Good Governance and Institutional Quality of Public Sector: Theoretical and Empirical Implications
Good Governance and Institutional Quality of Public Sector: Theoretical and Empirical Implications
Abstract:
Purpose: The main aim of this article is to conduct an econometric analysis and to examine
relations between institutional factors pertaining to the quality of governance and the level of
GDP per capita in 28 member states of the European Union.
Design/Methodology/Approach: The analysis of public governance and good governance
concepts is based on critical analysis of the recent literature. Institutional quality of the public
sector is analyzed as a part of New Institutional Economics theory. This allows to indicate the
institutional dimensions of the quality of public sector. In the empirical part, focus was given
to measuring governance and examining relations between institutional factors pertaining to
the quality of public governance and the level of GDP per capita in 28 member states of the
European Union. To this end, World Bank data were used, and six indicators proposed by this
institution were assumed as synthetic measures of governance quality (The Worldwide
Governance Indicators – WGI).
Findings: The conducted analyses resulted in positively verifying the model of relations
between dimensions of governance quality and the pace of economic growth in the EU-28.
Based on correlation studies, out of the six analyzed dimensions of governance quality i.e.
voice and accountability, political stability, government effectiveness, regulatory quality, rule
of law and control of corruption, only political stability transpired not to be correlated to the
level of GDP per capita in the studied economies.
Practical Implications: The results are especially important for policy makers to understand
the importance and the role of good governance. As for society, research results can increase
awareness in assessing the quality of governance in each country.
Originality/Value: The scientific results fill the gap in the research area of institutional quality
of the public sector, and also show the significant relationship between the quality of
governance and the economic outcomes (economic growth).
Keywords: Public sector, new institutional economics, public governance, good governance.
1
Full Professor, University of Bialystok, Faculty of Economics and Finance, Poland,
e-mail: [email protected]
2
Associate Professor, University of Bialystok, Faculty of Economics and Finance, Poland,
e-mail: [email protected]
3
PhD, University of Bialystok, Faculty of Economics and Management, Poland,
e-mail: [email protected]
Good Governance and Institutional Quality of Public Sector:
Theoretical and Empirical Implications
530
1. Introduction
The authors of this study, looking for an answer to the question how to shape the
system of effective and efficient public sector management, refer to the postulates of
economic doctrine by the achievements of New Public Management (NPM), New
Public Governance (NPG), as well as selected theoretical concepts of the New
Institutional Economics (NIE).
The literature often emphasizes that the concept of NPG was created as a result of
criticism of selected assumptions of the MPM model. With an improved and more
mature version of it, the paper puts a special emphasis on the model of public
governance, referred to as Good Public Governance (GPG), treating it as a specific
standard and model for good functioning of public authority.
The study has several tasks: 1) to explain the relationship between governance and
government according to public sector and public administration; 2) to outline the
different approaches to public governance; 3) to clarify some core concepts in public
governance theory and the different models of governance; 4) to present the
institutional aspect of quality of public sector in the context of the idea of good public
governance.
In the empirical part of this article, focus was given to measuring governance. The
empirical purpose of the work was to examine relations between institutional factors
pertaining to the quality of public governance and the level of GDP per capita in 28
member states of the European Union. It was assumed that good governance has a
positive effect on the level of GDP of the studied countries.
The primary source of knowledge used by the authors were the World Bank data. Six
indicators proposed by this institution were assumed as synthetic measures of (good)
public governance (The Worldwide Governance Indicators – WGI) i.e., Voice and
Accountability (VA), Political Stability and Absence of Violence (PS), Government
Effectiveness (GE), Regulatory Quality (RQ), Rule of Law (RL), Control of
Corruption (CC).
M. Poniatowicz, R. Dziemianowicz, A. Kargol-Wasiluk
531
The observation of the evolution of the public management concept allows for
distinguishing three basic models of public administration management (Osborne,
2006):
i. Old Public Administration (OPA) – a model covering the period from the late
nineteenth century to the late seventies/early eighties of the 20th century;
ii. New Public Management (NPM) – a model covering the period from the late
1980s to the early 21st century;
iii. The public governance (PG), then evolving towards New Public Governance
(NPG) – nowadays.
The theoretical foundations of the OPA are related to the traditional administration
model and the concept of ideal bureaucracy proposed by Weber (Max Weber's Ideal
Bureaucracy Model). Hierarchy and bureaucracy are crucial in this model, and the
principle of its operation comes down to a precise and bureaucratic definition of the
relations between the subordinate unit (citizen) and the superior unit (government,
state). Weber points to the following features of ideal bureaucracy in public
administration (Sager and Rosser, 2009; Katsamunska, 2012):
Thus, while the traditional bureaucratic model favoured the process of administration
above all, contemporary models (NPM and NPG) put the art of management before
the art of administration. This approach is aptly characterized by Huges:
“administration means filling in instructions, while management means achieving
results” (Huges, 1994).
