the futures exchange.
Product Destruction
Those engaged in marketing must face the possibility that fire or other
forces may suddenly damage or destroy the products they have on hand.
A marketing firm, especially if it is a large one, may build up its own fund
1 There is still another kind of risk inherent in the buying and selling of goods
which perhaps should be mentioned here. There is always the risk that the buyer of
goods may not be financially responsible. To overcome this risk many of our regulatory
measures require registration and bonding of marketing personnel. There are special in·
surance companies which will guarantee a man's financial responsibility for a stated
amount. Your author also acknowledges that many prefer to separate price uncertainty
into a classification separate from risk. However, it is believed that it is more realistic to
trea t them together in the discussion of this area in marketing.
202
Risk and the Futures Exchanges 20 3
LOCATION OF
VOLUME OF LEADING OTHER TRADING
COMMODITY UNIT TRADING MARKET MARKETS
up and down together. The difference between cash and futures markets is
called "basis." Both markets may move up and down reRecting a change in
the actual or anticipated demand-and-supply situations while the basis
remains unchanged. Actually, the two markets do not move up and down
together pcrfectly. The futures market is appraising the situation as it might
+10 +10
oI---=l-~~~!oo.-l 0~~~~~~~4
-10 ~~~~~~~~.
Jul. Nov.Jan. May Jul. Nov.Jan. May
Million Bushels Million Bushels
~--------------~
160
120
80
40
o1...Ii:i~:.:J..J-LJ-.l,..u:!tU
Jul. Nov. Jan. May
1950-1951
FIGURE 1. Relationship between the mid-month price of
the !vIay futures contract and the monthly
average of NO.3 yellow corn, volume of futures
trading, and open contracts for the trading
years 1950-1951 and 1951-1952, Chicago
Board of Trade.
average for the cash prices. BlJt we can check and see if the generalizations
we have been discussing seem to apply. First, the futures and cash did move
up and down together. In the 1951 contract period, the trend of both was
upward; in the 1952 contract period, a downward trend developed after
December. By October, the futures contracts had come closely in line with
the cash market. Prior to this time the volume of trading in the May con-
tracts was so limited that a representative market price was not really estab-
lished. From October until the following May, the futures prices were
generally above the' cash prices. By mid-?\Jay the gap between the two
quotations had closed, for the May contracts were soon to mature into
actual grain.
The volume of trading reached its peak in January of both years when
about 160 million bushels of May futures were traded. About this time
open contracts also reached their peak of about 40 million bushels. From
this time on, open interests covered themselves by offsetting their mar-
ket positions. By mid-May less than 5 million bushels remained as open
interests. If these had remained opened for a few days more, grain would
have moved, in fulfillment of the contracts. This would have represented
about 0.3 percent of some 726 million bushels of 1951 May wheat and
about 0.6 percent of some 850 million bushels of 1952 May wheat which
was traded during the life of the contracts.
Hedging
V\T e pointed out earlier that the fundamental justification for the
deve10pment of the futures markets is that it provides a means of transfer-
ring price risks. This risk transference is accomplished through a process
called hedging. 3 In order to understand how hedging works we must keep
in mind two things:
( 1) The successful operation of hedging rests upon the assumption
that futures and cash commodity prices move up and down together-that
is, the basis remains unchanged.
(2) The mechanic~ of hedging is that of making simultaneous but
opposite transactions on the futures and cash markets. That is, if cash wheat
is purchased, future wheat is immediately sold and vice versa.
Let us look at a hypothetical i1lustration of a terminal elevator op'
erator who purchased 100,000 bushels of wheat. He intended to store the
grain and sell it later making money from his handling charges. He was
3 The author is aware of the objections that are raised to the use of this type of
hedging as typical; however, he still believes that it furnishes the most effective road for
elementary understanding of the process, See Holbrook 'V orking, "Futures Trading and
Hedging," American Economic RevielV, June, 1953, pp. 314-343.
Risk and the Futures Exchanges 209
(On day of cash Bought 100,000 bushels Sold 100,00;) bushel contract
purchase) @ $2.00 @ $2.10
(On day of cash Sold 100,000 bushels @ Bought 100,000 bushel con-
sale) $1.95 tracts @ $2.05
A loss of 5 cents a bushel A gain of 5 cents a bushel on
on the cash transactions the futures transactions
\Vhen cash grain was purchased, futures were sold. When cash grain was
sold, futures were purchased. The cash market declined, as he feared it
might, and he lost 5 cents a bushel when he finaIly sold his grain. However,
the futures market also feIl, and there was a net gain of 5 cents a bushel on
his futures transactions. This was a perfect hedge, since the loss on one
market was exactly offset by the gain on the other. The elevator operator
shifted his price decline risk into the futures market.
Let us foIlow through stilI another example-this time the case of a
cotton merchant. This merchant purchased cotton from interior points.
He was unable to make the immediate sale he desired, so he decided to
hold the cotton in his warehouse. Later on he made his sale to a spinner.
Since the merchant was afraid of a price decline he hedged as follows:
CASH MARKET FUTURES MARKET
(On day of cash Bought 1,000 bales @ 28.50 Sold bale contracts @
1,000
purchase) cents per pound cents per pound
30.50
(On day of cash Sold 1,000 bales @ 31.00 Bought 1,000 bale contracts
sale) cents per pound @ 32.5° cents per pound
A gain of 2.5 cents a pound. A loss of 2 cents a pound on
on the cash transactions the futures transactions
This hedge was handled like the previous one of the elevator operator.
However, in this instance the market rose and he gained 2.5 cents a pound
from an increase in the cash cotton price. However, the futures market
also rose, and he lost 2 cents a pound on these transactions. This hedging
operation illustrates a very important point. A successful hedge not only
protects the hedger against a price loss, but also prevents him from sharing
in a price iSain. Hedging is the process of shifting the risk from prices which
change III either direction. This example also illustrates a hedge which is
not perfect and as such is much more representative of the actual market.
In this case, the cash and futures markets did not move up and down
210 MARKETING OF AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS
together in the same amounts. The basis changed. Only 2 cents of the 2.5
cents was "shifted" into the futures market.
The student should now be able to think of many situations in which
it would be desirable to shift price risk through hedging. The mechanics
of simultaneous offsetting transactions should now be clear. Also, it should
be apparent that the amount of price risk which is actually shifted depends
upon how perfectly the cash and futures markets move up and down
together.
Trading, Julius B. Bact and Olin C. Saxon (New York, Harper & Brothers, 1949), ch. 6.
MARKETING OF AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS
action was not sufficicntly -vigorous to offset the effect on prices. 7 Such
cffects were to be cxpected if the difference in size of traders was such as
to create an imperfectly competitive or oligopolistic situation. In the early
days of the exchanges, manipulations by large traders in attempting
squeezes and corners did violently affect prices. It was public reaction to
these situations which brought on the federal regulation of the exchanges.
Effects on lvlarketing Costs
The most obvious place where futures exchanges might affect market-
ing costs would be through the shifting of risk by hedging. If speculators
are willing to assume this risk at lower costs than the marketing agencies
handling and processing commodities, the costs wi11 be reduced both to the
users of the specific products and to society as a whole. It is very probable
that speculators are in reality advancing low cost money for this price risk
insurance.
Perfect hedges are probably the exception rather than the rule. How-
ever, cash and futures prices apparently do move close enough together so
that there is less risk involved from attempting a hedge which is not perfect
than not hedging at an. A study of the period, 1931 to 1941, found that the
proportion of the risks from price changes that could have been offset by
hedging in the futures averaged 64 percent for wheat, 44 percent for com,
and 49 percent for oats. 8 Though changes in basis were substantial, they
were not so great as changes in the cash prices themselves.
Pcrhaps the best answer to the charge that hedging cannot successfully
be done is that it is widely practiced by the trade. True, many studies
show that local elevators do not hedge. They shift their price risk to other
grain merchants and terminal elevators through the technique of advance
sales. However, terminal elevator operators, cash merchants, and processors
do hedge fairly consistently. One must conclude that they consider such
operations beneficial or they would not continue them.
Other benefits may accrue to the marketing machinery from the opera-
tion of the futures exchanges. Generany speaking, financing costs are
reduced as merchants may secure a higher percentage loan on their col-
lateral if it is hedged. Futures markets also encourage a highly efficient
information system. :Market price quotations get rapid and wide dissemina-
tion. Supply-and-demand factors receive continual analysis. The machinery
is set up for a uniform system of weighing. grading, inspection, and the
settling of trade disputes. In fact, these by-products making for rapid, effi-
7 c. \\'right Hoffman, Grain Prices and the Futures Market, USDA Technical
SELECTED REFERENCES
Chicago Board of Trade, Annual Symposium Proceedings, 1948 and years fol-
lowing.
Christensen, C. D., "The Use of Commodity Exchanges by the Iowa Grain In-
dustry," Journal of Farm Economics, May, 1952·
Duddy, E. A., and D. A. Revzan, Marketing, 2nd ed. (New York, McGraw-Hill,
1953)'
Federal Trade Commission, The Grain Trade ("Washington, D. C., Govern-
ment Printing Office, 1920 and 1926), Vols. 5 and 7·
Hoffman, G. W., Future Trading Upon Organized Commodity Markets (Phila-
delphia, University of Pennsylvania Press, 1932).
1lalott, Dean \V., Grain and Its Marketing (Chicago, Grain Exchange Insti-
tute, 1947).
Vaile, R. S., "Cash and Future Prices of Corn," Journal of !vIarketing, July,
1944·
u r 0: a summary of the CEA operations see USDA Leaflet 330, Commodity Ex-
change Act and Commodity Exchange Authority.
Part III
COMMODITY AND
'-
INSTITUTIONAL
PROBLEMS
o
Livestock Marketing 237
The fad that much livestock in this country travels long distances
before it is slaughtered complicates the handling of the shrink allowances
under the proposed setup. In Indiana, for example, nearly three-fifths of the
hogs sold at markets within the state were shipped alive for slaughter in
other areas-principally in the eastern states. These hogs shrank nearly 8
percent of their purchased weight before slaughtering. 1D Situations of this
nature would be difficult to handle.
else. Still, someone must bear this risk. Other commodities which do not
have futures markets are efficiently marketed. There are alternative ways
of organizing the risking function. Other countries, as they have moved to
various kinds of public economic control, have shut down these markets.
Today, with very limited exceptions, the United States is the only country
which permits thcir operation.
Future markets in this country arc periodically subjected to heavy
criticism. Their critics have ranged from the uninformed man on the street
to the President of the United States, who cannot be excused for being
uninformed. In order to appraise this highly controversial market institu-
tion, let us examine the arguments.
Effects on Prices
There can be no doubt that the practice of basing cash prices upon
futures is \videspread throughout the grain trade. It does not necessarily
follow, however, that futures prices therefore determine cash prices. They
would not be used for establishing cash prices if they were not in funda-
Risk and the Futures Exchanges 21 3
mental agreement with the opinion of the buyers and sellers of grain as
to the value of the commodity. The same body of underlying conditions
affects both cash and futures, since the two markets are closely connected.
To state categorically which of the two prices is causal would be like asking
the tail to wag without the dog.
This is not to say that the operation of futures exchanges has no effect
on prices. One of the real contributions of exchanges is the establishment
of a sensitive price registration machinery. All kinds of news and statistics
are focused on the trading floor. Here the information is interpreted by
literally thousands of people through their trading actions. There can be no
doubt that commodities with futures trading have continuous markets.
There are always those who are willing to buy or sell at some price. Con-
tinuous markets, however, are also present for other commodities which
do not have futures.
The net effect of futures trading on prices probably cannot be eval-
uated statistically. Some observers like to compare price habits of com-
modities traded on futures exchanges to those of commodities which are
not. This is not a valid comparison, however, since the commodity with
the futures organization often has better grading services, more uniform
trading procedure, and more economic information available. Such im-
proved trade conditions may be a result of futures trading but they cloud
the effect on prices. Perhaps the best conclusion concerning price effects
was advanced by Howell after his study of grain futures. He states:
The data along with other available information indicate that futures trading
usually tends to lessen the seasonal fluctuations of prices of grain and to reduce
the extent of price changes from one season to another. But futures markets, by
facilitating trading, no doubt increase the frequency of changes over relatively
short periods.5
There is also some indication that very large speculators may have an
influence on price movements. One study found that the great majority of
small amateur speculators lost money in their speculative activities. This
study concluded that if the sample was representative of small speculators
there must have been other groups-large speculators, scalpers, spreaders,
or hedgers-that made very large profits.6 The actions of these very large
speculators were directly correlated with price movements. That is, when
they sold, prices fell, and when they brought, prices rose. Of course, other
traders illust have taken the opposite side of these contracts, but their
5 ~. D. Howell, Analysis of Hedging and Other Operations in Grain Futures, USDA
Dairy Marketing
.. Includes dried milk (whole, skim, and cream), malted milk, dry ice cream mix,
and other minor uses.
SOURCE: USDA, Bureau of Agricultural Economics.
PRODUCTS
Milk which is used in various ways has different values. The highest
prices can be paid for milk which is used for fluid consumption. Next in
this scale of value is fluid cream and ice cream, Following this is the value
of milk for use by condenseries. The lowest valued uses for milk are in the
manufacture of cheese, dried milk, and butter-of these, dried milk and
butter are probably at the botton. This hierarchy of use-values means that
the demand for fluid milk will be satisfied first from the available supplies.
Usually all other uses for milk will be satisfied before milk is diverted into
butter and dried milk production. Butter manufacturing, other things being
equal, stands nearly last in the line of users of milk. It is within this frame-
work of different values that a good deal of the decline in butter manufac-
ture and consumption can be explained. The increasing demand for the
other dairy products, which has come about through population growth,
rIsing standards of living and an increased consciousness of the value of
milk .,s food, has meant that an ever-increasing proportion of the total milk
supply is needed to fulfill these demands. Less has been left for butter
manufacture, and into this gap have stepped the spreads manufactured
largely from vegetable oils.
}'IARKETING OF AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS
Over half of the total milk production of the country comes from the
North Central region. The North Atlantic region is also a large producer.
The other regions of the country, while still relatively small in production,
are increasing their relative output (Table 3).1 This table also illustrates
1 The picture of the growing dairy industry of the South is well presented in the
Southern Cooperative Series, Bulletin No. 19, Trends in the Production and Disposition
of Milk and the Importance of Dairying in the South, 1924-50, 1951.
Dairy Marketing 241
the geographic utilization differences. The bulk of the milk of the heavily
populated eastern areas is sold as whole milk to cities for fluid consumption.
Nearly two-thirds of the cream sold comes from the farmers in the west-
ern part of the North Central region, which is a heavy butter producing
area. During the twenty-five year period presented here, the total produc-
tion of milk has increased by one-third, the cream sales have decreased by
almost one-third, while the whole milk sales have increased tremendously.
As the output of the dairy herds and the utilization of this output for
fluid consumption has increased, there has been a marked trend toward
specialization of the dairy farms. There are now actually fewer dairy herds
than there were twenty years ago. The number of large commercial herds
has increased, while the number of the smaller "side-line" herds has de-
creased. In 1929, slightly over half of the total milk production came.from
herds of nine cows or less and only about 18 percent came from herds of
twenty cows or more. In 1944, about 38 percent of the total production
came from these smaller herds while nearly 30 percent came from the larger
herds (Table 4). In 1925, 26 percent of the total milk production was used
on the farm and only 29 percent was sold as fluid milk. In 1949, 17 percent
was used on the farm and 61 percent was sold in fluid form.
SIZE OF
MILKING HERD
(NUMBER OF COWS) NUMBER OF HERDS MILK PRODUCTION
19 24 1944 19 24 1944
% OF TOTAL % OF TOTAL
1 to 2 49 52 13 11
3 to 9 38 32 39 28
10 to 19 10 12 30 31
20 to 29 2 3 9 14
30 or more 9 16
cern with dairy marketing problems as the producers are becoming more
and more specialized.!!
Percent of Percent of
Monthly Monthly
Average Average
~------------------_,
130 p.~ Producer 130
/ ~,Deliveries
120 I', 120
110
I
I '\~
110
100 J=--P--........_~'~ 100
90 90
80 80
70~~~~~~~~~~ 70~~~~~._~~~~
Jan. Apr. Aug. Dec. Jan. Apr. Aug. Dec.
BOSTON, MASS. EVANSVILLE, IND.
price but whose demand is- more elastic. In these outlets net revenue will
not fall as additional quantities are offered.
This division of the total supply among many uses would take place in
this fashion even if milk were purchased at a uniform price. The pricing
procedures outlined below merely represent an attempt of producers to
share in the returns that processors might receive from such price-discrim-
inatory procedures.
This price of S+70 will be the basic price for milk of a given butterfat
content to be used in paying producers. Some producers will receive slightly
more and some less depending upon whether their butterfat test is above
or below the standard requirement. This price reflects the way in which the
total supply is used in the market, and no individual producer will gain or
lose because his particular milk is utilized differently. The justification of
the same basic price to all producers rests upon the fact that individual
producers have little control over the use made of their own milk.
The real problem in the above example, however, is that of deter-
mining the prices of the various classes of milk. \Vhy should the price of
Class I milk be $ 5.00 (in the above example) and of Class II milk be $4'00?
Almost all federally supervised markets have adopted formulas by which
these prices are determined. Such a formula, once determined, is used
automatically until it is changed. The large majority of formulas in use
are based upon the prices of butter, cheese, powdered milk, and condensed
milk. Ususally two or more alternative formulas are provided for establish-
ing the price of milk used for manufacturing. The formula which results
in the highest price is used. In this way, the city meets the highest available
manufacturing competition for its milk supply. To this price for the man-
ufacturing uses, fixed premiums are added to obtain the price of Class I
milk. In the above example, the highest price calculated from the various
formulas in use is $4.00. This becomes the price paid for milk used in man-
ufacturing. To this, a $1.00 premium is added to obtain the price of the
milk used for fluid consumption.
