Ang Cole Lin Agency-Costs-and-Ownership JF 2000
Ang Cole Lin Agency-Costs-and-Ownership JF 2000
Ang Cole Lin Agency-Costs-and-Ownership JF 2000
net/publication/2510694
CITATIONS READS
1,670 15,990
3 authors, including:
Some of the authors of this publication are also working on these related projects:
All content following this page was uploaded by Rebel Allen Cole on 06 December 2017.
ABSTRACT
We provide measures of absolute and relative equity agency costs for corporations
under different ownership and management structures. Our base case is Jensen
and Meckling’s ~1976! zero agency-cost firm, where the manager is the firm’s sole
shareholder. We utilize a sample of 1,708 small corporations from the FRB0NSSBF
database and find that agency costs ~i! are significantly higher when an outsider
rather than an insider manages the firm; ~ii! are inversely related to the manag-
er’s ownership share; ~iii! increase with the number of nonmanager shareholders,
and ~iv! to a lesser extent, are lower with greater monitoring by banks.
THE SOCIAL AND PRIVATE COSTS OF AN AGENT’S ACTIONS due to incomplete align-
ment of the agent’s and owner’s interests were brought to attention by the
seminal contributions of Jensen and Meckling ~1976! on agency costs. Agency
theory has also brought the roles of managerial decision rights and various
external and internal monitoring and bonding mechanisms to the forefront
of theoretical discussions and empirical research. Great strides have been
made in demonstrating empirically the role of agency costs in financial de-
cisions, such as in explaining the choices of capital structure, maturity struc-
ture, dividend policy, and executive compensation. However, the actual
measurement of the principal variable of interest, agency costs, in both ab-
solute and relative terms, has lagged behind.
To measure absolute agency costs, a zero agency-cost base case must be
observed to serve as the reference point of comparison for all other cases of
ownership and management structures. In the original Jensen and Meckling
agency theory, the zero agency-cost base case is, by definition, the firm owned
solely by a single owner-manager. When management owns less than 100
percent of the firm’s equity, shareholders incur agency costs resulting from
management’s shirking and perquisite consumption. Because of limitations
imposed by personal wealth constraints, exchange regulations on the mini-
mum numbers of shareholders, and other considerations, no publicly traded
firm is entirely owned by management. Thus, Jensen and Meckling’s zero
agency cost base case cannot be found among the usual sample of publicly
* Ang is from Florida State University; Cole is from The University of Auckland, New Zea-
land; and Lin is from Montana State University. We appreciate the comments of David Mauer,
Michael Long, René Stulz ~the editor!, and an anonymous referee.
81
82 The Journal of Finance
traded firms for which information is readily available. The absence of in-
formation about sole owner-manager firms explains why agency costs are
often inferred but not directly measured in the empirical finance literature.
No-agency-cost base case f irms, however, can be found among non–
publicly traded firms. Until recently, data on non–publicly traded firms, which
tend to be much smaller than their publicly traded counterparts, have been
sparse. In 1997, the Federal Reserve Board released its National Survey of
Small Business Finances ~NSSBF!, which collected data from a nationally
representative sample of small businesses. Data from the NSSBF enable us
to analyze the relationship between agency costs and ownership structure
because the survey provides financial data on a group of firms whose man-
agement owns 100 percent of equity. These firms enable us to estimate the
expected expense for the no-outside-equity agency-cost base case. Further-
more, the database includes firms with a wide range of ownership and
manager0owner structures, including firms owned by two individuals as well
as firms managed by outsiders with no equity stake. As a consequence, small
firms appear well suited for a study of equity-related agency costs.
We use two alternative measures of agency costs. The first is direct agency
costs, calculated as the difference in dollar expenses between a firm with a
certain ownership and management structure and the no-agency-cost base
case firm. This measure captures excessive expenses including perk con-
sumption. To facilitate cross-sectional comparisons, we standardize expenses
by annual sales. Our second measure of agency costs is a proxy for the loss
in revenues attributable to inefficient asset utilization, which can result
from poor investment decisions ~e.g., investing in negative net-present-value
assets! or from management’s shirking ~e.g., exerting too little effort to help
generate revenue!. This second measure of agency costs is calculated as the
ratio of annual sales to total assets, an efficiency ratio. We can then mea-
sure agency costs as the difference in the efficiency ratio, or, equivalently,
the dollar revenues lost, between a firm whose manager is the sole equity
owner and a firm whose manager owns less than 100 percent of equity.
