0% found this document useful (0 votes)
86 views3 pages

Ef4484 PS3

The document discusses three examples of Bayesian games: 1. An incomplete information game with a Bayesian Nash equilibrium of (B2, A0) and (B2, Y), meaning player 2 chooses Y and player 1's strategy depends on c. 2. A signaling game where players have private types and the Bayesian Nash equilibrium strategies are x1 = 17/7, x2L = 12/7, and x2H = 8/7. 3. An auction game where bidding one's own valuation is a weakly dominant strategy, resulting in a Bayesian Nash equilibrium where b1 = v1 and b2 = v2.

Uploaded by

Ziyan Cao
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
86 views3 pages

Ef4484 PS3

The document discusses three examples of Bayesian games: 1. An incomplete information game with a Bayesian Nash equilibrium of (B2, A0) and (B2, Y), meaning player 2 chooses Y and player 1's strategy depends on c. 2. A signaling game where players have private types and the Bayesian Nash equilibrium strategies are x1 = 17/7, x2L = 12/7, and x2H = 8/7. 3. An auction game where bidding one's own valuation is a weakly dominant strategy, resulting in a Bayesian Nash equilibrium where b1 = v1 and b2 = v2.

Uploaded by

Ziyan Cao
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 3

1.

According to the incomplete information game in the question, the extended and
normal-form representations in the following figure are obtained.

Therefore, the Bayesian Nash equilibrium is (𝐵2 𝐴0 , 𝑌), which means player 2 choose Y,
and when c=2, player 1 choose B, and when c=0, player 1 choose A.
2.

Let t = 2 with probability 1/2 be type L, and t = 3 with probability 1/2 be type H.

𝑢1 = 1/2[2(𝑥1 + 𝑥2 𝐿 + 𝑥1 𝑥2 𝐿 ) − (𝑥1 )2 ] + 1/2[2(𝑥1 + 𝑥2 𝐻 + 𝑥1 𝑥2 𝐻 ) − (𝑥1 )2 ]

= (𝑥1 + 𝑥2 𝐿 + 𝑥1 𝑥2 𝐿 ) + (𝑥1 + 𝑥2 𝐻 + 𝑥1 𝑥2 𝐻 ) − (𝑥1 )2

𝑢2 𝐿 = 2(𝑥1 + 𝑥2 𝐿 + 𝑥1 𝑥2 𝐿 ) − 2(𝑥2 𝐿 )2

𝑢2 𝐻 = 2(𝑥1 + 𝑥2 𝐻 + 𝑥1 𝑥2 𝐻 ) − 3(𝑥2 𝐻 )2
Using derivation, we can obtain:

𝐿 𝐻
𝑥2 𝐿 𝑥2 𝐻
𝐵𝑅1 (𝑥2 , 𝑥2 )=1+ +
2 2
1 + 𝑥1
𝐵𝑅2 𝐿 (𝑥1 ) =
2
1 + 𝑥1
𝐵𝑅2 𝐻 (𝑥1 ) =
3
Substitute 𝐵𝑅2 𝐿 (𝑥1 ) and 𝐵𝑅2 𝐻 (𝑥1 ) into 𝐵𝑅1 (𝑥2 𝐿 , 𝑥2 𝐻 ),

1 + 𝑥1 1 + 𝑥1
𝑥1 = 1 + 2 + 3
2 2
→ 𝑥1 = 17/7

→ 𝑥2 𝐿 = 12/7, 𝑥2 𝐻 = 8/7

Therefore, Bayesian Nash equilibrium: 𝑥1 = 17/7, 𝑥2 𝐿 = 12/7, 𝑥2 𝐻 = 8/7.


3.

Suppose that Player i is valued at vi, and he's trying to decide whether to bid bi = vi or
bid some other amount bi = x. The other player j, want to bid bj.

Assume x > vi,

• bj ≥ x. In this case, Player i will lose the auction whether he bids with x or vi.
• x >bj >vi. In this case, Player i is going to do worse by bidding x than by bidding
vi. If he bids vi, then he loses the auction and gets 0; If he bid x, he's going to win
the auction and pay bj, which is going to give him a negative yield of vi – bj.
• bj<x. In this case, bid vi and bid x are going to have the same payoff for Player i,
because Player i is both going to win the auction, pay bj, and get vi-bj.

So, no matter how Player j bids, Player i will get a higher payoff if he bids at his valuation
vi than if he bids for x. The same thing happens when x ≤ vi.

Therefore, bidding on player’s own valuation is a weakly dominant strategy, and there is
a Bayesian equilibrium in which both players adopt this strategy. This means that the
Bayesian Nash equilibrium of this game: b1 = v1, b2 = v2.

You might also like