Untitled
Untitled
DERIVATIVES MARKETS
Money Capital
Market Market
SECURITIES
TRUST FUNDS
WHAT IS
DERIVATIVE?
Derivatives contract
Definitions
Financing
February 25 August 25
Bid 35.22 39.65
Ask 35.37 39.80
Ali enters into a short sale on February 25 for 100 shares. He covers his
short position on August 25. The broker’s commission is RM10 per
transaction. What is Ali’s profit or loss on the short sale?
NOW LATER
Purchasing and Sale of Cash outflow to buy Cash inflow from sale of
Stock stock stock
Lending Money Cash outflow to lend Cash inflow from
money repayment of loan
NOW LATER
Short-selling stock Cash inflow from sale Cash outflow to buy
of stock stock
Borrowing Money Cash inflow from Cash outflow to repay
borrowing money loan
84 -20 20 10
0
94 -10 10 -10
74 84 94 104 114 124 134
104 0 0 -20
-30
114 10 -10
-40
124 20 -20 Long Forward (Sue) Short Forward (George)
134 30 -30
150
100
50
0
4 50 100 150
-50
-100
-150
Payoff on Long Forward Payoff on Immediate Purchase
150
100
50
0
4 50 100 150
-50
-100
-150
Payoff on long forward+bond Payoff on Immediate Purchase Payoff on Bond (RM104)
BUYER SELLER
Ms Sarah Nadirah Mohd Johari, 2021
CALL OPTIONS
• Purchaser: party who pays a premium for the right, but NOT the obligation,
to buy the underlying asset at the strike price.
• Writer: party who charges a premium for the purchaser’s right, but NOT
the obligation, to buy the underlying asset at the strike price. Obligated to
sell the asset at the specified price if the purchaser of the option wants to
buy it.
• Strike/Exercise price: Agreed-upon price for which the purchaser of the call
option can buy the asset.
• Exercising: Purchaser of the call decides to pay the strike price to buy the
underlying asset.
• Expiration date: Agreed-upon date by which the call option must be
exercised. If the purchaser of the option decides not to exercise it, the
option expires.
BUYER SELLER
Ms Sarah Nadirah Mohd Johari, 2021
PURCHASED/LONG CALL
• Payoff on a European – style purchased call:
Strike Call
35 6.13
40 2.78
45 0.97
Strike Call
35 6.13
40 2.78
45 0.97
BUYER SELLER
Ms Sarah Nadirah Mohd Johari, 2021
PUT OPTIONS
• Purchaser: party who pays a premium for the right, but NOT the
obligation, to sell the underlying asset at the strike price.
• Writer: party who charges a premium for the purchaser’s right, but
NOT the obligation, to sell the underlying asset at the strike price.
Obligated to buy the asset at the specified price if the purchaser of
the option wants to sell it.
• Purchased put has a short position with respect to the underlying
asset.
BUYER SELLER
Ms Sarah Nadirah Mohd Johari, 2021
PURCHASED/LONG PUT
• Payoff on a European – style purchased put:
𝑷𝒂𝒚𝒐𝒇𝒇 𝒐𝒏 𝒑𝒖𝒓𝒄𝒉𝒂𝒔𝒆𝒅 𝒑𝒖𝒕 = 𝒎𝒂𝒙[𝟎, 𝒔𝒕𝒓𝒊𝒌𝒆 𝒑𝒓𝒊𝒄𝒆 − 𝒔𝒑𝒐𝒕 𝒑𝒓𝒊𝒄𝒆 𝒂𝒕 𝒆𝒙𝒑𝒊𝒓𝒂𝒕𝒊𝒐𝒏]
Strike Put
35 0.44
40 1.99
45 5.08
Obligation to buy at strike price if purchaser Written (or Short) Put Long
of put exercises option
Can you think of anything you could do to protect yourself, using any
of the derivative contracts we have discussed so far?
What is the payoff if the spot price at expiration is less than or equal
to RM100?
What is the payoff if the spot price at expiration is more than RM100,
say RM120?
The financing cost is the RM100 you paid for the stock and the RM6.59 you
paid for the put at time 0.
Thus, assuming 4% effective for ½ year, the financing cost as of the end of 6
months is (100 + 6.50) (1.04) = 110.76
Ms Sarah Nadirah Mohd Johari, 2021
INSURING A LONG POSITION
Financing cost is shown in the 5th column and 6th column minus this
cost from the payoff to determine the profit.
Spot Price at PAYOFF Cost Profit
Expiration From From Put Combined (including
Stock interest)
70
80
90
100
110
120
130
Determine the total payoff from the stocks and the options at the end
of 6 month.
Current Spot Price Strike Price Put Premium Spot Price at Expiration
Stock A 60 60 3.90 50
Stock B 75 75 4.88 80
If the effective rate of interest is 4% for a ½ year period, determine the
total profit in Example 4(i).
Can you think of anything you could do to protect yourself, using any
of the derivative contracts we have discussed so far?
Determine the total payoff from the stocks and the options at the end
of 6 month.
Current Spot Price Strike Price Call Premium Spot Price at Expiration
Stock A 60 60 6.21 50
Stock B 75 75 7.86 80
If the effective rate of interest is 4% for a ½ year period, determine the
total profit in Example 5(i).
Try to make up a table of payoffs similar to the table for the covered
call in previous slide.