In turn, the term governance as a specific concept first appeared in the private sector
(corporate governance) in the sense of organizational power and the related strategic
level of corporate governance, as opposed to the current/operational level
(Raczkowski and Mikułowski, 2013; Thalassinos et al., 2014; 2015). It was only later
that the term was transferred to the public sector, interpreting it as a process of sharing
power in the process of public decision-making, supporting the autonomy and
independence of citizens and ensuring the process of development of the common
good through civic involvement (Jedrzejowska-Schiffauer et al., 2019). Pereira treats
public governance above all as a manifestation of the domination of public policy over
public administration. According to the opinion of this author, it allows to strengthen
the potential and powers of many stakeholders and thus a specific administrative and
regulatory order is achieved (Pereira et al., 2017).
The concept of NPM, based on the idea of managerialism in the public sector,
emphasizes certain similarities in the functioning of public administration to the
private sector. Hood is often considered to be the precursor of this idea (Hood, 1991).
The idea was popularised in the 1980s and 1990s, initially in countries such as
Australia, New Zealand and the USA, and later also in European countries. There is
also a proof of its growing popularity in the country of the authors of this paper, i.e.,
in Poland, where research articles related to the issue in question, referring both to the
government and local government sector are more and more frequently published
(Zalewski, 2007; Lubińska, 2009; Krynicka, 2006; Supernat, 2003; Zawicki, 2011;
Pająk, 2018).
The key postulates of the NMP may also serve as recommendations for necessary
changes in the context of increasing the effectiveness of the management system of
public sector entities. They are as follows (Poniatowicz and Dziemianowicz, 2017):
533
vi. The public sector should carry out some of its functions with the help of
private entities, e.g. in the formula of public-private partnership or
privatization; this is aptly illustrated by the acronym used by Osborne and
Gaebler in the public sector context: "steer, not row" (Osborne and Gaebler,
1992);
vii. The “3E rule” in the evaluation of public projects (economy, effectiveness and
efficiency);
viii. The need for public sector risk management – it is assumed that public sector
bodies, just like private entities, must look ahead, react dynamically to
changes and make optimal use of available opportunities; risk management is
the basis for such action and is an essential condition for optimising the
delivery of public goods and services;
ix. Moving away from the traditional understanding of the public budget toward
performance budgeting, which allows for the identification of tasks that are
the most important for the achievement of public objectives and the
determination, by means of appropriate measures, the degree of completion
of public tasks;
x. Long-term financial planning (multi-annual public finance) – it is assumed
that public finance management requires a long-term/perspective approach
(long-term financial planning; multi-annual public finance); it is no longer
sufficient to look at these issues from the perspective of the financial year
alone;
xi. Democratization and citizen participation – democratization of the processes
of managing public affairs, among other things, in the formula of involving
citizens in decision-making processes undertaken in the public sector (e.g.
public consultations, public referendums, participatory budgeting, etc.);
xii. Transparent public administration – special emphasis is placed on the
transparency of public administration and, consequently, on the
dissemination of good practices in the field of openness and transparency of
the public sector and the related system of public finances.
In the last decade, the NPM model has been criticised, among other things, for too
uncritical use of private sector experience and inadequacy for the specifics of public
sector decision-making (Monteduro, 2005). As a result, a new concept of public
governance has emerged, i.e., Public Governance (PG). It is assumed that just as in
the past NPM replaced the traditional concept of public administration, nowadays PG
will replace NPM (Bryson, Crosby, Bloomberg, 2014). Rhodes, based on the analogy
to NPM, proposes the term New Public Governance (NPG), defining the process of
public co-decision, with a significantly reduced role of government (governing
without government) (Rhodes, 1996). While the NPM concept focuses on the
professionalisation of management, standards and measures of success, results and
economic effects, the NPG concept focuses on processes involving public and private
sector actors in the form of governance as self-organizing networks, the relationship
between public authority and society (partnership, civic participation) and the
principles of liberal democracy (Rhodes, 1996).
Good Governance and Institutional Quality of Public Sector:
Theoretical and Empirical Implications
534
In order to systematise and compare key management aspects in each of the described
models of public administration (OPA, NPM and NPG), Iacovino, Barsanti and
Cinquini (2017) propose the use of this illustrative matrix in Table 1.
535
In economic sciences, more and more attention is paid to the issues of the public sector
in the context of the institutional approach. The terms institutionalism and institutional
development have become synonymous with actions aimed at reformation of this
sector in many countries, while the institutional approach in the process of
modernization of this sector is understood as creating new principles and mechanisms
for its functioning, especially in terms of increasing its efficiency and effectiveness.
What is characteristic of this approach is paying special attention to institutions, both
formal and informal, whose quality, but also mutual relations, implicate operation of
the sector concerned. From this perspective, institutional economics is a part of
economic sciences which, in order to explain the specificity of economic processes
that are taking place, analyze and emphasize in this scope primarily the influence of
non-economic factors (social, cultural, historical, legal, political factors etc.).