Dairy Marketing 249
From this brief explanation, it will be seen that two things might
have caused the blend price of $+70 to be different. The prices of butter,
cheese, condensed milk, or other formula factors might have caused a
change in the price of the basic milk class. In addition, if the way in which
the supply was utiiized had been different, the blend price would have been
different.lO
One of the objectives of pricing in a given market is to encourage a
more uniform seasonal pattern of milk production. A widely used technique
for this purpose is to vary the premium given for Class I milk. A greater
premium is offered in the winter months than during the heavy production
months of the summer. Assuming that the above illustration represents the
calculation for December, the premium added to the base price in June
may be only 50 cents. In this way, two forces work for a higher blend price
in the winter months than in the summer months. The premium for Class I
milk will be higher. Also, the proportion of the total supply used as
Class I milk will be higher in the winter than in the summer months (see
Figure 1). Such a seasonal factor in prices is used to encourage a more
even, year-round production.
Many markets have not found this method adequate to cope with
the problem of excess milk in the summer months. These have evolved still
other systems of giving incentives for winter production. One such system
is the base-surplus plan. Under one form of this plan, each producer has a
quota for his milk production. If the producer fails to deliver his quota
during the winter months, or delivers more than his quota during the sum-
mer months, he is penalized. Such a system coupled with the seasonal fluc-
tuations in the blend price obtained from the premium and utilization
changes offers a still stronger incentive for a more uniform productionP
Hearings are usually in progress at some market in the United States
at any particular time. These hearings may consider any of the provisions
of the marketing order, but usually they center around pricing problems.
Most markets have not solved the problem of the large variations in sea-
sonal production. Part of this problem is that of securing as much fluid
(Class I) consumption as possible. Most studies have found that the de-
10 The pricing details of the different markets vary. The method used in calculating
the prices of a particular market can be found in the market orders which may be ob-
tained from the market administrator. Many studies have been made by the Production
and ~r"rketing Administration of the USDA of the operation of the orders of different
cities. A general study giving the broad picture of the operation and problems of formula
pricing i3 Formula Pricing of Milk faT Fluid Use by E. S. Harris and I. R. Hedges,
USDA, Farm Credit Administration, 1948.
11 Effectiveness of this and other schemes has also been studied in several markets.
111ese reports are also available from the USDA, Production and l'\'larketing Adminis-
tration.
~I ARK E T r N G 0 FAG R r C U L T U R ALP ROD U C T S
mand for fluid milk is inelastic. 1!'! However, it seems possible that many
markets have reduced the returns from Class I sales through unwise pricing
practices. The flexibility of the wholesale pricing mechanism is the principal
concern of milk market regulation, since usually the retail resale prices are
not controlled by the marketing orders.13
The search for the proper pricing formula has led to some departures
from dependence upon the prices of manufactured products in establishing
the base price. The Boston formula illustrates an alternative approach
toward establishing prices. Formulas which follow the Boston pattern
attempt to include several measures of both the supply-and-demand situa-
tion and have divorced themselves from direct connection with butter,
cheese, and other milk product prices. In this type of formula, the United
States general wholesale price index, wholesale food price index, and index
of department store sales may be included as measures of the level of
demand. Data which measure the cost of milk production are included as
indications of supply conditions.
\Vhether such formulas are preferable must be answered by the future.
It is also increasingly evident that the butterfat content of milk is not
necessarily a true indicator of its value. The future will no doubt see
increased efforts to price milk on a nonfat basis. It seems probable that
dependence upon the prices of manufactured products as the sole factors
in fluid milk formula pricing will decline. \Vith increasing amounts of milk
being used for fluid distribution, basing its price upon the value of man-
ufactured products and butterfat content may be just a bit like asking the
tail to wag the dog.
12 \Vhat Makes the Market for Dairy Products? North Central Regional Publica·
tion la, \Visconsin Bulletin 477, 1948.
13 A few states and cities have extended their regulatory measures to the supervision
of dealers' margins and retail sales prices. For an explanation of one such set of regula·
tions see f\!aynard C. Conner, The Milk r>.Iarket Control Law in Virginia, Virginia
Bulletin 444, 195 1.
Dairy Marketing 251
the consumer as it does to deliver six. It also prohably costs more to deliver
directly to the consumer than it docs to deliver the milk in wholesale quan-
tities to the retailer.H
The frequency of delivery and the arrangements of routes also have
a direct bearing on the costs of distribution. Prior to \Vorld "\Var II, daily
delivery was the common practice. This practice, of course, reduced the
amount of milk delivered each day per customer. \Vith the modem home
refrigeration and the improved control of milk quality, milk can be satis-
factorily kept by the housewife for several 9ayS. As one of the measures to
conserve scarce rubber supplies during the war, milk delivery was reduced
from each day to every other day. This practice has remained in widespread
use even though governmental restrictions were lifted. Overlapping and
inefficient organization of routes of the several companies serving a city
are very similar to that of the routes assembling milk from the country
producer. Some routes are long and have small volumes. Overlapping is
frequent. Students of the problem have stressed the necessity of increasing
the density of deliveries in relation to the length of the route as a method
of reducing the unit costs of milk delivery.
0- 99.999 3 ·4
100,000-2 99>999 14 ·9
300,000 and over 22 1.2
All markets 39 1.0
SOURCE: Louis F. Herman and l\Iordecai Bail], Farm to Retail l\fargins for Fluid
Milk, USDA, Bureau of Agricultural Economics, processed, 19$1.
.14 For an excellent analysis of these costs, see An Analysis of the Spread Between
Farm and Consumer Milk Prices in New York City Under Present Practices, Part 1 of
the Annual Report of the New York State Temporary Commission of Agriculture, 1949.
MARKETING OF AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS
erations are ignored. It would follow, then, if costs are to be reduced, that
consumers should be encouraged either to take their milk less often and
in larger amounts or to pick it up at their grocery stores. However, many
cities have uniform prices regardless of how much or where the milk is
purchased. Some have small discounts for retail and quantity purchases.
Some have a completely illogical pricing system from the standpoint of cost.
One study found that some store prices were actually 5 to 8 cents a quart
higher than home deliveries. I5 Table 5 shows the situation which existed
in eighty-nine markets in 1949. These data indicate that there is very little
price incentive to encourage store purchases.
Marlwting Structure
Figure 2 shows the marketing channels which are used for butter,
cheese, and condensed milk. The principal channels used in marketing
butter is from the creamery to the wholesaler to the retailer. Cheese moves
from the local factories to country assemblers and processors, then to large
wholesalers to the retail store. Evaporated milk moves from the factories
to wholesalers, which may either be independent or factory-owned, and
then to the various retail outlets.
Though these channels appear rather simple, they are the result of a
significant change in the marketing structure which has occurred during the
last twenty-five years. At the time of \Vorld \Var I, the marketing of butter
was dominated by the independent wholesaler and jobber. Nearly half of
the cheese also was moved to terminal market cheese wholesalers, then to
wholesale grocers, and finally to retailers. The large meat packers were
major distributors handling about 30 percent of the butter and about 48
percen t of the cheese.
During the 1920'S and 1930's, there was a rapid growth of the chain
store system, large cooperative marketing organizations, and large diversi-
fied dairy products companies. These developments encouraged more direct
lTI«rkF:ting channels. Independent wholesalers and jobbers were by-passed
more and more. Both chains and packers secured their supplies directly
from plants in the production area. The cooperative marketing associations
and the large dairy product corporations owned country plant facilities and
MARKETING CHANNELS FOR BUTTER, UNITED STATES,1939.
.,Ull-OWIlIO U(A.(IT·O.IltO
.WClLfSA1.[ 'l.UU
11 ,
U:U.llSTOIU
·'$TJ)O{ArtD
ALL FlGUltrS ElPRl5StD AS
lUCENT OF roTAL VOLUlif
RETAil•.
CRUMERY·OWII[O $1'0111:1:1
'''SmunOIl4L
.,
WHOLESAlERS
WHOl[SA1,.[ PUNTS USERS
to
70
"
~ ~ ~
10.
'"
~ ~
-!STlMATED
AU FlGUUS U"UlSiD AS
PERCiN' 01 TOTAL roU/WI !t[TAIL
STORES
,lIoensoRS ... ,,~ FACTORY-OWNED WHO\,.[$.L£ IS_'
lXOUSTR,..,!,. USERS
AI.'
$ALE$ BIUNI:H£S
111 ...
~RO'US
Uleal "[C[lY''''
STATIONS
2U
l} i} l}
-1ST/MATED
ALL FIGURES IXFR£SSED AS IM~Ef[filCENf INDuSTRIAL I"OEP["~[1fT
f'£IIClIiT 01 TOTAL VOLUME WHOLESALERS USERS R.ETA.lERS
la.' 5.' "0
established their o\vn contacts with the large retailers.16 In the late 1930's,
it was estimated that the three leading firms of each industry did 21 percent
of the butter business, 63 percent of the cheese business, and 44 percent of
the condensed milk business. Chain stores also were major owners of pro-
duction facilities.
Though the marketing structure of the manufactured dairy products
has tended to become more direct and concentrated in the hands of fcwer
agencies, many production plants are still relatively small. Nearly two-fifths
of the butter and over one-half of the cheese were produced in plants
employing less than twenty men in 1947. Both evaporated milk and ice
cream factories tended to be much larger. Plants tended to specialize in one
product. Seven out of ten plants in 1944 produced only one product. About
50 percent of the butter plants, about 85 percent of the cheese plants, 72
percent of the ice cream plants, and 63 percent of the evaporated milk
plants were single product plants. For all practical purposes, the ability of
plants to shift from the manufacture of one product to that of another
was not great.1 7
16 A detailed account of this change in the marketing channels is found in two
Product Development
Substantial changes in manufacturing methods and product quality
have occurred. The butter and cheese made by the many small plants
originally varied markedly in quality. One of the earliest programs of the
Land O'Lakes Cooperative Association was to place emphasis on the stand-
ardization of the quality of its butter. In 1924, the Association was instru-
mental in setting up federal-state graders at its various concentration points.
\Vith grading done near production points, premiums for quality could
be paid to those who deserved them. Along with the quality improvement
came the establishment of the brand name, "Land O'Lakes," and a mer-
chandising program to promote the quality product. Is
The developmcnt of processed cheese and the shift from bulk cheese
to packaged loaves similarly made possible a cheese product more uniform
in quality. Here also the merchandising possibilities of branded products
were recognized. Evaporated milk also is a highly branded product.
Pricing Problems
The tendency of the manufactured dairy products to move more
directly from the factory to retail outlets has meant that much by-passes
the central wholesale markets. The growth of large-scale firms which dis-
tribute these products also has increased the possibility of price manipula-
tion. Many of the marketing problems of these products center around the
pricing process.
In thc early years of the butter industry, a large proportion of the
total supply passed through the large central wholesale markets such as
New York and Chicago. Here the organized exchanges for both cash and
futures trading developed. Though these products are by-passing these
market centers in increasing volume, prices still are based largely upon the
quotations of these centers. A study of the pricing of butter at Iowa
creameries found that these creameries sold almost exclusively subject to
prices quoted on the Chicago and New York exchanges. Though these
terminal prices furnished the basis of the quotation, almost every creamery
made an individual agreement with its buyers. Of the seventy creameries
studied, all but twenty-four received either a premium or a discount from
the central quotation. 19 (For details see Table 1, Chapter 11.)
A study of pricing practices of butter plants in the mid-west concluded
that commercial prices reported on the commonly used central markets
18 For an interesting account of the growth of this cooperative, see K. D. Ruble,
Men to Remember (Chicago, Donnelly and Sons), 1947.
19 A. C. l'vlathis and D. E. Hirsch, Butter Pricing by Iowa Creameries, USDA, Farm
Credit Administration Circular C·136, 1950.
Dairy Marketing 257
underquoted the actual market in the sense that premiums were added to
them in obtaining the gross prices paid at country points. The varying
premiums resulted in the actual prices received at creameries varying in
such an irrational manner that it was impossible for the average creamery
manager to tell wh'lt his grade of butter should bring at his plant location.
The study further concluded that creameries would have profited from
being more aggressive in their bargaining relationships with those to whom
they sold their butter. Some buyers of butter often paid significantly dif-
ferent prices to plants in the same locality.20
A similar situation exists in the marketing and pricing of cheese. Bulk
cheese prices are largely established on the two Plymouth, \Visconsin,
exchanges. The price for cheese paid to \Visconsin factories is almost univer-
sal1y based on the prices at the Plymouth exchanges. Both the Chicago and
New York wholesale cheese markets fol1ow the prices of these exchanges
closely. However, here again an extensive system of premiums over the
exchange quotation is used. Such premiums are usual1y secret arrangements
between the buyer and the factory. As in the case of butter, one factory does
not know what the other is actually receiving. 21
There is evidence that prices can be influenced by the larger operators.
It has been suggested that the purchases and sales on the cheese exchange
by large traders tend to maintain price stability. In the period studied, six
members of the exchange made over 80 percent of the purchases and nearly
two-thirds of the sales for the period. 22 A study of the operation of the
Challenge Cream and Butter Association noted that the Association had
achieved a strong position in regard to butter prices. It is credited with
stabilizing California prices, with the result that there are less day-to-day
fluctuations in California butter quotations compared to those in the
East. 23
These are all indications of a departure from the idea of a nearly per-
fect competitive situation which is often associated with wholesale markets
of farm products. \Vholesale market prices do not represent the price at
which the bulk of butter and cheese is actually traded. Butter and cheese
producers often sell their products in relative ignorance of what is the going
price. A few large firms appear to have the power to affect prices by their
operations. This situation takes on added significance when it is recal1ed
that many fluid milk markets use the quoted prices of these dairy products
as a basis for their pricing formulas.
20 Cook, Kelley, Koller, and Miller, op. cit.
21 Arthur H. Miller, Pricing American Cheese at \Visconsin Factories, \Visconsin
Bulletin 163, 1949. 22 r-.lilIer, op. cit.
23 Paul E. Quintus, Operating Methods of Challwge Cream and Butter Association,
The principal products of the poultry industry are eggs and meat. The most
important product as measured in terms of dollar value is eggs (Table 1).
Farm chicken meat is largely a by-product of the production of eggs. These
two products-eggs and farm chickens-account for about three-fourths of
the total value of poultry products. Seventy-eight percent of an United
States farms had some chickens in 1950. Broilers and turkeys are important
products on fewer, more specialized farms. Because of their different nature,
both from production and marketing viewpoints, the marketing of eggs and
poultry meat will be discussed separately.
TOTAL TOTAL
FARM GROSS SALES GROSS
PRODUCT SALES CONSUMPTION TOTAL VALUE VALUE
150
1251---
75~~~~~~~~~~~~~~-=~~~~
1935 1940 1945 1950 1955
jVIarlwting Channels
The widespread, small-unit nature of egg production has fostered a
large variety of agencies engaged in the buying and collection of eggs in
the country for shipment to other markets. A study of Table 2 will show
differences in outlets which can be attributed to the different production
patterns as well as the geographic locations. In the nonspecialized North
Central and Southern areas, the local grocer store is a principal egg buying
agency. In the more specialized Northeastern area, this outlet is not so
widely used. Here the cooperative association and the buyer from larger
outside outlets are more important. There is also reason to believe that
some outlets are more important during the heavy production season of
the spring than in the light production season of the fall. This is indicated
by difference in the April and August outlets used in the North Central
region (Table 2).
2 Christensen and ~lighell, op. cit.
Poultry and Egg Marketing 261
PERCENT OF TOTAL
assembling eggs is no doubt considerably below that necessary for the lowest
cost operations. This helps explain why many buying stations also buv
cream, wool, and other products. This small volume characteristic of sal;s
also helps explain why many retailers are side-line egg buyers. The benefits
of larger-scale operation can be realized more fully in the more specialized
areas of production. There appears to be less business stability in egg han-
dlers than in many other businesses, and the rate of business mortality is
high. The large nnmber d handlers operating in areas which cannot furnish
the volume for efficicnt operation may be a principal cause for this. 5
rvIany egg buyers have establish cd truck routes to pick up eggs from
producers. The proportion of eggs picked up at the farm ranges from 24
percent in the southern states to over 40 percent in the northeastern
states. The remainder of the eggs are delivered by farmers to the buyers.
In many instances, the pickup route must serve a wide territory in order
to secure adequate volume. Forty-five percent of the egg routes studied in
Indiana were over 100 miles in length. In Ohio, the average length of the
routes studied was 152 miles. The least efficicnt Ohio routeS were 163 miles
long and assembled about one-third of a case for each mile traveled; the
most efficient were 89 miles long and assembled about two cases for each
mile traveled. G Here again the importance of volume for low cost operation
is illustrated.
Problems of Quality
Problems in the maintenance of quality in eggs start on the farm.
It is generally agreed that the hen lays eggs which in the majority of cases
are high quality as measured by current grading systems. However, it was
found that only about two-thirds of the eggs which were delivered to the
country buying stdtions were of top quality.' Between the time of laying
and the time the farmer sold them to the first buyer, one egg in every
three had dropped below Grade A quality.
Eggs continue to deteriorate as they move on through the marketing
channel. Between the country buyer and the carlot assembler which may
be the next step in the marketing channel, an average of thirteen eggs per
hundred dropped in quality one grade. s 'Vhat is the quality of eggs which
finally reaches the retail stores? This varies widely. Some stores make
5 \V. P. r-.lortenson and T. F. Graf, Marketing Eggs ill the Lake States, \Visconsin
Bulletin 168, 1950.
6 T. C. Rothbauer, G. B. 'Vooel, and J. H. }.iartin, Poultry and Egg Truck Routes
in Indiana, Indiana Bulletin 571,1952, and R. E. eray, The Efficiency and Cost of Col·
lecting Eggs from Farms in Ohio, Ohio Bulletin 721 , 195:?-.