Try sketch the payoff graphs for long call, short put and combined.
What does the combined payoff graph look like?
What should the forward price be so that a forward contract has the
same profit as the combination of a purchased call and written put?
1) Outright Purchase
2) Forward Contract
3) Long Call ; Call 𝐾, 𝑇 and Short Put; Put 𝐾, 𝑇
This relationship is knowns as put – call parity. It derives from net cost
of buying an asset using options = net cost of buying an asset using a
forward contract.
𝑺𝟎 = 𝑪𝒂𝒍𝒍 𝑲, 𝑻 − 𝑷𝒖𝒕 𝑲, 𝑻 + 𝑷𝑽 𝑲
𝑪𝒂𝒍𝒍 𝑲, 𝑻 − 𝑷𝒖𝒕 𝑲, 𝑻 = 𝑺𝟎 − 𝑷𝑽(𝑲)
This relationship for a non-dividend paying stock derives from net cost
of buying an asset using options must be the same as the net cost of an
outright purchase of the asset
Bull Bear
SPREADS
Box Ratio
Straddles Strangles
EXAMPLES
Butterfly spreads
𝑃
𝐹0,𝑇 = 𝑆0 𝑒 𝛼𝑇 𝑒 −𝛼𝑇
𝑃
𝐹0,𝑇 = 𝑆0
𝑃
𝐹0,𝑇 = 𝐹𝑉(𝐹0,𝑇 )
𝐹0,𝑇 = 𝑒 𝑟𝑇 𝑆0 𝑒 −𝛿𝑇 𝑜𝑟 𝑆0 𝑒 𝑟− 𝛿 𝑇
1 𝐹0,𝑇
Annualized forward premium= ln
𝑇 𝑆0
BUYER SELLER
Ms Sarah Nadirah Mohd Johari, 2021
FUTURE CONTRACTS
MARGIN ACCOUNT WITH NO INTEREST
BUYER SELLER
Ms Sarah Nadirah Mohd Johari, 2021
SWAPS
• A contract that covers a stream of payment over a period of time.
• We can say, a forward contract is a single-payment swap.
• Four ways to settle a forward contract:
(i) Physical Settlement
(ii) Financial Settlement
(iii) Broker as a Go-Between (back-to-back or matched-book)
(iv) Broker Contracts Only With Buyer and Hedges Position
This contract can pay upfront by paying the present value of these
guaranteed prices at the risk-free interest rate and it is called as a
prepaid swap.
(b) Seller: After delivering the commodity to you at the end of one
and two years, will the buyer be able to pay for it?
(2) There are changes in the swap prices in contracts being written at
time T, as compared to contracts that were written at time 0.
In this entire section, we will deal only with European options, not American
ones.
Suppose you bought a European call option and sold a European put option,
both having the same underlying asset, strike price and time to expiry.
You would then pay 𝐶(𝐾, 𝑇) − 𝑃(𝐾, 𝑇) at time 0. An equivalent result can
be achieved without using options at all!
Ms Sarah Nadirah Mohd Johari, 2021
PUT – CALL PARITY
At time 𝑇, either one of the options is sure to be exercise unless the price of
the asset is exactly equal the strike price, (𝑆𝑇 = 𝐾).Therefore, both options
are worthless.
Whichever options is exercised, you pay 𝐾 and receive the underlying asset:
1. If 𝑆𝑇 > 𝐾, you exercise the call option you bought. You pay 𝐾 and receive
the asset.
2. If 𝐾 > 𝑆𝑇 , the counterparty exercises the put option you sold. You
receive the asset and pay 𝐾.
3. If 𝑆𝑇 = 𝐾, it does not matter whether you have 𝐾 or the underlying
asset.
By the no-arbitrage principle, these two methods must cost the same.
Discounting to time 0, this means:
𝐶 𝐾, 𝑇 − 𝑃 𝐾, 𝑇 + 𝐾𝑒 −𝑟𝑇 = 𝐹0,𝑇 𝑒 −𝑟𝑇
Or
𝑪 𝑲, 𝑻 − 𝑷 𝑲, 𝑻 = 𝒆−𝒓𝑻 (𝑭𝟎,𝑻 − 𝑲)
𝑪 𝑲, 𝑻 − 𝑷 𝑲, 𝑻 = 𝑺𝟎 − 𝑲𝒆−𝒓𝑻
𝑪 𝑲, 𝑻 − 𝑷 𝑲, 𝑻 = 𝑺𝟎 − 𝑲𝒆−𝒓𝑻
𝟐. 𝟖𝟒 − 𝑷 𝑲, 𝑻 = 𝟒𝟎 − 𝟒𝟓𝒆− 𝟎.𝟎𝟓 𝟎.𝟕𝟓
𝟐. 𝟖𝟒 − 𝑷 𝑲, 𝑻 = 𝟑. 𝟑𝟒𝟑𝟕𝟓
𝑷 𝑲, 𝑻 = 𝟐. 𝟖𝟒 + 𝟑. 𝟑𝟒𝟑𝟕𝟓 = 𝟔. 𝟏𝟖𝟑𝟕𝟓
Ms Sarah Nadirah Mohd Johari, 2021
STOCK PUT – CALL PARITY
A convenient concept is the prepaid forward. It is the same as a regular
forward except that the payment is made at the time the agreement is
entered, time 𝑡 = 0, rather than at time 𝑇.