4
The term of public value was originally used by M.H. Moore (Moore, 1995). Public value
refers to the value created by government through public services, laws,
regulation and other actions. This term relates to the following categories: public
satisfaction, social value from the user perspective, trust and legitimacy, public service
quality, protecting citizens’ rights etc.
Good Governance and Institutional Quality of Public Sector:
Theoretical and Empirical Implications
536
institutions (Veblen, 1899). The latter, John R. Commons, in his studies, focused
mainly on formal institutions including, above all, the system of law (Commons,
1957).
The trend of new institutional economics appeared in the early 70s of the twentieth
century, and its leading representatives were: the British economist Ronald Harry
Coase, the American economist Oliver E. Williamson, and the American economist
and historian Douglass C. North. Analysis of the theoretical achievements of these
authors allows to identify specific differences between traditional institutionalism and
the new institutional economics.
Thirdly, the difference between the traditional and modern institutional approach is
also reflected in the subject of research. As noted by M. Lissowska, in the former
approach, the area of research is extensive and not very specific, and it is based also
on non-formalized institutions such as, for instance, habits, traditions etc. In the latter
approach, however, the subject of research are clearly defined: transactions made
between economic entities (Lissowska, 2004).
537
ii. abandonment of the model of full economic rationality, in favor of the so-
called limited rationality in the formula of modification of the homo
oeconomicus conception’s assumptions, primarily in the context of
opportunism and people’s natural tendency to make mistakes; in such
approach, the method and results of public organizations’ operation
should also be considered through the prism of individual preferences and
choices (public decision-makers – politicians, consumers of public goods
– voters, private entities that cooperate with the public sector);
iii. abandonment of the conception of allocative effectiveness that is typical
of neoclassical economics (understood as optimization of the relations
between economic expenditures and results, in the given institutional
environment) in favor of adaptive effectiveness (understood in the context
of institutional flexibility i.e., institutions’ ability to adapt to the changing
conditions of the environment) (North, 2010);
iv. concentration of research on the contract/transaction category and their
associated benefits and costs (the so-called transaction costs and, in the
case of public sector entities, public transaction costs); in the context of
the public sector’s specificity, it ought to be added that public (political)
contracts are significantly different from contracts concluded on the
market of private goods and services i.e. private contracts. Among others,
this is due to the fact that the public (political) market is governed by
different rules, and the decisions made on this market are a public choice
that reflects social preferences and involves a compromise made between
economic rationality and social justice (Zbroińska, 2009).
Analysis of the possibilities of using the postulates of the new institutional economics
in development of the public sector, first of all, requires a broader discussion of the
issues connected with two key components that constitute pillars of the modern
institutionalism’s conception. These are: institutions and transaction costs.
Considering the aspect of institutions’ effect on the economic reality, Mary M. Shirley
divides them into two categories: (i) institutions which facilitate market exchange by
reducing transaction costs and increasing trust; (ii) institutions which shape the system
of state authority towards strengthening of private property and freedom of individuals
(Shirley, 2005).
From the standpoint of the research issues undertaken by the authors, the latter
category is particularly important. This is due to the fact that in the context of the
public sector, which is of most interest to us, the institutional approach allows to
evaluate the quality of governance by public authorities. This is connected with the
model of public governance referred to as good governance. These issues will be
further discussed in the paper.
M. Poniatowicz, R. Dziemianowicz, A. Kargol-Wasiluk
539
When analyzing the operation of the public sector, the new institutional economics
(NIE) refers to the term of governance (Przesławska, 2007). This term means:
governing, the quality of governing, exercising authority, public governance (co-
governing), co-managing, order, coordination, and even management. Generally
speaking, the term governance “(…) refers to all the models of rules. It is a set of
principles assumed by an organization such as an enterprise or the state, determining
how to rule and what principles to apply in internal and external relations between
the stakeholders” (Valkama et al., 2004). Governance is a concept from the field of
economic and political, or even sociological sciences (Hill and Lynn, 2004). As stated
by Jessop (2007), it can be easily moved between the boundaries of various schools
of thought and scientific disciplines as well as various areas of practical use.
Therefore, it is an ambiguous and multi-contextual term.
In the general sense, public governance means the government’s ability to function
with or without the private sector, in order to drive the economy and the society toward
achievement of common goals (Peters, 2012). According to Peters (2012), public
governance may also be realized via the use of traditional methods of hierarchical
nature, which means that the foundations of such co-governing are rooted in the
conception of traditional governments (centralized and autocratic). This is the case in
many countries. Traditional methods are used, e.g., in the sphere of taxation,
regulation of business activity, even in countries in which there are strong tendencies
toward governance using more interactive mechanisms. This is because the given
model of governance may not be suitable for every political system or every public
policy. The cited author notes that the term governance has become popular partly
because it constitutes an alternative to traditional hierarchical forms of ruling a nation
state, especially in centralized systems. The main logic behind governing without a
government is that self-organizing networks of actors can supply/constitute
alternative, more effective, human/humanitarian and democratic models of
governance (Peters, 2012). Table 2 presents the main differences between the
traditional way of governing by a government, and public governance.