7 Changes in Egg Quality During Marketing, ~\lichigan Special Bulletin 361, 1949.
8 Ibid.
Poultry and Egg Marketing 263
particular efforts to handle high quality eggs; others through poor handling
offer relatively low quality eggs for sale. There is also evidence that egg
quality varies considerably from city to city.9
Part of this quality deterioration is inherent in the marketing of a
perishable product. Egg driers and breakers utilize much of the lower
quality products. However, part of the deterioration in quality is prevent-
able through improved handling methods. Better handling practices by the
farmer may reduce the initial quality loss. One study found that if seyen
different farm practices in handling the farm flock and eggs were followed,
<jO percent of the eggs marketed were of "A" quality. If none of these
practices was followed, only 55 percent were of "A" quality.10 Speed,
refrigeration, and care in handling will help reduce quality deterioration
at both the wholesale and retail levels.
'Vhat are some of the causes of this continuing neglect in the handling
of eggs? One is that a great many producers do not find it profitable to
strive for product quality. In the North Central region, nearly 60 percent
of the eggs are sold by farmers on the ungraded basis. In the Southern
region, 90 percent of the eggs are sold ungraded. In the highly specialized
New England area, however, it is indicated that only about 5 percent are
sold ungraded. l l
On the other end of the marketing channel, a large proportion of eggs
which consumers buy are not designated by grade. The ability of the house-
wife to judge accurately the difference between Grade "A" and Grade "B"
eggs is very limited. The term "fresh eggs" appears to have more impact
on consumer acceptance than the grade label. In one city, less than half
of the consumers contacted knew that the term "Grade A" signified top
quality. In addition to this, many studies have shown the lack of relation-
ship between the price which the consumer pays and the quality of egg
received. Consumers apparently cannot rely on price as an indicator of
quality.l!!
The egg grading system as now constituted is extensively used only by
the wholesale handlers within the marketing channel. The question is
9 See, for example: N. Nybroten, j\Jarketing Eggs in Retail Stores of the Northeast,
1949 and Retailing Eggs in \Vest Virginia Stores, \Vest Virginia Bulletins 353 and 354,
Junc, 1952; D. M. Spillcr and G. B. \Vood, Egg Quality in the Indianapolis Market,
Indiana EC 5+ 1951; S. K. Seaver and R. A. King, Marketing Eggs Through \\'lzolesale
Ch<innels and Marketing Eggs Through Retail Stores, Connecticut Bulletins ::69, 1951,
and 768, i950; and R. L. Kohls and N. Oppenheimer, Quality Recognition and Pur·
chasing li"bits of Egg Consumers, Indiana Bulletin 59::, 1953.
1C Poultr;,' Farm Practices and Egg Quality, USDA Marketing Research Report ::::.
]] Starkey, Hester. and Hermann, op. cit.; Southern Cooperative Series Bulletin,
op. cit.; and \\T. Earle, Business Operations of Northeastern \Vholesale Egg Buyers, New
York Bulletin 868,1950.
12 Kohls and Oppenheimer, op. cit.
MARKETING OF AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS
largely unanswered as to- what is the quality desired by the consumer and
what price she will pay for it. The grading system is not adequately serving
its purpose of guiding production through price. It is not surprising that
producers and handlers are not vigorously pressing to handle eggs in a way
that will assure high quality.
POULTRY MARKETING
During the five-y~ar period, 1946-1950, the per capita consumption
of red meat averaged about 148 pounds. During this same period the per
capita consumption of chicken averaged about twenty-five pounds and that
of turkey slightly more than four pounds. Poultry meat has been largely a
by-product of egg production in the form of old hens, roosters, young
fryers, and roasters. In recent years, an increasing proportion of the total
supply, however, has been corning from the commercial broiler industry.
In 1940, only 14 percent of the total chicken meat came from broilers; by
1950, broilers accounted for 40 percent of the total chicken supply (Fig-
ure 2).
quality which their suppliers must meet. In the late 1930's, less than
3 percent of poultry sales were slaughtered under federal inspection. By
1950, this had riscn to about 12 percent.
Million Broilers
The leading broiler areas of the country are the Del-Mar-Va peninsula
and northwest Georgia. Other important areas of concentration are in the
Virginia Shenandoah Valley, northwest Arkansas, North Carolina, Texas,
California, Ivfaine, Indiana, Mississippi, Missouri, and Connecticut. These
various areas account for nearly 75 percent of the nation's total broiler
output. These widely scattered areas have various histories of development.
No one set of criteria can be used to explain the location pattern. Some
are close to eastern markets, but in areas of high feed and labor costs.
Others are far from market, but close to sources of surplus feed. Some have
Poultry and Egg Marketing 267
developed in areas of excess cheap labor. In some areas, alternative farming
opportunities are limited; in others, such opportunities are many and varied.
Though the location pattern is not easily explained, there appear to
be at least two major explanations for the rapid growth of the industry.
One of these lies in the pattern of expansion of egg production. As pre-
viously pointed out, the increased egg production was secured from only
a moderately larger laying flock, but with a marked increase in the rate of
lay (Figure 1). This meant that relative to the growing population there
was a smaller supply of poultry meat available as a by-product of egg pro-
duction. Into this gap stepped the broiler industry (see again Figure 2).
The other reason for growth lies in the rapid technological improvements
which permitted a continually lower cost of broiler production. Part of
this improvement was in the development of improved strains of chickens
for meat production. Another development was in the field of feed nutrition
which led to greater meat production per pound of feed. Improved brood-
ing and feeding equipment both reduced the labor required and the mor-
tality rates.
In the early years of the industry, most of the birds were shipped alive
from the production area to processing plants located in the central markets.
In some areas, this is still true. However, production area processing has
been increasing. It is estimated that 90 percent of the Del-Mar-Va produc-
tion, 75 to 85 percent of the Shenandoah Valley production, about 66 per-
cent of the Georgia production, and about 50 percent of the Arkansas
production are now processed in the production area. 14 In the Del-1hr-Va
area, for example, birds are processed and moved by overnight trucks to
New York City in order to assure the consumer a high quality, fresh
product.
A high degree of vertical integration has also developed within the
production process and the marketing channel. In some areas, large feed
companies operate hatcheries and processing plants. These companies may
also extend credit to producers, supervise production operations, and finally
buy the finished product. In some situations, the feed-hatchery financier
assumes most of the risk in both the production and marketing. Under these
circumstances, producers may be little more than hired laborers receiving a
wage or guaranteed return per bird. The broiler industry offers one of the
few examples in agriculture of across-the-board control of production,
process!\:g, and marketing by a single agency.
This industry also furnishes an example of one of the more sensitive
agricultural industries from the standpoint of output regulation. Produc-
'" S. T. Rice, Interregional Competition in the Commercial Broiler Industry, Dela-
ware Bulletin 290, 1951.
MARKETING OF AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS
tion can be started and the product marketed within a twelve-week period.
The broiler operation is relatively independent of c1imate. These factors
plus the development of the commercial producer who is largely dependent
on the sale of broilers for his income have encouraged continuous year-
round production. However, it is a production which can be regulated
quickly to favorable or unfavorable market conditions. Because of this, the
violent seasonal price pattern of the 1930's has been replaced by a one
with little seasonal variation.
Million Turkeys
537> 1949·
270 MARKETING OF AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS
PROBLE~lS OF INTEGRATION
AND PRICING
The poultry industry furnishes an excellen t illustration of the problems
which arise in marketing products which arc produced in small amounts
scattered over broad areas. The products change hands many times in the
marketing channel. l\hny of the handlers operate on a scale which is too
small for the greatest efFciency.
The lack of widely accepted grade standards plus the smal1 scattered
agencies and diversified methods of buying makes for many faulty pricing
situations. Price quotations from central terminals have only limited mean-
ing. For example, broilers are purchased on certain markets on the basis
of country weights or market weights plus 5 percent. On other markets,
the broilers are purchased on the basis of the market weight. Price quo-
tations under these two situations cannot be directly compared. The market-
ing agencies on the former market are assuming much of the shrinkage
which occurs between the country and the city. Therefore, a quoted price
on that market equal to the price quoted on markets following the latter
practice is in fact a higher price. 16 In addition to the differences in trade
practices, the wholesale poultry markets in many of our cities operate in a
very disorganized fashion. Assembling meaningful quotations which accu-
rately represent the prevailing price level is a difficult task.
There is evidence that active competition for buying eggs and poultry
in the production area is limited. In one area, over three-fourths of the
lots of chickens were sold after obtaining only one bid from prospective
buyersP This is in rather sharp contrast to the way in which farmers often
"shop around" when selling their hogs, and is probably due to the gen-
erally small scale and relative unimportance of the poultry enterprise.
Large flock owners tend to receive more for their eggs than small flock
owners.1S There is evidence that the large-scale producer follows better
handling practices which result in higher quality eggs. He therefore should
receive higher prices. However, it is also probable that the large-scale pro-
ducer is more active in shopping around for the best outlet or buyer for
his product.
Such conditions as described above mean that when the poultry enter-
prise reaches large-scale specialization in certain areas, new and better
outlets are sought. Often these take the form of vertical integration in the
16 R. L. Kohls and T. C. \Va]z, Broiler Trucker-Buyers in Indiana, Indiana Bulletin
s-8Cl. 1952.
. :7 R. H. Anderson, Marketing of Chickens from Producer to First Handlcr, \Vash-
ington, Oregon and Utah, 1948-49, Utah Bulletin 354.
18 See footnote 3.
Poultry ana Egg Marketing 271
marketing channel. This has been the development in tIle specialized turkey
areas through the growth of the marketing cooperatives. It has also been
true in commercial broiler areas usually under the direction of the financing
agency. Egg marketing cooperatives often attempt to obtain quality outlets
by dealing directly with wholesalers and retailers. The large chain stores in
search for assured supplies of standardized quality have reached backward
in the marketing channel and established direct buying and processing
facilities in the production areas. Such developments in simplifying the
marketing channels offer considerable opportunities for reducing marketing
costs.
Real progress in improving the marketing and pricing structure, how-
ever, can come only as fast as production tends to become more concen-
trated and specialized. Then will producers become more actively inter-
ested in improving their situation and force a more active competitive
situation. Also, the assembling and processing agencies then will be able
to capitalize on the economies which arise from specialization and large-
scale operations.
CHAPTER EIGHTEEN
Grain Marketing
Product Utilization
All of these gr~ins are the raw material for conversion into some other
product. Feed grains are converted into pork, beef, poultry, and dairy
products. Figure 1 illustrates the movement of corn into its various uses.
In recent years corn has made up about 60 percent of the total grain and
by-product feeds for livestock. It is this relationship which ties livestock
so closely to feed grain production. As indicated in Figure 1, such food
industries as the meat packing and dairy products industries are indirectly
but closely tied to the problem of feed production and marketing. Food
grains are usually first converted into flour which is the raw material of
the baking industry for bread and other bakery products. In recent years
a sizable portion of the wheat crop has been exported to foreign countries.
The principal products from soybeans are the oil and meal. In recent
years, about 50 to 60 percent of the value of soybeans has been derived
27 2
MOVEMENT OF CORN
Co,n Haryell
Ooh. bortey, ~o';"'\Jft\
grg!n. wheat and rye
fed, byproduct fnch Imporh
1I
lowgha;. co""~",.d
by lIy.,tock
Dolt)" proc.uCl'
Wool, Mea', lard, Mille, blltttr. &• .,"00 .... rndu.,tlol prod'uc:t ... tc:~ j
01ch Md... .tc. ,".. n. ,te. Co,,, lMIor. bOn'llny, CO'I\ flake&. .tc·,
.re.
p"Wtr $ta,c~. lugor.sIrup. 01: Export
Fa.rm and Nonfarm Consumption
o
.G~AINS AND IYPlOOUCr FEEDS FED AS SUCH Ol IN COMMElCIAtlY.1REPAHD FEEDS
4THE ENTIRE lOX MEASURES THE TOTAL FEED FEDI THE SHADED AUAS THE AMOUNT Of COlN fED
from the meal and about 40 to 50 percent from the oil. In 1948, soybean
meal amounted to 21 percent of all by-product feed, surpassed in impor-
tance only by wheat mil1feeds. Soybean oil represented 22 percent of the
total supply of food fats in 1948, exceeded only by lard and butter.1 As a
major source of food fats and oils, soybeans are comparatively new. Figure 2
shows the rapid growth of soybean oil compared to other vegetable fats
and oils. It is now the largest single source of vegetable fats and oils. Nearly
three-fourths of the soybean oil is used in margarine and shortening manu-
facture.
Table 1 shows the utilization of several grains. Nearly nine-tenths of
the corn and oats is used as livestock feed. Though these are the largest
crops from the standpoint of bushels produced, only a very small amount
actually moves into the commercial marketing channels, since most are
consumed on the farms where they are grown. In the case of wheat, how-
ever, a very large proportion of the total production is sold from the farms
to be further processed. The same is true of soybeans.
I Don Paarlbcrg, Prices of Soybeans and Soybean Products, Indiana Bulletin 538,
1949·
«00 I I ~ I'l" o
o....
I I
o
....o
I I
00 00
I '" I I ... o
00 o
....
,..on
<: oo~
o
o o'"
" ....
~
o \0 V\f'("\~O-lr\('..
u r:..,..:~ ci +0."':
P'"O r-j r~.-tOO ('("\,0"-
\0 ...
01
~: C' I I
'"
u
'§
~~I I o
t::
o
u
W
" 00
I I
I I ~n ~
00
-r
MARKETING OF AGRICULTlTRAL PRODUCTS
Variable Production
The acreage planted to the various grains does not vary markedly from
year to year, but the production does. This is largely because of the weather
and its effect on yields. Production is also highly seasonal. ~\'Iost of the com
is harvested during October through November. The entire crops of wheat,
oats, and rye are harvested during the relatively short period of June through
September. The soybean crop is harvested during the eady fall months.
In contrast to the seasonal nature of production, there is a fairly con-
stant demand throughout the year either for animal or human food. Some-
where in the marketing channel, then, must be the facilities for the huge
amount of seasonal storage.
The unpredictable nature of production also means that some stocks
must be carried over from one year to another. This is necessary if there
is to be any stability of supplies of food and feed from year to year. If the
harvest is a bumper one, the season-end carry-over will be large. If the
harvest is small, the carry-over will be much reduced. Such carry-overs are
the safety factors which protect dependent industries from violent feast-
and-famine f1uctu3tions. Table 2 shows the source of our annual average
total available supply. For most of the grains the average carry-over has
been running from one-sixth to one-fifth of our total supplies.
The government loan programs to support prices, of course, have a
definite effect on the amount of carry-over. How much carry-over the coun-
try should assure itself is a matter of public debate. If part of the carry-
over is government-owned because of its price support operations, the com-
position of the carry-over becomes an important factor. The amount which
is in private hands is "free" to move in response to market price fluctu-
ations. The amount which is in government hands is "frozen" and can be
released only for commercial use when prices reach certain levels or under
certain circumstances prescribed by law.
2 \V. R. Askew and V. J. Brensike, The Mixed-Feeds Industry, USDA Marketing
Research Report 38, 1953.
Grain Marketing 277
TAB L E '2. Composition of the Annual Available Supply of
Selected Grains in the United States, 1946-1950
Average
PERCENT OF TOTAL
Production 84 70 87 84 78 98
Carry-over 16 17 13 15 19 ::
Imports " 13 3
Total supply 100 100 100 100 100 100
Country Elevators
For most producers, the country elevator is the major buyer for their
grain. These elevators are scattered throughout the production area, usually
along railroads. The typical country elevator is estimated to have a storage
capacity of from 25,000 to 30,000 bushels, though many are much larger.
Depending upon the size of crop, they will handle from 100,000 to 300,000
bushels annually.5
Country elevators faU into three general c1asses according to their
ownership and organization. The independent elevators are under the
3 D. R. Stokes, Marketing ]\Jargins and Costs for Grains, Grain Products, and Dry
Edible Beans, USDA Technical Bulletin 934, 1947.
4 A. R. Sabin, Marketing Channel and Margin for Soybean and Soybean ProGucts,
USDl\, Bureau of Agricultural Economics, 1950.
5 D. \V. Mallott, "Grain and Its Marketing," Grain Exchange Institute, Inc., 1947.
}\1 ;\ R K ~ T I KG 0 FAG RIC U L T U R ALP ROD U C T 5
Kansas study found that even with considerable side-line business, eleva-
tors handling less than 250,000 bushels required a margin of 4-6 cents a
bushel to break cven, while those handling more than 250,000 required
3.6 cents (1945-1948).7 In this same study, 50 percent of the elevators
studied handled less than 250,000 bushels. An Indiana study found that
elevators with a sales volume under $125,000 had a net profit of 2.6 percent
of sales while those with a volume of over $375,000 had a net profit of 4.1
percent of sales. s
Increased volume for an elevator can be obtained in two principal
ways. One is to add other business lines to that of grain handling. The
other is to consolidate elevators so as to obtain a larger trade area. The
great majority of elevators have taken on various side-line enterprises to
boost their volume and offset the highly seasonal nature of their grain
operations. For many elevators the word "side-line" is not appropriate, as
the income frem the other enterprises may equal or surpass that received
from the handling of grain alone. The most common side-line is the feed
business. In addition, coal, seeds, implements, building materials, petro-
leum, and farm supplies are common sales departments. In some com-
munities the elevator is not only the outlet for grain, but also the principal
source of general farm supplies.
Increased volume can be obtained by the consolidation of existing
elevators. :tvluch of the present locational pattern was established back in
the era of horse-drawn transportation, poor roads, and poor communication.
The supply area of many elevators is sman. In Indiana, half of the total
business of the large majority of the elevators was obtained from a radius
of less than ten miles. 9 In Illinois the territory served varied from forty-
three to seventy-one square miles, and within this area there were from
three to six competitors.10 As is the case in other considerations, the number
of firms \vhich will provide an adequate volume for low cost operation
must be balanced against the industry structure which will assure effective
competition. The modern farmer, however, with his telephone, daily news-
paper, and radio, has a communication network which covers a larger area
than was available to his grandfather. \Vith his truck he can sen his grain
over a wider area. Some reasonable consolidation seems possible without
sacrificing an effectively competitive situation.
IvIost country elevator operators sell their grain to firms located at a
terminal market and ship it to the designated terminal elevators. Grain
7 E. B. Ballow, j\Jargins fwd Costs in Cooperative Grain Marketing in Kansas,
\ lSDA, Farm Credit Administration, Bulletin 66, 1951.