𝑃
We use the notation 𝐹𝑡,𝑇 for the value at time 𝑡 of a prepaid forward
𝑃
settling at time 𝑇. Then 𝐹0,𝑇 = 𝑒 −𝑟𝑇 𝐹0,𝑇 .
𝑃
If the forward maturing at time 𝑇 is prepaid at time 𝑡, 𝐹𝑡,𝑇 = 𝑒 −𝑟(𝑇−𝑡) 𝐹𝑡,𝑇
𝑟𝑑 −𝑓𝑟 𝑇−𝑡
Currency, denominated 𝑥𝑡 𝑒 𝑥𝑡 𝑒 −𝑟𝑓 𝑇−𝑡
in currency 𝑑 for
delivery of currency 𝑓
𝑪 𝑲, 𝑻 − 𝑷 𝑲, 𝑻 = 𝑭𝑷
𝟎,𝑻 − 𝑲𝒆 −𝒓𝑻
𝑪 𝑲, 𝑻 − 𝑷 𝑲, 𝑻 = 𝑺𝟎 𝒆−𝜹𝑻 − 𝑲𝒆−𝒓𝑻
𝑪 𝑲, 𝑻 − 𝑷 𝑲, 𝑻 = 𝑺𝟎 𝒆−𝜹𝑻 − 𝑲𝒆−𝒓𝑻
𝑺𝟎 = (𝑪 𝑲, 𝑻 − 𝑷 𝑲, 𝑻 + 𝑲𝒆−𝒓𝑻 )𝒆𝜹𝑻
Suppose the price of a European call based on put-call parity is 𝐶, but the
price it is actually selling at is 𝐶 ′ < 𝐶. You would then buy the underpriced
call option and sell a synthesized call option. Since
𝑪 𝑺, 𝑲, 𝑻 = 𝑺𝟎 𝒆−𝜹𝑻 − 𝑲𝒆−𝒓𝑻 +𝑷 𝑺, 𝑲, 𝑻
You would sell the right hand side of this equation.
EXPIRATION
TRANSACTION TIME 0 𝑺𝑻 ≤ 𝑸𝑻 𝑺𝑻 > 𝑸𝑻
Buy call −𝐶 𝑆𝑡 , 𝑄𝑡 , 𝑇 − 𝑡 0 𝑆𝑇 − 𝑄𝑇
Sell put 𝑃 𝑆𝑡 , 𝑄𝑡 , 𝑇 − 𝑡 𝑆𝑇 − 𝑄𝑇 0
Sell prepaid forward on A 𝑃 −𝑆𝑇 −𝑆𝑇
𝐹𝑡,𝑇 (𝑆)
Buy prepaid forward on B 𝑃 𝑄𝑇 𝑄𝑇
−𝐹𝑡,𝑇 𝑄
TOTAL −𝑪 𝑺𝒕 , 𝑸𝒕 , 𝑻 − 𝒕 + 𝑷 𝑺𝒕 , 𝑸𝒕 , 𝑻 − 𝒕 + 𝑭𝑷 𝑷
𝒕,𝑻 𝑺 − 𝑭𝒕,𝑻 (𝑸) 𝟎 0
𝑢𝑆 𝐶𝑢
𝑆 𝐶
𝑑𝑆 𝐶𝑑
Value of replicating portfolio at time ℎ, with stock price 𝑆ℎ :
∆ × 𝑑𝑆 × 𝑒 𝛿ℎ + 𝐵 × 𝑒 𝑟ℎ = 𝐶𝑑
Solve for ∆ and 𝐵:
𝐶𝑢 − 𝐶𝑑
∆= 𝑒 −𝛿ℎ
𝑆(𝑢 − 𝑑)
𝑢𝐶𝑑 − 𝑑𝐶𝑢
𝐵= 𝑒 −𝑟ℎ
𝑢−𝑑
Ms Sarah Nadirah Mohd Johari, 2021
THE BINOMIAL SOLUTION
• Cost of creating the option is the net cash flow required to buy the
shares and bonds. Thus, the cost of the option is ∆𝑆 + 𝐵
𝑒 𝑟−𝛿 ℎ
−𝑑 𝑢 − 𝑒 𝑟−𝛿 ℎ
∆𝑆 + 𝐵 = 𝑒 −𝑟ℎ 𝐶𝑢 + 𝐶𝑑
𝑢−𝑑 𝑢−𝑑
• No –arbitrage condition:
𝑢>𝑒 𝑟−𝛿 ℎ >𝑑
𝑪 = 𝒆−𝒓𝒉 𝑪𝒖 𝒑∗ + 𝑪𝒅 𝟏 − 𝒑∗
𝑟−𝛿 ℎ+𝜎 ℎ
𝑢=𝑒
𝑟−𝛿 ℎ−𝜎 ℎ
𝑑=𝑒
𝑟𝑎𝑛𝑛𝑢𝑎𝑙 = 𝑟𝑚𝑜𝑛𝑡ℎ𝑙𝑦,𝑖
𝑖=1
2
𝜎 2 = 12 × 𝜎𝑚𝑜𝑛𝑡ℎ𝑙𝑦
𝜎
𝜎𝑚𝑜𝑛𝑡ℎ𝑙𝑦 =
12
𝜎ℎ = 𝜎 ℎ
𝜎ℎ
𝜎=
ℎ
𝑢𝑆𝑡 = 𝐹𝑡,𝑡+ℎ 𝑒 +𝜎 ℎ
𝑑𝑆𝑡 = 𝐹𝑡,𝑡+ℎ 𝑒 −𝜎 ℎ
𝑒 𝑟−𝛿 ℎ− 𝑑 𝑢 − 𝑒 𝑟−𝛿 ℎ
∆𝑆 + 𝐵 = 𝑒 −𝑟ℎ 𝐶𝑢 + 𝐶𝑑
𝑢−𝑑 𝑢−𝑑
• The value of the option if it is exercised is given by max 0, 𝑆 − 𝐾 if it is
a call and max(0, 𝐾 − 𝑆) if it is put.