Rotberg (2004) believes that “public governance is good” when it allows to allocate
and manage the resources so as to satisfy the collective needs (solve collective
problems) or, in other words, when the government effectively provides public goods
of appropriate quality. Therefore, governments should be evaluated in terms of both
quality and quantity of goods supplied. Supply of public goods as part of public
policies is based on such principles as: human rights, democratization and democracy,
transparency, participation of decentralized authority, good public administration,
responsibility/accountability, rule of law, effectiveness, equality, strategic vision
(Cheema, 2005).
Good Governance and Institutional Quality of Public Sector:
Theoretical and Empirical Implications
540
The term good governance was first used in documents of the World Bank in the early
90s of the twentieth century. World Bank’s definition of 1992 described good
governance using the following qualities: an open and developmental policy,
professional administration, acting for the public good, rules of the law, transparency
of processes, a strong civil society (Schöler and Walther, 2003). It ought to be added
that, in various texts, different values defining the idea of good governance are
specified. For instance, UN documents mention eight principles associated with this
formula of public administration’s operation. These are: participation, social
consensus, accountability of public authority, transparency, timeliness, effectiveness
and efficiency, social justice, rule of law (United Nations, 2009).
541
encompasses state institutions and their actions as well as the private sector and civil
society organizations. In practice, such rules should translate into “strengthening of
democratic institutions” (Cheema, 2005). Moreover, good public governance
provides the basis for good corporate governance. Good public governance is the
foundation for stable and effective economies. Those who question the possibility of
defining conditions of good governance are inclined toward creating/defining
conditions of the good enough governance model. As a conception, good enough
governance suggests that not all the deficits/shortcomings of public governance must
be immediately remedied, and that building of institutions and capabilities of the state
requires time (Grindle, 2011). Grindle proposes that, within the frameworks of good
enough governance, attention is paid to the minimum conditions of governance that
enable political and economic development, and a solution that may be used in
practice is not necessarily presented (Grindle, 2011).
6. Measurement of Governance
However, measurement of governance which, in recent years, has become the subject
of many empirical analyses, poses many problems. Application of statistical tools to
evaluate governance quality is not easy because these actions are often immeasurable.
In the opinion of Przesławska, governance quality indicators do not measure the
objective state, which is probably indefinable, but rather “(…) the perception of the
given phenomenon in the selected group of respondents, e.g., experts of the given field
or companies operating in the given country. Here, a certain institutional model is the
point of reference (…)” (Przesławska, 2007). Therefore, many institutions have made
attempts to prepare relevant models. The most elaborate governance quality measures,
based on aggregated data and international comparative studies, have been published
by the World Bank, the European Central Bank, the International Institute for
Management Development (IMD) and the World Economic Forum (WEF)
(Wojciechowski and Podgórniak-Krzykacz, 2008). Each of the proposed methods for
this evaluation has its advantages and disadvantages.
Good Governance and Institutional Quality of Public Sector:
Theoretical and Empirical Implications
542
Still, the leading institution in terms of construction of quality indicators is the World
Bank. The first empirical study concerning this measurement was published in 1996
by Kaufmann, Kraay and Zoido-Lobaton (1999). The study covered 178 countries.
The next study was published in 1999 in the World Bank’s Policy Research Working
Paper (Kaufmann et al., 1999). The analysis concerned 199 countries and was
prepared on the basis of 300 indicators. Its authors aggregated individual measures of
governance quality into six categories that encompass the key dimensions of
governance quality (Kaufmann et al., 1999):
The way in which the above categories are put into groups does not aspire to the status
of a precise definition of governance quality. It is, rather, a reflection of the author’s
views on “a coherent and useful organization of data, consistent with the common
notion of governance quality (a model of unobservable components)” (Przesławska,
2007).
5
Originally, this category was defined as: Graft (i.e. bribery). Only in 2002 it was changed to
control of corruption (Wojciechowski and Podgórniak-Krzykacz, 2008).
M. Poniatowicz, R. Dziemianowicz, A. Kargol-Wasiluk
543
According to some researchers, the weakness of WGI lies in being based solely on
subjective data and, therefore, the possibility of formulating biased opinions and
discrepancy between respondents. However, in many cases, objective data, as
emphasized by Zawojska, (2012), may be even more inadequate due to extreme
incompatibilities between the de jure and de facto situations. Other researchers
(Glaeser et al., 2004) criticize WGI for failing to relate to the permanent elements of
an institution’s definition proposed by North (1990) and for measuring results of an
institution (i.e., policy choices) rather than the formal limitations of executive
authority. According to Kurtz and Schrank (2007), WGI’s deficiency is the mutual
correlation of subindices.
