ArbitragePricing Set1
ArbitragePricing Set1
Paul Schneider
1 / 41
Introduction
Basic instruments
Forwards
Futures
Options
No-arbitrage in discrete time with discrete states
Discrete-time models
Continuous-time models
Purpose
Construction
Applications
To get there
Review: random variables, probability, statistics
Estimation, calibration
Monte-Carlo simulation
2 / 41
Introduction
Personal
[email protected]
[email protected]
Office hours on demand
Modus
Theory (Paul)
Practice (Marc)
Keep checking icorsi for info and lecture slides
3 / 41
Introduction
Literature
Main textbook:
Stochastic Calculus for Finance I,II, Steven E. Shreve, 2004 Springer
Useful references:
Arbitrage Theory in Continuous Time, Tomas Björk, 1998 Oxford
University Press
Interest Rate Models – Theory and Practice, 2006 Springer
Statistical Inference, George Casella, Roger L. Berger, 2002 Duxbury
Advanced Series
4 / 41
Introduction
Basic Ideas
Instruments
Payoffs
Strategies
No-arbitrage
Discrete and finite state-sapce
Basic principle
Structure that comes with no-arbitrage
Linearity
Convexity
Stochastic processes
Discrete-time
Continuous-time models
Stochastic processes and no-arbitrage
Basic construction
No-arbitrage in continuous-time
Black-Scholes
Affine term structure models
5 / 41
Introduction
1600
1400
1200
1000
800
600
400
200
1990 1994 1998 2002 2006
6 / 41
Introduction
0.5
0.45
0.4
0.35
0.3
0.25
0.2
0.15
0.1
0.05
1990 1994 1998 2002 2006
7 / 41
No Arbitrage
Take a market X := R3 and assume there is one risky asset in the market
with payoff
x = [1, 2, 4] (1)
and a European call option on x with strike K = 2 and payoff
y = (x − K )+ = [0, 0, 2] (2)
H = {z ∈ X : z = αx + βy } (3)
9 / 41
No Arbitrage Portfolio Example
12
10
8
6
4
2
0
4
3.5
3
0 2.5
2
0.5 1.5 β
1 1
α 1.5 0.5
2 0
10 / 41
No Arbitrage Complete Markets
11 / 41
No Arbitrage Law of One Price
2 state 2
1.5
1 state 3
β
0.5
-0.5
-1
-1.5
-1 0 1 2 3 4
α
12 / 41
No Arbitrage Law of One Price
The LOOP says that the price of a portfolio is the sum of the prices
of the constituents
This is a realistic assumption most of the times
13 / 41
No Arbitrage Arbitrage
Arbitrage
Definition 5 (Arbitrage).
A payoff Z ∈ [D] such that (p(Z ) ≤ 0 and Z > 0) or (p(Z ) < 0 and
Z >= 0) is called an arbitrage.
14 / 41
No Arbitrage Arbitrage
hD 0 and hp(D) ≤ 0
p(D) = DM and M 0.
15 / 41
No Arbitrage Arbitrage
1.5
1 p = (p1 , p2 )
0.5
0
β
-0.5
-1
-1.5
-2
-2 -1.5 -1 -0.5 0 0.5 1 1.5 2
α
16 / 41
No Arbitrage Arbitrage
3 state 1
p
2 state 2
1 state 3
0
β
-1
-2
-3
-4
-4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4
α
17 / 41
No Arbitrage Arbitrage
3 state 1
2 state 2
0
β
-1
-2
-3
-4
-4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4
α
18 / 41
No Arbitrage The Pricing Kernel
Example 6.
19 / 41
No Arbitrage The Pricing Kernel
dQ M̂s qs
(s) = =
dP ps ps
Write M̃ := M0 dQ
dP
20 / 41
No Arbitrage Example: Binomial Model
B0 = 1
Bt = 1 + R
S0 = s
(
u with probability pu
St = sZ , Z =
d with probability pd
21 / 41
No Arbitrage Example: Binomial Model
Replicating Portfolio
Consider now a portfolio where you buy x of the bond and y of the
stock, then the value V h of your portfolio with strategy h at time 0
and at time t will be given by
V0h = x + ys
Vth = x(1 + R) + ysZ
22 / 41
No Arbitrage Example: Binomial Model
23 / 41
No Arbitrage Example: Binomial Model
24 / 41
No Arbitrage Pricing Kernels and Measure Changes
p(W ) = M0
25 / 41
No Arbitrage Pricing Kernels and Measure Changes
26 / 41
No Arbitrage Widely Used Pricing Measures
Forward Measure
The probability measure associated with the zero bond price pt,T as
numeraire is called the QT forward measure
Writing the asset pricing equation (7) with the zero bond numeraire
Xt QT XT
= Et = EQ T
t [XT ] (8)
pt,T pT ,T
In this expectation we have just XT – no dependence problems
Exercise 2.1.
Show that Q = QT if and only if interest rates are deterministic.
Change of Measure
The process RT
e − t ru du dQT
h RT i =:
Q
Et e − t ru du dQ
is a Q martingale
28 / 41
No Arbitrage Basic Instruments
Forward Price
29 / 41
No Arbitrage Basic Instruments
Forward Price II
30 / 41
No Arbitrage Basic Instruments
∂ log pt,T
ft,T ≡ lim F (t, T , S) = − (13)
S→T ∂T
32 / 41
Options
Definition 11.
A European option on an underlying S pays at maturity T
(ST − K )+ call option
(K − ST )+ put option.
Denote the price at time t ≤ T of a European call option with strike price
K by Ct,T (K ), that of a European put option by Pt,T (K ).
33 / 41
Options
100
long call
short put
50
Payoff
-50
-100
0 50 100 150 200
S
34 / 41
Options
(S − K )+ = (K − S)+ − K + S (14)
Exercise 3.1.
Prove Proposition 3.1 by using the FTAP under the forward measure
35 / 41
Options
Breeden Litzenberger
Exercise 3.2.
Prove Proposition 3.2 and derive an expression in terms of put prices.
Hint: Start from
Z ∞
QT +
Ct,T (K ) = pt,T Et (ST − K ) = pt,T (s − K )qt,T (s) ds.
K
36 / 41
Options
Convexity of Options
Suppose the market is arbitrage-free. Then European call and put options
are convex in strike.
Exercise 3.3.
Prove Proposition 3.3. Hint: Reuse the derivatives you have taken in
Exercise 3.2.
The convexity property of option prices sets arbitrage bounds for the
relation between puts and call options. For example
37 / 41
Options
Convexity II
Pt,T (K1 )
Pt,T (K )
Pt,T (K0 )
The picture shows the admissible region (in blue) that is determined
by Pt,T (0) = 0, Pt,T (K0 ) and Pt,T (K1 ).
Exercise 3.4.
Show that
0
Pt,T (K ) ≥ Pt,T (K0 ) + Pt,T (K0 )(K − K0 ) (17)
38 / 41
Options
39 / 41
Options
Exercise 3.6.
Show that for Φ twice differentiable almost everywhere
Hint: Use put-call parity Eq. (14) and start from first-order Lagrange
remainder
Exercise 3.7.
Prove Proposition 3.4 using Exercises 3.5 and 3.6. 40 / 41
Options
Exercises
Exercise 3.8 (Simply-Compounded Forward Rates).
Use the FTAP (7) to show that the simply compounded forward rate
F (t, T , S) is under no-arbitrage given by
pt,T
= 1 + (S − T )F (t, T , S)
pt,S