8 E. G. Byer, G. B. \Voad, and G. S. Abshier, A Financial and Business Analvsis of
l1,di;,na Grain Elevators, Indiana Bulletin 547, 1950. .
9 Ibid. 10 Norton, op. cit.
MARKETING OF AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS
Terminal Elevators
Terminal elevators furnish the large storage reservoirs necessary in the
grain marketing channel. The capacity of these large elevators ranges from
3°0,000 bushels to more than 10,000,000 bushels.u Besides furnishing
storage, the operators of terminal elevators condition the grain for storage
and prepare it for future sale.
Operators of terminal elevators may be grain dealers or merchants
11 rvlallott, op. cit., p. 154.
Grain Marketing 281
who buy grain for storage and later sell to millers and processors. Or the
operators may merely run the elevator and store and process the grain for
others for a fee. In still other cases, the large millers and processors may
own and operate their own terminal elevator facilities.
Terminal elevators are one of the principal groups which utilize the
futures markets for hedging. Very few country elevator operators hedge
their holdings. The country elevator operators often sell their grain almost
immediately upon purchase by utilizing "to-arrive" and "on-track" bids.
Under such circumstances, they quickly shift the price risk to their buyers.
On the other hand, terminal operators often hold grain for considerable
periods of time. These operators are small-margin, large-volume handlers,
and price fluctuations might easily turn profits into losses. Therefore,
hedging insurance is very desirable.
GRAIN GRADING
The use of federal standards is mandatory for the grading of any grain
which moves in interstate commerce. Because of the national nature of
the grain market, this means that the great bulk of commercial grain is
at some time in the marketing channel graded according to federal
standards.
TNhenever grain arrives in a large terminal market, a sample is drawn
and gradd. Grain grades range from the highest grade, Number 1, down
through Number 5 and sample grade. There is also a division into classes
and subclasses for each kind of grain. For example, Class I of wheat con-
sists of bard red spring wheat. This is further divided into the subclasses
of Dark Northern Spring, Northern Spring, and Red Spring. \Vithin each
class, the requirements for the various grades are set up.
::.82 MARKETING OF AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS
M.\XnIU;\[ L1~[lTS OF
DAMAGED KERNELS
PCU:-';OS PERCENT
SOURCE: Handbaa" of Official Grain Standards of the United States, USDA, 1947.
storage operation. Against these costs of farm storage must be weighed the
cost of hiring the country elevator to store the grain.
Several studies have reached the general conclusion that it is usually
less costly to hire storage in commercial elevators than to store on the
farmP All studies, however, point out the exceptions which may exist to
the general rule. If farm storage capacity exists which would otherwise
remain unused, then this conclusion may have to be modified. If the grain
is to be used later on as feed, the assurance of having a safe supply might
outweigh the other cost considerations. Several of these studies have cal-
culated the dollar-and-cents cost of storage. However, these costs vary so
much under different conditions that any generalization about actual costs
has little validity.
Grain is a good illustration of the fact that storage may be done more
efficiently at some levels in the marketing channel than in others. Very
little grain is stored by country elevators for their own account. Once grain
is sold by farmers it is quickly moved forward in the channel and the
major storage operation occurs at the terminal elevator level. Here the low
cost possibilities of large-scale handling by experienced operators can best
be realized. However, it must be recognized that the price support program
has encouraged more storage in the production area and in the majority
of the cases on the farm of the producer.
Cotton Marketing 1
between 1931 and 1936. With the 270 pounds in 1937, a new era of yields
began starting a sharp upward trend that reached 311 pounds per acre in
1948. In recent years the smaller acreages in cotton have been accompanied
by higher fertilization and a larger proportion grown on better adapted
lands. \Vith these, production has remained relatively constant, fluctuating
with weather and control programs.
Most of the cotton is produced on relatively small farms. About a
fourth of the farms producing cotton in 1949 harvested five acres or less
(Table 1). Another 40 percent harvested between six and fourteen acres
and less than 10 percent of the farms producing cotton harvested fifty
acres or more. This meant that most of the farmers must sell in relatively
5 or less
6-- 1 4
15-49
,0- 1 99
:00-499 1·3
500 and over ·3
SOURCE: United States Census, 1950.
288 MARKETING OF A.GRICULTURA.L PRODUCTS
small lots. About 40 percent of the farms growing cotton produced three
bales or less in 1949 (Table 2) . One-third produced between four and nine
bales and only 10 percent produced over twenty-five bales.
3 or less 39
4-<) 33
10-2 4 18
25-49 5
50 and over 5
Computed from United States Census, 1950
Coiton Standards
Cotton is classed according to grade and staple length. Cotton classi-
fication is technical and most cotton farmers are unable to determine
accurately the official quality. Many local buyers are not trained buyers
and estimate the classification. The official standards for grades of American
upland cotton are given in Table 3.
1
liz
IT.r
l:i1z
" Short staple cotton is cotton 1 h inches and shorter. Long staple cotton is cotton
111 inches and longer.
Cotton Marketing 289
The Smith-Doxey Act and the Cotton Grade and Staple Statistics Act
were passed to provide cotton classification service to producers. This classi-
fication service is provided free to producers in certain communities. In
1949 about one-half of the crop was included in the program.
Consumption of All Fibers
Per capita consumption of all fiber in the United States has beeen more
than a third higher during and after the years of World War II than in the
prewar period (Figure 2). The shift was due primarily to a high level of
20
10
~'orHUS' IHClUPE WOOL. "AX. SIUI: loa All rEARS AHP • OTHER MAH·MADE'IIBfU loa IP40 TO "ATE
Utilization of Cotton 3
Most cotton moves to the mills in bales. At the mills the bales are
opened and the cotton is cleaned, carded, combed (for fine yams), and
2 For a detailed discussion of foreign consumption sec the statement by Frank
Lowenstein, Agricultural Economist, before the Senate Committee on Agriculture and
Forestry, April 24, 1953.
3 L. D. Howell, "]'vlarketing and ,vfanufacturing Services and Margins for Textiles,"
USDA Technical Bulletin 1062, 1952.
Cotton Marketing 29 1
spun into yarn. On the average, about 4 percent of the gross weight of the
ba1e usually is discarded as tare (bagging and ties), about 7 percent usua11y
is removed as nonspinnable waste, and most of the remainder, which
amounts to about 89 percent, is made into yarn (Figure 3). According to
census reports for 1947, for example, about 75 percent of the yarn was
woven into cloth, 9 percent went to the knit-goods industry, 9 percent was
used in tire cords, and the remainder was used in making thread, carpets,
cordage, twine, and other products.
APPROXIMATE DISTRIBUTION OF A
TYPICAL BALE OF COTTON, 1947
I COTTON IN BAL E
500 POUNDS GROSS WEIGHT
1129POUNOS!
LOCATION OF MILLING
The average mill consumption of cotton during the period of 1948-
1952 was slightly over 9 million bales (Table 5). Mill consumption was
fairly stable during the period of 1920-1939, then increased sharply, reach-
ing a peak of over 11 million bales in 1941; afterward it remained relatively
constant from 1943 through 1952 at about 9 million bales.
::-.nLL CONSU::-'IPTION
TOTAL
UNITED STATES COTTON
YEARS BEGINNING l\HLL GROWING NEW
AUGUST 1 CO:-lSU~IPTION STATES ENGLAND OTHERS
19 20- 2 4 5, 86 9 6-) 29 6
1930-34 5,4 6 5 81 16 3
194°-44 10,3°1 87 10 3
1948-52 9,162 91 7 2
MARKETING CHANNELS
Channels Used
Taking cotton from farms and delivering it in the form of finished
clothing and household textiles to ultimate consumers requires the services
of many different types of middlemen, including handlers of raw cotton,
manufacturers, and distributors of cotton products (Figure 4). These
services begin when seed cotton is hauled from farms to gins. Gins perform
services such as conditioning and cleaning of seed cotton, separating the
lint from the seed, and packing and wrapping the lint into bales weighing
approximately 500 pounds.
Local Markets 4
Almost the entire cotton crop is produced on farms located within a
fcw miles of a market outlet for cotton. Some 2,500 of these producers'
or local markets form a vast network of primary markets which dot the
entire expanse of the cotton belt. Growers, with few exceptions, dispose
of their cotton at these local markets.
Few local markets have a formal market organization set up specifically
for cotton trading. Trading between producers and buyers usually is con-
ducted on an informal basis with the producer selling his own cotton
according to his desire to sell and his ability to bargain. A local market
customarily serves a small community or trading area. Sales by growers
averaged 6,784 bales per market in 1947, although individual markets varied
widely in the volume of cotton handled.
The small volumes available and the relatively short duration of the
active marketing period require most first-buyers either to engage in some
related cotton activity or to have some other type of year-round business.
During 1947, approximately 62 percent of sales by growers were made to
buyers whu reported other business activities. Ginning has been the major
activity associated with cotton buying.
" For more details on marketing practices, see R. C. Saxman, "Marketing of Cotton
in Producer's Local Markets," USDA, P.M.A., processed, 1949.
........_
<:
@
~
<II
I- ~
W
~
'"
c: .: ....
«
:::E
iii
()
5
"( 0
in
a: ...0 '--
w
z ...... ....:
z b ]
c::
(/) """- ;:
"" .8
(,)
i::'" '0
u
~ ,._
I- 0 ...._
0
Z ~
(,) ~
..J "" ~
:.:'" §
Z
0
'" '"5
;;;
~
l-
I-
;3
Q .S
.....
0 ~
U
., "',._'""
'"z '".,... ~ 1;l
~
0
l:'
z'"
<",
.
0
;:
U
"'"w
~
2:
(,)
11.
W
(/)
I-
W
"'w
Uo.
5~
,.~
.~
w
'"~
~
z
"¢"
i:;:::!
..J
W
'"<:a:
:::E
:50
~z
~<
8
>
S
w
0.
";;;
'"
E!
'g..."
0
(,)
c:=:::
::J
Z -' 0
«
Z
a:
I-
0
U
'~" C)
......
ct '"uZ g ~
J: '~"
;::
U ()
l!) ::
Z 2:
:::.
0
I- '"""
W :.:'"0:
~ ;;;
~ 0
ct
~
'"
;::
''<"
0:
~
E
(/) ;3
,_'"w Q
::
:::J
...'"'"
Q
()
.,'~"
'"
0:
(/)
...
0:
U
::>
o
o
0:
0.
Cotton Marketing 295
Central Markets 5
A relatively small number of spot cotton market5 situated at strategic
locations throughout the cotton belt exercise a dominant role in the
marketing of American raw cotton. These major centers are called central
spot cotton markets and have large-scale facilities for storing and concen-
trating cotton. Trading in most of these markets is carried on according
to rules of the local cotton exchange. Each market has a fairly well-defined
trading territory.
Central markets such as Houston, New Orleans, and Galveston are
deep-water ports and form the gateway through which American cotton
moves to overseas markets. Others, including Memphis, Dallas, Greenwood,
Little Rock, Augusta, and Montgomery, are interior markets located stra-
tegically with respect to important areas of production and inland lines
of transportation to mil1s or ports.
For a number of years, :rvIemphis has been the leading central cash
cotton market. l\hrkets next in order of volume of sales are Dallas,
Houston, and New Orleans, respectively. These four largest markets usually
handle slightly more than one-half of total cotton production.
The three principal buying agencies in these markets are cotton
merchants, mill buyers, and cotton brokers. Cotton merchants acquire the
bulk of their stocks by purchases made in local markets, usually from gin-
ners and other local buyers. In a study of five central markets it was found
that merchants secured about 22 percent of their cotton from producers, 27
percent from ginners, 18 percent from other first buyers, slightly less than
7 percent from other merchants, 20 percent through brokers, and the re-
mainder from varied sources. lvIil1 buying agencies followed the same gen-
eral pattern as did merchants in buying chiefly at local markets. More than
three-fourths of the purchases were made at country markets.
Sales made by spot brokers were chiefly for producers or various types
of first buyers. About 37 percent of sales by brokers were made for pro-
ducers, approximately 52 percent for ginners and other local buyers, only
about 9 percent for merchants, and the remainder for cooperatives and
others.
Merchants normally attempt to avoid all possible risk of adverse price
movements. Merchants sell some purchases immediately, but almost all
unsold purchases are hedged by the sale of future contracts. l\'fill buying
agencies usually purchase for the account of certain mills or have estab-
lished outlets for immediate sale.
5Adapted from R. C. Soxman and A. L. Roberts, "i\I<lrketing Practices at Central
~?)t Cotton Markets," USDA, P.M,A., processed, 1948.
MARKETING OF AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS
MARKETING MARGINS6
The farmer receives a small portion of the consumer's dollar paid for
finished cotton products. Data relating to the retail value of forty-two
cotton articles of clothing and household furnishings and to farm values
of equivalent quantities of cotton indicate that from 19'27 to 1950 farm
producers received an average of 10.6 percent of the consumer's dollar. The
portion 'of the consumer's dollar represented by the farm value of the
cotton usually varied directly with the price of cotton. It ranged from about
5 percent in 193'2, when farm prices of cotton averaged about 6 cents a
pound, to 14 percent in 1950, when farm prices of cotton averaged about
40 cents a pound.
Gross marketing margins for cotton include the costs or charges made
for taking seed cotton to the gins, having it ginned and baled, delivering
the bales to mills at the desired time, manufacturing the cotton into cotton
goods, distributing the goods and selling to the ultimate consumer.
The fact that, on the average, almost 90 percent of each dollar paid by
consumers for finished cotton goods is accounted for by marketing margins
emphasizes the importance of these margins.
Charges for ginning vary considerably from year to year with changes
in general business conditions, in prices of cotton, and in costs of bagging
and ties. They vary also from one state or region to another with differences
in kinds and amounts of services rendered. For the United States as a whole,
average charges for ginning a 5°o-pound bale of American Upland Cotton,
including charges for bagging and ties, ranged from 4.04 for the 1931 crop
when farm prices of cotton averaged 5.66 cents per pound to $11.19 for
the 1950 crop when farm prices averaged 40.07 cents a pound. The pro-
Where It Goes
THE CONSUMER'S COTTON DOLLAR,
BY OPERATIONS OR SERVICES
Paid for Apparel and Household Goods, Selected Years
$122
Rehiling
Wholesali ng
75¢
Manuf. apparel 60
household goods
Manuf., dying, 60 finish-
ing yarns 60 fabrics
25¢ Merchandising coHon
F=~-Ginning and baling
Farm produdion
O--~~--~~~~--~~------------~
1939 1947 1949 1950
BASED OH OFFICIAL AHD OTH~R OATA. AHD ,pARTLY ESTIMATED ..
portion of the farm value of the cotton accounted for by ginning charges
ranged from 5 percent for the 1946 crop when farm prices averaged 32.64
cents a pound to 14 percent for the 1931 crop when farm prices averaged
5.66 cents a pound. For the 1950 crop, when farm prices averaged 40 cents
a pound, this proportion averaged 5.6 percent. The portion of the con-
sumer's dollar represented by ginning and baling has averaged less than
one cent (Figure 5).
cotton-selling practices in Egypt, India, and Brazil is based on observations by P. K.
"'':lrris, former marketing specialist, Bureau of Agricultural Economics, during his studies
at production and marketing of cotton in these countries.
MARKETING OF AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS
Manufacturing lvlargins
The manufacturing margins include the costs for spinning yam, weav-
ing cloth, and dyeing and finishing the fabrics; and for the manufacture
of apparel and household textiles.
Different kinds of agencies engage in some of the same kinds of serv-
ices. Consequently, the margins indicated for each type of sp.rvice do not
show specifically the charges made by each type of agency. Some textile
manufacturers, for example, although they engage primarily in spinning
and weaving, dye and finish some cloth, fabricate some of the cloth into
household and other goods, and sell the products to wholesalers or retailers.
The proportions of the consumer's dollar accounted for by average margins
for cotton manufacturers who are primarily engaged in spinning, weaving,
dyeing, and finishing cotton yarns and fabrics averaged 18,5 percent in
1950. Similar proportions for manufacturers of apparel and household
goods averaged slightly more than 29 percent in 1950.
Where It Goes
THE CONSU~AER'S COTTON DOLLAR,
BY COST ITEMS
Paid for Apparel and Household Goods, Selected Years
$1~~~~~'---~~'---~~'---~~
Profil:s if
44.0 48.0
254
7.S 11.3 11.2 13.3 - Farm producHon
O ~~~--~~~~~--~------------~
1939 1947 1949 1950
e.-SED ON' OFFICIAL AND OTHER: DATA, ANt) PARTLY ESTIMATED •
.. NET PROFITS OF Al.L AC!HCIES. EXCEPT FARM PRODUCERS. A.FTER: OEOUCTIOH OF FEDERAL INCOME A.HD EXCESS-
PROFIT TA.XES.
o INCLUDES DEDUCTIOHS FOR FEDERA.L ''''COME APID EXCESS-PR.OFIT TAXES.
tions for net profits for all agencies combined ranged from 5.7 percent in
2939 to 14 percent in 1947, and averaged 11 percent in 1950. The propor-
tions for advertising and for other items decreased markedly after 1939.
Salaries and wages for employees engaged in marketing cotton and cotton
products average more than four times as much, and net profits to market-
ing agencies average almost as much as returns to grO\vers for farm pro-
duction of the cotton.
Thest. data relating to the distribution of the consumer's donar paid
for apparel and household goods made of cotton may serve to indicate the
r~lative importance, from the viewpoint of costs, of increasing efficiency
MARKETING OF AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS
and of reducing costs for the different agencies and functions involved. Data
show that the margins for ginning and baling, combined \vith those for all
the merchandising services involved in taking cotton from gins and deliver-
ing it to mills, amount, on the average, to only about 5 percent of the
combined margins for manufacturing and finishing the cloth and for
fabricating it into wearing apparel and household goods. They amount to
only about 6 percent of the combined margins for wholesaling and retail-
ing these products. Thus a reduction of only 3 percent in the margins for
wholesale and retailing, or for manufacturing and finishing cloth and fabri-
cating it into apparel and household goods, would tend to reduce the spread
between retail prices to consumers and prices to growers for the cotton to a
greater degree than would a 50 percent reduction in the margins for ginning,
baling, and merchandising the raw cotton.