The authors of the research made an attempt to examine the statistical relationship
between institutional factors of the so-called good governance, and the level of
economic growth in 28 member states of the European Union. Therefore, it was
assumed that the quality of governance has a positive effect on the level of GDP per
capita in the studied countries. The main source of knowledge were the World Bank’s
data. Six indicators proposed by this institution were assumed as the measures of
governance quality (The Worldwide Governance Indicators – WGI).
WGI represent aggregated indicators based on several hundred variables that evaluate
the perception of institutions (Table 3), collected from dozens separate sources of data
gathered by 30 organizations from around the world. The indicators of governance
quality (or the state’s institutional efficiency) assumed for the study reflect the
processes of selecting, monitoring and changing public authorities (Voice and
Accountability VA), political stability and absence of violence/terrorism (PS), the
public authorities’ ability to effectively formulate and implement the right decisions
(Government Effectiveness GE, and Regulatory Quality RQ) as well as the respect of
citizens/the state for institutions which govern mutual relations (Rule of Law RL and
Control of Corruption CC) (Kaufmann et al., 2010; Zawojska, 2012).
6
See: Poniatowicz, Dziemianowowicz, Kargol-Wasiluk, 2017.
Good Governance and Institutional Quality of Public Sector:
Theoretical and Empirical Implications
544
The year 2018 was chosen for the purposes of the analysis because the most recent
(available) data come from that period. In order to serve as a measure of the gross
domestic product, GDP was assumed as an average GDP per capita for the EU-28
(the so-called dependent variable). Selected indicators of governance quality for the
EU-28 (independent variables) and the level of GDP per capita in 2018 are presented
in Appendices 1–7. The following table (Table 4) presents the variables used in the
empirical analysis, together with the applied abbreviations and data sources.
545
The IBM SPSS Statistics (version 25) program was used for empirical analyses.
Descriptive statistics are presented in Tables 5 and 6 for raw data and for ranged data,
whereas the correlation matrix is presented in Table 7.
When analyzing descriptive statistics of independent variables VA, PSV, GE, RQ, RL
CC and of the GDP dependent variable, one could conclude that, due to similar values
of the mean and median in all the cases, the distributions of these variables are normal.
The kurtosis, which is a measure of flattening, is positive for GDP which means that
its distribution is slimmer than in the case of the normal distribution. As regards the
other variables, the distributions are more flattened. The skewness coefficient is
negative in all the cases (except for CC and GDP), which indicates left-sidedness of
the distribution.
Good Governance and Institutional Quality of Public Sector:
Theoretical and Empirical Implications
546
Due to the high skewness of the distribution for GDP and the value of kurtosis,
normalization (standardization) of variables was conducted, leading to the results
presented in Table 6.
547
Based on the analysis of data from the correlation matrix, PSV was excluded as an
indicator which is not significantly correlated to GDP. Next, a regression analysis was
performed, trying to find the answer to the question of which governance indicators
influence the economic growth in the EU-28 to the greatest extent. Therefore, in
further analyses, the following model was subjected to verification:
The model of multiple regression was chosen for the analysis. Parameters of the model
were estimated using the least squares method (OLS). In the regression equation, the
regression coefficients (β) represent independent contributions of each independent
variable to forecasting the GDP dependent variable. After carrying out repeated
analyses, the following results were obtained:
Unstandardized Standardized
Coefficients Coefficients Linearity Statistics
Standa
rd
Model B Error Beta t Significance Tolerance VIF
1 (Consta 3.606 4.287 .841 .408
nt)
PRSVA .930 .072 .930 12.8 .000
1 1
62
a. Dependent Variable: FRPGDP
Beta (β) – correlation strength
Source: Own study.
Table 10. Summary of the model – value of the multiple correlation coefficient and
the R-squared statistics
Model – Summary
A multiple regression analysis was carried out, in which the explained variable was
GDP per capita in the EU-28 as an average GDP per capita for all the member states,
and the explaining variables was VA. The proposed regression model transpired to be
well matched to the data of F (1;26) = 165.42 p ˂ 0.01. Based on the analysis of
regression coefficients, it may be concluded that GDP per capita in the EU-28 is
strongly and positively associated with VA (beta = 0.93, p < 0.01). This means that a
country characterized by a high level of GDP per capita is also characterized by a
high level of VA. The tested model explains 86% of the variability of the dependent
variable. The independent variable, which was included in the model, have a positive
effect on the dependent variable.
The obtained model presents the relationship between GDP and such dimension of
governance quality as voice and accountability. Extension of the analysis could prove
that, at the given stage of economic development, other dimensions of governance
quality have a greater significance. However, if you use the linear regression model,
you can build five one-factor models (one-factor regression model) (Table 11).