• For an American put, the value of the option at a node is given by
𝑒 𝑟−𝛿 ℎ
−𝑑
𝑝∗ =
𝑢−𝑑
Then,
𝑟−𝛿 ℎ
𝑒 −𝑑 𝑢 − 𝑒 𝑟−𝛿 ℎ
∆𝑆 + 𝐵 = 𝑒 −𝑟ℎ 𝐶𝑢 + 𝐶𝑑
𝑢−𝑑 𝑢−𝑑
𝑪 = 𝒆−𝒓𝒉 𝑪𝒖 𝒑∗ + 𝑪𝒅 𝟏 − 𝒑∗
𝑒 𝛼ℎ − 𝑑
𝑝=
𝑢−𝑑
𝛾ℎ
𝑆∆ 𝛼ℎ
𝐵
𝑒 = 𝑒 + 𝑒 𝑟ℎ
𝑆∆ + 𝐵 𝑆∆ + 𝐵
𝐶𝑒 𝛾ℎ = 𝑆∆𝑒 𝛼ℎ + 𝐵𝑒 𝑟ℎ
𝑝𝐶𝑢 + 1 − 𝑝 𝐶𝑑
𝑍𝑛 = 𝑌𝑖
𝑖=1
• Turns out, the more times you flip, on average the farther you will move
from where you start.
𝑍𝑛 − 𝑍𝑛−1 = 𝑌𝑛
Or
𝐻𝑒𝑎𝑑𝑠: 𝑍𝑛 − 𝑍𝑛−1 = +1
𝑇𝑎𝑖𝑙𝑠: 𝑍𝑛 − 𝑍𝑛−1 = −1
𝑑 = 𝑒 −𝜎 ℎ
𝑆𝑡𝑢 𝐶𝑑 − 𝑆𝑡𝑑 𝐶𝑢
𝐵 = 𝑒 −𝑟ℎ − ∆𝐷𝑒 −𝑟ℎ
𝑆𝑡𝑢 − 𝑆𝑡𝑑
𝑑2 = 𝑑1 − 𝜎 𝑇
𝑑2 = 𝑑1 − 𝜎 𝑇
𝑑2 = 𝑑1 − 𝜎 𝑇
∆𝑝𝑜𝑟𝑡𝑓𝑜𝑙𝑖𝑜 = 𝜔𝑖 ∆𝑖
𝑖=1
𝜀∆
𝐶 𝑆∆
𝛺= 𝜀 =
𝐶
𝑆
Ms Sarah Nadirah Mohd Johari, 2021
EXAMPLE 5
For a European 3-month put option, you are given:
i) The price of the underlying stock is 40.
ii) The strike price is 38.
iii) The stock pays no dividends
iv) 𝜎 = 0.1
v) 𝑟 = 0.05
Calculate the elasticity of the put option
CALENDAR SPREADS
𝑋 𝑡 𝜇+0.5𝜎 2 𝑡
𝐸 =𝑒
𝑋 0
• It follows 𝜀 = 𝜇 + 0.5𝜎 2 .
• From GBM to ABM, subtract 0.5𝜎 2 if you wish to use the normal tables
to look up probabilities or percentiles.
𝑑𝑆 𝑡
= 0.15𝑑𝑡 + 0.20𝑑𝑍(𝑡)
𝑆 𝑡
Given that 𝑆 9 = 40, calculate the probability that 40 < 𝑆 13 < 50.
𝑑𝑆 𝑡
= 𝛼𝑑𝑡 + 𝜎𝑑𝑍(𝑡)
𝑆 𝑡
𝑋(𝑡) = 𝛼𝑡 + 𝜎𝑍(𝑡)
𝑑𝑋 𝑡
= 𝜀𝑑𝑡 + 𝜎𝑑𝑍(𝑡)
𝑋 𝑡
Calculate 𝑑 ln 𝑋 𝑡 using Ito’s lemma.
EXAMPLE 21
The process 𝑋 𝑡 = 𝑍 𝑡 3 + 𝑐𝑡𝑍(𝑡) is a martingale.
Determine 𝑐.