Monitoring of managers’ expenditures on perquisites and other personal
consumption relies on the vigilance of the nonmanaging shareholders and0or
related third parties, such as the company’s bankers. The lack of specific
operational knowledge on the part of nonmanaging shareholders, and the
lack of an external market for shares, however, may offset the presence of
dominant shareholders. Additionally, heavy reliance of the non–publicly traded
firms on bank financing could give banks a special role in delegated moni-
toring on behalf of other shareholders. Thus, it would seem that determina-
tion of the size of agency costs for these firms is an empirical issue.
Our results provide direct confirmation of the predictions made by Jensen
and Meckling ~1976!. Agency costs are indeed higher among firms that are
not 100 percent owned by their managers, and these costs increase as the
equity share of the owner-manager declines. Hence, agency costs increase
with a reduction in managerial ownership, as predicted by Jensen and Meck-
ling. These results hold true after controlling for differences across indus-
Agency Costs and Ownership Structure 83
II. Data
Our empirical approach utilizes two fundamental assumptions about agency
costs: ~1! A firm managed by a 100 percent owner incurs zero agency costs and,
~2! agency costs can be measured as the difference in the efficiency of an im-
perfectly aligned firm and the efficiency of a perfectly aligned firm. To opera-
1
Theoretical support for the null hypothesis is due to Demsetz ~1983!, who suggests that the
sum of amenities for on-the-job consumption and take-home pay for similar quality managers is
the same for both high-cost and low-cost monitoring organizations. The proportion paid to the
managers, however, differs according to the cost of monitoring. Here, it would seem that total
operating expense, which include direct pay to the managers as well as perks and firm level
monitoring cost, is the appropriate measure to test the hypothesis.
Agency Costs and Ownership Structure 85
tionalize this approach for measuring agency costs, we need certain data inputs:
~i! data on firm efficiency measures; ~ii! data on firm ownership structure, in-
cluding a set of firms that are 100 percent owned by managers; and ~iii! data on
control variables, including firm size, characteristics, and monitoring technology.
Of these data requirements, the most demanding in terms of availability
is item ~ii! because sole-ownership firms typically are not publicly listed, and
because financial information on U.S. private firms usually is not available
to the public. The Federal Reserve Board’s National Survey of Small Busi-
ness Finances ~NSSBF!, fortunately, does provide financial information about
privately held firms, including their ownership structure, and does include a
set of firms entirely owned by managers. Consequently, we use data from
the NSSBF to measure agency costs.2
The NSSBF is a survey conducted by the Federal Reserve Board to gather
information about small businesses, which have largely been ignored in the
academic literature because of the limited availability of data. The survey
collected detailed information from a sample of 4,637 firms that is broadly
representative of approximately 5 million small nonfarm, nonfinancial busi-
nesses operating in the United States as of year-end 1992. Cole and Wolken
~1995! provide detailed information about the data available from NSSBF.
For this study, we limit our analysis to small C-corporations, collecting
information on the governance structure, management alignment, extent of
shareholder and external monitoring, size, and financial information. We
focus on corporations to minimize problems associated with the financial
statements of proprietorships, which typically commingle personal and busi-
ness funds. We eliminate partnerships and S-corporations because, unlike
C-corporations, they are not subject to corporate taxation, and this may lead
owner-managers to take compensation in the form of partner distributions
or dividends rather than salary expense because there is no double taxation
of such earnings at the firm level. By focusing solely on C-corporations, we
avoid the complications of comparing operating expenses across organiza-
tional forms. This restriction on the NSSBF database yields an analysis
sample of 1,708 firms.3
A. Agency Costs
To measure agency costs of the firm, we use two alternative efficiency
ratios that frequently appear in the accounting and financial economics
literature: the expense ratio, which is operating expense scaled by annual
2
Data from the NSSBF yield significant and interesting results that appear in several re-
cent published papers. See the studies on banking relationships and credit markets by Petersen
and Rajan ~1994, 1995, 1997!, Berger and Udell ~1995!, and Cole ~1998!.
