MCBM - 21-Monetised-Benefits-And-Costs-Manual
MCBM - 21-Monetised-Benefits-And-Costs-Manual
MCBM - 21-Monetised-Benefits-And-Costs-Manual
This publication is copyright © Waka Kotahi NZ Transport Agency. Material in it may be reproduced
for personal or in-house use without formal permission or charge, provided suitable acknowledgement
is made to this publication and Waka Kotahi NZ Transport Agency as the source. Requests and
enquiries about the reproduction of material in this publication for any other purpose should be made
to the Manager, Corporate Information and Records Management, Waka Kotahi NZ Transport
Agency, Private Bag 6995, Wellington 6141.
The permission to reproduce material in this publication does not extend to any material for which the
copyright is identified as being held by a third party. Authorisation to reproduce material belonging to
a third party must be obtained from the copyright holder(s) concerned.
Disclaimer
Waka Kotahi NZ Transport Agency has endeavoured to ensure material in this document is
technically accurate and reflects legal requirements. However, the document does not override
governing legislation. Waka Kotahi does not accept liability for any consequences arising from the use
of this document. If the user of this document is unsure whether the material is correct, they should
refer directly to the relevant legislation and contact Waka Kotahi.
More information
Waka Kotahi
First published August 2020
Version 1.5, August 2021
If you have further queries, call our contact centre on 0800 699 000 or write to us:
Waka Kotahi NZ Transport Agency
Private Bag 6995
Wellington 6141
This document is available on the Waka Kotahi website at
https://www.nzta.govt.nz/resources/monetised-benefits-and-costs-manual
MONETISED BENEFITS
AND COSTS MANUAL
CONTENTS
CONTENTS
List of tables ........................................................................................................................................7
List of figures .....................................................................................................................................13
Introduction........................................................................................................................................14
Purpose of this manual ...............................................................................................................14
Who this manual is for ................................................................................................................15
1. Concepts ....................................................................................................................................16
1.1 Social cost–benefit analysis .............................................................................................16
1.2 Equity or distributional effects of land transport initiatives ..........................................16
1.3 Steps in BCR calculation...................................................................................................17
1.4 Counterfactuals and the do-minimum .............................................................................18
1.5 Alternatives and options ...................................................................................................19
1.6 Period of analysis ..............................................................................................................19
1.7 Benefits ...............................................................................................................................20
1.8 Costs ...................................................................................................................................22
1.9 Discounting ........................................................................................................................24
1.10 Benefit–cost ratios and other appraisal tools ............................................................25
1.11 Sensitivity analysis ........................................................................................................26
2. Demand estimation and mode share .........................................................................................28
2.1 Demand estimates and importance to economics .........................................................28
2.2 Key concepts ......................................................................................................................29
2.3 Key industry guidance and references ............................................................................32
2.4 Methods for demand estimation .......................................................................................33
2.5 Definitions of transport model types ...............................................................................34
2.6 Future guidance development areas ...............................................................................35
2.7 Drivers of trip-making and mode share ...........................................................................36
2.8 Land use projections and regional planning structures ................................................37
2.9 Mathematical methodologies and elasticities .................................................................38
2.10 Demand estimation and transport modelling in New Zealand ..................................38
2.11 Optimism bias ................................................................................................................39
2.12 Factors and considerations influencing demand estimation ...................................40
2.13 Fixed trip matrix and variable trip matrix assessments ............................................44
2.14 Demand estimation uncertainty ...................................................................................46
2.15 Checks, reporting and reviewing .................................................................................48
3. Benefits ......................................................................................................................................51
3.1 Impact on social cost of deaths and serious injuries ....................................................53
3.2 Impact of mode on physical and mental health ..............................................................56
3.3 Impact of air emissions on health ....................................................................................57
CONTENTS
CONTENTS
LIST OF TABLES
LIST OF TABLES
Table 1: Guidance on potential suitability of sources of, and approaches to, demand estimation for
different geographic contexts and transport environments ......................................................... 34
Table 2: Guidance on factors affecting demand – project model and calculation focus ...................... 41
Table 3: Guidance on factors affecting demand – transport modelling focus ....................................... 43
Table 4: High-level guidance on potential for VTM or FTM approaches .............................................. 45
Table 5: Relationship between benefits included in the Waka Kotahi Land Transport Benefits
Framework and EEM’s benefits .................................................................................................. 52
Table 6: New pedestrian facility benefits ($/pedestrian km – 2018) ..................................................... 56
Table 7: New cycle facility benefits ($/cyclist km – 2018) ..................................................................... 57
Table 8: Calculating traffic-related emission loads ............................................................................... 58
Table 9: Damage costs for use in project evaluations ($/tonne – 2016) .............................................. 59
Table 10: Calculating traffic-related emission loads ............................................................................. 60
Table 11: Recommended shadow price of carbon (NZ$2020 per tonne of CO 2 equivalent) ............... 61
Table 12: Average noise design levels (Leq 24 hour) .......................................................................... 63
Table 13: Behavioural values of time for mode user for transport modelling purposes ($/h – July 2002)
.................................................................................................................................................... 66
Table 14: Values of time by trip purpose ($/h/person – July 2002) ...................................................... 66
Table 15: Values of vehicle and freight time ($/h/vehicle – July 2002) for vehicles that are used for
work purposes as an input for calculating BCR .......................................................................... 67
Table 16: Composite values of travel time in $/h/vehicle (all occupants and vehicle types combined –
July 2002) ................................................................................................................................... 67
Table 17: Volume to capacity (VC) ratios for level terrain, overtaking sight distance and percentage of
time delayed (PTD) following slow vehicles................................................................................ 68
Table 18: Volume to capacity (VC) ratios for rolling terrain, overtaking sight distance and percentage
of time delayed (PTD) following slow vehicles ........................................................................... 69
Table 19: Volume to capacity (VC) ratios for mountainous terrain, overtaking sight distances and PTD
following slow vehicles ................................................................................................................ 69
Table 20: Increased service headway .................................................................................................. 72
Table 21: Breakdown of base VOC by component (2015 NZ$) ........................................................... 74
Table 22: Running cost by speed and gradient regression coefficients (cents/km – July 2015) .......... 75
Table 23: Additional VOC due to congestion regression coefficient by vehicle class (cents/km –July
2015) ........................................................................................................................................... 76
Table 24: Additional VOC due to congestion regression coefficients by road category (cents/km – July
2015) ........................................................................................................................................... 76
Table 25: Additional VOC due to roughness – regression coefficients (cents/km – July 2015) ........... 78
Table 26: Increase in VOC per vehicle – kilometre per 1mm increase in Benkelman beam deflection
(July 2015) .................................................................................................................................. 79
Table 27: Additional VOC due to bottleneck delay by vehicle class (cents/minute – July 2015) ......... 79
Table 28: Additional VOC due to bottleneck delay by road category (cents/minute – July 2015) ........ 79
Table 29: Valuation of public transport (PT) user benefits/disbenefits due to a price change ............. 80
Table 30: Equivalent time to a minute-late ratios .................................................................................. 81
Table 31: Summary of user experience benefits .................................................................................. 83
Table 32: Vehicle feature values for public transport services – rail..................................................... 86
Table 33: Vehicle feature values for public transport services – bus.................................................... 87
Table 34: Infrastructure features value for public transport – bus ........................................................ 88
Table 35: Relative benefit for different types of cycle facilities ............................................................. 89
Table 36: Data requirements ................................................................................................................ 93
Table 37: Weighted average agglomeration elasticities for New Zealand by industry ......................... 93
Table 38: Imperfect competition parameters ........................................................................................ 99
Table 39: Categories of visitors .......................................................................................................... 101
Table 40: International visitor activity and estimated economic activity, by region ($2018) ............... 102
Table 41: Diversion rates and composite benefit for abatement of marginal congestion costs for major
urban corridors (worksheet SP9.1) ........................................................................................... 105
Table 42: Composite benefit for abatement of marginal congestion costs for major urban corridors by
PT modes ($/additional passenger boarding) (worksheet SP10.1) .......................................... 105
Table 43: Workplace travel plan benefit ($/employee/year – 2008) ................................................... 109
Table 44: School travel plan benefit ($/student/year – 2008) ............................................................. 109
LIST OF TABLES
Table 45: Household community-based activity benefits ($/capita/year – 2008) ............................... 109
Table 46: Simplified procedures in relation to full procedures ............................................................ 111
Table 47: Simplified procedure summaries......................................................................................... 112
Table 48: SP11 Walking and cycling facilities procedure template .................................................... 115
Table 49: Steps in the SP11 evaluation of walking and cycling activities ........................................... 115
Table 50: Benefit factors for different types of cycle facilities ............................................................. 115
Table 51: Full procedure for walking and cycling activities ................................................................. 116
Table 52: Cycle demand ..................................................................................................................... 117
Table 53: Cycling commute share ...................................................................................................... 118
Table 54: SP1 Road renewals procedure template ............................................................................ 122
Table 55: Steps in the SP1 evaluation of road renewal activities ....................................................... 122
Table 56: SP2 Structural bridge renewals procedure template .......................................................... 125
Table 57: Steps in the SP2 evaluation of structural bridge renewal activities .................................... 125
Table 58: Cost factors for different type of heavy trucks .................................................................... 125
Table 59: SP3 Road improvement activities procedure template ....................................................... 126
Table 60: Steps in the SP3 evaluation of road improvement activities ............................................... 126
Table 61: SP4 Seal extensions procedure template ........................................................................... 127
Table 62: Steps in the SP4 evaluation of seal extension activities ..................................................... 127
Table 63: SP5 Isolated intersection improvements procedure template ............................................ 128
Table 64: Steps in the SP5 evaluation of isolated intersection activities ............................................ 128
Table 65: Multiplication factors for items with an estimated life of less than 40 years ....................... 128
Table 66: Full procedures for evaluation of road improvement activities ........................................... 129
Table 67: Breakdown of vehicle operating costs (VOC) by component ............................................. 138
Table 68: Recommendations on diversion rates to/from public transport from changes in car travel
costs .......................................................................................................................................... 138
Table 69: Coefficients to calculate standard deviation of travel time .................................................. 139
Table 70: Travel time variability – rural two lane road, level terrain.................................................... 141
Table 71: Travel time reliability – rural two-lane road, rolling terrain .................................................. 141
Table 72: Travel time variability – rural two-lane road, mountainous terrain ...................................... 141
Table 73: Adjustment factors to apply to variability calculations table ................................................ 142
Table 74: Contingency allowances ..................................................................................................... 146
Table 75: SP9 New public transport services procedure template ..................................................... 149
Table 76: Steps in the SP9 evaluation of new public transport service activities ............................... 149
Table 77: SP10 procedure template ................................................................................................... 150
Table 78: Steps in the SP10 evaluation of new public transport service activities ............................. 150
Table 79: Stages of analysis for the evaluation of public transport services ...................................... 151
Table 80: Issues in elasticity estimation and application .................................................................... 155
Table 81: Overall (short run) direct elasticity estimates (at 12 months after service etc change) ...... 156
Table 82: Summary of evidence on component elasticities for key variables .................................... 157
Table 83: Typical fare and service level (short-run) relative elasticities by time period...................... 158
Table 84: Patronage ramp-up profile data by category of initiative .................................................... 160
Table 85: Prior modes of new public transport passengers resulting from urban public transport