Chapter 6.1
The Lognormal Distribution
The Normal Distribution
1 x − 2
1 −
• Normal distribution (or density) ( x; , ) 2
e
2
The Normal Distribution (cont’d)
yv 2
• If x ~ N(m,v2), then
1
m+ v 2
E (e ) = e
x 2
Var(e ) = e
x 2 m+v 2
( e −1)
v2
The Lognormal Distribution
(cont’d)
A Lognormal Model of Stock
Prices
• If the stock price St is lognormal, then St / S0 = ex,
where x, the continuously compounded return from
0 to t, is normally distributed
• If R(t, s) is the continuously compounded return
from t to s, and, t0 < t1 < t2, then R(t0, t2) = R(t0,
t1) + R(t1, t2)
• From 0 to T, E[R(0,T)] = nah , and Var[R(0,T)] =
nh2
• If returns are i.i.d., the mean and variance of the
continuously compounded returns are proportional
to time
A Lognormal Model of
Stock Prices (cont’d)
• If we assume that
ln(St / S0 ) ~ N[(a − − 0.5 2 )t , 2t ]
then ln( St / S0 ) = (a − − 12 2 )t + tZ
(a − − 2 ) t + tZ
1
and therefore St = S0e 2
1 1
(a − − 2 ) t + t N −1 ( p /2) (a − − 2 ) t − t N −1 ( p /2)
StL = S0e 2
StU = S0e 2
Lognormal Probability
Calculations (cont’d)
= 0.038208 52 = 0.2755
• Annualized expected return
Chapter 6.2
Monte Carlo Valuation
Monte Carlo Valuation
n
n!
European Call Price = e − rT
max[0, Su n−i d i − K ]( p*)n−1(1 − p*)i
i =1 (n − i )!i !
Computing the Option Price As a
Discounted Expected Value (cont’d)
Computing the Option Price As a
Discounted Expected Value (cont’d)
Computing Random Numbers
e − l t (l t ) i
m
P(m, lt ) = Pr( x m; lt ) =
i =0 i!
The Poisson Distribution (cont’d)
e
where J and J are the mean and standard deviation of the
jump and Z and Wi are random standard normal variables
Chapter 6.1
Brownian Motion and Itô’s Lemma
Introduction
• Then
dZ (t ) = Y (t ) dt
(20.4)
where Y(t) is a random draw from a binomial
distribution, such that Y(t) is 1 with probability
50%
dX (t ) = dt + dZ (t ) (20.8)
• This process is called arithmetic Brownian
motion
– is the instantaneous mean per unit time
– 2 is the instantaneous variance per unit time
– The variable X(t) is the sum of the individual changes dX.
X(t) is normally distributed, i.e., X(T) – X(0) ~ N (T, 2T)
Arithmetic Brownian Motion
(cont’d)
• An integral representation of equation (20.8) is
T T
X (T ) = X (0) + dt + dZ (t )
0 0
• Here are some properties of the process in equation
(20.8)
– X(t) is normally distributed because it is a scaled Brownian
process
– The random term is multiplied by a scale factor that
enables us to specify the variance of the process
– The dt term introduces a nonrandom drift into
the process
Arithmetic Brownian Motion
(cont’d)
dX (t ) = X (t ) dt + X (t )dZ (t )
– This is an Itô process that can also be written
dX (t )
= a dt + dZ (t ) (20.11)
X (t )
– This process is known as geometric Brownian motion
Geometric Brownian Motion
(cont’d)
T T
X (T ) − X (0) = X (t )dt + X (t )dZ (t )
0 0
Lognormality
2 i =1 j =1
n
1 1 n n
E[dC ( S1, . . ., Sn , t )] = i SiCSi + i j ij Si S jCSi S j + Ct
dt i =1 2 i=1 j =1
The Sharpe Ratio
αi − r
Sharpe ratio i = (20.25)
i
The Sharpe Ratio (cont’d)
(1 − r) / 1 = ( 2 − r) / 2
Risk-Neutral Valuation
• Proposition 20.3:
– Using equation 18.13 to compute the expectation of a
lognormal variable
− rT − rT a [ a ( r − )+0.5 a ( a −1) 2 ]T
e E[ S (T ) ] = e
a
S (0) e
– The value at time 0 of a claim paying S(T)a—the prepaid
forward price—is
1
[ a ( r − ) + a ( a −1) 2 ]T
F0P,T [ S (T ) a ] = e −rT S (0) e a 2
(20.32)
– The forward price for S(T)a is
1
[ a ( r − ) + a ( a −1) 2 ]T
F0,T [ S (T ) a ] = S (0) e a 2
(20.33)
Valuing a Claim on Sa (cont’d)
• Claims on S
– Suppose a = 1. Equation (20.32) then gives us
V (0) = S (0)e −T
• This is the prepaid forward price on a stock
• Claims on S0
– If a = 0, the claim does not depend on the stock
price. Since S0 = 1, it is a bond. Setting a = 0
gives us
V (0) = e − rT
• Claims on S2
– When a = 2, the claim pays S(T)2. From equation
(20.33), the forward price is
−[ − r + 2 − 2 ]T
F0,T ( S ) = e S (0) e
2 rT 2
2 ( r − )T 2T 2 2T
= S (0) e
2
e = [ F0,T ( S )] e
(20.35)
– Thus, the forward price on the squared stock
price is the squared forward price times a
variance term
Examples (cont’d)
• Claims on 1/S
– If a = –1, the claim pays 1/S. Using equation
(20.33), we get
( − r )T 2T −1 2T
F0,T (1 / S ) = [1 / S (0)]e e =F
0 ,T e
• As with the squared security, the forward price is
increasing in volatility
– The payoffs for both the S2 and 1/S securities
are convex. Therefore, according to Jensen’s
inequality, the price is higher when the asset
price is risky than when it is certain.