3
The staff at the Federal Reserve Board partially edited the financial statement items for
violations of accounting rules, such as when gross profit is not equal to sales less cost of goods
sold, and some improbable events such as when accounts receivable are greater than sales, or
cost of goods sold equals inventory.
86 The Journal of Finance
sales,4 and the asset utilization ratio, which is annual sales divided by total
assets. The first ratio is a measure of how effectively the firm’s management
controls operating costs, including excessive perquisite consumption, and other
direct agency costs. More precisely, the difference in the ratios of a firm with
a certain ownership and management structure and the no-agency-cost base
case firm, multiplied by the assets of the former, gives the excess agency
cost related expense in dollars.
The second ratio is a measure of how effectively the firm’s management
deploys its assets. In contrast to the expense ratio, agency costs are in-
versely related to the sales-to-asset ratio. A firm whose sales-to-asset ratio is
lower than the base case firm experiences positive agency cost. These costs
arise because the manager acts in some or all of the following ways: makes
poor investment decisions, exerts insufficient effort, resulting in lower rev-
enues; consumes executive perquisites, so that the firm purchases unpro-
ductive assets, such as excessively fancy office space, office furnishing,
automobiles, and resort properties.
These efficiency ratios are not measured without error. Sources of mea-
surement error include differences in the accounting methods chosen with
respect to the recognition and timing of revenues and costs, poor record-
keeping typical of small businesses, and the tendency of small-business own-
ers to exercise f lexibility with respect to certain cost items. For example,
owners may raise0lower expenses, including their own pay, when profits are
high0low. Fortunately, these items are sources of random measurement er-
rors that may be reduced with a larger sample across firms in different
industries and age.
B. Ownership Structure
The corporate form of organization, with the limited-liability provision that
makes it more efficient for risk-sharing than proprietorships or partner-
ships, allows the firm to expand and raise funds from a large number of
investors.5 Thus, it has a richer set of ownership and management struc-
tures. The NSSBF provides four variables that we use to capture various
4
Operating expenses are defined as total expenses less cost of goods sold, interest expense,
and managerial compensation. Excessive expense on perks and other nonessentials should be
ref lected in the operating expenses. Strictly speaking, agency costs that are measured by this
ratio are those incurred at the firm level ~i.e., shirking and perquisite consumption by the
managers!. This may underestimate total agency costs since this ratio does not fully measure
firm-level indirect agency costs, such as the distortion of operating decisions due to agency
problems. ~See Mello and Parsons ~1992! for an attempt to measure such costs in the presence
of debt.! Nor does it measure off-income-statement agency costs, such as the private monitoring
costs by the nonmanagement shareholders or the private costs of bonding incurred by the manager.
5
Manne ~1967! and Alchian and Demsetz ~1972! agree that limited liability is an attractive
feature of the corporate form of organization. Jensen and Meckling ~1976! point out that al-
though unlimited liability gives more incentive for each shareholder to monitor, in the aggre-
gate it leads to excessive monitoring. Thus, it may be more economical to offer a single high
premium to creditors to bear risk of nonpayment and, thus, monitoring in exchange for limited
liability.
Agency Costs and Ownership Structure 87
6
Technically, the survey does not provide a variable for the number of nonmanager share-
holders. Rather, we define this variable as the number of shareholders for firms that have an
outside manager and as the number of shareholders less one for firms that have an insider
manager.
7
This formulation recognizes the unequal and diminishing role of additional shareholders,
and the problem of undefined zero when there is no other shareholder.
88 The Journal of Finance
~1994!, Berger and Udell ~1995!, and Cole ~1998! argue and present evidence
that firm-creditor relationships generate valuable information about bor-
rower quality.
Because banks generally require a firm’s managers to report results hon-
estly and to run the business efficiently with profit, bank monitoring com-
plements shareholder monitoring of managers, indirectly reducing owner-
manager agency costs. That is, by incurring monitoring costs to safeguard
their loans, banks lead firms to operate more efficiently by better utilizing
assets and moderating perquisite consumption in order to improve the firm’s
reported financial performance to the bank. Thus, lower priority claimants,
such as outside shareholders, should realize a positive externality from bank
monitoring, in the form of lower agency costs. Additionally, local bankers’
ability to acquire knowledge concerning the firms from various local sources,
such as churches, social gatherings, and interactions with the firm’s cus-
tomers and suppliers, makes them especially good monitors. We use two
variables to represent bankers’ incentive, cost, and ability to monitor: the
number of banks used by the firm and the length of the firm’s longest bank-
ing relationship.8
The bank’s cost of monitoring is proxied by the number of banks from
which the firm obtains financial services. The incentive for each bank to
monitor may decrease as the number of banks with which the firm deals
increases ~Diamond ~1984!!. Part of the reduced incentive to monitor is due
to a form of lenders’ free-rider problems, and part is due to the shorter
expected length of banking relationships when there is a greater perceived
likelihood of the firm switching its banking business between banks.