initiatives ................................................................................................................................... 161
Table 86: Recommendations on diversion rates to/from public transport from changes in car travel
costs .......................................................................................................................................... 163
Table 87: Bus operating cost variables ............................................................................................... 170
Table 88: Unit cost categories and allocation ..................................................................................... 171
Table 89: Unit cost rates, 2009/10 prices (standard diesel bus)......................................................... 172
Table 90: Sensitivity tests ................................................................................................................... 175
Table 91: Stages of analysis for TDM ................................................................................................. 177
Table 92: Stages of analysis for evaluation of education, promotion and marketing activities .......... 182
Table 93: SP6 HPMV route improvements procedure template ......................................................... 187
Table 94: Steps in the SP6 evaluation of HPMV route improvement activities .................................. 188
Table 95: SP8 Freight services procedure template ........................................................................... 188
Table 96: Steps in the SP8 evaluation of freight service activities ..................................................... 189
Table 97: Stages of analysis for freight activities ................................................................................ 190
Table 98: Elasticities for freight commodities...................................................................................... 192
Table 99: Calculate reduction of road user charges (RUC) revenue .................................................. 200
Table 100: Sensitivity tests ................................................................................................................. 203
Table 101: Stages of analysis for private sector financing, and road tolling activities ........................ 206
LIST OF TABLES
Table 102: Annual single payment present worth factors ................................................................... 214
Table 103: Guidance on importance of sensitivity tests – project model and calculation focus ......... 222
Table 104: Guidance on importance of sensitivity tests – regional transport modelling focus ........... 223
Table 105: Likelihood rating (Z/44) ..................................................................................................... 227
Table 106: Consequence ratings ........................................................................................................ 228
Table 107: Risk consequence – qualitative rating criteria (Z/44) ........................................................ 228
Table 108: Risk matrix ........................................................................................................................ 229
Table 109: Benefit risks from base year models/source data used to develop demand estimations . 232
Table 110: Benefit risks from future year forecast demand estimations ............................................. 234
Table 111: Benefit realisation risks ..................................................................................................... 236
Table 112: Cost risks .......................................................................................................................... 237
Table 113: Risk treatment options example ........................................................................................ 239
Table A1: Forecasting demand for improvements to services or facilities ......................................... 249
Table A2: Fixed or variable trip matrices from a regional transport model ......................................... 254
Table A3: Travel behaviour change target population ........................................................................ 256
Table A4: Composite evaluation of TBhC packages .......................................................................... 257
Table A5: Scoring system for workplace travel plan diversion rates .................................................. 258
Table A6: Workplace diversion rates .................................................................................................. 258
Table A7: School diversion rates ........................................................................................................ 258
Table A8: Household and community diversion rates ........................................................................ 259
Table A9: Steps to apply growth constraint to the do-minimum/activity trip matrix ............................ 259
Table A10: Steps to apply matrix scaling ............................................................................................ 261
Table A11: Steps to apply incremental matrix capping ....................................................................... 262
Table A12: Steps to apply the shadow network technique ................................................................. 262
Table A13: Steps to apply elasticity methods ..................................................................................... 263
Table A14: Long-run generalised cost elasticities .............................................................................. 264
Table A15: Steps to apply variable matrix methods ........................................................................... 266
Table A16: Steps to apply variable matrix method B .......................................................................... 267
Table A17: Guidelines for estimating user time and vehicle operating costs ..................................... 269
Table A18: Required cost and trip matrices ........................................................................................ 270
Table A19: Suggested checks for fixed and variable trip matrix calculations/adjustments ................ 272
Table A20: Suggested checks for capacity ......................................................................................... 273
Table A21: Crash trend adjustments factors ....................................................................................... 285
Table A22: Growth adjustment factors ................................................................................................ 285
Table A23: Ratio of fatal to serious crash severities by movement for 50km/h speed limit areas ..... 287
Table A24: Ratio of fatal to serious crash severities by movement for 70km/h speed limit areas ..... 287
Table A25: Ratio of fatal to serious crash severities by movement for 100km/h speed limit areas ... 287
Table A26: Factors for converting from reported injury crashes to total injury crash ......................... 288
Table A27: Factor for converting from reported non-injury crashes to total non-injury crashes ......... 288
Table A28: Cost per crash by movement and vehicle involvement for fatal injury crashes in 50km/h
speed limit areas ....................................................................................................................... 288
Table A29: Cost per crash by movement and vehicle involvement for serious injury crashes in 50km/h
speed limit areas ....................................................................................................................... 289
Table A30: Cost per crash by movement and vehicle involvement for minor injury crashes in 50km/h
speed limit areas ....................................................................................................................... 289
Table A31: Cost per crash by movement and vehicle involvement for non-injury crashes in 50km/h
speed limit areas ....................................................................................................................... 290
Table A32: Cost per crash by movement and vehicle involvement for fatal injury crashes in 100km/h
speed limit areas ....................................................................................................................... 290
Table A33: Cost per crash by movement and vehicle involvement for serious injury crashes in
100km/h speed limit areas ........................................................................................................ 291
Table A34: Cost per crash by movement and vehicle involvement for minor injury crashes in 100km/h
speed limit areas ....................................................................................................................... 291
Table A35: Cost per crash by movement and vehicle involvement for non-injury crashes in 100km/h
speed limit areas ....................................................................................................................... 292
Table A36: Cost per reported injury crash ($000 2015) ...................................................................... 292
Table A37: Cost per reported injury crash for special sites ($000 2015) ............................................ 293
Table A38: Cost per reported injury crash by mode ($000 2015) ....................................................... 293
Table A39: Ratio of fatal and serious/all injury factors by crash type, ONRC grouped and by alignment
type, 80–100km/h ..................................................................................................................... 294
LIST OF TABLES
Table A40: Ratio of fatal and serious/all injury factors by crash type, ONRC grouped and by alignment
type, 60–70km/h ....................................................................................................................... 295
Table A41: Ratio of fatal and serious/all injury factors by crash type, ONRC grouped and by alignment
type 40–50km/h ........................................................................................................................ 296
Table A42: Ratio of fatal and serious/all injury as a function of crash type by ONRC for 80–100km/h
.................................................................................................................................................. 297
Table A43: Ratio of fatal and serious/all injury as a function of crash type by ONRC for 60–70km/h 298
Table A44: Ratio of fatal and serious/all injury as a function of crash type by ONRC for 40–50km/h 299
Table A45: Vehicle classes ................................................................................................................. 302
Table A46: Road categories................................................................................................................ 303
Table A47: Traffic composition (%) ..................................................................................................... 303
Table A48: Steps to separate an activity into its component sections ................................................ 304
Table A49: Steps to divide the year into time periods ........................................................................ 305
Table A50: Vehicle occupancy and travel purpose ............................................................................. 306
Table A51: Axel pair adjustment factors ............................................................................................. 308
Table A52: Steps to determine traffic volumes ................................................................................... 311
Table A53: Steps to calculate the free speed travel time ................................................................... 312
Table A54: Steps to determine the free speed of a multi-lane road ................................................... 313
Table A55: Steps to determine the free speed of a two-lane rural road ............................................. 314
Table A56: Steps to determine the free speed of an 'other urban road' ............................................. 315
Table A57: Steps to select the appropriate procedure for determining the capacity of road sections 316
Table A58: Steps to determine the capacity of a motorway section with separate motorway
components in each direction of travel ..................................................................................... 317
Table A59: Steps to determine the capacity of a multi-lane road ....................................................... 318
Table A60: Steps to determine the capacity of a two-lane rural road ................................................. 319
Table A61: Steps to determine whether the effects of vehicle interactions are significant ................. 320
Table A62: Steps to determine the peak interval ................................................................................ 323
Table A63: Steps to calculate the average peak interval traffic intensity ........................................... 324
Table A64: Steps to determine the volume to capacity (VC) ratio ...................................................... 325
Table A65: Steps to calculate additional travel time ........................................................................... 325
Table A66: Steps to calculate bottleneck delay .................................................................................. 327
Table A67: Steps to determine whether to consider peak spreading ................................................. 329
Table A68: Steps to determine the additional travel time of speed change cycles from substandard
curves........................................................................................................................................ 330
Table A69: Steps to calculate the time period total average travel time per vehicle .......................... 331
Table A70: Lane width factors ............................................................................................................ 332
Table A71: Approach grade factors .................................................................................................... 332
Table A72: Parking factors .................................................................................................................. 333
Table A73: Locality factors .................................................................................................................. 333
Table A74: Arrival type ........................................................................................................................ 333
Table A75: Delay adjustment factor .................................................................................................... 334
Table A76: Platoon dispersal distances (m) ....................................................................................... 334
Table A77: Critical gap (Tg) ................................................................................................................. 336
Table A78: Average peak interval delay ............................................................................................. 336
Table A79: Passenger car VOC by speed and gradient (cents/km – July 2015) ............................... 338
Table A80: LCV VOC by speed and gradient (cents/km – July 2015) ................................................ 339
Table A81: MCV VOC by speed and gradient (cents/km – July 2015) ............................................... 340
Table A82: HCVI VOC by speed and gradient (cents/km – July 2015) .............................................. 341
Table A83: HCVII VOC by speed and gradient (cents/km – July 2015) ............................................. 342
Table A84: Bus VOC by speed and gradient (cents/km – July 2015) ................................................ 343
Table A85: Urban arterial VOC by speed and gradient (cents/km – July 2015) ................................. 344
Table A86: Urban other VOC by speed and gradient (cents/km – July 2015) .................................... 345
Table A87: Rural strategic VOC by speed and gradient (cents/km – July 2015) ............................... 346
Table A88: Rural other VOC by speed and gradient (cents/km – July 2015) ..................................... 347
Table A89: Urban additional VOC due to roughness by vehicle class (cents/km – July 2015) .......... 348
Table A90: Rural additional VOC due to roughness by vehicle class (cents/km – July 2015) ........... 349
Table A91: Additional VOC due to roughness by road category (cents/km – July 2015) ................... 350
Table A92: Urban arterial and urban other – additional VOC due to congestion by vehicle class
(cents/km – July 2015) .............................................................................................................. 351
LIST OF TABLES
Table A93: Rural strategic and rural other – additional VOC due to congestion by vehicle class
(cents/km – July 2015) .............................................................................................................. 352
Table A94: Motorway – additional VOC due to congestion by vehicle class (cents/km – July 2015) 353
Table A95: Additional VOC due to congestion by road category (cents/km – July 2015) .................. 354
Table A96: Passenger car additional travel time due to speed change cycles (seconds/speed cycle)
.................................................................................................................................................. 355
Table A97: Passenger car additional VOC due to speed change cycles (cents/speed cycle – July
2015) ......................................................................................................................................... 356
Table A98: LCV additional travel time due to speed change cycles (seconds/speed cycle) .............. 357
Table A99: LCV additional VOC due to speed change cycles (cents/speed cycle – July 2015) ........ 358
Table A100: MCV additional travel time due to speed change cycles (seconds/speed cycle) ........... 359
Table A101: MCV additional VOC due to speed change cycles (cents/speed cycle – July 2015) ..... 360
Table A102: HCVI additional travel time due to speed change cycles (seconds/speed cycle) .......... 361
Table A103: HCVI additional VOC due to speed change cycles (cents/speed cycle – July 2015) .... 362