MARKETING COTTONSEEDs
Cottonseed usually ranks among the ten leading field crops in farm
value in the United States and has been third in rank in the cotton belt.
Since cottonseed is the less valuable member of the lint-seed crop, the
production of seed is often influenced primarily by factors determining
production of lint cotton. Cottonseed is processed into oil, cake or meal,
linters, and hulls, all of which are important in the national economy.
The physical movement of cottonseed from farm to mill is character-
ized by directness and simplicity. Growers bring seed cotton to gins where
the lint and seed are separated. The greater part of this seed, except that
retained for planting and other farm uses, is sold immediately to ginners
who usually sell promptly to processors.
As compared with many other agricultural products, cottonseed is very
bulky in relation to weight. Cottonseed weighs about thirty-two pounds per
bushe1. This bulkiness creates relatively high costs in storing and transport-
ing cottonseed and re3tricts its movement over long distances for processing.
Processors, therefore, customarily are located in close proximity to the
source of supply.
The quality of cottonseed often varies appreciably with location and
season of harvest. Since such variations in quality can be measured only by
highly technical chemical analyses, cottonseed normally is purchased by
ginners without regard to the quality of individual lots of seed but is sold
to the oil mills largely on the basis of quality.
Many methods are used to determine the weight of cottonseed being
sold. Only a small part of the trading between the ginner and grower is
8 For more details on the handling of cottonseed, see M. E. \Vhitten and J. H.
Stevenson, The Marketing of Cottonseed, USDA, P.M.A., processed, 1949.
Cotton Marketing 301
15
10
Before \Vorld War II the total volume of the world's cotton export
trade approximated 13 million bales a year, of which the United States had
more than 40 percent (Figurc 8). Other principal exporters of American
type cotton were Brazil anel India. During \Vorlel \Var II the international
trade in cotton declincd drastically. Recovery following \Vorld \Var II was
slow until 1948-1949 when the European Recovery Program gave cotton
trade a new emphasis, bilt the volume in trading sti1l remains more than a
million bales under the prewar yearly average.
GROWERS GROWERS
LOCATION K:'>OWING GROWERS GROWERS KNOWING
OF 1IARI:ETS BOTH GRADE K~OWING KNOWING NEITHER GRADE
(STATE) AND STAPLE GRADE ONLY STAPLE ONLY NOR STAPLE TOTAL
PERCr::'>T
Alabama 50 9 40 100
Arizona 1CO 100
Arkansas 66 34 100
California 99 1 100
Florida 58 100
Georgia 44 55 100
Louisiana 32 6 62 100
l'IIississippi 38 62 100
l\Iissouri 23 77 100
New l\Iexico 100 100
Xorth Carolina 27 72 100
Oklahoma 47 52 100
South Carolina 9 91 100
Tennessee 9 91 100
Texas 71 * * 2q 100
Virginia 2 98 100
at the mar~ets in Arizona, California, and New j\Iexico had quality infor-
mation at the time of sale. Two-thirds of the growers in Arkansas and
9 Saxman, op. cit.
MARKETING OF AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS
about three-fourths of those in Texas knew the quality of cotton being sold.
In contrast, less than one-tenth of growers at markets in Florida, South
Carolina, Tennessee, and Virginia was informed as to the grade and staple
of their cotton.
Federal grading service is available to producers participating in im-
provement programs without any direct charge for the service. Growers
marketing 46 percent of the total volume had documents at the time of sale
such as reports from federal grading or licensed classers' certificates that
indicated grade and staple. Approximately 28 percent of all sales (about
three-fifths of the cotton so documented) were completed on the basis of
such impartial quality information without buyers examining a sample.
stand in the United States usually averages less than 300 bales. This indi-
cates that the cost of ginning might be reduced considerably by increasing
the volume of cotton per ginP This would require a reduction in number
of gin stands operated. Such a reduction might well be brought about by
discontinuing the use of old, badly worn, and obsolete equipment. In the
1947-1948 season, 75 percent of the cotton was hauled six miles or less to
gin, therefore the number of gins could be decreased considerably without
causing farmers to travel unusually long distances to gins. Bureau of Census
reports relating to the number and capacity of gins and to the number of
bales ginned during the 1945-1946 season indicate that if all gins had been
operated at capacity on the basis of a twelve-hour day, the 1945 crop could
have been ginned in about twenty days.
SELECTED REFERENCES
The Classification of Cotton, USDA, Miscellaneous Publication 310, 1938.
The Cotton Textile Industry, U. S. Bureau of Internal Revenue, Excess Profits
Council, 1948.
Cox, A. B., Cotton Markets and Cotton Merchandising, 2nd ed. (Austin, Texas,
Hemphill, 1949)'
Data Relating to Practices and Costs in the Primary Marketing of Cotton,
USDA, Production Marketing Administration, 1950.
Facts About Cotton, USDA Leaflet 167, 1952.
Home, M. K, Jr., "Cotton's Way Forward," Oxford Business Research, Uni-
versity of lVIississippi, 1949.
Little, H. \V., and R. A. Ballinger, Progress of Free Classing and Market News
Service for Members of Cotton Improvement Groups in Louisiana, Louisiana
Bulletin 362, 1943.
Merrill, G. R., American Cotton Handbook, 2nd ed. (New York, Textile Book
Publishers, 1949)'
Richards, F. A., The Marketing of Cotton and the Financing of Cotton Mer-
chants (New York, Chase National Bank, 1949)'
Roberts, A. L., and A. J. Fortenberry, Charges for Ginning Cotton, 1941-42 to
1946-47, USDA, Production Marketing Administration.
Whitten, M. E., and J. H. Stevenson, The Marketing of Cottonseed, USDA,
Production Marketing Administration, 1949.
Wright, J. \V., Cotton Quality as Related to Marketing, USDA, Production
Marketing Administration, 1946.
Wright, J. 'V., F. L. Gerdes, and C. A. Bennett, The Packaging of American
Cotton and iV1ethods of Improvement, USDA Circular 736, 1945.
12 Howell, op. cit.
CHAPTER TWENTY
cr bacco Marketing
0 1
Classification of Tobaccos
The tobacco industry in the United States is highly specialized. To-
bacco is not a single crop, but rather a group of crops each having distinctive
characteristics and uses. :Methods of curing vary materially, and except for
the cigar and miscellaneous types, they provide one basis for classification.
The cigar types are classified on the basis of use.
Tobacco is first classified on the basis of its distinct characteristics
caused by ,oaricties of soils, climate and methods of cultivation, harvesting
1 By Co B. Cox (see Chapter 19).
Tobacco Marketing 307
and curing; this division is called a class.!! Each class is subdivided into
types. Tobacco which has the same characteristics and corresponding
qualities, colors, and lengths is treated as one type. Types are further sub-
divided into grades. The grade of tobacco is based upon three factors-
group, quality, and color. The group is determined by the shape of leaf,
body, percentage of injury, and other common characteristics. For example,
the normal groups for flue-cured tobacco are lugs, cutters, and leaf. The
second factor of a grade is quality which is based on a combination of
elements of smoothness, oil, maturity, body, width, porosity, color shade,
finish, and uniformity. The six degrees of quality for flue-cured tobacco
are choice, fine, good, fair, low, and common. The third factor of the grade
is color. The colors recognized in flue-cured tobacco arc lemon, orange, red,
clark red, and green.
Any combination of group, quality, and color can be made to form a
grade. As this method of expressing grades is too cumbersome for practical
purposes, symbols are used for each group, quality, and color. For example,
flue-cured tobacco, produced principal1y in the Piedmont section of Vir-
ginia and North Carolina, taken from the top portion of the plant (leaf),
and being of choice quality and lemon color, would be designated as
type 11 BIL.
The following are the six main classes of tobaccos which are divided
into twenty-nine recognized different types: 3
Class 1. Flue-cured, types 11, 12, 13, and 14
Class 2. Fire-cured, types 21, 22, 23, and 24
Class 3· Light air-cured, types 31 and 32, and
dark air-cured, types 35, 36, and 37
Class 4· Fillers, types 4 1, 4 2, 43, 44, and 45
Class 5· Binders, types 51, 52, 53, 54, 55, and 56
Class 6. \Vrappers, types 61, 62, and 65
Class 7· 1Iiscellaneous, types 71 and 72
The type numbers indicate not only the type but also the class. For ex-
ample, the first digit for all flue-cured types is 1.
Class 1, the flue-cured tobacco, accounts for more than half the total
production of American tobacco (Figure 1). It is light colored and aro-
matic, and is the largest component in domestic cigarettes. The great
majority of all our tobacco exports is from this class. Trends in the produc-
tion of flue· cured tobacco have been steadily upward, whereas the opposite
~ For a ;TIore complete discussion of grades, see Tobacco Inspection, l'vIar:wt News,
and Demonstraiion Sen-ices, USDA, Production and l\1arketing Administration, l\Jimeo-
graph, 1950.
3 :\dapted from J. F. l\larsh, J. A. Hicks, and C. E. Burkhead, Tobaccos of th_!;
has been true of some other classes. Nearly all flue-cured tobacco is now
"prime"-that is, the leaves are pulled individually as they reach maturity.
The leaves are then hung in barns in which heat through metal flues is
applied gradually. Temperatures of from 1500 to 1700 F. or higher are
reached during the drying proccss, which requires from three to five days.
Flue-cured tobacco is grown in southern Virginia, North Carolina, and the
coastal plain region of South Carolina, Georgia, and northern Florida.
1,000
800
600
400
200
light and dark. The difference in these is in the characteristics of the to-
bacco rather than the method of curing. The dark types are heavy-bodied,
coarse in texture, and to some extent comparable to the fired types. Over
the years, the dark air-cured types have averaged somewhat lower in price
than the fired types. Production of this tobacco has also declined through
the years. These dark types are grown in western Kentucky and to a less
extent in Tennessee, Indiana, and Virginia.
The light air-cured types are not interchangeable with or substitutable
for the dark air-cured because each has special characteristics. Type 31,
burley, is the most widely grown single type of tobacco in the United
:i States. It is grown in ten states and accounts for 25 percent of all the
i
tobacco grown in this country. It is flavorful but much milder than the
darker types, and is used with the flue-cured tobacco as the base for making
I blended cigarettes. Large quantities of burley are also used in pipe tobacco,
plugs, and twists. Type 32, or Southern Nlaryland, a mild and more neutral
tobacco with less oil, is generally thought to be about ideal with respect to
burning quality. Concentrated production areas of light air-cured types are
found in north central Kentucky and southern Maryland. Some is also
produced in Tennessee, North Carolina, Virginia, \Vest Virginia, Ohio,
Indiana, Missouri, and Kansas.
The cigar types are al1 air-cured but are classified on the basis of use.
The classifications do not imply exclusive uses, however. Some of the lower
grades in all three of the cigar classes go into scrap-chewing and other uses.
The three main classes of cigar tobacco now grown in the United States are
fillers, binders, and wrappers.
Fil1ers are grown in Pennsylvania and Ohio. They constitute the core
or body of cigars. These types are high-yielding, and the curing methods
are similar to those used for burley. The stalks are cut in the fields and
curing is done by the natural air unless the weather is so damp as to require
artificial heat.
The binder types are grown mostly in \Visconsin and in the Con-
necticut val1ey. SmaIl quantities are grown in Minnesota, New York, Penn-
sylvania, and along the Georgia-Florida line. They are used for binding
the fillers into the form of cigars.
\Vrappers are the most costly tobacco. Used for the outside cover of
cigars, the leaves must be elastic, relatively free of damage, uniform in color,
and of good burning qualities. In addition, the best wrappers are thin,
smooth, anti of fine texture. In order to obtain such qualities some protec-
tion is needed from the sun and weather. A permanent framework is erected
over which open mesh cloth is tacked enclosing large fields. Cultivation is
MARKETING OF A.GRICULTURAL PRODUCTS
carried on under this cover. The leaves of wrapped tobacco are primed as
for flue-cured tobacco, and the curing and conditioning require much more
handling than most other classes. The wrapper types are grown in the Con-
necticut vaney and in Georgia and Florida.
Domestic Consumption
About 80 percent of all tobaccos used in this country in 1952 was Con-
sumed in the form of cigarettes. This is in sharp contrast to tobacco utiliza-
MIL.LBS.
TOBACCO
PRODUCTS
IN U. s.
800
400
o
1935 1940 1945 1950 1955
UNSTEMMfD PROCESSINC;~WEIGH7 EQUIVALENT
tion in 1920 when twice as much was used for pipe tobacco and snuff as
for cigarettes. Cigar consumption accounted for 9 percent of total utiliza-
tion in 1952 compared to 26 percent in 1920. Tobacco and snuff accounted
for only 10 percent of total consumption in 1952 compared to 51 percent
in 1920 (Figure 2).
Owing to the time required for off-farm curing and processing, most to-
bacco is stored for as long as several years before it is used. Storage stocks
usually exceed annual production. In 1950, stocks were 52 percent greater
than production.
---
I
I
On-Farm Sales
Some tobacco is purchased by buyers who come to the farm itself. Such
on-farm sales are of considerable importance in the sale of cigar tobaccos.
Sales may be made during the growing season, but the bulk of sales are
made during or after the curing season. The price may be either for the
farmer's entire crop or quoted by different grades. On-farm sales of tobacco
other than cigar types are declining but are still of considerable importance
in some dark air-cured, fire-cured, and burley areas. Buyers may be local
speculators, dealers, and manufacturers who wish to buy certain crops be-
cause of their quality.
There are several disadvantages of on-farm sale which can be sum-
marized as follows:
Hogshead Selling
Hogshead marketing began in colonial days when packed hogsheads
were fitted with shafts for transportation to central markets. Sales were made
on the basis of official inspection. This form of marketing reached its peak
about the time of the Civil \Var but began to decline about 1889. :lvIarket-
ing by hogshead is almost nonexistent today. Baltimore is the only
remaining market which receives, inspects, and sells such deliveries.
" Fur hrther detail see C. E. Gage, American Tobacco Types, Uses arid Markets,
USDA Circular 249, 1942.
5 For more details see H. H. Bakken and \V. F. I'dueller, "Oligopsony in the \Vis·
ron sin Tobacco Industry," Land Economics, May, 1952.
MARKETING OF AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS
TOBACCO
AUCTION MARKETS AND PRODUCING AREAS, 1952-53
(CIGAR lEAF PRODUCING AREAS NOT SHOw"l
t. 'L~.· c~~, •. ..
H ..
UC""'U'II>'
on''', u,
,., ••• '. Q¥
,.,,,.,,,~
ON.'"
..
- - - -•••- -'U- -,00001(D --- - - -
00" '''"
K.t.NSA
coT!
- -- ,• • • ~1"".
-
n.t u,.
- -_.
sold is usually brought in by the farmers themselves (Figure 3). The to-
bacco is weighed and tagged and displayed on the floor in round piles with
the stem end out. Before the sale, the tobacco is graded by a federal grader.
Sales are conducted according to a prearranged schedule which per-
mits buyers to move among the several warehouses in a given market area.
Small markets with only two or three sales warehouses may have only one
group of buyers, while a larger market may have several sets of buyers which
work simultaneously. This also is shown in Figure 3. Buyers include repre-
sentatives of tobacco manufacturing and exporting companies and specu-
lators (pinhookers). The sale is conducted as the auctioneer moves about
the various piles of tobacco on display in the warehouse.
To the uninitiated observer, sales are a scene of utter confusion. He
can scarcely tell auctioneer from buyer from warehouseman, and finds it
almost impossible to determine who bought which pile of tobacco for what
price! The owner may "no sale" any basket and place it elsewhere in the
warehouse, remove it to another warehouse, or hold it for later sale. No
warehouse charges are paid if tobacco is removed from the warehouse
unsold.
The sales dates vary with production areas. The Georgia-Florida mar-
kets open first, usually in mid-July, and continue through most of August.
l'vlarkets in South Carolina open a week or so later and continue through
October. North Carolina markets follow and conduct sales through No-
vember. Burley and fire-cured markets operate from December to February
or :March. Southern Maryland markets begin sales in May and continue
through the summer months. Thus some type of tobacco is being sold
nearly every month in the year.
Cooperative Associations
At the present time, cooperative associations do not make up a separate
type of market organization, but function largely as farmers' representatives
in conjunction with the auction system. Tobacco cooperatives have a long
and turbulent history. By 1923, almost half of the nation's tobacco was
marketed through various cooperative associations. But the movement
declined, and by 1930 only about 2 percent of the production was marketed
by cooperative organizations. At the present time "Cooperative Stabiliza-
tion Corporations" perform the storage functions in connection with the
govern men t loan programs which are the mechanism of price supports.
MARKETING CHANNELS
As indicated in Figure 4, tobacco may be sold directly to the manufac-
turer, or to dealers or specu1ators who in turn sen to the manufacturers.
MARKETING OF AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS
In the case of indirect sales, redrying, stemming, and packing may occur
before the tobacco finally reaches the manufacturer.
Tobacco, as delivered to the market by farmers, is in a semiperishable
condition because of high moisture content. Except for certain cigar types,
aging and fermentation occur after leaving the farm. Sometimes a period
TOBACCO MANUFACTURING
As has been pointed out, tobacco leaf is the raw product for many dif-
ferent kinds of products. Cigarettes are by far the most important of these
products in the United States. In 1947, there were 1,086 tobacco manufac-
turing establishments which employed a total of 111,782 persons. How-
ever, the manufacturing capacity is highly concentrated in the hands of a
very few firms. More than 90 percent of all cigarettes made in 1947 were
manufactured by four companies (Figure 5). Eight companies made over
80 percent of the snuff, chewing, and smoking tobacco. In cigars, the top
eight companies produced 57 percent of the total. The nature of tobacco
manufacturing is such that mass production and assembly line techniques
can be widely used.