M. Poniatowicz, R. Dziemianowicz, A. Kargol-Wasiluk
549
Results obtained in the empirical study are, to a considerable extent, convergent with
the results of the study conducted by Bayar in transition countries (Bayar, 2016).
8. Conclusions
The new institutional economics assumes that modern economic processes are
determined by various kinds of institutions. Hence, an important role in dynamizing
the processes of socio-economic development is attributed to the quality of
governance, which is often expressed in institutional terms. Studies are undertaken
which, on the one hand, enable identification of its dimensions and, on the other,
demonstrate the impact of the governance quality on the rate of growth and the level
of economic development.
The conducted theoretical study falls within the boundaries of the new institutional
economics trend, providing the basis for further advancement of research in reference
to the public sector, especially as far as governance quality is concerned. Key
theoretical concepts in this context, which are consistent with the paradigm of the new
institutional economics, include the public choice theory (along with constitutional
economics and the economic theory of democracy that were derived from it) as well
as other theories i.e. the agency theory, the transaction costs theory and the property
rights theory.
As the conducted empirical study has demonstrated, changes in operation of the public
sector, in relation to governance quality, exert an influence on economic results of the
given country such as the level of GDP per capita. The conducted analyses resulted
in positively verifying the model of relations between dimensions of governance
quality and the pace of economic growth in the EU-28. Based on correlation studies,
out of the six analyzed dimensions of governance quality i.e., voice and
accountability, political stability, government effectiveness, regulatory quality, rule of
law and control of corruption, only political stability transpired not to be correlated to
the level of GDP per capita in the studied economies, where the individual dimensions
are, to a varying degree, correlated to the explained variable.
The empirical model of dependences between the studied values has confirmed the
assumptions of the authors about the positive effect of Voice and Accountability (VA).
Based on the analysis of regression coefficients, it may be concluded that GDP per
capita in the EU-28 is strongly and positively associated with VA (beta = 0.93, p <
Good Governance and Institutional Quality of Public Sector:
Theoretical and Empirical Implications
550
0.01). This means that a country characterized by a high level of GDP per capita is
also characterized by a high level of VA. The tested model explains 86% of the
variability of the dependent variable.
References:
Bayar, Y. 2016. Public Governance and the Economic Growth in the Transitional Economies
of the European Union. Transylvanian Review of Administrative Sciences, 48 E, 5-
18.
Barczewska-Dziobek, A. 2018. Impact of the concept of good governance on the way public
administration functions in Poland – an outline of the issues. Administracja.
Roczniki Nauk Prawnych, XXVIII(1), 151-166.
Bryson, J.M., Crosby, B.C., Bloomberg, L. 2014. Public Value Governance: Moving beyond
Traditional Public Administration and the New Public Management. Public
Administration Review, 74(4), 445–456.
Cheema, S.G. 2005. Building democratic institutions: governance reform in developing
countries, New York, Kumarian Press Inc., 4-6.
Dickinson, H. 2016. From New Public Management to New Public Governance: The
implications for a ‘new public service’. In: J. Butcher, D. Gilchrist (eds.), The Three
Sector Solution: Delivering public policy in collaboration with not-for-profits and
business. The Australia and New Zealand School of Government (ANZSOG), ANU
Press, The Australian National University, Canberra, Australia, 41- 60.
Glaeser, E., La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A. 2004. Do institutions cause
growth? Journal of Economic Growth, 9(3), 271-303.
Hill, C.J., Lynn Jr, L.E. 2004. Governance and Public Management, an Introduction. Journal
of Public Analysis and Management, 23(1), 3-11.
Hood, C. 1991. A Public Management for All Seasons. Public Administration, 69(1), 3-19.
Huges, O.E. 1994. Public Management and Administration. An Introduction. London,
Macmillan Press.
Iacovino, N.M., Barsanti, S., Cinquini, L. 2017. Public Organizations Between Old Public
Administration, New Public Management and Public Governance: the Case of the
Tuscany Region. Public Organization Review, 17, 61-82.
Jędrzejowska-Schiffauer, I., Schiffauer, P., Thalassinos, I.E. 2019. EU Regulatory Measures
Following the Crises: What Impact on Corporate Governance of Financial
Institutions? European Research Studies Journal, 22(3), 432-456.
Jessop, B. 2007. Promoting "good governance" and hiding its weaknesses: reflection on
political paradigms and political narratives in the sphere of governance. Zarządzanie
Publiczne, 2(2), 5-25.
Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A., Mastruzzi, M. 2010. The Worldwide Governance Indicators:
Methodology and analytical Issues. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper,
5430, 1-31. Retrieved from:
https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1682130.
Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A., Zoido-Lobaton, P. 1999. Governance Matters. Policy Research
Working Paper, 2196. Retrieved from:
http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/665731468739470954/pdf/multi-
page.pdf.