Table A104: HCVII additional travel time due to speed change cycles (seconds/speed cycle) ......... 363
Table A105: HCVII additional VOC due to speed change cycles (cents/speed cycle – July 2015) ... 364
Table A106: Bus additional travel time due to speed change cycles (seconds/speed cycle) ............ 365
Table A107: Bus additional VOC due to speed change cycles (cents/speed cycle – July 2015) ....... 366
Table A108: Urban arterial additional travel time due to speed change cycles (seconds/speed cycle)
.................................................................................................................................................. 367
Table A109: Urban arterial additional VOC due to speed change cycles (cents/speed cycle – July
2015) ......................................................................................................................................... 368
Table A110: Urban other additional travel time due to speed change cycles (seconds/speed cycle) 369
Table A111: Urban other additional VOC due to speed change cycles (cents/speed cycle – July 2015)
.................................................................................................................................................. 370
Table A112: Rural strategic additional travel time due to speed change cycles (seconds/speed cycle)
.................................................................................................................................................. 371
Table A113: Rural strategic additional VOC due to speed change cycles (cents/speed cycle – July
2015) ......................................................................................................................................... 372
Table A114: Rural other additional travel time due to speed change cycles (seconds/speed cycle) . 373
Table A115: Rural other additional VOC due to speed change cycles (cents/speed cycle – July 2008)
.................................................................................................................................................. 374
Table A116: Crash rates for rural mid-block locations (/108 veh/km) ................................................. 378
Table A117: Traffic flow profiles .......................................................................................................... 378
Table A118: Classification of passing lane costs ................................................................................ 379
Table A119: Passing lane average costs ($ 2005) ............................................................................. 379
Table A120: Steps to determine passing lane spacing strategy ......................................................... 380
Table A121: Combined terrain classification....................................................................................... 381
Table A122: Terrain relationship to passing sight distance ................................................................ 381
Table A123: Traffic growth correction factors for BCR graphs ........................................................... 382
Table A124: Steps to refine passing lane spacing strategy ................................................................ 382
Table A125: Limiting lengths m for consideration of climbing lanes ................................................... 383
Table A126: Steps for assessment of individual passing lanes .......................................................... 388
Table A127: Traffic growth correction factors for travel time and VOC graphs .................................. 389
Table A128: Traffic growth correction factors for driver frustration graphs ......................................... 389
Table A129: Passing lane length factors for travel time delays and vehicle operating cost savings .. 390
Table A130: Passing lane length factors for frustration cost savings ................................................. 390
Table A131: Traffic growth correction factors for crash savings graphs ............................................. 391
Table A132: Quarterly single payment present worth factors ............................................................. 401
Table A133: Annual uniform series present worth factors .................................................................. 401
Table A134: Annual arithmetic growth present worth factors ............................................................. 403
Table A135: Summary of benefit risks ................................................................................................ 405
Table A136: Summary of cost risks .................................................................................................... 406
Table A137: Summary of other risks ................................................................................................... 407
Table A138: Identified high or critical risks ......................................................................................... 408
Table A139: Risk adjusted BCR ......................................................................................................... 410
Table A140: Do-minimum VC ratios ................................................................................................... 415
Table A141: Option VC ratios ............................................................................................................. 415
Table A142: Do-minimum flow matrices ............................................................................................. 416
Table A143: Option flow matrices ....................................................................................................... 416
LIST OF TABLES
LIST OF FIGURES
LIST OF FIGURES
Figure 1: Decision process for selecting crash analysis methods ........................................................ 55
Figure 2: Percentage of time delayed (PTD) two-lane rural roads level terrain .................................... 70
Figure 3: PTD for two lane rural roads, rolling terrain ........................................................................... 70
Figure 4: PTD for two lane rural roads, mountainous terrain ................................................................ 71
Figure 5: Procedure for estimating changes in VOC due to congestion ............................................... 77
Figure 6: Graphs of driver frustration benefits for all terrain ................................................................. 85
Figure 7: Step by step guidance for agglomeration benefits ................................................................ 96
Figure 8: Estimating imperfect competition benefits ............................................................................. 99
Figure 9: Decision chart for bridge replacement ................................................................................. 124
Figure 10: Stages for estimating travel time ....................................................................................... 136
Figure 11: Risk analysis process ........................................................................................................ 144
Figure 12: Risk analysis steps ............................................................................................................ 145
Figure 13: Typical public transport patronage ramp-up profiles from service changes ...................... 159
Figure 14: Flow chart for estimating road section travel time ............................................................. 166
Figure 15: Risk analysis process ........................................................................................................ 169
Figure 16: Risk analysis steps ............................................................................................................ 169
Figure 17: Flow chart for estimating road section travel time ............................................................. 195
Figure 18: Risk analysis process ........................................................................................................ 198
Figure 19: Risk analysis steps ............................................................................................................ 198
Figure 20: Risk management process ................................................................................................ 230
Figure A1: Decision process for selecting crash analysis methods .................................................... 275
Figure A2: Method A flow chart ........................................................................................................... 278
Figure A3: Method B flow chart ........................................................................................................... 280
Figure A4: Method C flow chart .......................................................................................................... 282
Figure A5: Stages for estimating road section travel time .................................................................. 310
Figure A6: Vehicle interaction delay and bottleneck delay ................................................................. 321
Figure A7: Average peak interval traffic intensity ............................................................................... 322
Figure A8: Benefit length of installing passing lanes .......................................................................... 375
Figure A9: Selection of passing lane analysis procedure ................................................................... 376
Figure A10: Graphs of strategy BCR for flat terrain ............................................................................ 384
Figure A11: Graphs of strategy BCR for rolling terrain ....................................................................... 385
Figure A12: Graphs of strategy BCR for hilly terrain .......................................................................... 386
Figure A13: Graphs of strategy BCR for mountainous terrain ............................................................ 387
Figure A14: Graphs of vehicle operating cost and delay savings for all terrain .................................. 392
Figure A15: Graphs of driver frustration benefits for all terrain ........................................................... 393
Figure A16: Graphs of crash savings for flat terrain ........................................................................... 394
Figure A17: Graphs of crash savings for rolling terrain ...................................................................... 395
Figure A18: Graphs of crash savings for hilly terrain .......................................................................... 396
Figure A19: Graphs of crash savings for mountainous terrain ........................................................... 397
Figure A20: The relative risk indicator for project costs ...................................................................... 409
Figure A21: Township bypass overview ............................................................................................. 415
Figure A22: Example cashflows .......................................................................................................... 422
Figure A23: Incremental BCR between two options ........................................................................... 423
INTRODUCTION
Purpose of this manual
The Monetised benefits and costs manual (MBCM) is Waka Kotahi NZ Transport Agency’s
standardised guidance for assessing the monetised benefits and costs of proposed investments in
land transport (activities). The primary purpose of this manual is to establish consistency,
transparency and comparability between activities to aid the evaluation of their economic efficiency.
This manual is a substantial refresh of the earlier Economic evaluation manual (EEM). With the
introduction of appraisal summary tables (AST) for capturing a wider range of impacts in social cost–
benefit analysis, including non-monetisable and monetisable impacts, this manual has been
refocused to only cover costs and monetised benefits (including disbenefits). This manual is one of
the primary tools for assessing economic efficiency.
The MBCM includes guidance for assessing the 12 monetised benefits of the 25 benefits within the
benefits framework. It is designed to be read in conjunction with the Land transport benefits
framework and management approach: guidelines and the Non-monetised benefits manual, as
together, these manuals provide all the information necessary for preparing an AST.
Proposal submitters
The cost–benefit analysis and appraisal concepts at the start of this manual should be used to guide
the development of investment proposals and options. They are references that will help ensure that
proposals have been correctly scoped.
Additionally, the summaries of monetised benefits will encourage the systematic identification of a
proposal’s benefits and disbenefits.
Transport analysts
The procedures, values and worksheets in this manual have been designed to assist analysts in
developing fit-for-purpose evaluations for transport activities. The material in this manual enables
activities to be assessed using standardised approaches, however, professional judgement and
supporting evidence can be utilised for bespoke analyses.
Decision makers
Decision makers use benefit–cost ratios, an output of the monetised components of cost–benefit
analysis as a decision support tool. By standardising the methods of evaluation, this manual is able to
assist decision makers when proposals are compared or put forward for funding decisions.
1. CONCEPTS
1.1 Social cost–benefit analysis
Social cost–benefit analysis, generally referred to as economic cost–benefit analysis or CBA, differs
from financial analysis by incorporating social, economic, environmental and cultural impacts. A CBA
measures costs and benefits at a national level and is a systematic method of organising information
about the costs and benefits of a proposed activity.
CBA is primarily a decision support tool and so the level of effort put into measuring impacts should
reflect the scale, scope and complexity of the decision that needs to be made. This manual sets out
standardised guidance for measuring impacts and monetising them, but a CBA can include non-
monetised costs and benefits.
Benefit–cost ratios, or BCRs, are often confused with CBA. BCRs are an indicator of economic
efficiency in the CBA framework, but they focus solely on monetised benefits and costs. Waka Kotahi
uses BCRs as one measure of efficiency, but decisions are further supported by the impacts captured
in the appraisal summary table (AST), including non-monetised benefits.
The appraisal summary table is a structured way to show the monetised and non-monetised
benefits and costs of short-listed options and the preferred solution. This tool plays a key role in
demonstrating how a preferred solution contributes to outcomes and also enables Waka Kotahi to
track benefits.
BCRs indicate whether activities will generate more benefits than they cost, make it possible to
compare activities, and enable prioritisation of activities under funding constraints – all within a well-
defined framework. For this reason, they remain the primary measure of economic efficiency used by
Waka Kotahi when assessing an activity from a purely monetised point of view.
Refer to the Waka Kotahi Planning and Investment Knowledge Base for information on when a BCR
is required to support a funding application.
The process for preparing an analysis of an activity is detailed step by step throughout this section of
the manual and specific information about BCRs, and other appraisal tools, is discussed in section
1.10.
For a more in-depth discussion of social cost–benefit analysis in a New Zealand context, please
refer to Treasury’s Guide to social cost benefit analysis
While an analysis of the distribution of benefits and costs among different groups of people is not
required for economic efficiency analysis, evaluations of an activity should report the distribution of
benefits and costs, particularly where they relate to the needs of transport disadvantaged
populations. This reporting forms a part of the funding allocation process.
When it is required, distributional effects should be reported separately from, but alongside, the
CBA results.
• Do-minimum
• Improvement alternatives and options
• Consider whether the improvement(s) should be part of a package and/or
Options programme of activities
• Collect data
Demand • Use of transport models and calibration
forecast
• Measure and monetise the impacts (benefits and disbenefits) for the do-minimum
and options
Benefits
estimates
• Undertake risk analysis when there are significant unpredictable events that may
affect or be affected by the improvement activity
Risk
analysis
• Discount the monetised benefits and costs over the analysis period to obtain present
values
Discounting
• Use incremental cost–benefit analysis to select the preferred option for mutually
exclusive options
Incremental
analysis
• Perform sensitivity tests on the preferred option to determine how robust the
calculations are and whether a small change in one of the input parameters has a
Sensitivity large change on the evaluation outcome
analysis
Do-nothing
Most forms of activity evaluation involve choices between different options or courses of action. In
theory, every option should be compared with the option of doing nothing at all, ie the do-nothing. This
is often not practical due to limitations in analysis techniques and tools.
Do-minimum
For many transport activities, it is often not practical to do nothing. A certain minimum level of
expenditure or activity may be required to maintain a minimum level of service. This minimum level of
expenditure or activity and the resultant performance is known as the do-minimum, and should be
used as the basis for evaluation, rather than the do-nothing. It is important not to overstate the scope
of the do-minimum.
The do-minimum may include maintaining the status quo and should account for committed and
funded transport activities. For the purposes of this manual, the do-minimum is defined as the least
cost option that provides a minimum level of service.
Particular caution is required if the cost of the do-minimum represents a significant proportion of, or
exceeds, the cost of the options being considered. In such cases, the do-minimum should be re-
examined to see if it is being overstated.