Recent years have seen substantial changes in manufacturing tech-
nology which have still further increased the advantages of large-scale pro-
duction. In 1947, about 370 billion cigarettes were produced compared
Tobacco Marketing 315
with 122 biI1ion in 19 2 9. However, the number of workers in the industry
only increased 21 percent during this period.
In the marketing of the finished product, large-scale operations are
also favored. To a substantial extent, the market for any given brand of
cigarette is nation-wide. The cigarette is a low-bulk-and-weight product
CONCENTRATION IN TOBACCO
MANUFACTURES
(Value of Produc:1:s Made in 1947)
MIL. DOL.
o 200 400 600 800 1,000 1,200
~g!Ak·~~·~~·.:::~·~··~"~~~~~~~~~~~U':S'·.'~t1
NEXT4 MFRS.
TOTAL .. ·· .... · ..
TOP 8 MFRS.···r-:--a'J-
NEXT 12 MFRS.
TOTAL ......... ..
TOP 8 MFRS.···
NEXT 12 MFRS.
compared to its value, and transportation charges, therefore, are not a lim-
iting factor in its distribution. The distribution system is built largely on
nonprice competition. As any listener to the radio or viewer of television
can testify, the various companies make a tremendous attempt to make the
public brand conscious.
MARKETING MARGINS
OF CIGARETTES
The farm value of tobacco in a package of cigarettes has fluctuated
from a low in 1931 of about a half cent to a high in 1950 of slightly over
H cents (Figure 6). The average during the prewar period of 1935-1 939
was about 1.4 cents. To a substantial degree, all of the analysis of the
farmer's share of the food dollar which was developed in Chapter 5 applies
to tobacco.
MARKETING OF AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS
The retail price of cigaretes has gradually increased from 12.7 cents per
pack in 1933 to about 22~5 cents in 1953. The retail price includes the
farmer's share, the manufacturer's and leaf dealer's margin, the distributor's
margin, and federal and state excise taxes.
CIGAR ETTES
Estimated Farm Value of Leaf Tobacco, Marketing Margins, and Taxes
¢ PER PACKAGE-
Re{:ail price
INTERNATIONAL TRADE
Of a total world production of p million tons (the USSR and China
excluded) in 1940, 560 thousand tons entered international trade. The
principal importing and exporting countries are given in Table 1. The
United Kingdom was the leading importer, and imported one-fourth of all
tobacco that entered international trade. The United States, the leading
exporter, exported nearly two-fifths of the total tobacco sold internationally.
IMPORTERS EXPORTERS
AI\IQUNT AMOUNT
( 1,000 METRIC (1,000 I\!ETRIC
COUNTRY TONS) COUNTRY TONS)
Indeed, the same basket of tobacco sold on a given market may bring
different prices if the -bid is refused and the tobacco sold again in a
different location on the warehouse floor. An extreme case is that of a
farmer who sold the same basket of tobacco ten times at prices ranging
from 8 to 28 cents per pound.9 Variations in prices of identical tobacco
or of tobacco of the same federal grade may arise from the follow-
ing causes:
(a) Inability of buyers to accurately determine grade. This may arise
from crowded warehouse conditions and rapidity of sales which
prevent proper inspection of the tobacco by all buyers. Lighting
conditions (location of skylights and amount of sunlight) may
prevent accurate quality determination. Variations in price of the
same federal grades of tobacco could be due to the fact that federal
grades and buyer grades are determined by different criteria. And
some variation may arise from the inherently subjective nature of
grade determination.
(b) Tobacco is sold by many small producers and purchased by a
relatively sma11 number of large manufacturers. This fact has been
used to argue that the individual farmer has little or no bargaining
power and must accept the price offered by the buyer. The federal
government has investigated the tobacco manufacturing industry
to determine whether or not there existed violations of the Sherman
Anti-Trust Act. Several leading tobacco manufacturers were con-
victed in federal courts as possessing power to exclude competition.
(c) Tobacco is a semiperishable product which is difficult or imprac-
ticable to store on the farm for more than a few months. Thus, the
bargaining position of the farmer is further impaired since he can-
not withhold his product from the market in anticipation of higher
prices. However, the price support program of the federal govern-
ment has greatly increased the bargaining power of farmers.
2. It is claimed that tobacco marketing costs are excessive because many
warehouses operate at considerably less than their capacity.10 This con-
dition also results in a shorter marketing season which may be to the
disadvantage of the farmer in curing and preparing his crop for market.
The short market season is said to be particularly disadvantageous in
the Georgia belt. It must be remembered, however, that a certain
9 J. J. \\Tooten, Jr., The Plight of the Cigarette Industry of North Carolina (Chapel
Hill University of North Carolina Press, 1931)'
10 See P. D. Conycrse, "Tobacco Auctions Evaluated," Journal of Business, Uni-
WHAT IS A COOPERATIVE?
Distinctive Characteristics of American Cooperatives
Almost an cooperative leaders of both past and present have had their
pet conception of what constituted a good definition of a cooperative.
322
The Place and Problems of Agricultural Cooperatives 32 3
H. E. Babcock, an eastern cooperative leader, phrased it weB when he said
that cooperatives are a legal, practical means by which a group of self-
selected, selfish capitalists seek to improve their individual economic posi-
tion in a competitive society. Several aspects of this definition deserve
attention. First, a cooperative is a device which permits group action
for the economic gain of the individual members. Secondly, it is an active
part of our competitive business framework. And thirdly, the cooperative
is an institution whose characteristics are formalized in the laws of the land
as one of the legal forms of business organization.
TIle so-called Rochdale principles are generally conceded to be the
cornerstone of the modern cooperative structure. This list of practices
received its name from the group of weavers of Rochdale, England, who
are credited with founding one of the first successful cooperative businesses
with the opening of a store in 1844- These principles of cooperative opera-
tion as developed by the Rochdale pioneers are usually listed as follows:
(1) open membership, (2) democratic control, (3) dividends on the basis
of purchase, (4) limited returns on capital, (5) political and religious
neutrality, (6) cash trading, and (7) promotion of member education.
Much of the intent of these operating principles has been incorporated
into the body of law which sanctions American cooperation. The legal
definition of what constitutes a cooperative has gradually evolved through
the passage of laws by the different states. The passage of the Capper-
Volstead Act by Congress in 1922 helped codify this legal concept of agri-
cultural cooperation, though even today the details of laws vary among the
several states. l
It is from the Rochdale and post-Rochdale experience that the basic
concepts of modern cooperative business organization have been developed.
There are three fundamental concepts which help differentiate a cooperative
from other forms of business enterprises. These concepts must be incor-
porated in the organizational and operating pattern of an enterprise in
order for it to qualify as a cooperative.
The first of these distinctive concepts is that the ownership and control
of the enterprise must be by those who utilize its services.2 The control is
exercised by the owners as the patrons of the business rather than by the
O\vners as investors in the business. In no other form of business enterprise
is there a comparable patron-owner relationship. Such a relationship means
1 For a brief review of the continuous changes in the legal provisions, see R. L. Kohls
may collect members' products for sale, grade, package, and perform other
functions. Cooperative livestock commission organizations, producers' milk
associations, and cooperative elevators are examples of the cooperatives act-
ing as marketing cooperatives. The objective of such organizations is to
secure the greatest possible amount for the products of their farmer-owners.
Some associations act solely as commission agents. Some associations act as
bargaining agents and do not actually handle the products. Others will
actually buy the commodity from the farmer for resale.
Marketing cooperatives of various types handle approximately 20 per-
cent of all farm commodities sold. The proportion of commodities which
is marketed cooperatively varies from commodity to commodity, as can be
seen by studying Table 2. Some of the marketing cooperatives are large and
PERCENT PERCENT
PRODUCT OF TOTAL PRODUCT OF TOTAL
SOURCE: Indiana Farm Bureau Co-op Bulletin, Co-ops, \"I'lhat They Are and How
They Work, p. 6. .
MARKETING OF AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS
Feed 42
Petroleum products 22
Fertilizer 10
Field seeds 5
Fann machinery 4
Building materials 2
~leats, groceries, etc.
Other
the United States, Bulletin 55, 1948; H. C. Hensley, Marketing Policies of the California
Prune and Apricot Growers Association, Circular C·l F, 1948; K. B. Gardner and
A. \v. :t\IcKay, The California Fruit Growers Exchange System, Circular C-135, 1950.
The Place and Problems of Agricultural Cooperatives 32 9
gained momentum during \Vorld \Var I and reached its peak in the
postwar depression of the early 1920'S. The number of marketing and
purchasing cooperatives doubled in the ten-year period 1915-1924 (see
Figure 1).
Several factors favored the cxpansion of cooperation in this period.
First, rapidly falling prices in the immcdiate post-\Vorld-\Var-I period led
many cooperatives to be organized to stabilize or raise prices. Aaron
Sapiro, an early proponent of using cooperation to fix prices is credited
Number Membe~
(1000) (Millions)
~--------------------~
4
2
o~~_.~~~~~~~~
o 1915 '20 '25 '30 '35 '40 '45 'SO 1915 '20 '25 '30 '35 ~O ~5 '50
NUMBER OF ASSOCIATIONS MEMBERSHIP
*data unavailable
o 5 10 15 20 25 30
Percent of Total Business
FIG U R E 2. Regional distribution of total business done by
marketing and purchasing associations, 1949-
1950. (Source: USDA, Farm Credit Adminis-
tration.)
o 510 15 20 25 30
Percent of Total Business
FIG U R E 3. Distribution of total business done by market-
ing and purchasing associations by commodities,
1949-195°. (Source: USDA, Farm Credit Ad-
ministration.)
:. Reduce the price or improve the quality of the purchases of its members,
and/or
3. Render new or improved service or give more equitable treatment to its
members.
foremost importance. One -study asked the farmers what they considered
to be the main advantage of cooperatives. Sixty-three percent of the mem-
bers answered lower costs, high returns, and refunds. s
It is not enough to do a job as well as it was done by other agencies.
The cooperative must do it better. A good cooperative should be the pace-
setter for the industry with which it is associated. Only under these cir-
cumstances is the creation of an additional market agency justified.
There are things which even a successful cooperative cannot do for its
members. A clear understanding of these limitations is necessary for suc-
cessful operation. The cooperative should recognize that it cannot "set"
prices unless it has monopolistic control of the supply.9 This means that it
cannot "guarantee cost of production" to its members. Cooperative asso-
ciations cannot eliminate the marketing functions performed by other
middlemen. Neither can they successfully, for any period of time, coerce
their members against their will into trading with the association. Coopera-
tives are circumscribed by the same set of economic restrictions as any
other form of business organization. As has been emphasized before, their
success depends not upon their uniqueness, but rather upon their business
ability to operate profitably and satisfy their patron-owners.
monopolistically by controlling production was the Burley Tobacco Society in the early
1900'S. Physical force in the form of "Night Riders" was used to coerce growers into
reducing production. \Vithin a short time, however, the attraction of higher prices soon
caused the control scheme to fail. See E. F. Dummeier and R. B. Heflebower, Economics
with Application to Agriculture, :md ed. (New York, McGraw-Hill, 1940), pp. 264-:66.
The Place and Problems of Agricultural Cooperatives 335
1. Can an adequate volume be secured and maintained? The economies
of large-scale operation are just as important to cooperatives as to
private corporations.
2. Can adequate and reasonable financing be secured? To build an efficient
plant takes capital-to build less than an efficient plant invites failure.
3. Is efficient management available and will the association pay its
price? In management, as in other things, high quality demands a high
price. Successful cooperatives need as high a level of managerial ability
as other businesses.
4. Is the membership prepared to meet competitive trouble? Especially
in the initial stages, competitive conditions usually get worse rather than
better. A new cooperative can usually expect that the rest of the business
community will unite against it during the early period of its existence.
The reasons why cooperatives fail point up the importance of these
factors. One study of failure problems listed difficulties in the field of man-
agement and membership relations as accounting for nearly two-fifths of
the failures. Insufficient business volume and financing troubles accounted
for another one-fifth of the failures! 10 In all likelihood, those cooperatives
which failed because of "membership difficulties" really were having mem-
bership troubles because the association was not operating profitably or
because the membership was not prepared to face the facts of business life.
the memberships into districts or units which elect delegates who elect
board members. In many instances, the one-man, one-vote idea has been set
aside in favor of cumulative voting on the basis of business volume. Once
a director is selected, the tendency is for him to serve until he resigns or
dies. One study found a direct relationship between the age of the director
and the length of years of service in his post. Only 13 percent of the direc-
tors of 174 cooperatives were under forty years of age. Nearly 90 percent
of the directors and managers who were contacted admitted that they could
influence the election of new directors.ll
Growth in size and economic power also has made further expansion
of existing cooperatives easier. New ventures do not have to be scrutinized
as carefully to ascertain whether the cooperative effort is needed. Accumu-
lation of large financial reserves makes it possible for associations to carry
on unneeded ventures for long periods of time. This situation may not be
compatible with the goal of increased efficiency of the marketing machinery.
The question of how far the cooperative should expand its operations
needs close study. Eventually, the question of the relationship of farm and
consumer cooperatives must be faced. On the surface at least the aims of
these two kinds of cooperatives are quite different. The consumer coopera-
tive strives to obtain goods at lowest cost; the farmers' marketing coopera-
tive aims to sell its products for as much as possible.
Financing
As stated previously, cooperatives require the same amount of capital
as noncooperatives in performing similar functions. But with limitations
placed on voting rights, share transferability, and the returns paid on
invested capital, cooperatives cannot utilize the noncooperative method
of selling additional shares to the investing public in order to secure addi-
tional funds.
Vlhen cooperative enterprises were relatively simple, only limited
amounts of capital were needed. However, the desire of cooperatives to
expand has focused attention on the techniques of securing growth capita1.
In general, cooperatives have relied on members to provide much of the
financing needed, although other sources also have been used occa-
sionally.
Membership fees are the source of capital in some cooperatives. Non-
stock cooperatives of this kind are called membership cooperatives and do
not have stock outstanding. In addition to membership fees, some coopera-
11 o. R. Ray, Selection and Responsibilities of Indiana Coopcratire Directors, un-
published 1\I.S. thesis, Purdue Unh·crsity, 1953.
The Place and Problems of Agricultural Cooperatives 337
tives also use other methods such as selling certificates of indebtedness as
a means of financing operations. Such certificates are a method of borrow-
II ing money from members and othersP
In the early years, earnings were returned to patrons in the form of
I'
cash refunds. l'vIany cooperatives have abandoned this in the process of
!
growth. Savings are now often returned in the form of stock refunds instead
of cash. This procedure permits the retention of earnings above cost within
the association itself to use as it sees fit.
The stock refund plan has the advantage of spreading the financial
burden. Under this plan each patron of the cooperative becomes a part
I:
owner upon receipt of his stock. Since the refund is based on the amount
of business done with a cooperative, ownership is divided in direct propor-
tion to the use each patron makes of the store or business. The methods
under which a member may withdraw his investment from a cooperative
will vary from one association to another. Generally, in case a member
ceases to be a farmer or moves out of the trade area, his investment is
returned. If a member dies, his investment is usually returned to the estate.
Usually the member also may sell his stock to any buyer subject to
approval of the cooperative directors or hold his stock until it is redeemed
by the cooperative. Some cooperatives have a fixed time for redeeming
stock; others do not. If the cooperative has a policy of redeeming its stock
after a fixed time, this is generally referred to as a revolving fund.
Though a continuous stock refund program is a relatively easy and
cheap method of capital accumulation from the standpoint of the man-
agement, there is reason to believe that membership relations start to
deteriorate under it. Such a policy also may encourage the management
to follow a vigorous competitive price policy so that greater savings can
be accumulated for further growth.
The sale of additional common or preferred stock provides capital for
some cooperatives. The market for this stock will be limited mainly to
cooperative members. Common stock has voting rights, usually one vote
per member, but no guaranteed dividend. Nonmembers may hold common
stock but they may not vote. Most cooperatives also sell preferred stock
and sometimes bonds. These carry a fixed dividend or interest rate and
will attract investors other than cooperative members. Preferred stock can
be cumulative or noncumulative but usually carries no voting rights.
In practice, cooperatives secure capital by a combination of these
methods. Part of the problem is that of adequate financing. Of great im-
12 For a more complete discussion of this and other techniques see Bakken and
portance, however, is a financing plan which wi11 not destroy the essential1y
cooperative nature of the enterprise.
Management
Three groups of people are involved in the management of a coopera-
tive-the members, the board of directors, and the hired manager. The
members exercise their control through their elected directors. The directors
have the responsibility of formulating general operating policies and of
obtaining a manager to carry out these policies and report the results to
the members. The manager is charged with the operating responsibility of
the cooperative enterprise. He puts into actual practice the policies bid
down by the board.
Problems in cooperative management are essential1y the same as in
other enterprises. Boards of directors cannot manage the details of a going
business effectively. The manager must be competent and have the con-
fidence of his board. On the other hand, boards cannot surrender their
duties and become puppets of the manager and yet fulfi11 their responsi-
bilities to the membership.
Membership Relations
The nature of cooperative business makes it imperative that good
relationships be maintained between the members and their association.
In many ways this is more important to cooperatives than stockholder rela-
tions are to noncooperative corporations. A stockholder's relationship to
the corporation is that of an investor, and when he is dissatisfied with the
returns he may dispose of his stock through sales to anyone else who will
buy it. i\{embers of a cooperative, however, are at the same time both
owner-investors and owner-users of the business itself. They cannot as
readily divorce themselves from the responsibility of the business by selling
their stockholdings.
Many of the problems of membership relations are fundamentally
by-products of the increased size and complexity of the associations. In
large associations, the feeling upon the part of members of "the co-op"
instead of "my co-op" becomes prevalent. In a great many instances only
a very small minority of the member-owners take an active interest in the
problems and management of their association.
A good member is an informed member. Farmers who support co-
operatives are those who know what cooperatives have done and what they
can and cannot do. 13 The really successful cooperatives rank this task of
13 J. K. Stem and A. F. Dam, Farmer's Support of Cooperatives, Pennsrlvania
Bulletin, 1948. .. .