The bank’s ability to monitor is proxied by the length of a firm’s relation-
ship with its primary bank. A longer relationship enables the bank to gen-
erate information about the firm that is useful in deciding its creditworthiness
~Diamond ~1984!!. Both Petersen and Rajan ~1994! and Cole ~1998! find that
longer relationships improve the availability of credit to small firms while
Berger and Udell ~1995! find that longer relationships improve the terms of
credit available to small firms.
The bank’s incentive to monitor is proxied by the firm’s debt-to-asset ratio.
Because our sample consists entirely of small businesses, virtually all of the
firm’s debt is private rather than public, and the majority of this debt is in
the form of bank loans. As leverage increases, so does the risk of default by
the firm, hence the incentive for the lender to monitor the firm. While the
primary purpose of this monitoring is to prevent risk-shifting by sharehold-
ers to debtholders, increased monitoring should also inhibit excessive per-
quisite consumption by managers. ~Most of the sample firms’ nonbank debt
8
These are also the same governance variables used by Berger and Udell ~1995! and Cole
~1998! in their studies of banking relationship. However, none of their variables, except for the
corporate form dummy, are found to significantly affect either the loan term or the use of
collateral.
Agency Costs and Ownership Structure 89
Figure 1. Operating expense-to-sales ratio by one-digit SIC for a sample of 1,708 small
corporations.
is in the form of loans from finance companies and other nonbank private
lenders, who also have greater incentive to monitor the firm as leverage
increases.!
D. Control Variables
We realize that the length of banking relationship variable may be corre-
lated with firm age, which in turn could be related to a firm’s efficiency. Due
to the effects of learning curve and survival bias, older firms are likely to be
more efficient than younger ones and, especially, than start-up firms. Hence,
we include firm age as a control variable in all our tests involving the vari-
able measuring the length of the firm’s relationship with its primary bank.
Both of our efficiency ratios vary widely across industries because of the
varying importance of inventory and fixed assets. Figure 1 shows the ratio
of operating expenses to sales by one-digit SIC. These ratios vary from a low
of 0.39 for construction and manufacturing to a high of 0.65 for finance and
real estate and professional services. Figure 2 shows the ratio of annual
sales to total assets by one-digit SIC. This efficiency ratio ranges from 3.6
for manufacturing to 6.2 for professional services. Hence, these figures un-
derscore the importance of controlling for differences across industries in
our analysis of agency costs. We do this by including a set of 35 dummy
variables, one for each two-digit SIC that accounts for more than one per-
cent of our sample of firms.
Small firms such as those surveyed by the NSSBF seem likely to realize
scale economies in operating expenses ~e.g.,overhead items!. Thus, there is a
need to control for firm size. This adjustment is especially important for
90 The Journal of Finance
Figure 2. Sales-to-asset ratio by one-digit SIC for a sample of 1,708 small corporations.
Figure 3. Operating expense-to-sales ratio by sales quartile for a sample of 1,708 small
corporations.
9
In Fama and Jensen ~1983a!, the delegation of decision control management and residual
owner ~i.e., hiring of outsiders as managers! is related to the decision skill and the accompa-
nying specialized knowledge that are needed to run the firm. Shareholders, however, still have
to bear the costs of monitoring.
92 The Journal of Finance
Figure 4. Sales-to-asset ratio by sales quartile for a sample of 1,708 small cor-
porations.
10
As a way of comparison, Dong and Dow ~1993! estimate that 10 to 20 percent of total labor
hours are attributed to supervision or monitoring in the Chinese collective farms. Dobson ~1992!
finds that X-inefficiency measures 0.2 percent of sales among large U.S. manufacturing firms.