If an activity’s option results in cost savings compared with the developed do-minimum, then the
option becomes the new do-minimum that all other options should assessed against.
Alternatives
Alternatives are different means of achieving the same objective as a proposed activity. For example,
travel demand management (TDM) programmes are generally alternatives to the provision of road
capacity. Alternatives should also consider whether non-transport solutions, such as changes to
existing policy, are suitable responses to the identified problem.
Options
Options are variants of a proposed activity. Activity options may differ in scale, scope, or even
alignment, and all realistic options for addressing the problem must be evaluated.
It is a common mistake for evaluations to concentrate on a single preferred option. Typically, this is
caused by a failure to understand the problem that needs to be addressed, by overstating the do-
minimum, or from narrowing the scope of analysis too early.
Some options may be classed as being mutually exclusive. Mutually exclusive options occur when
proceeding with a specific option would preclude another option from being progressed. For example,
when choosing between two different alignments for a road, the choice of one alignment precludes
the choice of the other alignment. The two alignment options are therefore mutually exclusive.
The concept of mutually exclusive options is important for incremental assessment.
Multi-modal options
When considering the possible options to solve a problem, the solutions should not be constrained to
a specific mode. Solutions to problems can come from different modes and can even be combinations
of interventions targeting multiple modes. These options should be considered in the analysis.
Time zero
Time zero is the date that all future cost and benefit streams are discounted to. Time zero for all
proposed activities is standardised to 1 July of the financial year in which the analysis is submitted.
Time zero is independent of the construction date of a proposed activity and therefore all options
being assessed must use the same time zero.
Base date
The base date is used to standardise the valuation of all monetised impacts to a common year. The
base date for all proposed activities is standardised to 1 July of the financial year in which the analysis
is prepared.
The base date does not need to coincide with time zero. It is common for the base date to be one
year earlier than time zero.
This manual contains factors for converting the value of monetised impacts from earlier base years to
the current financial year.
Analysis period
The analysis period, starting from time zero, is the period for which all costs and benefits are included
in the BCR calculations.
The time period used in economic evaluations must be sufficient to cover all costs and benefits that
are significant in present value terms.
Analysis periods specified in this manual are designed to capture at least 90% of the present value of
future costs and benefits. For a 4% discount rate, the standard analysis period remains 40 years.
An increase of the analysis period to 60 years is permitted to ensure that the whole-of-life costs and
benefits of long-lived infrastructure activities are captured. An extension of the analysis period
increases the importance of demand forecasting. Emphasis should be placed on developing a range
of options and scenarios, and on reporting uncertainty in the business cases and economic
evaluation, when the analysis period is extended.
The appropriate period of analysis may also be less than the standard 40 years. It is important to
consider the useful lifespan of an activity and adjust the analysis period accordingly. For activities with
short-lived assets, or activities where benefits dissipate quickly, it may only be necessary to assess
the activity over a 5- to 10-year period. In these circumstances changes to the analysis period should
be used as a sensitivity test.
1.7 Benefits
Benefits are any positive or negative impacts that are attributable to an activity. The benefits within
this manual have been named impacts to explicitly account for the generation of both positive benefits
and negative benefits (disbenefits).
The Waka Kotahi policy is that any expenditure on delivery, maintenance operations and renewal
is treated as a cost while all the negative impacts are treated as disbenefits.
The impacts of transport activities may affect individuals outside of the transport system.
Externalities – the impacts that affect individuals outside the transport system – must be considered in
the BCR calculation, as the analysis is conducted from a national viewpoint.
As a rule, only changes to real resources should be considered an impact in the analysis. Where
there is a transfer of resources between parties, such as a road user paying a toll, this should be left
out of the BCR. Similarly, any change in resources that is not attributable to the activity should be left
out of the BCR.
If there is no change in resources between the do-minimum and the activity scenario then there can
be no impact.
This manual provides standardised methodologies for monetising a range of impacts generated by
transport activities.
Transfers
Care must be taken to ensure that a change in real resources for one set of individuals is not offset by
a change of real resources in the opposite direction for another set of individuals. Where this transfer
occurs, there is no net effect on national resources and therefore these transfer payments must be
excluded from the BCR calculation.
Specifically, tolls, which are a cost to transport system users, simultaneously benefit transport
operators and are excluded from the BCR. It is important, however, that tolls are considered during
demand estimation.
Similarly, any changes to business or retail profitability as a result of a transport activity are also
considered transfers and must be excluded from the BCR unless there are economy-wide efficiencies
from increased competition. In this instance the wider economic impact procedures for calculating
reductions in imperfect competition, contained within section 3.12 of this manual, must be followed.
Double counting
The benefits listed in this manual generally constitute the total economic impact of improved levels of
service, accessibility or safety.
Certain external impacts of activities, such as increased land values, may arise because of an
improved level of service and accessibility, but these impacts must be excluded from the BCR
calculation. The capitalisation of reduced travel costs leads to an increase in the underlying land
value, but including this in the BCR would be double counting as direct travel-cost benefits and wider
economic benefits should already have been calculated using the benefits in this manual.
Monetisation
After benefits have been quantified they should be monetised, where possible. Chapter 3 of this
manual contains all impacts ascribed standardised monetary values for transport appraisal in New
Zealand. Section 3.15 contains advice on approaches for monetising impacts not contained in this
manual, while the Non-monetised benefits manual contains information on non-monetised measures,
namely quantitative and qualitative measures, for all of the benefits included in the benefits
framework.
any differences between market prices and resource costs, and therefore they do not require any
further adjustment.
Rule of half
The rule of half is a simplifying assumption used to calculate the benefits that accrue to transport
system users who change their travel behaviour, such as by switching their mode of travel, as a result
of changes to the cost or quality of travel.
In the do-minimum, users experience benefits from their existing travel behaviour. If they choose to
change their travel behaviour in response to a new or improved activity, then it must be the case that
they experience a higher level of benefits as a result of the activity. However, upon changing their
travel behaviour, the users must also forgo the benefits of their previous travel behaviour in the do-
minimum, which offsets the increase in benefits after the change. Therefore, the transport system
users who change their travel behaviour receive only an incremental increase in benefits between the
do-minimum and activity scenarios.
The rule of half assumes that, on average, transport system users will receive half of the incremental
benefits after changing their travel behaviour.
In the case of transport system users who change their mode of travel, some new users may have
been almost indifferent between the two modes in the do-minimum. After changing their behaviour in
response to an improvement in the activity scenario, they receive the full value of the incremental
benefits. Other new users may only be marginally better off in the activity scenario compared with the
do-minimum, and they receive almost zero benefit from the improvement. If it is assumed that new
users are evenly distributed along the demand curve, then the average new user gains one half of the
maximum incremental benefits. The sum of new user benefits can then be approximated by
multiplying half of the maximum incremental benefit by the number of new users. This is also known
as a consumer surplus calculation.
Without this assumption extensive surveys of potential travel behaviour change would be required to
establish the willingness to pay of any improvements, which is not realistically feasible for the majority
of activities.
A worked example of consumer surplus and the rule of half is provided in Appendix 8: Worked
examples.
1.8 Costs
The costs taken into account in a BCR calculation include all costs necessary for the planning and
investigation, delivery, maintenance, operation and renewal of a transport activity. These whole-of-life
costs cover all resource costs incurred at any time during the analysis period.
The full economic procedures contained within Chapter 4 of this manual list the common costs of
transport activities; however, these costs are not exhaustive and care must be taken to account for all
costs.
Expected cost
The costs included in the BCR calculation should be expected costs, which are the 50th percentile, or
p50, costs.
The expected cost is based on probability and risk theory. That is, if the activity was theoretically
delivered 100 times, in 50 instances the total cost of delivery would be below the expected cost and
the total cost of delivery for the remaining 50 instances would be above the expected cost. Full
information on estimating expected costs is contained within the Waka Kotahi Cost estimation manual
(SM014).
The expected cost must include any contingency that has been allowed for in the cost estimate.
In some instances, it may be appropriate to use 95th percentile, or p95, costs as a sensitivity test of
the cost risks of an activity.
Sunk costs
Sunk costs are costs that have been irrevocably committed and which have no realisable value
through resale or salvage.
Sunk costs that have already been incurred, such as prior investigation or design costs, must not be
included in the BCR calculation. If a pre-committed cost has a market value that could be realised in
the future, such as land, then this must continue to be included in the BCR calculation.
Interest costs
Interest payments are generally excluded from BCR calculations irrespective of any arrangements to
finance an activity by way of loans. Interest is excluded as it forms part of the cost of capital and is
accounted for in the discount rate. In the analysis, capital costs should be included as cash flows in
future years according to when the costs are incurred.
An exception to the interest payment rule applies only when Waka Kotahi borrows to fund its share of
an activity, whether this is through a traditional loan or alternative funding arrangements such as
public private partnerships (PPPs). In this instance the costs are treated as cash flows from the
National Land Transport Fund (NLTF) in the future years that actual payment is predicted to occur.
Escalation
Costs must be measured in real terms and reported in constant present-day dollars using the base
date year. In practical terms, this means that escalation is not applied to future costs and that all costs
must be calculated according to the prices of inputs in the financial year that the analysis is prepared.
Inflation and escalation are often confused. Inflation is defined as an increase in general prices
throughout the full economy. Escalation refers to an increase in the cost of inputs relevant to an
activity. The rate of escalation can be different to the inflation rate, and the rate of escalation may
even differ between inputs. Full information on cost estimation and escalation is available in the Cost
estimation manual (SM014).
No adjustments to the discount rate should be made to account for future inflation or escalation, as
the discount rates in this manual are real discount rates.
Funding gap
All BCR calculation procedures in this manual use economic costs based on changes to real
resources. This differs from financial analysis, which does include the effects of transfer payments
between parties.
The simplified and full procedures for public transport services require an additional step that includes
financial analysis of the expected funding gap between future revenue and cost of operating a
service.
The funding gap is the deficit in cash flow that needs to be funded by local and central government if
the activity is to be financially viable from the public transport service provider’s point of view, based
on the best estimate of service provider revenue and the service provider’s desired rate of return.
The service provider costs can be compared with the predicted revenue or increase in revenue if
there is a pre-existing service, using a net present value methodology to determine whether or not the
activity is viable in a financial sense.
Full information on conducting funding gap analysis for public transport services is contained within
section 4.4 of this manual.
1.9 Discounting
There is a trade-off between consuming resources now and in the future. In most instances people
demonstrate a preference in favour of immediate consumption rather than delaying consumption to
future years. This preference is the time preference or, alternatively, the time value of money.
Over a 40-year analysis period activities will have a profile of costs and benefits that are generated
over time. Furthermore, different activities will generate, often quite substantially, different profiles of
costs and benefits. However, due to the time value of money, costs and benefits in one period cannot
be treated with the same weighting as costs and benefits in another period. To ensure that costs and
benefits that occur in the future are given less weight than those incurred today, and to ensure that
costs and benefits from different years and different activities can be compared in a common unit,
they must be discounted.
Discount rate
The discount rate serves two purposes. Firstly, the discount rate represents the rate at which society
is willing to trade off present benefits and costs against future benefits and costs, thus capturing the
time value of money. In this instance, a high discount rate indicates a high degree of impatience in the
time value of money or more simply a greater preference towards immediate consumption of
resources.
Secondly, as resources committed to one activity preclude those resources being committed to
another purpose, the discount rate reflects the opportunity costs of resource expenditure. Here a high
discount rate indicates that the committed resources may have a higher return if put to an alternative
use.