The Place and Problems of Agricultural Cooperatives 339
keeping an informed and participating membership high on their list of
problems. 14
Relations with the General Public
In the early years, with few exceptions, the general public was disposed
favorably toward cooperation. This attitude took concrete form in the
passage of legislation favorable to cooperatives by both the state and federal
governments. The Capper-Volstead Act, while not exempting cooperatives
from antitrust prosecution, for all practical purposes made prosecution
improbable. The federal government provided public funds for the Farm
Credit Administration to aid cooperation with research and other services.
It has actively participated in the formation of some cooperatives. In the
legislation which provided for marketing agreements and orders, we have
already seen that cooperatives received the permission to wield large de-
grees of monopoly power.
In most cases aid and public approval was extended to cooperatives
under the assumption that a strong cooperative business helped maintain
effective competition. Currently, the public appears to be in a state of in-
decision concerning cooperatives. Some of this has come about through
the agitation over the income tax exemption privileges granted cooperatives.
Under strict legal interpretation, cooperatives as a business entity do
not have income. They are, by definition, businesses which operate at cost.
The eamings above cost belong to the individual member-owners and not
to the association. Patronage refunds in the legal sense, as we have already
noted, are either an adjustment for original underpayment in the case of
marketing cooperatives or an adjustment for original overcharge in the
case of a purchasing or service cooperative. As long as these earnings were
returned to members in the form of cash patronage refunds there was little
complaint. However, as has been mentioned previously, cooperatives in-
creasingly tended to make refunds in the form of stock or ownership cer-
tificates and thereby retained these earnings in the association as growth
capital. Thus, many cooperatives have accumulated large reserves tax-free,
while their noncooperative competitors paid income taxes on their accumu-
lations. This has led to the charge of unfair discrimination. No doubt,
cooperatives must critically examine this whole area if they are to maintain
their high standing in the public eye. 15
14 For a,1 appraisal of the methods of member education see O. R. LeBeau and J. H.
SELECTED REFERENCES
Erdman, A. E., "Trends in Cooperative Expansion, 1900-1950," Journal of
Farm Economics, November Proceedings, 1950.
Knapp, J. G., E. A. Stol,dyk.-Architect of Cooperation (\Vashington, D. C.,
American Institute of Cooperation, 1953)'
Packcl, 1., The Law of the Organization and Operation of Cooperatives, :md cd.
(Albany, New York, Bender, 1947).
Pcrregaux, E. A., "The Future of Farm Cooperatives in the United States,"
Journal of Farm Economics, February Proceedings, 1947.
Nourse, E. G., The Legal Status of Agricultural Cooperation (New York, Mac-
millan, 1929). .
Robotka, F., "A Theory of Cooperation," Journal of Farm Economics, Febru-
ary Proceedings, 1947.
CHAPTER TWENTY-TWO
1"lany readers, when they arrive at this chapter, will start humming the
tune, "Anything you can do, I can do better." For some it means that
anything done by government can be done better by private business. For
others it means that government can do most things better. The more
accurate appraisal lies somewhere between the two extremes. The l1istory
of our government participation in marketing has been similar to a
pendulum-sometimes swinging near one extreme, then reversing itself
and swinging to the other side. In most instances, though, the search for
the proper role of government has been motivated by the desire to main-
tain the type of competitive free enterprise system which will maximize
the social, economic, and moral desires of our people.
Throughout this book, reference has been made to this or that law
or agency. It is the purpose of this chapter to organize into some sort of
logical framework the principal relationships of government to the opera-
tion of the marketing machinery. :Most of the. references are to the positions
taken by the federal government. State and local government actions do
have important effects on marketing, but because of their wide variation
onl~' general mention can be made.
In studying this chapter, we should always keep in mind that this
is a highly controversial area. Laws are passed by legislative bodies, inter-
preted by the courts, and carried out and enforced by various administrative
agencies. \\-ith interpretation by the courts through a period of time, the
actual results of many laws may be far different from their original intent.
In order to understand the full effect of governmental actions, one should
).p
MARKETING OF AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS
study both the original statutes and the interpretations which have evolved
through the many court cases. Obviously such detail is beyond the scope
of this chapter.
AREAS OF REGULATION
The classification scheme which is used here is, of course, not the only
one possible. To develop a set of pigeon-holes which will perfectly catalog
governmental relationships to the marketing machinery is impossible.1
The classification offered here is a broad one. For many observers, govern-
ment relationships to agricultural marketing consist of that group of laws
dealing directly with agricultural products and those handling them. This
is too narrow a view. More and more people interested in agricultural
marketing will have to concern themselves with broader aspects if they
wish to come to grips with some of the more fundamental issues. The
classification which we will use for discussion is as follows:
1 Others have developed classification schemes which are possibly equally helpful.
See, for example: F. E. Clark and C. P. Clark, Principles of i\larketing, 3rd ed. (New
York, :t-.Iacmillan, 1947), chs. 25 and 26; E. A. Duddy and D. A. Revzan, Marketing,
1St cd. (New York, McGraw·Hill, 1947), ch. 28; F. L. Thomsen, Agricultural Market·
ing (New York, J\1cGraw·Hill, 1951), ch. n; R. S. Vaile, E. T. Grether, and R. Cox,
Marketing in the American Economy (New York, Ronald Press, 195 2 ), ch. 34.
Government and Agricultural Marketing 343
became the cornerstone of federal antimonopoly policy. It stated that
"every contract, combination in the form of trust or otherwise, or con-
spiracy in restraint of trade or commerce among the several states, or with
foreign nations is hereby declared to be illegal."
It was not enough, however, simply to declare actions illegal. The
subsequent history of legislation in this area has been largely to determine
what are "undesirable" or "unfair" methods of competition. Both the
Clayton Act (1914) and the Federal Trade Commission Act (1914)
started to spell out how firms should and should not compete in order to
maintain competition. In 1936, the Robinson-Patman Act attempted to
establish rules against price discrimination. Equal treatment must be given
to all buyers unless the discounts can be shown to be derived from econ-
omies in manufacture, sale, or delivery. The intent of this latter law was
to prevent large concerns from using their market power to secure unfair
price advantage over their competitors.
Vlith the development of large-scale retailing, the cry arose to protect
the small retailer. IVIany states passed so-called "fair trade acts" which
permitted manufacturers to control the retail selling prices of their prod-
ucts. In this way the large retailer was not permitted to undersell the
smaller retailer if he wished to continue handling the manufacturer's
products. These state regulations were made legal in interstate commerce
b\' the Tydings-:l\1i11er Act (1937). This urge to protect the smaIl operator
aiso has resulted in the regulation of selling margins for many products.
:"lany states prohibit the selling of products below "cost" or cost plus a
stated margin.
The present status of such resale price maintenance laws is not certain.
In 1951, the court held that resale maintenance as then practiced was
illega1. Movement was quickly underway in Congress to repair the damage.
The ivlcGuire Act (1952) attempted to restore the legality of resale price
maintenance. It was a touch of irony that the r.IcGuire Act put the en-
forcement of price maintenance in the hands of the Federal Trade Com-
mission which has been a vigorous opponent of the practice.
i, \Vhen one studies the trends in interpretation of the regulations in
I: this area of maintaining and policing competition, it becomes obvious that
I, there is considerable confusion as to what is desired. !vlonopoly is illegal.
II
I, But a business does not run around with a sign on it saying, "I am a
I' ~Ionopoly"! Both the Robinson-Patman and the resale price maintenance
I acts have protected the "litt1e fe1low" as a way of maintaining competition.
i:i' The resale price maintenance laws seem to take the additional position
~]:1t numbers of business establishments are the key to desired competition .
'I
• I
i
!I·,
; ;
i
:, i
f j
3-H ~I ARK E TIN G 0 FAG RIC U L T U R ,\ L PRO Due T S
Falling within this general classification arc many of the laws and
regulations that have been mentioned in various other chapters. Laws to
facilitate trade have attempted to create uniformity and reduce possibilities
of fraud.
The Commodity Exchange Act provides the elimination of question-
able practices and supervision of those dealing on futures exchanges (1922,
amcnded 1936). The Packers and Stockyards Act (1921) sets up the
supervisory machincry to control marketing practices and charges on ter-
minallivestock markets. The United States \Varehouse Act (1916) pro-
vides for the licensing and supervision of warehouses and their operations.
The produce Agency Act (1927) attacks fraudulent practices of commis-
sion agents and brokers. The Perishable Agricultural Commodities Act
(193 0 ) proVIdes for the licensing of commission men, dealers, and brokers
handling fresh fruits and vegetables. All of these laws have attempted to
establish standards of practice and operation of markets and men operating
on these markets.
There have been many laws passed affecting the product and its
handling. Laws regulating weights and measures of containers have aimed
for uniformity in this important area. There have also been a series of acts
which established the authority of the United States Department of Agri-
culture to study and promulgate standards and grades for agricultural
commodities.
Legislation has established the market news service and the various
grading and inspection services. Another series of laws have sanctioned the
collection and dissemination of statistics of various commodities and the
agricultural census. 3
Ivluch federal legislation can affect only those commodities which
enter into interstate commerce. Therefore, in most of these fields states
have evolved counterpart legislation to cover trading within the several
states.
can make informcd dccisions and to protcct the consnmer from products
and practices which might harm him.
The principal regulations in this area were initiated by the Federal
Food and Drug Act (1906, expanded 1938) along with the related laws
of the states. Generally, the purpose of this law is to prevent shipments
of adulterated or misbranded foods, drugs, and cosmetics. The adminis.
trator of the Act also has the power to establish minimum quality and
fill of container for most packaged goods. The law provides for labeling
of contents. The use of food preservatives, artificial coloring, and so on are
under the administrator's jurisdiction.
The \Vheeler-Lea Act (1935) sets up a code of ethics for advertising.
It makes false and deceptive advertising an unfair method of competition
and thereby illegal. The ?\cleat Inspection Act (19°7) authorizes inspection
of animals, meats, and packing establishments to assure that products will
be fit for human food. Also, individual state and local governmental units
have set up required health standards for milk and milk processing and
for various slaughtering and food processing facilities.
To a great extent it is because of these various laws that the consumer
can depend upon the weight, volume, and content labels of the food he
buys. He can learn the fiber content of his clothes. He can have some
assurances that in this age of new chemicals, someone is watching out for
his health and well-being.
The dividing line between protector and dictator is a fine one. The
intent of these laws has been to protect the consumer from fraud and
danger which he reasonably could not detect for himself and to give him
knowledge npon which to make wise decisions. There is always the danger
that such regulations may be administered in such a way as to actually
make the choice for the consumers. Such interpretation may stifle change
and initiative if industry must serve the administrator instead of the con-
sumer. It should not be the role of these regulations to decide what is best.
That decision should always be left to the consumer himself. Regulations
should provide the basis for informed consumer action. Beyond this point
the consumer should go the road alone.
ever, with the advent of two major wars and a drastic depression within
the short span of thirty years, actions have been taken to directly establish
prices of individual commodities. .
?vfuch of the agricultural price and income legislation already has
been discussed in Chapter 9. It should merely be reviewed here that with
the establishment of the Federal Farm Board in 1929, a long succession
of laws has firmly established the federal government as an active partici-
pant in determining farm prices. In addition to such direct farm price
regulations, provisions have been made to reduce the price of food to
certain groups of people. The Food Stamp Program and the passing of the
National School Lunch Act (1946) are illustrative of such developments.
Of equal importance has been the acceptance of the validity of the
place of government in controlling prices throughout the ,vhole economy.
Legislation established the Office of Price Administration (OPA) during
World \Var II and the Office of Price Stabilization (OPS) during the
Korean \Var. Under these agencies, prices of commodities and services at
all levels in the marketing system were controlled.
The impact of such regulations upon marketing is obvious. \Vith the
power to regulate margins and prices, the government in effect assumed
the power to regulate the operation of all phases of the marketing structure.
It was in a position to favor one type of market or product over another.
Using its powers, it effected such marketing changes as every-other-day
delivery of milk, the reduction of the kinds and types of packaging; the
expansion of federal meat grading, and so forth. Agricultural price regula-
tions also affected marketing channels used, places of storage, and other
details of the marketing process.
:,;;.'[on \Vatkins, Monopoly and Free Enterprise (New York, Twentieth Century Fund,
195 1), ell. Lt.
MARKETING OF AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS
The original intent was to give to the innovator the right of monopoly
exploitation for seventeen years, after which the innovation was to become
available to the public for general use. Such incentive for gain has no doubt
fostered development. But as with other regulations, abuse is possible.
l1uough legal manipulations, protection can be extended well beyond the
statutory seventeen years. There is record of one inventor successfully
maintaining his exclusive rights for fifty-three years. 5 There is also evidence
that patent and copyright privileges are being used today to prevent some-
one else from working in given fields and making discoveries which might
destroy the current business power of the involved firms. Such actions, of
course, do not encourage progress but retard it. \Vith increasing food
processing and more synthetic products, patent and copyright provisions
are of growing importance in the marketing of farm products. The chal-
lenge is how to furnish incentive for the continuing parade of new and
better things and methods without, at the same time, preventing the active
search for improvement by anyone in any area of endeavor.
Another very important group of laws is that providing for public
support of education and research. G In 1862, Congress established the
Department of Agriculture. The Ivlorrill Land-Grant College Act (1862)
provided the basis for our extensive system of government-supported higher
education. This was followed by the Hatch Act (1887), which provided
for the establishment of agricultural experiment stations in conjunction
with the land-grant colleges.
In 1914, the Smith-Lever Act broadened the educational system in
agriculture by establishing the agricultural extension system. Now, through
a widespread system of county agents and various types of trained special-
ists, the findings of the experiment stations are quickly brought to the
farmers' attention. This Act was followed in a few years by the Smith-
Hughes Act whicl1 provided federal support for teaching vocational agri-
culture in the public schools. In 1953 there were over 10,500 vocational
agricultural teachers and over 5,250 county agents at work in the United
States. Our agricultur;}l research-educational team today is the envy of the
world.
This educational and research structure has been augmented by a long
series of laws making monies available for research in specific areas. Early
work was aimed largely at farm production problems. However, the Re-
search and Marketing Act of 1946 laid the groundwork for a broad research
5 Stocking and Watkins. op. cit., p. 458.
6 An excellent report, "Organization of Agricultural Research in the United States,
Questions and Answers," was issued as a ~limeograph by the USD1\, Agricultural Re·
search Administration, July, 1950.
----
I
I
Government and Agricultural Marketing 349
Federal appropriations for agricultural research during the fiscal year 1950
approximated $59 million of which $-1-7 million was allotted to USDA agencies
and $12 million was made a\-ailablc to state agricultural experiment stations as
federal grant funds. The states themselves provided more than $40 million
which averaged about $3' 50 for each $1.00 received from federal grants.
tion methods, improved methods of insect and disease control, and so on.
The Utilization Division is- active in experimentation which may lead to
!lew products and new uses for agricultural commodities. \Ve now should
realize that production cannot be realistically separated from marketing, so
all of these activities can have a real influence on marketing.
The Agricultural Research Service also has certain regulatory re-
sponsibilities. The Animal Quarantine Act, the twenty-eight-hour transpor-
tation law for livestock, the meat and poultry inspection work, and the
insect control and eradic1tion work all come nnder its supervision. l\llan1'
of these activities are of direct concern to marketing agencies.
SELECTED REFERENCES
Brown, 'V. F., "The Federal Trade Commission and False Advertising" (2
parts) , Journal of Marheting, July and October, 1947.
Edwards, C. D., "Trends in Enforcement of Antimonopoly Laws," Journal of
Marketing, April, 1950.
- - - , Maintaining Competition (New York, McCraw-Hill, 1949)'
Cans, J. £vI., and L. O. ,"\Tolcott, Public Administration and the United States
Department of Agriculture (Chicago, Public Administration Service, 1940).
Lee, 1\1. 'V., "The A-and-P Case," Journal of Marketing, October, 1949.
Steiner, C. A., Government's Role in Economic Life (New York, :tvlcCraw-Hill,
1953)·
CHAPTER TWENTY-THREE
Since thc farmer sells raw materials which must often be processed further
into food products, a study of marketing must consider the part which
these food processors play in the over-all marketing processes. 1 TIle defini-
tion of marketing which we developed in Chapter 1 excluded the crea-
tion of form utility. The manufacturing processes of food processors are
concerned with the addition of value which comes from the changing of
form. \Vheat is milled into flour. Livestock is converted into meat. Fresh
\'cgctables are processed into the canned product. However, as we men-
tioned in the discussion of marketing institutions in Chapter 2, these
activities are only part of the activities of food processors. They also perform
to a variable extent some of the marketing functions. They are not a passive
element in the marketing channel. They buy and sell products. They may
have \'ertically integrated themselves until they act institutionally in
wholes;lling capacities. And because they are often the largest and best
informed business aggregate in the marketing channel, they play an im-
portant role in the all-important activities of pricing. \Ve have already
studied some of thesc processor activities in our commodity discussions.
The purpose of this chapter is to bring together these various industries
so that we can obtain a better picture of the over-all structure of food
processing.
353
354 MARKETING OF AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS
NUMBER OF
NUMBER PRODUCTION VALUE ADDED
OF WORKERS BY
PLANTS (THOUSANDS) MANUFACTURE
MILLION PERCENT
DOLLARS OF TOTAL
z
az
p
~T~U\qo-~
~rlNOr-t'\ON
o
;:;<
--
o
"''"I"!"
00 00
355
MARKETING OF AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS
PERCENT OF TOTAL
Food industry:
Number of establishments 24 76 49 27 20 4
Value added 61 39 89 4 5 2
All U. S. industry:
Number of establishments 15 85 49 29 21
Value added 59 41 92- 3 5
* Operation of more than one manufacturing unit from a central administrative
office.
t Includes cooperatives, receiverships and trustees, and public ownership_
; Less than 1 percent.