Agency Costs and Ownership Structure 93
Table I
Agency Costs, Ownership Structure, and Managerial Alignment
with Shareholders
Agency costs are presented for a sample of 1,708 small corporations divided into two groups of
firms: those managed by owners ~aligned with shareholders! and those managed by an outsider
~not aligned with shareholders!. Agency costs are proxied alternatively by the ratio of operating
expenses to annual sales and the ratio of annual sales to total assets. Separate analyses are
presented for each agency cost proxy and for subgroups where the primary owner owns 100 per-
cent of the firm, where the primary owner owns more than half of the firm, where a single
family owns more than half of the firm, and where no owner or family owns more than half of
the firm. The last column shows the difference between the mean ~median! ratios of the outsider-
managed firms and the insider-managed firms. Statistical significance of the differences in the
mean ratios is based on the t-statistic from a parametric test ~based on the assumption of
unequal variances! of whether the difference in the mean ratios of the two groups of firms is
significantly different from zero. Statistical significance of the differences in the median ratios
is based on a chi-square statistic from a nonparametric test of whether the two groups are from
populations with the same median ~Mood ~1950!!. Data are taken from the Federal Reserve
Board’s National Survey of Small Business Finances.
Type of Manager
*, **, *** indicate statistical significance at the 10, 5, and 1 percent levels, respectively.
94 The Journal of Finance
firms’ equity but hire an outside manager. For these two groups of firms,
the difference in operating expense ratios is 3.4 percentage points. Al-
though this univariate difference in means is not statistically significant, a
multiple regression model that corrects for size and industry effect, shown
in Table III later, indicates that firms hiring outside managers have oper-
ating expenses that are 5.4 percent greater than those at firms managed
by a shareholder.
Also included in the full sample are 1,001 firms in which the primary
owner holds a controlling interest of more than half of the firm’s equity. As
shown in Table I, Panel A, line 3, the ratio of operating expenses to sales for
these firms is 2.8 percentage points lower when the owner manages the firm
than when the owner hires an outside manager. However, this difference is
not statistically significant.
There are also 1,249 firms in which a single family holds a controlling
interest of more than half of the firm’s equity. As shown in line 4 of Panel A,
the average ratio of operating expenses to sales for these firms is 3.9 per-
centage points higher when the firm is managed by an outsider than when
the firm is managed by a shareholder. This difference is statistically signif-
icant at the 5 percent level.
One final group of interest is composed of 336 firms in which no person or
family holds a controlling interest of more than 50 percent of the firm’s
equity. As predicted, because of the more diffuse ownership of these firms,
the average ratio of operating expenses to sales is indeed much higher: 7.2 per-
centage points more at firms managed by outsiders than at firms managed
by shareholders. This difference is statistically significant at the 5 percent
level. To confirm that our finding is robust with respect to sample distribu-
tions, we also perform nonparametric tests on the difference between the
medians, and find similar results.
11
The distribution of the sales-to-asset ratio is highly skewed by the presence of large out-
liers. Consequently, the ratio is capped at the value found at the 95th percentile, a ratio of 19.0.
Agency Costs and Ownership Structure 95
For the full sample, displayed in line 1, the average sales-to-asset ratio at
insider-managed f irms is almost 10 percent higher than at outsider-
managed firms at 4.76 and 4.35, respectively. The 0.41 difference in these
means is statistically significant at the 10 percent level. This difference im-
plies that the revenues of a median-size firm, which has $438,000 in total
assets, are $180,000 per year higher when a shareholder rather than an
outsider manages the firm. In each of the remaining four comparisons ~lines
2–5 of Panel B!, the average ratio of annual sales to total assets also is
greater when the firm is managed by a shareholder than when the firm is
managed by an outsider. However, this difference is statistically significant
at least at the 10 percent level only when the primary owner holds a con-
trolling interest in the firm ~line 3!.
Overall, the results displayed in Table I suggest that both the ratio of
operating expenses to annual sales and the ratio of annual sales to total
assets are adequate proxies for small corporations’ agency costs. Each pro-
vides results consistent with the predictions of agency theory for a wide
range of potentially high to low agency cost organizational and management
structures.