In either case a high discount rate means costs and benefits incurred in future years are given much
less weight than those occurring immediately or in the near term. Therefore, particular care must be
taken when allocating cost and benefit flows to the first five years of the analysis period as this can
have a large impact on an activity’s economic efficiency compared with costs and benefits occurring
in future years.
Waka Kotahi has revised the discount rate from 6% to 4%. This is based on the social opportunity
cost of resources methodology.
Further information on the methodology used to calculate and revise the discount rate can be found in
Heerdegen (2013) and Waka Kotahi NZ Transport Agency (2019a).
Present value
The discount rate is used to calculate discount factors for future years according to the formula:
1
(1 + i)n
net costs and benefits that enable activities to be compared with the do-minimum and other activities,
despite their different cost and benefit profiles.
Chapter 5 of this manual contains the formulas used to calculate discount factors, while Appendix 6:
Discount factors contains tables of discount factors for 3%, 4% and 6% discount rates to assist in
calculating the present value of costs and benefits.
Benefit–cost ratio
The benefit–cost ratio (BCR) of an activity is calculated by dividing the present value of net benefits
by the present value of net costs.
A BCR greater than 1.0 indicates that an activity generates more than it costs, while a BCR less than
1.0 indicates that the costs of an activity outweighs its benefits.
Additionally, it is possible for an activity to have a negative BCR. This can only occur when an activity
generates net disbenefits when evaluated against the do-minimum. If an option is of lower cost than
the do-minimum, then the option is treated as the new do-minimum and therefore it is not possible for
a BCR to be negative based on costs.
BCRs can and should be used as an aid for prioritising activities when funding is constrained. An
activity with a higher BCR than another indicates that the activity with the higher BCR delivers greater
benefits per dollar of cost. Therefore, prioritising on the basis of BCRs ensures the most efficient
allocation of resources.
present value of the activity benefits in first full year following completion × 100
FYRR =
present value of the activity costs over the analysis period
The FYRR is useful for sequencing activities when funding is constrained, but it should not be used to
evaluate whether an activity is economically efficient. The FYRR indicates the extent to which the
benefits of an activity arise immediately, or are dependent on future growth, but the overall economic
efficiency cannot be evaluated on the basis of the activity’s benefits in the first year of operation.
It is a requirement that the FYRR is reported for the preferred option of any activity submitted for
funding from the NLTF. Ideally, the FYRR should be calculated and reported for a range of possible
implementation start dates. This allows changes in the FYRR over time to inform the optimal timing of
investment.
Back to 1.1 Social cost–benefit analysis >>
Scenario testing
One of the most powerful sensitivity analysis tool available is scenario testing. Scenarios are plausible
states of the future and are developed by changing key assumptions such as population and
employment growth rates, future land use patterns and future travel behaviour.
Before defining the do-minimum or developing alternatives and options, consideration should be given
to how sensitive the problem being addressed is to changes in the assumptions being made about the
future. If the nature or scale of the problem is likely to change substantially based on changes in the
assumptions, then multiple do-minimums and scenarios should be developed. Doing so early will
ensure that an appropriate range of alternatives and options are developed that are adaptable to
forecasting uncertainties.
Sensitivity testing
Sensitivity testing is a simple method of checking the sensitivity of a BCR to changes in assumptions
and uncertain input variables. The most basic method of sensitivity testing involves manipulating a
single variable, such as an activity’s cost, for a range of values to produce a BCR range. A more
robust method, which can highlight interactions between assumptions, is to manipulate multiple
variables at the same time. This should be used as a precursor to full risk analysis.
Sensitivity testing is useful for quickly testing the veracity of the analysis and demonstrating to
decision makers the robustness of the BCR to often extreme changes in key assumptions. It should
be noted, however, that sensitivity testing is unable to provide information on the probability of
outcomes occurring, and the choice of variables tested can greatly impact on the credibility of the
analysis.
When conducting sensitivity testing focus should be given to variables that have the highest impact
and are uncertain.
Risk analysis
Risk analysis is a more detailed type of sensitivity testing that involves describing the probability
distributions of the input variables and those of the resulting estimates of benefits and costs. For a risk
analysis to be possible, both the benefits and costs arising from each of the possible outcomes and
their probability of occurrence have to be estimated.
Risk analysis can support the development of methods for minimising, mitigating and managing
uncertainties.
2. DEMAND ESTIMATION AND MODE SHARE > 2.1 DEMAND ESTIMATES AND IMPORTANCE TO ECONOMICS
Travel demand
The representation of movements (vehicles, persons, etc) across the area spatially and over time.
Commonly in the form of origin–destination (OD) trip matrices and the profile of demand or
proportions through the time period modelled. (Transport model development guidelines (NZ
Transport Agency 2019)).
Trips
A trip is a journey made between a start and end point for a specific reason or purpose. A trip can
involve multiple modes, for example, a trip to work could involve walking from home to a bus stop,
catching the bus, getting off the bus at the bus stop and then scootering to the office – all of which is
one home-to-work trip. A trip chain is a series of linked trips made from point A to B, and then from
point B to point C, etc. Traditional regional transport models model trips rather than trip chains, which
are from a start point to an end point for an associated travel purpose. For example, a home-to-
recreation trip.
Demand estimation
The estimation of travel, including trip numbers, destination choices, mode choices, time choices,
route choices, etc. Demand estimation encompasses multiple and different types of analyses. One
example is developing vehicle trip origin–destination matrices representing base or future years.
Another example is estimating future-year cycle link volumes or pedestrian crossing volumes at a
particular location.
Mode share
The percentage split of demand using a particular travel mode, typically related to person travel
demand. Typically assessed travel modes are: private vehicle/car (sometimes differentiated by driver
and passenger), public transport (bus, rail, ferry, etc), walking, and cycling. Freight (for example,
commercial vehicle trips) is usually considered separately and is not considered a travel mode.
Elasticities
Elasticity is a general term for the relative rate of change of demand when compared to a causal
variable. Economists refer to elasticities as the percentage change in consumption/use of a ‘good’
caused by a 1% change in its price or other characteristic. In transport demand estimation, elasticities
typically describe a percentage change associated with a demand response linked or related to a
change in the transport system or environment. For example, public transport elasticities are defined
as the percentage change in patronage resulting from a 1% change in the relevant transport service
attribute, for example, fare level or service frequency.
Elasticities are one of many methods that may be used to develop future demand and mode choice
estimations.
Rule of half
The rule of half is applied in situations where there is a difference in the travel demand (number of
trips between any origin and destination) in the study area between the do-minimum scenario and the
activity scenario for the same evaluation year. When estimating demands and carrying out economic
assessments, it is important to distinguish situations where the rule of half is and isn’t applied; in other
words what constitutes a ‘real’ difference in trip numbers between the do-minimum and what does
not. This is important for how economic benefits are calculated from the demands used in these
assessments. (Refer to ‘Rule of half’ in Chapter 1 for more information.)
The following elements of potential changes relating to travel may produce variable trip matrices in
the activity scenario and may have the rule of half applied. The four elements listed below may be
collectively described as ‘demand responses’, particularly with reference to changes in travel between
the do-minimum and activity scenarios.
Re-distributed trips
A trip where the destination is changed due to the transport or land use activity causing the
impedance on travel to move around different areas of the network, making another destination more
attractive. For example, a home-to-shop trip, where the shopping destination alters as a particular
retail location has become easier to travel to or provides greater opportunities with the activity in
place.
Mode-shifted trips
A trip which switches from one travel mode to an alternative mode due to changes in the transport
system and/or land use bought about by the activity. For example, when a home-to-work trip
previously made by car changes to being made on public transport due to transport system changes
associated with the activity.
The study area for an economic assessment should be defined such that any potentially significant
reassignment effects associated with changes due to the activity are captured within the study area.
Where origin–destination demand matrices are used in transport economic analyses and assessment,
the OD trip volumes in the do-minimum and activity scenarios should not differ due to reassignment
(re-routeing).
The following general terms and concepts have important links with demand estimation.
Land use
Land use is used in transport assessments to describe the data and characteristics relating to the use
of land parcels (often zones in a transport model, developed from census area units, statistical areas
or meshblocks) which is used as input to estimating travel demand. Typically includes information
such as the population, households, education roll numbers, employment numbers by type, and
further information relating to family units (for example, numbers of vehicles available, income, age
band, number of school-aged children, number of working aged adults, etc).
Travel/transport capacity
The maximum number of travellers or vehicles, typically by travel mode, that can pass through a
system or a specific point in a set period of time. For example, the maximum number of vehicles that
can pass through a traffic lane on a road each hour, or the maximum number of passengers on a bus,
or the maximum number of passengers that can be carried along a rail corridor in one direction in the
morning commuter period.
Travel/transport supply
The total available capacity in the transport system by travel mode and over a time period.
Supply influences people’s choices in travel patterns, such as the destination, mode or route chosen.
As such, the transport system supply influences demand estimation.
Tolling
A fee charged for the use of part of a transport system, typically a road or waterway.
Road pricing
Fee charged for the use of roads. As well as tolling, the following are examples of road pricing:
• distance or time-based charges
• congestion charges
• vehicle-type charges
• fuel-type charges.
2. DEMAND ESTIMATION AND MODE SHARE > 2.3 KEY INDUSTRY GUIDANCE AND REFERENCES
Historical Economic evaluation manual (EEM) and Monetised benefits and costs
manual (MBCM) guidance
Older versions of the EEM and MBCM have contained demand estimation guidance. The majority of
this content has been updated or redeveloped within this chapter and Appendix 1: Demand estimation
methods and guidance.
2. DEMAND ESTIMATION AND MODE SHARE > 2.4 METHODS FOR DEMAND ESTIMATION
2. DEMAND ESTIMATION AND MODE SHARE > 2.5 DEFINITIONS OF TRANSPORT MODEL TYPES
Table 1: Guidance on potential suitability of sources of, and approaches to, demand
estimation for different geographic contexts and transport environments
Geographic Potential source/approach to demand estimation
context/transport Regional Regional Project Simple First
environment model with model with models mathematical principle
comprehensive more (may be models (eg estimates
forecasting limited fed by growth (eg
capability forecasting regional trends, trip engineering
capability model generation estimate of
and/or rate etc) facility use)
simple
math
models)
Major urban centre S P P U U
Moderate urban centre S S P P U
Small urban centre P S S P P
Township U U S S S
Rural corridor U U S S S
S = Generally suitable and likely to be available
P = Potentially useful and possibly available
U = Generally unsuitable and/or unlikely to be available
For some locations, it will be preferable to use combinations of models and techniques. For example,
in major urban centres an analyst might apply a regional transport model that takes account of
changing land use patterns, changing public transport services and the impact of new infrastructure
on destination choice, in combination with a project model for more detailed and robust analysis of
route choice and/or estimation in changes in travel time for a specific mode (such as vehicle trips).
2. DEMAND ESTIMATION AND MODE SHARE > 2.6 FUTURE GUIDANCE DEVELOPMENT AREAS
2. DEMAND ESTIMATION AND MODE SHARE > 2.7 DRIVERS OF TRIP-MAKING AND MODE SHARE
Trip-making considerations
The demand for transport is derived, it is not an end in itself. People travel in order to satisfy a need
(for example, related to work, leisure or health), undertaking an activity at particular locations (Ortúzar
and Willumsen 2011). Transport demand is the distribution of these activities over space and time.
Transport demand and supply has a strong dynamic element, for example, in urban areas a large
proportion of this activity takes place during weekday morning and evening peak periods.