Valuing a Claim on Saqb
dS
= (r − S )dt + S dZ S (20.36)
S
and Q follows
dQ
= (r − Q )dt + Q dZQ
Q (20.37)
• Proposition 20.4
– Suppose that the forward prices for Sa and Qb
are given by Proposition 20.3. Then the forward
price for SaQb is
ab S Q (T −t )
Ft ,T ( S aQb ) = Ft ,T (S a ) Ft ,T (Qb )e
• The forward price for SaQb is the product of those two
forward prices times a factor that accounts for the
covariance between the two assets
a 2 S2 + b 2 Q2 + 2ab S Q
Valuing a Claim on Saqb (cont’d)
ab S Q = 2
S
• Proposition 20.5
– Suppose an asset follows equation (20.42). If
C(S, t) is a twice continuously differentiable
function of the stock price, the process followed
by C is
1
dC(S , t ) = CS dS + CSS 2 S 2 dt + Ct dt + EY [C ( SY , t ) − C (S , t )]
2
(20.43)
• The last term in the equation is the expected change in
the option price conditional on the jump times the
probability of the jump.
ASC637
FINANCIAL RISK MANAGEMENT
Chapter 7
Value at Risk
Introduction
S h = S 0 (1 + z h ) (26.8)
1 n
1 n n
Rh ~ N hW i i, 2 i j ij
hWW
i j
(26.9)
W i =1 W i =1 j =1
Var for Nonlinear Portfolios
W i=1 j =1 (26.11)
• Example 26.6
– Consider the 1-week 95% value at risk of an at-
the-money written straddle on 100,000 shares of
a single stock
– Assume that S = $100, K = $100, = 30%, r =
8%, T = 30 days, and = 0
– The initial value of the straddle is −$685,776
Monte Carlo Simulation (cont’d)
( − −0.5 2 ) h + h z
S h = S0e (26.13)
11,173.59
Example of Calculation: 11,022.06 = 10,977.08
11,219.38
n n
= covij a i a j
2
P
i =1 j =1
2P = α T Cα
P S d
i
i i xi
Asset Price
Asset Price
Short
Call
Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 8th Edition,
Copyright © John C. Hull 2012 35
Quadratic Model
2
this becomes
1 2
P = Sd x + S (x) 2
Chapter 8
Credit Risk
1
Credit Ratings
In the S&P rating system, AAA is the best
rating. After that comes AA, A, BBB, BB, B,
CCC, CC, and C
The corresponding Moody’s ratings are Aaa,
Aa, A, Baa, Ba, B,Caa, Ca, and C
Bonds with ratings of BBB (or Baa) and
above are considered to be “investment
grade”
2
Historical Data
Historical data provided by rating agencies
are also used to estimate the probability of
default
3
Cumulative Ave Default Rates (%)
(1970-2009, Moody’s, Table 23.1, page 522)
1 2 3 4 5 7 10
Aaa 0.000 0.012 0.012 0.037 0.105 0.245 0.497
Aa 0.022 0.059 0.091 0.159 0.234 0.384 0.542
A 0.051 0.165 0.341 0.520 0.717 1.179 2.046
Baa 0.176 0.494 0.912 1.404 1.926 2.996 4.851
Ba 1.166 3.186 5.583 8.123 10.397 14.318 19.964
B 4.546 10.426 16.188 21.256 25.895 34.473 44.377
Caa-C 17.723 29.384 38.682 46.094 52.286 59.771 71.376
4
Interpretation
The table shows the probability of default
for companies starting with a particular
credit rating
A company with an initial credit rating of
Baa has a probability of 0.176% of
defaulting by the end of the first year,
0.494% by the end of the second year, and
so on
5
Do Default Probabilities Increase
with Time?
6
Hazard Rates vs Unconditional Default
Probabilities (page 522-523)
The hazard rate (also called default intensity) is the
probability of default for a certain time period
conditional on no earlier default
The unconditional default probability is the probability
of default for a certain time period as seen at time
zero
What are the default intensities and unconditional
default probabilities for a Caa rated company in the
third year?