I
I
Food Processing Industries
359
TABLE 5· Relative Importance of Different-Sized Firms in
Selected Food Processing Industries, 1947
NUMBER OF EMPLOYEES
1,000
INDUSTRY 1-9 10-49 50- 2 49 250-999 AND OVER
PERCENT OF TOTAL
All industry:
Number of firms 49 33 14
Value added 3
3 12 25 27
All food industries: 33
Number of firms 50 36 12 2
Value added 5 18 26
"
36 15
Grain:
Flour milling
Number of firms 58 25 15 2
Value added 3 15 60 22
Cereal manufacturing
Number of firms 42 25 19
Value added 9 5
Baking (selling to grocers)
" 3 11 42 44
Number of firms 44 34 20 2
Value added 3 17 58 22
Biscuits, crackers, pretzels '----v------'
Number of firms 30 29 24 17
Value added 3 18
Meat: 78
l\leat packing
Number of firms 44 35 I; 2
Value added 4
3 10 19 21
Poultry dressing 47
Number of firms 29 49 21 1
Value added 4 29 20
47
Dairy:
Butter
Number of firms 68 27 5
Value added 22 43 35
Natural cheese
Number of firms 82 16 2
Value added 44 39 17
Concentrated milk
Number of firms 27 46 27
Value added 4 28 68
Fruits and vegetables:
Canning and preserving
Number of firms 24 48 24
Value added 1 14
4 "
38 31 16
NU)'!nER OF E)'[PLOYEES
IXDUSTRY HIGH MOXTII LOW).IO:-;TH
Selling Operations
As in procurement, a processor is faced with the necessity of choosing
between alternative methods of selling the finished product. He may either
utilize the existing independent wholesale channels or set up his own
sales organization to distribute his product directly to retailers.
It is probably true that food processors have been more interested in
securing direct control over the selling phase of their operations than the
buying phase. But here again, industries vary in the direction they have
taken.
The meat packing industry, for example, has largely become its own
wholesaler. It is h'lI1dling a perishable commodity which has wide fluctua-
tions in volume over a short period. In order to keep such a product mov-
ing effectively, packers consider it imperative that they have control of
the distributive channel through to the retailer. Independent meat whole-
salers handle a relatively small volume.
The milling industry offers a good illustration of the wayan industry
adapts itself to changing conditions. Originally flour millers shipped their
flour on consignment to commission men in the consuming areas. These
commission men sold and delivered the flour to retail stores who were
their principal customers. However, abuse by some unscrupulous commis-
sion men gave rise to flour brokers. The broker acted as the sales agent of
the miller, but the miller himself kept control of the transportation and
delivery arrangements. Then came the widespread movement away from
Food Processing Industries 363
home baking and the rise of large commercial bakeries. Bakers, not retail
stores, became the principal flour consumers. This development of rela-
tively large volume customers caused the miller again to revamp his selling
methods. Now large millers, like the packers, set up their Own wholesaling
organization with direct salesmen and strategically located branch houses
to facilitate delivery.
Though the processing units for butter and cheese are small many
have grown into large organizations with their own wholesaling setdp . Th~
large-scale canners have also developed their own wholesaling organization
to sell directly to retailers. However, the small independent canner cannot
afford his own selling organization. He must depend upon independent
brokers and commission men to sell his products.
FOOD WHOLESALING
The food wholesaler operates between the food processor and the
retailer. The up-to·date food retailer stocks relatively small amounts of
literally hundreds of widely different items. Retailers, who are primarily
interested in the problems which arise from servicing their customers,
could not possibly search out and deal with the producer and processor
sources of all his products. And on the other hand, processors could not
in mo~t circumstances profitably service the small unit needs of the retailer.
To assemble efficiently these various products in reasonable quantities
from the rebtively specialized processors and to sell them in small quantities
is the job of the food wholesaler. As we can see in the following diagram,
1 The source of the statistical data used in this chapter has been the United States
the merchant wholesaler who actually buys and brings the needed products
together is a focal point in the distribution scene.
Too, as we mentioned in the last chapter, many processors perform
the functions of a wholesaler for themselves. Through sales offices and
branch warehouses, they can contact and service retailers directly. On the
other hand, many processors who do not have an adequate line or volume
(G~:;:~;;'t~:~~;I;'~~:r11 Md 011""
function, limited function)
/ ~
Retailer Food Stores)' Restaurants, Institutions
~~
Consumers
of products may utilize food brokers and commission men to act as their
salesman. As in the case of the other brokers and commission men which
we have already studied, this group of middlemen does not take ownership
of the products. It merely searches out potential sales outlets for processors
and keeps the processor informed of trade conditions and needs for a fee.
Types of Wholesalers
Merchant wholesalers may be classified on the basis of the functions
they perform. The service or full-function wholesaler performs all of the
various marketing functions to some degree. He is an expert in the buying
of goods, and the retailer often looks to him for advice on what to stock
and how to merchandise individual items to the best advantage. He extends
a line of credit and delivers to his retailers. Since he must be able to
furnish retailers with small quantities at frequent intervals, he stores large
amounts of food in the form of inventory stocks.
In contrast, the limited-function wholesaler does not perform this
complete array of services. He may be a cash-and-carry merchant, extending
no credit or giving no delivery. He may set up order-size requirements for
Wholesaling and Retailing of Food 367
his customers, thus requiring them to order larger amounts less frequently.
Many of the manufacturers' sales branches are in this classification of the
limited-function wholesalers.
In addition to this functional basis, wholesalers may be classified as
to the kind of goods which they handle. The general-line grocery whole-
saler will stock a wide variety of goods so that a retailer can secure all
of his needs from one wholesaler (with the usual exception of meat). The
1948 Census of Business estimated that the sales of the average general-
line merchant grocery wholesaler were as follows:
saler who operates a warehouse and handles goods, and the broker who i3
only a contact man doing no physical handling. Over 90 percent of the
brokers employ under ten people. In fact, one-fifth of the brokers operate
without any paid employees and another fifth have only onc other person
working for them.
~{crchant wholesalers:
Groceries. meat. confections 11,35';" 7"Z
Dairy and poultry products,
fresh fruits :ind n:gdables 6"Z
i\!anufacturers' sales
br:lIIches anel offices:
Groceries. 111ea t. confections 7.9 6 7
Dairy anel poultry products 955
Agents anel brokers:
Groceries. meat. confections 3,17 1 5.4 87 1.4
Dairy and poultry products.
fresh fruits and vegetables 1.15:; 1.77 8
~IERCII.\NT .\GI:NTS
~!El\CIl.\:\T WIlOI.ES.\I.ER A:\n BROKERS
WIIOl.ES.\LERS E~!pI.On:LS :\0, NO.
SALES \'O!.!J~!E NO. OF A:\:\U,\L Hlln:n OF OF ,\N:\U.\L
PER FIl\~r nH~IS S,\LES PElt FII(~! Fllt:O-!S S.\ u:s FIR:o.!S S.\I.ES
FOOD RETAILING
It will be recalled that retailing accounts for about 40 percent of the
total marketing charges for food (see Chapter 5). It is the most expensive
single stage in the marketing process. Retail food stores are the major
consumer outlets for agricultural products. The only other substantial
consumer outlets for food are restaurants and other large-scale eating
places. It has been cstimated that approximately 16 percent of the total
ci"ilian food supply is marketed through these various commercial eating
places. 3
The rctailing part of the marketing channel has long been ignored
by those interested in the problems of agricultural marketing. This has
been a serious omission. Not only is retailing the most expensive operation,
but the nation's grocers are also tIle farmers' sales representatives to the
final consumer. Efficient marketing of farm products depends to a con-
siderable degree on efficient, progressive, and well-informed retailing.
o Snncy Ill' thc \\'holcsale Grocer's Association reported in \Veekl)' Digest of Food
Distribution'. 0fo\'cmber 3, 195I.
3 Lester C. Sartorius, Eating Places as Marketers of Food Products, USDA, Market-
PERCENT OF PERCENT OF
TYPE OF STORE NU~!BER TOTAL Nu~rBER TOTAL SALES
I
!~
i
::\1 ARK E TIN G 0 FAG RIC U L T U R ALP ROD U C T S
importance of the various· types of retail food stores. By far the most
important type of retail food outlet is the complete grocery store which
also handles meat. 111is type of store makes up nearly one-half of the total
store population and accounts for two-thirds of the total food sales.
Basically, food retailing is organized into relatively small, independent
units. O\'er 90 percent of the total number of food stores are operated as
independent, individual units owned by individual proprietors or partners.
This large group docs ne'lrly two-thirds of the total retail business.
Over half of the stores have no employed help in addition to the
owners (Table 4). Half of the food stores did under $30,000 annual
business in 1948. It takes no mental giant to conclude that the net re-
turns to the owners of this group of stores must be very small indeed.
These are the "?vla and Pa" stores-the retail counterpart of the subsistence
farmer. Though making up a large share of the store population, these
small stores do a relatively small share of the total food business. Stores
in this large group are very often high cost stores. Their volume is too
small to make practical the utilization of much of the cost-saving tech-
nology of modern food merchandising. However, this group often sells
service in addition to food. They are the convenient neighborhood stores,
extending credit, offering delivery, and often staying open nights and
Sundays. Therefore, one must usc considerable caution in directly com-
paring the price of goods sold through these stores with other types of
grocery stores.
At the other extreme is a very small group of stores having a very
large volume, employing many people, and selling over a third of the
38~, 195 2 •
374 MARKETING OF AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS
CHANGES IN THE
WHOLESALE-RETAIL STRUCTURE
The Corporate Chain Store
One cannot study the pattern of food retailing without giving some
attention to the development of chain food stores. The origin of chain
retailing is usually traced back to the establishment of the Great Atlantic
and Pacific Tea Company in 1858. However, it was not until after vVorld
\Var I and during the decade of the 1920'S that real growth occurred.
By 1929, it was estimated that chain stores were doing about 38 percent
of the total business of combination grocery and meat stores. Also, about
this time food chains reached their peak in number of outlets.
Starting in the late thirties and continuing after \Vorld \Var II,
chain organizations consolidated their holdings into fewer, but larger,
stores. In 1948, the Census of Business reported that only 8 percent of the
total food stores were operated as multiple units; the remainder were
independent single units. In 1951, the trade magazine, Progressive Grocer,
estimated that 38 percent of the combination grocery and meat store
business was done by chains. Interestingly enough, this was the same
proportion as reported in 1929.
Originally the chain store organization collected several retail outlets
under one management in order to secure price advantage of large volume
buying from wholesalers and processors. At the retail level they adopted
the policy of cash-and-carry. They aimed for low cost, large volume
operations, and competed with low prices instead of with service.
As time moved on, however, chains have not been satisfied with
horizontal expansion into more retail outlets. They have moved to in-
tegrate vertically. They have become their own wholesalers, often buying
rlirectly from growers in the production areas. They have acquired various
processing facilities, so as to broaden their control over the marketing
channel. Large chains have acquired canning companies, cheese and
butter firms, bakeries, and other miscellaneous food processors. These
firms operate under the brand label and standards set by the chain. Chains
also take large portions of the output of independent processors who meet
the standard and use the brand label of the chain.
PERCENT OF TOTAL
Summing Up
\Ve have now had an introduction to some of the more important concepts
of marketing. \Ve initiated our study with a broad view of the marketing
task. Production is undertaken for consumption purposes. The responsi-
bility of the marketing machinery is to coordinate production and con-
sumption. In doing this, certain marketing functions must be performed.
Some of these, such as storage and transportation, we examined in con-
siderable detail. Pricing, which is the result of the functions of buying
and selling, received our attention. \Ve then turned to specific agricultural
commodities and studied their particular marketing structures and prob-
lems. The place of cooperatives, the role of government, and finally the
businesses engaged in food processing, wholesaling, and retailing received
our attention. Now it is proper to pull some of these many details back
into focus and perspective. \Ve must also point out some of the areas
which have been treated lightly or not at all. For it should be evident now
that the introductory statement made in the first chapter is very true. This
has not been a complete book on agricultural marketing. It can only open
wide the gate to the desire for further exploration in a very complex field.
PROBLEMS OF CHANGE
TIle marketing machinery is a changing one. Solutions which are
adequate today may be woefully inadequate tomorrow. Changes may be
initiated by some change in the production machinery. They may be
initiated by changes in the consumer and his actions. Or they may originate
with new developments in the marketing processes themselves. \Vherever
they initially occur, however, the repercussions will be felt throughout the
entire marketing channel.
\Ve have seen examples of various types of changes. As our country
bas expanded over the years, the relationship of production and con-
sumption areas has changed. This rearrangement has resulted in the rise
of new marketing centers and the decline of old ones. It has left excess
processing capacity for some of our industries scattered throughout the
country. Changing production technology has also had its effect. For
example, the increase in the efficiency of egg production per hen reduced
the supply of poultry meat from this source but helped make possible the
rapid expansion of the broiler industry. Increasing specialization in many
of our farm enterprises, such as dairying, has given increasing emphasis
to marketing.
Consumers, too, have changed. With increased urbanization and
smaller families, the demand for smaller purchase units has increased.
The turkey industry has had to recognize this by developing a smalIer-
sized product and by merchandising turkey parts. Retailers have had to
adjust by continually reducing the size of their sales unit. Consumers'
tastes and preferences have also changed. \Ve have seen the ramifications
of one of the demand shifts-the decreasing desire for animal fats-in two
;nstances. One was the problem created by the consumers' desire for
leaner pork. This raised issues of adequate grading standards and buying
MARKETING OF AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS
practice~ for hogs. Another was in the area of milk marketing. Here the
major pricing methods were still basing the value of \vhole milk on the
butterfat content, even though it was evident that butterfat value was a
declining source of milk value.
\Vithin the marketing area proper, we have noted the results of
technological change. Improved transportation and refrigeration have made
long hauling practical. New technology has permittcd improvement in
methods of grading and qnality control. The development of the integrated
retail grocery chain, self-service, and the supermarket has had its repercus-
sion in wholesaling, processing. and even in the buying structures at pro-
ducer leyels.
Such a few examples merely serve to illustrate that changes occur and
always have consequences_ These consequences pose new methods which
always must be evaluated. It is this evaluation process which throws down
the gauntlet to the status quo. Any method of doing a job soon develops
groups of people who have a vested interest in its continuing operation.
Change will often mean a loss of invested capital or even a loss of jobs
for them. The natural reaction of such groups is to fight the change. The
existing situation is often "right" because it is in operation. In such battles
the objective is to win, not necessarily to present an unbiased picture.
From this comes one of the cardinal rules in evaluating a controversial
subject: Ascertain \vho is involved and what they have to gain or lose.
Armed with this knowledge, we will be in a better position to give our
best judgment to the decision at hand.
Decentralization
Perhaps one of the most general changes which has occurred has been
the decentralization of the concentration precess of marketing agricultural
products. Old established central wholesale markets and associated insti-
tutions have declined in importance as buying agencies have increasingly
moved into producing areas. \Ve noted this tendency in livestock, eggs,
dairy products, and fr:lits and vegetables.
Basically much of this change was initiated by a changing transpor-
tation situation which has removed the dependence on the railroads.
\Vith this decentralization have corne other changes and problems. The
system of collection of news from only the large central markets is no
longer adequate. Old established pricing habits are no longer satisfactory.
The regulatory machinery which was established to cover the old centers
must be extended to provide the needed supervision of the newer market-
ing channels. Such circumstances put increasing responsibility on the in-
dividual farmer-seller for selecting the most advantageous outlet.
Integration
Another general development in most marketing channels has been
an increasing degree of vertical integration. Food processors have extended
themselves both backward to producers and forward to retailers. Retail
organizations have integrated under their management wholesaling, proc-
essing, and, in many instances, producing area procurement. Farmers'
cooperatives have also been active in this integration process. Such de-
velopments of large integrated firms often have offered considerable
opportunities to reduce marketing costs. However, integration has also
given us an additional challenge to maintain an effective oompetitive
structure. No longer can the competitive assumption of multitudinous,
small, independent firms be indiscriminately made.
Consumer Education
If the marketing system is to be consumer directed, then how the
consumers behave is of primary importance. Such direction, if it is to be
successful, requires that consumers be informed. It is axiomatic that a
successful democratic form of government depends upon an enlightened
and informed electorate. It is just as true that an effectively competitive
marketing system cannot be built upon the ignorance of consumers. If
quality standards are to serve their purpose, the consumers must be aware
of and accept their meaning. They must be aware that services frequently
are added to products and that these services are not costless.
No one has a right to choose for the consumer, but there is an obliga-
tion to see that he has adequate information upon which to base decisions
and choices. Uninformed consumers are an open invitation to chicanery
and abuse. The agricultural producer who is at the other end of the
marketing channel has a real stake in the field of consumer education.
Increasing Efficiency
Time and time again we have examined ways in which the techno-
logical efficiency is being improved and could be further improved. Ex-
amples were often given of labor saving arrangements, new machinery,
new processes for control of quality, and new methods to cut costs. Cer-
tainly in many areas science and invention are offering many opportunities
to do the job better or even produce a better product.
In many instances it was suggested that costs could be lowered if the
volume of operation of individual firms were increased. It was pointed out
that many grain elevators could reduce their unit costs if they could secure
a larger volume. ~Jany of our livestock and poultry buying agencies are
operating at less than optimum size. Milk routes could be advantageously
consolidated. \Ve have seen how many firms have integrated either hori-
zontally or vertically in their efforts to obtain larger volumes.
Against these possibilities of greater operating efficiencies from in-
creased size has always loomed the question of what would be its effect
on the economic efficiency of marketing. 'Vhat would be its effect on the
consumers' freedom of choice? To obtain lower marketing costs would
not in itself be desirable if, in obtaining them, we fostered conditions
bv which the marketing agencies secured increasing monopoly power. The
~;ld of marketing improvement should be not only more for the marketing
firms, but rather more for all.
I t was as an aid to understanding this issue that we studied aspects
of imperfect competition, government price programs, and government
regulatory laws. The challenge is to develop a sound marketing policy.
Bench Mlrks must be developed for judging the adequacy of competi-
tion. \Ve have seen that large numbers alone are not the key. Large
national giants are not necessarilv less competitive than small isolated local
MARKETING OF AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS
389
39 0 INDEX