Transport demand (trip-making) is influenced by various economic and socio-economic factors such
as composition of household or family unit, household size, age (school or working age), employment
status, disposable income, accessibility to activities and services, and social and environmental
beliefs. Historically, trip-making was also considered to be influenced by vehicle availability and/or
ownership, although this is likely to be evolving, particularly in larger urban areas, with access to car-
sharing companies and a shift to more social and environmental responsibility.
2. DEMAND ESTIMATION AND MODE SHARE > 2.8 LAND USE PROJECTIONS AND REGIONAL PLANNING
STRUCTURES
robustness of the assessment due to excess demand, and note how these aspects may effect
outcomes. If demand is significantly greater than supply, this will lead to undesirable situations where,
for example, the model may gridlock, there may be instability in the model results, and the models
may fail to reach convergence.
Estimating demands and mode share for the purpose of an economic assessment, particularly in
future years, effectively includes considering, and often accounting for, quantitative aspects (for
example, travel time) and qualitative aspects (for example comfort and perceived safety).
2. DEMAND ESTIMATION AND MODE SHARE > 2.9 MATHEMATICAL METHODOLOGIES AND ELASTICITIES
In addition to population, other land use data that may be input to regional transport models includes
the number of households, household composition, work or labour force, vehicles, employment by
type, and school roll.
In some regions, the road controlling authorities have systems and structures in place that may
develop a ‘given’ set of future land use projections, which are sometimes linked to the Statistics NZ
population projections. In addition, a ‘given’ set of transport system supply and service assumptions
may exist. These in turn will feed an associated set of future-year travel demand estimates. In other
regions these structures may be less formalised.
This data and these regional systems and structures are important aspects to consider when
receiving and/or developing future demand estimates. Where regional assumptions around land use
projections are less structured, more effort may be required by the analyst to check the underlying
assumptions feeding demand estimates and to be particularly mindful of the potential for optimism
bias in these assumptions. Optimism bias relating to projections and demand estimates is described
further in the section 2.11.
An Excel workbook is available on the MBCM web page to record checks on model specification, as
well as coarse and detailed checks of model outputs. These are designed to help an analyst or peer
reviewer to carry out and record some of the required sense checks, and provide Waka Kotahi with
information for assurance purposes.
Where these regional structures do exist, a level of discussion and collaboration is anticipated
between the analyst and the organisations involved in the development of land use and/or transport
supply information, so that the underlying assumptions in the demand estimates used in an economic
assessment are well established and understood. For example, existing and future traffic demands for
a subset area of a regional transport model may be provided for a project model. In this case, it is
important to understand the assumptions in the regional transport model for the future year. What PT
services are anticipated? What is the assumption of PT fares or parking costs or parking availability?
All of these assumptions in the regional transport model will be inherent in the project model and the
analyst should have, and communicate, a clear understanding on the basis of the demand estimate.
being assessed. Broadly there are two types of models that are currently most relevant to the
estimation of demands and application in economic assessments:
• regional models, which have some capability to estimate demand responses to changes in
land use and transport supply
• project models, which have no direct incorporation of land use, demographics etc. where
demands are specified as an input to the model.
Many of New Zealand’s urban centres with populations greater than around 30,000 are represented
by a regional model. All urban areas with populations above 100,000 are represented by a regional
model.
The larger the population the more complex the transport environment, and generally the more
components and aspects to the transport model system that are available. The transport models that
cover the main urban regions (Auckland, Tauranga, Waikato, Wellington, Christchurch, Queenstown
Lakes and Dunedin) have, or are likely to have in the future, some aspect of mode choice estimation
capability. Some smaller urban area models have an aspect of mode choice capability, but most of
these types do not.
A list of transport models is provided in the first table in Appendix A in Urban transport modelling in
New Zealand – data and practice and resourcing (Smith 2019). This largely focuses on regional
models – that is, models with capability to produce future-year demand estimates. As it is only a
snapshot taken at a certain time, it cannot be considered a comprehensive list of available transport
models. However, it does provide a good indication of the coverage of this form of transport model
across New Zealand’s urban centres.
2. DEMAND ESTIMATION AND MODE SHARE > 2.12 FACTORS AND CONSIDERATIONS INFLUENCING DEMAND
ESTIMATION
• Adjusting a model input, parameter or assumption that is sensitive and known to reduce PT
mode share to produce an alternative future-year demand estimation with a higher volume of
vehicle trips and lower number of PT trips (or vice versa). For example, reducing the
frequency of planned PT services, increasing modal transfer penalties reflecting people’s
general dislike of transferring.
See section 7.3: Demand estimation sensitivity tests for further discussion around sensitivity tests
relating to demand estimates.
Other reasonable responses to optimism bias include:
• analysts and clients being aware of the potential for it to occur and simply taking steps to
avoid or reduce the influence of optimism bias (for example, by not basing economic
assessments on a single demand estimation scenario with potentially high population levels
and land use development)
• clearly identifying in reporting any areas of the assessment/analysis where optimism bias may
be present and noting the effect it may have on outcomes.
2. DEMAND ESTIMATION AND MODE SHARE > 2.12 FACTORS AND CONSIDERATIONS INFLUENCING DEMAND
ESTIMATION
Table 2: Guidance on factors affecting demand – project model and calculation focus
Factors affecting demand estimates Project model/calculation approaches
Network Short Spreadsheet Straightforward
project corridor/ or similar calculations
model intersection equations/
(not linked model (not models/
to/fed by linked calculations
regional to/fed by
model) regional
model)
Suitability and appropriateness of I P P U
elasticity methods, relationships and
values
Knowledge and certainty of local land I I P P
use changes
Knowledge and certainty of local I I P P
transport system and supply changes
Source and suitability of trip rates I P P U
Expanding on Table 2, some key high-level considerations relating to each of the elements, methods
and approaches that may be used to develop demand and mode share estimates are noted below.
• Elasticity methods, relationships and values: elasticities are based on historical and
international studies into the relationships and responses in transport demand and
characteristics of the supply. An elasticity value, such as the public transport demand change
response to a fare change, may be based on analysis from a particular city over a particular
time period. The relevance and suitability of any elasticities used need to be carefully
considered when applying them to a particular activity in a certain location. Sensitivity tests –
that is, varying the elasticity value or values used – are one approach to examine the
response and suitability in relation to the specific activity in the local context.
• Local land use changes: understanding local land use changes, and the degree of certainty
related to them, are an important consideration when accounting for them in demand
estimations. Examples include new residential or retail developments nearby but outside the
study area, the impact of which will affect the demand estimate. Optimism bias may be an
issue; for example, assuming all potential plan changes occur, and are fully developed, within
a short-term horizon could overestimate future demands and the benefits associated with a
particular activity.
• Local transport system and supply changes: as with land use, the degree of certainty
around local potential transport system and supply changes and the timing of these may be
an important consideration.
2. DEMAND ESTIMATION AND MODE SHARE > 2.12 FACTORS AND CONSIDERATIONS INFLUENCING DEMAND
ESTIMATION
• Trip rates: the suitability of trip rates used in the development of existing and future demand
estimations should be checked and understood. For example, a retirement village trip rate
based on a small number of surveys in urban Sydney may not be relevant to a rural town in
New Zealand.
• Distribution analysis: the method and data used to develop first principle trip distributions
associated with a certain area and/or specific land use activity should be carefully considered.
Depending on the location and scale of the activity, if a first principle distribution approach is
used to estimate origin–destination demands it may be appropriate to check the estimated
distribution against observed data (for example, a vehicle number plate survey determining a
key distribution aspect, such as the number of trips passing directly through a town centre).
• Factoring methods: the relevance and suitability of any factors used to estimate demand
and mode share should be considered when applying this approach to a particular activity in a
certain location. For example, annual freight growth rates in rural Southland may not be
appropriate in urban locations with low volumes of freight passing through the study area.
• Trend analysis: trend analysis, which is used in the development of existing and future
demand estimations, should be carried out in a careful and considered manner. Seemingly
small inaccuracies in a trend analysis may have a significant effect on future projections; for
example, using a small sample of historical counts to estimate an annual growth rate and
applying this growth rate to predict 20, 30 or 40 years into the future. As an example of
checks and considerations, if historic traffic counts are used to estimate growth these should
be based on a sufficient sample (the number of robust data points over time) and be checked
for robustness (such as consistent vehicle classification data, seasonality effects, local
issues/events, longer term patterns in the wider economy, etc.). Sensitivity tests may be one
approach to account for broader issues such as wider economic patterns.
• Engineering estimates of predicted facility use: similar to elasticities and trip rates, the
relevance and suitability of an engineering estimate approach should be considered when
applying a method to a particular activity in a certain location. Again, using approaches that
are based on examples in major urban areas and applying these to more rural locations is an
example of relevancy or suitability check, and sensitivity testing may be one approach to
account for this form of issue.
Table 3 provides some high-level guidance on elements that may influence demand estimation,
focused on regional transport modelling.
2. DEMAND ESTIMATION AND MODE SHARE > 2.12 FACTORS AND CONSIDERATIONS INFLUENCING DEMAND
ESTIMATION
Road pricing/tolling I P U U
Route choice I I P P
Expanding on Table 3, key high-level considerations relating to each of the elements, methods and
approaches that may be used to develop demand and mode share estimates are noted below.
• Population structure/make-up: a person’s age (for example, school age, working age,
retirement age) and characteristics (for example, whether they are in the workforce or not) are
a key driver for transport demand. This is particularly important considering localised demand
around specific attractors such as schools.
• Household/family structure: the household or family unit strongly drives transport demand
in terms of the number of trips for certain purposes.
• Vehicle availability/access to a vehicle: access to a vehicle influences mode choice and
was historically a measure of overall trip-making, with households with more cars generally
undertaking more trips.
2. DEMAND ESTIMATION AND MODE SHARE > 2.13 FIXED TRIP MATRIX AND VARIABLE TRIP MATRIX ASSESSMENTS
• Access to alternative modes and infrastructure: examples include proximity at both ends
of a trip to a bus stop/service, or whether there is a quality cycleway available. These
elements will influence both transport demand (including the destination a person chooses)
and mode choice.
• Public transport coverage/frequency/charges: access to a bus stop, a public transport
service with good connectivity between a person’s origin and destination, the frequency of the
service, and the monetary fares will all influence demand by mode and also the destination
selected (for example, for shopping, recreation, etc).
• Residential density: how close a person is to activities (for example, shops or school) is a
key driver of demand (destination chosen and the resulting trip length) and mode choice.
• Parking: parking charges, availability of supply, and location of supply relative to the final
destination influence mode choice and demand (destination selected, particularly for
discretionary trips such as shopping or recreation).
• Road congestion/delay: travel times by road are a key driver of choice of mode, for
example, rail verses car. Congestion and delays are a significant factor in which route a driver
chooses, and a primary component of a demand estimate, for example, the demand for a
proposed new bypass.
• Road pricing/tolling: monetary charges are a key driver of the mode a person selects,
heavily influenced by the reason why that person is travelling. For example, a business
traveller is more likely to pay higher out-of-pocket costs to minimise the time they are not
productive. Human responses also need to be considered, as theoretically ‘cheaper’ choices
are not necessarily preferred by all people.
• Route choice: the route people choose, whether by road, cycleway, or public transport
service, influences the demand for each element of the transport system (for example,
specific roads).
• Policy and practices: these include government policies and commercial and/or employment
practices. Examples include whether employers offer more flexible working hours or working
from home, and the influence of work or school travel plans.
• Technology influences: examples of technologies that influence demand and/or mode
choice are online shopping, food delivery services, car sharing companies, and electric bikes
and electric scooters. These technological advances influence travel behaviour in terms of
how people choose to travel and where they decide to go, particularly for discretionary trips.