7
Hazard Rate
The hazard rate that is usually quoted is an
instantaneous rate
If V(t) is the probability of a company surviving to time
t
V (t + t ) − V (t ) = −(t )V (t )
This leads to
t
V (t ) = e 0
− ( t ) dt
8
Recovery Rate
The recovery rate for a bond is usually
defined as the price of the bond immediately
after default as a percent of its face value
Recovery rates tend to decrease as default
rates increase
9
Recovery Rates; Moody’s: 1982 to 2009
Class Mean(%)
1st lien bank loan 65.6
Subordinated 31.3
10
Estimating Default Probabilities
Alternatives:
Use Bond Prices
Use CDS spreads
Use Historical Data
Use Merton’s Model
11
Using Bond Prices (Equation 23.2,
page 524)
13
Calculations (Table 23.3, page 525)
Time Def Recovery Risk-free Loss given Discount PV of Exp
(yrs) Prob Amount Value Default Factor Loss
0.5 Q 40 106.73 66.73 0.9753 65.08Q
Total 288.48Q
14
Calculations continued
We set 288.48Q = 8.75 to get Q = 3.03%
This analysis can be extended to allow
defaults to take place more frequently
With several bonds we can use more
parameters to describe the default probability
distribution
15
The Risk-Free Rate
The risk-free rate when default probabilities
are estimated is usually assumed to be the
LIBOR/swap zero rate (or sometimes 10 bps
below the LIBOR/swap rate)
Asset swaps provide a direct estimates of the
spread of bond yields over swap rates
16
Real World vs Risk-Neutral Default
Probabilities
17
A Comparison
Calculate 7-year default intensities from the
Moody’s data, 1970-2009, (These are real
world default probabilities)
Use Merrill Lynch data to estimate average 7-
year default intensities from bond prices,
1996 to 2007 (these are risk-neutral default
intensities)
Assume a risk-free rate equal to the 7-year
swap rate minus 10 basis points
18
Data from Moody’s and Merrill Lynch
Cumulative 7-year default Average bond yield spread in bps *
probability (Moody’s: 1970-2009) (Merrill Lynch: 1996 to June 2007)
19
Real World vs Risk Neutral Hazard
Rates (Table 23.4, page 527)
Rating Historical hazard rate1 Hazard rate from bond Ratio Difference
% per annum prices2 (% per annum)
Aaa 0.04 0.60 17.0 0.56
Aa 0.05 0.73 13.2 0.67
A 0.17 1.15 6.8 0.98
Baa 0.43 2.13 4.9 1.69
Ba 2.21 4.67 2.1 2.46
B 6.04 8.02 1.3 1.98
Caa 13.01 18.39 1.4 5.39
1 Calculated as−[ln(1-d)]/7 where d is the Moody’s 7 yr default rate. For example, in the
case of Aaa companies, d=0.00245 and -ln(0.99755)/7=0.0004 or 4bps. For investment
grade companies the historical hazard rate is approximately d/7.
2 Calculated as s/(1-R) where s is the bond yield spread and R is the recovery rate
(assumed to be 40%).
20
Average Risk Premiums Earned
By Bond Traders
Rating Bond Yield Spread of risk-free Spread to Extra Risk
Spread over rate over Treasuries compensate for Premium
Treasuries (bps)1 historical default (bps)
(bps) rate (bps)2
Aaa 78 42 2 34
Aa 86 42 3 41
A 111 42 10 59
Baa 169 42 26 101
Ba 322 42 132 148
B 523 42 362 119
Caa 1146 42 781 323
1Equals average spread of our benchmark risk-free rate over
Treasuries.
2Equals historical hazard rate times (1-R) where R is the recovery rate.
For example, in the case of Baa, 26bps is 0.6 times 43bps.
21
Possible Reasons for These
Results (The third reason is the most important)
Corporate bonds are relatively illiquid
The subjective default probabilities of bond traders
may be much higher than the estimates from
Moody’s historical data
Bonds do not default independently of each
other. This leads to systematic risk that cannot be
diversified away.
Bond returns are highly skewed with limited upside.
The non-systematic risk is difficult to diversify away
and may be priced by the market
22
Which World Should We Use?
We should use risk-neutral estimates for
valuing credit derivatives and estimating the
present value of the cost of default
We should use real world estimates for
calculating credit VaR and scenario analysis
23
Using Equity Prices: Merton’s
Model (page 530-531)
Merton’s model regards the equity as an
option on the assets of the firm
In a simple situation the equity value is
max(VT −D, 0)
where VT is the value of the firm and D is the
debt repayment required
24
Equity vs. Assets
The Black-Scholes-Merton option pricing
model enables the value of the firm’s equity
today, E0, to be related to the value of its
assets today, V0, and the volatility of its
assets, sV
E 0 = V0 N (d 1 ) − De − rT N (d 2 )
where
ln (V0 D) + (r + sV2 2)T
d1 = ; d 2 = d 1 − sV T
sV T
25
Volatilities
E
s E E0 = sV V0 = N (d1 )sV V0
V
26
Example
A company’s equity is $3 million and the
volatility of the equity is 80%
The risk-free rate is 5%, the debt is $10
million and time to debt maturity is 1 year
Solving the two equations yields V0=12.40
and sv=21.23%
The probability of default is N(−d2) or 12.7%
27
The Implementation of Merton’s
Model
Choose time horizon
Calculate cumulative obligations to time horizon. This is
termed by KMV the “default point”. We denote it by D
Use Merton’s model to calculate a theoretical probability
of default
Use historical data or bond data to develop a one-to-one
mapping of theoretical probability into either real-world or
risk-neutral probability of default.
28
Credit Risk in Derivatives
Transactions (page 531-534)
Three cases
Contract always an asset
Contract always a liability
Contract can be an asset or a liability
29
General Result
Assume that default probability is independent of
the value of the derivative
Define
t1, t2,…tn: times when default can occur
qi: default probability at time ti.
fi: The value of the transaction at time ti
R: Recovery rate
30
General Result continued
The expected loss from defaults at time ti is
qi(1−R)E[max(fi,0)].