Krynicka, H. 2006. The concept of New Public Management in the public sector. Studia
Lubuskie, 2, 193-202.
M. Poniatowicz, R. Dziemianowicz, A. Kargol-Wasiluk
551
Kurtz, M., Schrank, A. 2007. Growth and governance: Models, measures, and mechanisms.
Journal of Politics, 69(2), 538-554.
Lubińska, T. (ed.). 2009. Nowe Zarządzanie Publiczne – skuteczność i efektywność. Budżet
zadaniowy w Polsce. (New Public Management – efficiency and effectiveness.
Activity-based budget in Poland). Difin: Warszawa.
Mayntz, R. 2003. From government to governance: political steering in modern societies.
Summer Academy on IPP: Wuerzburg, September 7-11. Retrieved from:
http://www.ioew.de/fileadmin/user_upload/DOKUMENTE/Veranstaltungen/2003/S
uA2Mayntz.pdf.
Miłaszewicz, D. 2014. Problems of social efficiency of the public sector. Studia
Ekonomiczne Uniwersytetu Ekonomicznego w Katowicach, 180(2), 163-173.
Miłaszewicz, D. 2015. Proposition of assessment of the public sector social efficiency based
on example of European Union countries. Zeszyty Naukowe Uniwersytetu
Ekonomicznego w Katowicach, 209, 127-135.
Monteduro, F. 2005. La riforma delle amministrazioni pubbliche: Verso la Public
Governance. In: Nuovi profili di accountability nelle PA: Teoria e strumenti.
Quaderni Formez, 40, 27-42.
Monteduro, F., Hinna, A., Gnan, L. (ed.). 2013. Conceptualizing and Researching
Governance in Public and Non-profit Organizations. Studies in Public and non-
profit Governance, Volume 1. United Kingdom – North America – Japan – India –
Malaysia – China, Emerald Group Publishing Limited.
Moore, M. 1995. Creating Public Value – Strategic Management in Government. Cambridge,
Harvard University Press.
North, D.C. 1990. Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance. Cambridge,
Cambridge University Press.
Osborne, S.P. 2006. The new public governance? Public Management Review, 8(3), 377-
387.
Osborne, D., Gaebler, T. 1992. Reinventing Government: How the Entrepreneurial Spirit is
Transforming the Public Sector. New York, Addison-Wesley.
Pająk, K. 2018. New public management: theoretical and practical aspects. Wydawnictwo
Naukowe PWN, Warszawa.
Pereira, F.N., Alledi Filho, C., Quelhas, O., Bonina, N., Vieira, J., Marques, V. 2017. New
Public Management and New Public Governance: A Conceptual Analysis
Comparison. Revista Espacios, 38(07).
Peteres, B.G. 2012. Is Governance for Everybody? The Use and Abuse of Governance. In:
A.M. Bissessar (ed.), Governance: Is It for Everyone? New York, Nova Science
Publishers, Inc.
Peters, B.G., Pierre, J. 1998. Governance Without Government? Rethinking Public
Administration. Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory, 8, 223-243.
Peters, B.G., Pierre, J. 2000. Citizens Versus the New Public Manager. The Problem of
Mutual Empowerment. Administration and Society, 32, 9-28.
Poniatowicz, M., Dziemianowicz, R. 2017. Effective financial management of local
government units – postulates of economic doctrine and instruments. Problemy
Zarządzania, 15/2(1), 126-146.
Poniatowicz, M., Dziemianowicz, R., Kargol-Wasiluk, A. 2017. Institutional Dimensions of
Public Governnace in the European Union Member States. Third International
Scientific Conference: Knowledge Based Sustainable Economic Development
ERAZ. Conference Proceedings, Belgrade, Serbia.
Good Governance and Institutional Quality of Public Sector:
Theoretical and Empirical Implications
552
553
Zawojska, A. 2012. Economic and political institutions and prices of consumer goods.
Roczniki Ekonomii Rolnictwa i Rozwoju Obszarów Wiejskich, 99(4), 7-28.