2. DEMAND ESTIMATION AND MODE SHARE > 2.13 FIXED TRIP MATRIX AND VARIABLE TRIP MATRIX ASSESSMENTS
• pure induced demand: entirely new trips that would not have occurred without the activity
• re-distributed trips: trip destination is changed due to the activity
• mode shifted trips: trip changes from one travel mode to an alternative due to the activity
• macro-time shifted trips: trip shifts from one discrete time period to another.
The following elements of potential changes relating to travel do not typically have the rule-of-half
applied. Or, in other words, these responses do not result in a difference in OD demand matrices
used in the do- minimum and activity scenarios;
• micro-time shifted trips: trip departure time is changed within a discrete period (more
information is provided in Applying peak spreading in Appendix 1)
• re-assigned trips: a trip travelling from A to B in the same period and by the same mode but
takes a different route to get there.
The above demand responses are described further in section 2: Key concepts.
Table 4 provides some high-level guidance on when VTM and FTM approaches may need to be
considered.
Table 4 provides general guidance, rather than specifying a prescribed approach. For example, there
are cases where an FTM approach could be applied to assess a large-scale roading activity in a
major urban centre. This could involve assigning the do-minimum demands to the activity network
scenario (or vice versa, assigning the activity demands to the do-minimum) directly in the regional
model; the FTM and/or VTM approaches may be considered as a sensitivity test.
Methods for applying FTM and VTM techniques are described further in Appendix 1 (Fixed trip
matrices and Variable trip matrices).
2. DEMAND ESTIMATION AND MODE SHARE > 2.14 DEMAND ESTIMATION UNCERTAINTY
Where a demand response is anticipated, in New Zealand’s main urban centres demand estimation
and, to some degree, assessing economics outcomes of the activity is likely to involve some form of
application of existing regional transport models. Review of the model is required to determine if it is
suitable for the assessment. For example, the assessment of a major new cycleway in an urban area
would need to consider how cyclists are represented in the modelling tools available. See section
2.10 for more information on the availability of regional models in New Zealand.
2. DEMAND ESTIMATION AND MODE SHARE > 2.14 DEMAND ESTIMATION UNCERTAINTY
Forecasting travel demand into the future may very broadly be thought of in terms of the following
horizons:
• short-term horizon, forecasting forward 10 years or less
• medium-term horizon, forecasting forward 10–20 years.
• long-term horizon, forecasting forward more than 20 years.
In congested urban centres, regional models can and do produce longer-term demand forecasts.
However, there is a noted challenge and often concern with use of longer-term forecasts in project
models being applied for economic assessment, particularly the types of project models where
vehicles are physically represented on the network, for example, microsimulation traffic models.
Techniques for scenarios where demand exceeds network capacity are described further in Appendix
1 (Fixed trip matrices and Variable trip matrices).
The issue of congested urban networks and project model application complicates considerations
around forecasting horizons for economic assessments.
Some broad considerations around forecast horizons are noted below:
• Rural area, smaller town and similar (largely uncongested): for smaller-scale activities,
although short- to medium-term forecasts may be sufficient for an uncomplicated projection
and economic assessment, in contrast it may be straightforward to produce a small number of
long-term forecasts without the sensible analysis of scenarios suffering from issues
associated with higher levels of congestion.
For larger-scale activities, it is likely to be relevant to develop a small number of longer-term
forecasts. That is, develop several sensitivity test scenarios for demand estimates 20 years or
more into the future.
• Small- to moderate-sized town, inter-urban area, urban periphery and similar (low to
medium levels of congestion): for smaller-scale activities, a small number of short- and
medium-term forecasts are likely to be sufficient for economic assessments.
For larger-scale activities, several medium- to longer-term forecasts may be appropriate, and
there is the potential that applying longer-term forecasts in project models may generate the
need to apply techniques to manage scenarios (for example, the do-minimum) where the
demand exceeds network capacity or breaches analytical limits.
• Moderate to major urban centre (medium to high levels of congestion): for smaller-scale
activities, several short- to medium-scale forecasts and demand sensitivities may be
appropriate.
Large-scale activities in congested networks are the most complex scenario and require more
careful consideration around the development and treatment of forecasts. As noted above,
regional models can and do produce longer-term forecasts; however, there are issues with
these. such as the level of uncertainty in the estimates and the levels of congestion that these
forecasts may produce in project models.
A consideration in carrying out economic assessments in larger urban areas, where higher
levels of congestion are experienced, is to test economic outcomes in two models: a regional
model, utilising longer-term forecasts where demand may not be constrained to supply when
passing through the network; and a project model, utilising short- to medium- term forecasts
where the demand and capacity representation is more overt. The project model application is
likely to include techniques to manage demand exceeding capacity. Sensitivity tests of
demand forecasts would be likely in both models.
2. DEMAND ESTIMATION AND MODE SHARE > 2.15 CHECKS, REPORTING AND REVIEWING
2. DEMAND ESTIMATION AND MODE SHARE > 2.15 CHECKS, REPORTING AND REVIEWING
2. DEMAND ESTIMATION AND MODE SHARE > 2.15 CHECKS, REPORTING AND REVIEWING
Any sensitivity tests developed are likely to be reported and include sense checks, such as those
described above. Reporting would include describing the logic behind any sensitivity test scenarios
used.
Mathematical methodologies and elasticities
Any growth rates (for example, trend rates, trip generation rates and similar) and any elasticity values
used in demand estimation should be directly reported. Key reported information relating to
forecasted or estimated demand is likely to include:
• per annum demand growth rate by time period and, where appropriate, vehicle classification
and travel mode
• total study area demand growth/change by time period and, where appropriate, vehicle
classification and travel mode
• change in travel mode by time period (total trip change and percentage mode split change)
• change in study area demand with and without an activity.
Any sensitivity tests developed are likely to be reported and include the key information above.
3. BENEFITS
3. BENEFITS
Waka Kotahi has developed a common Land Transport Benefits Framework for use across the entire
benefit management process. These benefits are mode neutral and are aligned to the Ministry of
Transport’s enduring Transport Outcome Framework (MoT TOF). High level benefit clusters have
been developed to demonstrate meaningful alignment between the new mode neutral benefits and
the MoT TOF.
In addition, the assessment process has evolved towards a more comprehensive approach through
the introduction of appraisal summary tables (AST). AST systemise the inclusion of non-monetised
impacts in the appraisal process alongside monetised benefits and costs. Thus, the new benefits
framework includes both monetised and non-monetised benefits.
In summary, the new benefits framework:
• is aligned with the enduring MoT TOF
• is used in all stages of benefit management, from business cases to economic evaluation,
and through to post-implementation benefits realisation
• includes three groups of benefits: monetised, quantitatively described and qualitatively
described
• captures the actual benefits to people, society and the environment, rather than functioning as
benefit indicators
• is mode neutral
• is direction neutral, by using the term ‘impacts’ to cover benefits, disbenefits and costs.
This manual only provides guidance on the monetisation of the benefits with provided standard
monetary value. Qualitative and quantitative measures, associated to all of the benefits included in
the benefits framework except wider economic benefits, are provided in the Non-monetised
benefits manual.
If the benefits provided in this manual are not sufficient or relevant for the improvements under
consideration, then the benefit and cost parameters can be adjusted, subject to agreement from
Waka Kotahi. Table 5 shows the whole framework in relation to the benefits specified in the now-
superseded EEM. The benefits included in this manual are highlighted in turquoise.
The monetary values presented in this manual have been measured and monetised at different
points in time and therefore have varying base dates. To update these values to the current year
Waka Kotahi provides update factors annually. The update factors also account for any escalation
in construction costs. The update factors for benefits and constructions costs are available on the
Waka Kotahi website.
3. BENEFITS
Table 5: Relationship between benefits included in the Waka Kotahi Land Transport Benefits Framework and EEM’s benefits
In EEM indicated by
MoT TOF
Benefit
Benefit cluster and
Monetised
Monetised
1. Changes in user safety Impact on social cost of deaths and serious injuries Crash cost savings (social cost of crash)
3. Changes in human health Impact of mode on physical and mental health Walking and cycling health benefits
4. Changes in impact of Impact of system vulnerabilities and redundancies Risk reduction benefits
and security
Resilience
5. Changes in transport costs Impact on system reliability Journey time reliability benefits
7. Changes in natural Impact on water External benefits (water quality and flows)
environment
Impact on land and biodiversity Other external benefits (ecological impact)
8. Changes in climate Impact on greenhouse gas emissions Vehicle emission reduction benefits
(greenhouse gas emissions)
10. Changes in access to social Impact on user experience of the transport system Driver frustration reduction benefits
and economic opportunities
Seal extension benefits
12. Changes to te ao Māori Impact on te ao Māori* Other external benefits (eg iwi, Māori values)
* It is not part of neither the MoT TOF nor the Government Policy Statement on Land Transport priorities, but a requirement of the Waka Kotahi Māori
strategy, Te ara kotahi.
3. BENEFITS > 3.1 IMPACT ON SOCIAL COST OF DEATHS AND SERIOUS INJURIES
3. BENEFITS > 3.1 IMPACT ON SOCIAL COST OF DEATHS AND SERIOUS INJURIES
network change will result in major redistributions of traffic, analysis is required of the incidence of
crashes on the links to which the traffic is being diverted and on the links for which traffic volumes reduce.
For a new link, using crash rates appropriate to its intended design, speed limit and intersections along it
can be applied. In some situations, the use of the site (or route) specific crash rates may be more
appropriate than using the crash rates provided in the Crash estimation compendium.
The full analysis process for calculating crash costs for area-wide changes in traffic networks is not
outlined in this manual, and practitioners should refer to an expert in the field of crash analysis during
this process.
3. BENEFITS > 3.1 IMPACT ON SOCIAL COST OF DEATHS AND SERIOUS INJURIES
Crash migration
When undertaking a crash analysis, it is important that the potential crash migration is considered. It is
possible that when a site (or route) is upgraded, crashes will be reduced at the site but may migrate to
a different site downstream. In this case the benefits that have occurred at the site will be offset by the
disbenefits that occur downstream. Ideally the potential for crash migration should be identified and
addressed.
Crash migration downstream of the treated site is normally not an issue in the urban road environment
(under 70km/h). Crash migration is more prevalent on rural roads and in close proximity to the site being
treated. The migration of crashes from the improved site down to the next curve or substandard road
element (eg a narrow bridge) is more likely than migration to a similar element 20km downstream.
To assess the possibility of crash migration, 1–2 kilometres either side of the study area should be
considered. If road elements, such as low-design speed curves (75km/h or less), narrow bridges and
railway crossings occur within this 1–2 kilometres, the analysis should assess whether an increase in
travel speeds through the project area will increase crashes at the adjoining road elements. If there is an
expected increase in the crash occurrence, then:
• the negative impacts (disbenefits) need to be included in the economic evaluation
• improvements need to be made to downstream road elements to eliminate or reduce the crash
migration, or
• a reduced estimate of crash savings should be used in the analysis.
A similar exercise should be undertaken for a longer length, up to 5 kilometres either side of the study
area, if the speed change from the site improvements is expected to influence speeds and driver
perception over a wider area. This may be the case for major realignments, which significantly impact on
the speed environment.
Walking
A value of $4.40 per kilometre of new facility may be applied to pedestrians using a new facility. This
value is shown in Table 6.
Cycling
A value of $2.20 and $1 per kilometre of new facility may be used for new cyclists using conventional and
electric-assisted cycling, respectively. These values are shown in Table 7.
Step Action
1 Determine the:
• traffic composition
• time period’s total average travel time per vehicle (min).