Defining ui=qi(1−R) and vi as the value of a
derivative that provides a payoff of max(fi,0) at
time ti, the PV of the cost of defaults is
n
Credit Value Adjustmen t (CVA) = u v
i =1
i i
31
Applications
If transaction is always an asset so that fi > 0
then vi = f0 and the cost of defaults
n
is f0 times
the total default probability, qi times 1−R
i =1
If transaction is always a liability then vi= 0
and the cost of defaults is zero
In other cases we must value the derivative
max(fi,0) for each value of i
32
Using Bond Yields for Instruments
in the First Category
All instruments that promise a (non-negative) payoff at time T
should be reduced in price by the same amount for default risk
f 0* B0*
=
f 0 B0
so that
− ( y * − y )T
f 0* = f0e
where f0 and f0* are the no-default and actual values of the
instrument; B0 and B0* are the no-default and actual values of a
zero-coupon bond maturing at time T; y and y* are the yields on
these zero coupon bonds
33
Example
A 2-year option has a Black-Scholes value of
$3
Assume a 2 year zero coupon bond issued by
the company has a yield of 1.5% greater than
the risk free rate
Value of option is 3e−0.015×2 = 2.91
34
Expected Exposure on Pair of Offsetting
Interest Rate Swaps and a Pair of
Offsetting Currency Swaps
Exposure
Currency
swaps
Interest Rate
Swaps
Maturity
35
Interest Rate vs Currency Swaps
The ui’s are the same for both
The vi’s for an interest rate swap are on
average much less than the vi’s for a currency
swap
The expected cost of defaults on a currency
swap is therefore greater.
36
Credit Risk Mitigation
Netting
Collateralization
Downgrade triggers
37
Netting
Suppose a bank has three transactions worth
of $10 million, $30 million, and −$25 million
Without netting the exposure is $40 million
With netting the exposure is $15 million
38
Collateralization
Transactions are marked to market
periodically (e.g. every day)
If total value of transactions Party A has with
party B is above a specified threshold level it
can ask Party B to post collateral equal to the
excess of the value over the threshold level
After that collateral can be withdrawn or must
be increased by Party B depending on
whether value of transactions to Party A
decreases or increases
39
Downgrade Triggers
A downgrade trigger is a clause stating that a
transaction can be closed out by Party A when
the credit rating of the other side, Party B, falls
below a certain level
In practice Party A will only close out
transactions that have a negative value to Party
B
When there are a large number of downgrade
triggers they are likely to be counterproductive
40
Default Correlation
The credit default correlation between two
companies is a measure of their tendency to
default at about the same time
Default correlation is important in risk
management when analyzing the benefits of
credit risk diversification
It is also important in the valuation of some
credit derivatives, eg a first-to-default CDS
and CDO tranches.
41
Measurement
There is no generally accepted measure of
default correlation
Default correlation is a more complex
phenomenon than the correlation between
two random variables
42
Survival Time Correlation
Define ti as the time to default for company i
and Qi(ti) as the probability distribution for ti
The default correlation between companies i
and j can be defined as the correlation
between ti and tj
But this does not uniquely define the joint
probability distribution of default times
43
Gaussian Copula Model (page 538-540)
• Define a one-to-one correspondence between the
time to default, ti, of company i and a variable xi by
Qi(ti ) = N(xi ) or xi = N-1[Q(ti)]
where N is the cumulative normal distribution
function.
• This is a “percentile to percentile” transformation. The
p percentile point of the Qi distribution is transformed
to the p percentile point of the xi distribution. xi has a
standard normal distribution
• We assume that the xi are multivariate normal. The
default correlation measure, rij between companies i
and j is the correlation between xi and xj
44
Example of Use of Gaussian Copula
(Example 23.3, page 539)
45
Use of Gaussian Copula continued
We sample from a multivariate normal
distribution to get the xi
Critical values of xi are
N -1(0.01) = -2.33, N -1(0.03) = -1.88,
N -1(0.06) = -1.55, N -1(0.10) = -1.28,
N -1(0.15) = -1.04
46
Use of Gaussian Copula continued
When sample for a company is less than
-2.33, the company defaults in the first year
When sample is between -2.33 and -1.88, the
company defaults in the second year
When sample is between -1.88 and -1.55, the
company defaults in the third year
When sample is between -1,55 and -1.28, the
company defaults in the fourth year
When sample is between -1.28 and -1.04, the
company defaults during the fifth year
When sample is greater than -1.04, there is no
default during the first five years
47
A One-Factor Model for the
Correlation Structure
xi = ai F + 1− ai2 Z i
The correlation between xi and xj is aiaj
The ith company defaults by time T when
xi < N-1[Qi(T)] or
N −1[Qi (T ) − ai F ]
Zi
1 − ai2
48
Credit VaR (page 540-542)
49
Calculation from a Factor-Based
Gaussian Copula Model (equation 23.13, page
540)
Consider a large portfolio of loans, each of which has
a probability of Q(T) of defaulting by time T. Suppose
that all pairwise copula correlations are r so that all
ai’s are r
We are X% certain that F is less than
N−1(1−X) = −N−1(X)
It follows that the VaR is
N Q(T ) + r N ( X )
−1 −1
V ( X ,T ) = N
1 − r
50
Example (page 541)
A bank has $100 million of retail exposures
1-year probability of default averages 2% and the
recovery rate averages 60%
The copula correlation parameter is 0.1
99.9% worst case default rate is
N −1 (0.02) + 0.1N −1 (0.999 )
V (0.999 ,1) = N = 0.128
1 − 0.1
The one-year 99.9% credit VaR is therefore
100×0.128×(1-0.6) or $5.13 million
51
CreditMetrics (page 541-542)
Calculates credit VaR by considering possible
rating transitions
A Gaussian copula model is used to define
the correlation between the ratings transitions
of different companies