Ownership variables
Firm manager is a shareholder 0.73 1 0.78 0.69 0.09*** 0.71 0.75 20.04*
One family owns .50 percent of the firm 0.73 1 0.75 0.71 0.04* 0.72 0.74 20.02
Ownership share of primary owner 0.65 0.54 0.66 0.64 0.02 0.62 0.68 20.06***
Number of nonmanager shareholders 3.51 1 3.89 3.14 0.75** 2.35 4.68 22.33***
*, **, *** indicate statistical significance at the 10, 5, and 1 percent levels, respectively.
Agency Costs and Ownership Structure 97
Ownership variables
25.4*** 25.7***
*, **, *** indicate statistical significance at the 10, 5, and 1 percent levels, respectively.
Table IV
Determinants of Agency Costs at Small Corporations
The dependent variable proxying for agency costs is the ratio of annual sales to total assets. There are four groups of independent variables:
common ownership0managerial alignment variables, external monitoring variables, capital structure variables, and control variables. Sample
size is 1,708. Each specification includes a set of 35 dummy variables indicating each two-digit SIC that accounts for more than one percent of
the sample of firms. In column 10, the four ownership variables have been orthogonalized. Data are from the Federal Reserve Board’s National
Survey of Small Business Finances.
~1! ~2! ~3! ~4! ~5! ~6! ~7! ~8! ~9! ~10!
Ownership variables
Manager is a shareholder 0.51** 0.30 0.46*
~2.0! ~1.2! ~1.8!
One family owns .50% of the firm 0.087 20.34 20.22
~0.3! ~21.2! ~20.8!
Ownership share of primary owner 0.012*** 20.011* 0.012***
~3.0! ~21.8! ~3.1!
Log of the number of nonmanager 20.82*** 21.05*** 21.05***
stockholders ~26.2! ~25.4! ~25.4!
External monitoring variables
Length of the longest banking 20.025* 20.01 20.01
relationship ~21.7! ~20.4! ~20.4!
Number of banking relationships 21.09*** 20.50*** 20.50***
~24.7! ~24.3! ~24.3!
Debt-to-asset ratio 1.05*** 1.11*** 1.11***
~5.3! ~5.5! ~5.5!
Control variables
Two-digit SIC dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Log of annual sales 0.05 0.03 0.07 0.18*** 0.07 0.11* 0.02 0.28*** 0.28***
~0.7! ~0.5! ~1.1! ~2.7! ~1.1! ~1.7! ~0.3! ~3.9! ~3.9!
Firm age 20.012 20.01 20.01
~21.2! ~20.8! ~20.8!
Regression summary statistics
Adjusted R 2 0.032 0.030 0.035 0.051 0.035 0.042 0.045 0.080 0.080
F-statistic 2.51*** 2.40*** 2.65*** 3.49*** 2.63*** 3.02*** 3.20*** 4.37*** 4.37***
99
*, **, *** indicate statistical significance at the 10, 5, and 1 percent levels, respectively.
100 The Journal of Finance
the primary owner has only a one percent share. Each of the variables an-
alyzed in columns 2 through 4 is statistically significant at least at the
5 percent level.
In column 5 of Table III we analyze ~the natural logarithm of one plus! the
number of nonmanager shareholders. We expect a positive relationship be-
tween agency costs and this variable, as the returns to monitoring decrease
and free-rider problems increase with the number of nonmanager sharehold-
ers. We use the natural logarithm rather than the level of this variable
because we expect that the relationship is stronger at smaller values of the
variable. The estimated coefficient is positive and significant at better than
the one percent level, confirming our expectations. For a firm with 30 non-
manager shareholders, the maximum value imposed by our cap at the 95th
percentile, the estimated coefficient of 1.9 implies that agency costs are 6.5 per-
centage points higher, or $85,000 greater, than at a firm with zero nonman-
ager shareholders.
In columns 6 and 7 of Table III we analyze the two bank monitoring vari-
ables: the length of the firm’s longest banking relationship and the firm’s
number of banking relationships. As discussed in Section II, we expect agency
costs to vary inversely with the length of the longest banking relationship
and directly with the number of banking relationships. To distinguish be-
tween the private information generated by bank monitoring and the public
information generated by a firm’s durability, we also include firm age in the
specification analyzing the length of the firm’s longest banking relationship.