Appendices:
Appendix 1. Voice and Accountability
GEO/TIME 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018
Austria 1.39 1.43 1.40 1.45 1.46 1.39 1.38 1.34 1.34 1.38
Belgium 1.35 1.36 1.33 1.35 1.37 1.37 1.39 1.38 1.38 1.40
Bulgaria 0.56 0.53 0.45 0.40 0.34 0.37 0.43 0.40 0.38 0.32
Cyprus 1.07 1.02 1.05 1.02 0.98 1.02 1.03 1.05 1.06 1.04
Czechia 1.03 1.01 1.02 0.97 0.98 1.03 1.04 1.02 0.97 0.93
Germany 1.33 1.30 1.35 1.39 1.41 1.44 1.42 1.36 1.39 1.42
Denmark 1.54 1.54 1.55 1.67 1.67 1.52 1.55 1.54 1.52 1.61
Spain 1.18 1.12 1.09 1.06 0.99 0.99 1.04 1.04 1.03 1.06
Estonia 1.09 1.11 1.13 1.11 1.12 1.17 1.19 1.21 1.21 1.21
Finland 1.47 1.49 1.51 1.60 1.57 1.54 1.54 1.53 1.55 1.61
France 1.24 1.20 1.17 1.24 1.22 1.22 1.21 1.14 1.15 1.18
United Kingdom 1.30 1.29 1.30 1.34 1.33 1.28 1.30 1.29 1.33 1.38
Greece 0.89 0.90 0.82 0.70 0.69 0.62 0.65 0.67 0.71 0.86
Croatia 0.49 0.48 0.52 0.54 0.51 0.51 0.56 0.52 0.51 0.50
Hungary 0.91 0.89 0.84 0.75 0.74 0.55 0.56 0.40 0.37 0.32
Ireland 1.35 1.32 1.31 1.32 1.31 1.32 1.33 1.29 1.29 1.32
Italy 1.03 0.96 0.91 0.92 0.95 1.00 1.03 1.03 1.05 1.05
Lithuania 0.90 0.92 0.86 0.93 0.94 0.96 0.97 1.00 0.99 0.92
Luxembourg 1.56 1.57 1.60 1.65 1.63 1.55 1.55 1.50 1.52 1.57
Latvia 0.85 0.79 0.74 0.78 0.77 0.85 0.85 0.84 0.80 0.81
Malta 1.15 1.17 1.14 1.17 1.16 1.18 1.20 1.20 1.17 1.12
Netherlands 1.46 1.45 1.54 1.61 1.57 1.55 1.56 1.54 1.57 1.60
Poland 1.03 1.04 1.03 1.06 1.00 1.11 1.04 0.84 0.78 0.72
Portugal 1.13 1.11 1.11 1.03 1.07 1.11 1.13 1.16 1.21 1.20
Romania 0.46 0.43 0.38 0.32 0.31 0.43 0.49 0.54 0.52 0.46
Slovakia 0.88 0.91 0.97 0.97 0.96 0.96 0.97 0.96 0.94 0.88
Slovenia 1.06 1.05 1.06 1.00 1.00 0.96 0.99 1.01 1.00 0.99
Sweden 1.55 1.54 1.61 1.69 1.66 1.61 1.57 1.56 1.58 1.61
Source: World Bank. The Worldwide Governance Indicators – WGI. Retrieved from:
http://info.worldbank.org/governance/wgi/index.aspx#home (16.01.2020).
Slovakia 0.92 1.05 0.97 1.09 1.12 1.04 0.87 0.72 0.91 0.75
Slovenia 0.93 0.87 0.97 0.94 0.88 0.97 0.95 0.99 0.87 0.91
Sweden 1.09 1.09 1.23 1.17 1.13 1.07 0.95 1.02 0.98 0.91
Source: World Bank. The Worldwide Governance Indicators – WGI. Retrieved from:
http://info.worldbank.org/governance/wgi/index.aspx#home (16.01.2020).
555
Portugal 0.99 0.72 0.63 0.83 0.80 0.75 0.96 0.84 0.91 0.89
Romania 0.60 0.64 0.66 0.55 0.61 0.58 0.60 0.59 0.49 0.45
Slovakia 1.05 1.00 1.00 1.05 0.93 0.89 0.79 0.89 0.82 0.81
Slovenia 0.92 0.76 0.70 0.63 0.63 0.66 0.63 0.64 0.58 0.69
Sweden 1.65 1.66 1.90 1.91 1.91 1.81 1.82 1.85 1.80 1.80
Source: World Bank. The Worldwide Governance Indicators – WGI. Retrieved from:
http://info.worldbank.org/governance/wgi/index.aspx#home (16.01.2020).
Netherlands 2.13 2.14 2.12 2.12 2.05 1.99 1.88 1.91 1.87 2.01
Poland 0.45 0.50 0.56 0.66 0.60 0.64 0.67 0.74 0.72 0.64
Portugal 1.09 1.09 1.11 0.96 0.95 0.95 0.96 0.93 0.87 0.85
Romania -0.26 -0.23 -0.21 -0.26 -0.19 -0.11 -0.02 -0.02 -0.03 -0.12
Slovakia 0.27 0.29 0.28 0.10 0.08 0.16 0.18 0.23 0.22 0.36
Slovenia 1.06 0.92 0.95 0.84 0.73 0.73 0.77 0.82 0.81 0.87
Sweden 2.25 2.27 2.20 2.31 2.29 2.15 2.24 2.19 2.14 2.14
Source: World Bank. The Worldwide Governance Indicators – WGI. Retrieved from:
http://info.worldbank.org/governance/wgi/index.aspx#home (16.01.2020).