As shown in column 6 of Table III, agency costs are reduced by a statis-
tically significant 0.22 percent for each additional year in the length of the
firm’s longest banking relationship. The coefficient on firm age is not sig-
nificantly different from zero. In column 7, however, a related variable, the
number of banking relationships, is negative and statistically significant at
better than the 10 percent level. This finding conf licts with our hypothesis
in which multiple banking relationships reduce each bank’s incentive to mon-
itor, and, therefore, increase agency costs. One possible explanation recon-
ciling the two seemingly contradictory results is that the number of banking
relationships may proxy for factors other than the banks’ incentive to mon-
itor the firm. The most prominent explanations are the increasing financial
sophistication and maturity of the firms and their managers, and regulatory
limitations on loans to a single borrower, which may constrain a small bank’s
ability to supply funds to a larger firm.
In column 8 of Table III we analyze the complex relation between capital
structure and ownership on agency costs. As discussed in Section II, we ex-
pect an inverse relationship between agency costs and the debt-to-asset ra-
tio. We do, indeed, find a negative relationship, but the coefficient is not
significantly different from zero.
In each of the seven specifications displayed in columns 2 through 8 of
Table III, observe that our size variable, the natural logarithm of annual
sales, is negative and statistically significant at better than the 1 percent
level, which is strong evidence of economies of scale. Not shown in Table III
Agency Costs and Ownership Structure 101
12
Fama and Jensen ~1983! realize that for shareholders to monitor the firm’s management
they must hold sufficient ownership; however, the cost of large ownership shares is suboptimal
risk-taking, and, possibly, underinvestment. Also, Demsetz ~1983! suggests that firms with con-
centrated ownership have lower monitoring costs.
102 The Journal of Finance
13
The sales-to-asset ratio is likely subject to additional biases that render it much noisier
than the operating expense-to-sales ratio. Note that the adjusted-R 2 statistics appearing at the
bottoms of Tables III and IV indicate that we are able to explain about 26 percent of the
variability in the latter ratio but only about eight percent of the variability in the former ratio.
This led us to investigate additional control variables in the sales-to-asset regression, including
the ratio of operating expenses to sales. Results from specifications including the operating
104 The Journal of Finance
mains negative and significant at better than the 1 percent level, but the
primary owner’s ownership share switches back from negative to positive
and also is significant at better than the 1 percent level. The dummy indi-
cating that the firm is managed by a shareholder also is positive, but is
significant at only the 10 percent level. The dummy indicating that a family
controls the firm is not significantly different from zero. In sum, the results
for the four ownership variables are not qualitatively different from those
reported in columns 2 through 5, when each of these variables is examined
independently, and provide strong support for the agency-cost theory of Jensen
and Meckling ~1976!.14
expense-to-sales ratio as an additional regressor are not qualitatively different from those in
Table IV. In no case was the operating expense-to-sales ratio statistically significant at even the
20 percent level. Because we view the operating expense-to-sales ratio as an endogenous vari-
able, we also tested a specification that included a predicted value of this ratio rather than the
actual value. The predicted value was obtained using the model appearing in column 9 of Table III.
Again, the results from this robustness check are not qualitatively different from those appear-
ing in Table IV
14
For the sake of completeness, we also perform the same procedure on the regression equa-
tion in column 9 of Table III. We find that orthogonalizing the ownership variables does not
qualitatively affect the results. Only the same two ownership variables are statistically signif-
icant. Overall, although both measures of agency costs provide qualitatively similar results, the
expense ratio regression yields greater explained variations.
15
There are few empirical studies in related areas of corporate finance that analyze own-
ership, organizational, and management structures in detail. For example, see a study of ex-
ecutive compensation in Israel by Ang, Hauser, and Lauterbach ~1997!.
Agency Costs and Ownership Structure 105
REFERENCES
Alchian, Armen A., and Harold Demsetz, 1992, Production, information costs, and economic
organization, American Economic Review 62, 777–795.
Ang, James S., Samuel Hauser, and Beni Lauterbach, 1997, Top executive compensation under
alternate ownership and governance structure, in Mark Hirschey and M. Wayne Marr, eds.:
Advances in Financial Economics ~JAI Press Inc., Greenwich, Conn.!.
Arnold, R. J., 1985, Agency costs in banking firms: An analysis of expense preference behavior,
Journal of Economics and Business, 103–112.
Barclay, Michael J., and Clifford W. Smith Jr., 1995, The maturity structure of corporate debt,
Journal of Finance 50, 609–632.
Berger, Allen N., and Gregory F. Udell, 1995, Relationship lending and lines of credit in small
firm finance, Journal of Business 68, 351–382.
Cole, Rebel A., 1998, The importance of relationships to the availability of credit, Journal of
Banking and Finance, forthcoming.
Cole, Rebel A., and Hamid Mehran, 1998, CEO compensation, ownership structure, and taxa-
tion: Evidence from small businesses, mimeo, Northwestern University.
Cole, Rebel A., and John D. Wolken, 1995, Sources and uses of financial services by small
businesses: Evidence from the 1993 National Survey of Small Business Finances, Federal
Reserve Bulletin 81, 629–667.
Cole, Rebel A., John D. Wolken, and Louise Woodburn, 1996, Bank and nonbank competition for
small business credit: Evidence from the 1987 and 1993 National Surveys of Small Busi-
ness Finances, Federal Reserve Bulletin 82, 983–995.
Demsetz, Harold, 1983, The structure of ownership and theory of the firm, Journal of Law and
Economics 26, 375–393.
Demsetz, Harold, and Kenneth Lehn, 1985, The structure of corporate ownership: Causes and
consequences, Journal of Political Economy 93, 1155–1177.
Denning, Karen C., and Kuldeep Shastri, 1993, Changes in organizational structure and share-
holder wealth, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 28, 553–564.
Diamond, Douglas W., 1984, Financial intermediation and delegated monitoring, Review of Eco-
nomic Studies 51, 393–414.
Dobson, John, 1992, Agency costs in U.S. manufacturing: An empirical measure using X-efficiency,
Journal of Economics and Finance 16, 1–10.
Dong, Xiao Y., and Gregory K. Dow, 1993, Monitoring costs in Chinese agricultural teams,
Journal of Political Economy 101, 539–553.
Fama, Eugene F., and Michael C. Jensen, 1983a, Separation of ownership and control, Journal
of Law and Economics 26, 301–325.
Fama, Eugene F., and Michael C. Jensen, 1983b, Agency problems and residual claims, Journal
of Law and Economics 26, 327–349.
Fama, Eugene F., and Michael C. Jensen, 1985, Organizational forms and investment decisions,
Journal of Financial Economics 14, 101–119.
Jensen, Michael C., 1986, Agency costs of free cash f low, corporate finance and takeovers,
American Economic Review 76, 323–329.
Jensen, Michael C., and William H. Meckling, 1976, Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior,
agency costs and capital structure, Journal of Financial Economics 3, 305–360.
Kim, Wi S., and Eric H. Sorensen, 1986, Evidence on the impact of the agency costs of
debt in corporate debt policy, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 21, 131–
144.
Knight, Frank H., 1921, Risk, Uncertainty and Profit ~University of Chicago Press, Chicago!.
Manne, Henry G., 1967, Our two corporate systems: Law and economics, Virginia Law Review
53, 259–284.
Mello, Antonio S., and John E. Parsons, 1992, Measuring the agency cost of debt, Journal of
Finance 47, 1887–1904.
Milgrom, Paul, and John Roberts, 1995, Economics, Organization, and Management ~Prentice
Hall, Englewood Cliffs, N.J.!.
106 The Journal of Finance
Petersen, Mitchell A., and Raghuram G. Rajan, 1994, The benefits of lending relationships:
Evidence from small business data, Journal of Finance 49, 3–38.
Petersen, Mitchell A., and Raghuram G. Rajan, 1995, The effect of credit market competition on
lending relationships, Quarterly Journal of Economics 110, 407–442.
Petersen, Mitchell A., and Raghuram G. Rajan, 1997, Trade credit: Theories and evidence,
Review of Financial Studies 10, 661–691.
Shleifer, Andrei, and Robert Vishny, 1986, Large shareholders and corporate control, Journal of
Political Economy 94, 461–488.
Williams, Joseph, 1987, Perquisites, risk, and capital structure, Journal of Finance 42, 29–48.
Zeckhauser, Richard, and John Pound, 1990, Are large shareholders effective monitors? An
investigation of share ownership and corporate performance, in R. G. Hubbard, ed.: Asym-
metric Information, Corporate Finance, and Investment ~University of Chicago Press, Chicago!.