2 Convert the traffic composition vehicle classes into light and heavy emission classes according
to % of vehicle kilometres travelled (VKT):
Emission class Vehicle classes (Table A45)
Light Passenger cars
(vehicles less than 3.5 tonnes) Light commercial vehicles
Heavy Medium commercial vehicle (MCV)
(vehicles greater than 3.5 tonnes) Heavy commercial vehicle I (HCVI)
Heavy commercial vehicle II (HCVII)
Buses
3 Calculate average speed on the link road, either using a model, or according to the formula:
Speed (km/h) = 60 × length / TT
where: length = road link length (km)
TT = time period total average travel time per vehicle (min).
4 Calculate the emission rates for light and heavy vehicle types using average speed on the link
road from step 3, and emission factors from the latest VEPM version.
5 Weight the calculated emission rates by vehicle flow composition (g/vkt):
= % light vehicles × light vehicle fleet average emission factor + % heavy vehicles ×
heavy fleet average emission factor
6 Multiply the weighted emission rates by the time period’s total vehicle volume and the road’s
length (ie VKT) to give the emission load (g).
While emission rates are provided for all vehicle classes over the speed and gradient ranges, certain
combinations of vehicle class, speed and gradient do not occur in practice, such as the sustained
operation of laden heavy vehicles at high speed on steep gradients. Emission rates at these extremes are
not available, so the closest available rate is used.
Valuation of emissions
The external impacts of air emissions are costed using the damage cost approach. This assigns a cost to
each tonne of pollutant emitted to reflect the damage done to the surrounding environment, including
people and ecosystems. Emissions are calculated for each assessment scenario and then multiplied by
the costs per tonne so that the likely impacts can be compared. The damage cost approach is simpler
than undertaking exposure modelling, which requires detailed understanding of the sources, receptors,
terrain and meteorology to arrive at predicted concentrations to which exposure response functions are
then applied. However, it utilises factors which apply to the project as a whole, rather than at a local
scale.
To calculate the damage cost of each option, use the total calculated emissions for each option and the
damage cost per tonne from Table 9.
Damage costs in Table 9 have been calculated based on the 2016 value of statistical life (VoSL) of
$4,140,000 (NZ$). For project evaluations in future years, damage costs for all pollutants should be
updated based on the published VoSL. For example, if the published VoSL in June 2020 is $4,500,000
then all ‘as at June 2016’ damage costs will need to be multiplied by 1.087 (=$4,500,000/$4,140,000).
PM10 $460,012
NOX $16,347
CO $4.13
HC $1,310
Notes:
These damage costs for New Zealand have been developed based on:
• PM10 costs and emissions from Kuschel et al (2012)
• damage costs for CO and HC from Austroads (2012)
• DEFRA (2015), Valuing impacts on air quality: Updates in valuing changes in emission of Oxides
of Nitrogen (NOx) and concentrations of Nitrogen Dioxide (NO 2), which has been used to derive
NO2 damage costs as there has been considerable research on the health effects of NO2
exposure since the publication of the Austroads figures
• all costs have been updated based on Ministry of Transport (2017).
The predicted value change in emissions should be calculated and must be included in the BCR.
Emissions should also be quantified in tonnes and reported in the appraisal summary table. Kuschel et al
(2012) includes damage costs by region, which may be used as a sensitivity test.
A worked example of the Vehicle emissions procedure is provided in Appendix 8: Worked examples.
Impact of CO2
While CO2 occurs naturally, in the last 200 years the concentration of CO 2 in the earth’s atmosphere has
increased by 25%. As these extra amounts of CO2 are added to the atmosphere they trap more heat,
causing the earth to warm. This extra warming is called the enhanced greenhouse effect and is predicted
to significantly alter the earth’s climate.
CO2 makes up around half of the extra greenhouse gases and a significant proportion of this extra CO2 is
emitted by motor vehicles.
Step Action
1 Determine the:
• traffic composition
• time period’s total average travel time per vehicle (min).
2 Convert the traffic composition vehicle classes into emission classes:
Emission class Vehicle classes (Table A45)
Light Passenger cars
(vehicles less than 3.5 tonnes) Light commercial vehicles
Heavy Medium commercial vehicle (MCV)
(vehicles greater than 3.5 tonnes) Heavy commercial vehicle I (HCVI)
Heavy commercial vehicle II (HCVII)
Buses
3 Calculate average speed on the link road, either using a model, or according to the
formula:
Speed (km/h) = 60 × length / TT
where: length = road link length (km)
TT = time period total average travel time per vehicle
4 Calculate the emission rates (g/km) for light and heavy vehicle types using average
speed on the link road from step 3, and emission factors from latest VEPM version.
5 Weight the calculated emission rates by vehicle flow composition (g/vkt):
= % light vehicles × light emission rate + % heavy vehicles × heavy emission rate
6 Multiply the weighted emission rates by the time period’s total vehicle volume and the
road’s length to give the emission load (g).
While emission rates are provided for all vehicle classes over the speed and gradient ranges,
certain combinations of vehicle class, speed and gradient do not occur in practice, such as the
sustained operation of laden heavy vehicles at high speed on steep gradients. Emission rate at
these extremes are not available, so the closest available rate is used.
1For more information see the technical paper Economic valuation of greenhouse gas emissions (Waka Kotahi NZ
Transport Agency 2021) on the Waka Kotahi website.
Table 11: Recommended shadow price of carbon (NZ$2020 per tonne of CO2 equivalent)
Year 2021 2022 2023 2024 2025 2026 2027 2028 2029 2030
Low $61 $63 $64 $66 $67 $69 $70 $71 $73 $74
High $122 $125 $128 $131 $134 $137 $140 $143 $146 $149
Year 2031 2032 2033 2034 2035 2036 2037 2038 2039 2040
Low $76 $78 $80 $81 $83 $85 $87 $89 $91 $93
High $152 $156 $159 $163 $166 $170 $174 $178 $182 $186
Year 2041 2042 2043 2044 2045 2046 2047 2048 2049 2050
Low $95 $97 $99 $102 $104 $106 $109 $111 $114 $116
High $190 $195 $199 $203 $208 $213 $217 $222 $227 $232
A shadow price places a value on future greenhouse gas emissions emitted or reduced, usually
concerning international and/or national emissions goals.
Shadow prices are different from market traded prices in the Emissions Trading Scheme (ETS), which
do not currently reflect the full marginal cost of achieving New Zealand’s emission targets. An ETS is
typically only one of the many policies that governments implement to meet their climate targets.
levels of vibration perceived will be a function of vehicle size, speed, proximity to the road, subsoil
geology, building characteristics and sensitivity at the receiver location.
• consumers may not consider the full effects at time of purchase (supported by a German study
which showed increased willingness to pay with increased understanding of noise)
• effects on other travellers and on occupants of commercial or institutional buildings are not
captured
• hedonic studies typically consider values of homes which experience noise above and below
certain levels (a German study shows increasing willingness to pay as base noise rises).
A reasonable figure for New Zealand is suggested as being 1.2% of value of properties affected per dB of
noise increase (0.6% multiplied by a factor of 2 to take into account the factors mentioned by Bein). Using
average values for urban property of $640,000 according to residential property data (REINZ) February
2020, and occupancy of 2.8 persons according to Census 2018 data, this suggests a present value cost
of $7680 per dB per property and $2740 per dB per resident affected ($495 per household or $177 per
person per year). This figure should be applied in all areas, since there is no reason to suppose that noise
is less annoying to those in areas with low house prices. It is arguable as to what range of noise increase
the cost should be applied to, but a conservative approach would be to apply it to any increase above
existing ambient noise. This reflects a belief that most people dislike noise increases, even if the resulting
noise is less than 50dB.
Costs of road noise shall be valued at:
$495(2020) per year × dB change × number of households affected
Where noise affects schools, hospitals, high concentrations of pedestrians and other sensitive situations
an analysis may be required to determine the cost of noise that is site specific. The methodology for
undertaking a valuation of noise at sensitive sites should be appropriate to the site (ie willingness-to-pay
surveys may be appropriate for sites with high concentrations of pedestrians and inappropriate for
hospital sites).
Travel time values are presented in this section under the following headings:
• Base values for travel time
• Composite values of travel time and congestion
• Traffic congestion values.
Base values for travel time
Table 13 provides behavioural values of time for transport modelling purposes only. The values are for
all mode users by trip purpose in $/hour.
Table 13: Behavioural values of time for mode user for transport modelling purposes ($/h – July
2002)
Mode user Work travel Commuting Other non-work
purpose to/from work travel purposes
Base values of time for uncongested traffic ($/h)
Car, motorcycle driver 23.85 7.80 6.90
Car, motorcycle passenger 21.70 5.85 5.20
Light commercial driver 23.45 7.80 6.90
Light commercial passenger 21.70 5.85 5.20
Medium/heavy commercial driver 20.10 7.80 6.90
Medium/heavy commercial passenger 20.10 5.85 5.20
Seated bus and train passenger 21.70 4.70 3.05
Standing bus and train passenger 21.70 6.60 4.25
Pedestrian and cyclist 21.70 6.60 4.25
Maximum increment for congestion (CRV, $/h)
Car, motorcycle driver 3.15 2.75
Car, motorcycle passenger 2.35 2.05
Commercial vehicle driver 3.15 2.75
Commercial vehicle passenger 2.35 2.05
Table 14 provides values of travel time by trip purpose for all modes combined. These values are used for
calculating travel times benefits as an input into the BCR calculations. The values are in $/hour for
all trip purposes for congested or uncongested traffic conditions.
Table 15 provides values of travel time for vehicles and freight where these vehicles are used for work
purposes. The values are for vehicle and freight time in $/hour. These values are used for calculating
travel times benefits as an input into the BCR calculations.
Table 15: Values of vehicle and freight time ($/h/vehicle – July 2002) for vehicles that are used for
work purposes as an input for calculating BCR
Vehicle type Vehicle and freight time ($/h/vehicle)
Passenger car 0.50
Light commercial vehicle 1.70
Medium commercial vehicle 6.10
Heavy commercial vehicle I 17.10
Heavy commercial vehicle II 28.10
Bus 17.10
Composite values of travel time and congestion
Travel time values combining passenger and commercial (including freight) occupants, and vehicle types
for standard traffic compositions are given in Table 16. These include different time periods for the four
road categories defined in Table A46. The right-hand column gives the maximum additional values for
traffic congestion (CRV), to be applied as describes in this section.
Table 16: Composite values of travel time in $/h/vehicle (all occupants and vehicle types
combined – July 2002)
Road category and time period Base value of time Maximum increments for congestion
($/h/vehicle) (CRV $/h/vehicle)
Urban arterial
Morning commuter peak 15.13 3.88
Daytime inter-peak 17.95 3.60
Afternoon commuter peak 14.96 3.79
Evening/night-time 14.93 3.68
Weekday all periods 16.83 3.79
Weekend/holiday 14.09 4.26
All periods 16.27 3.95
Urban other
Weekday 16.89 3.82
Weekend/holiday 14.10 4.32
All periods 16.23 3.98
Rural strategic
Weekday 25.34 4.23
Weekend/holiday 19.21 5.22
All periods 23.25 4.39
Rural other
Weekday 24.84 4.24
Weekend/holiday 18.59 5.23
All periods 22.72 4.40
Traffic congestion values
Road users value relief from congested traffic conditions over and above their value of travel time saving.
The maximum increments for congestion values apply to vehicle occupants or road category and time
periods as indicated in Table 13, Table 14, Table 15 and Table 16. The actual additional value for
congestion used in the evaluation is adjusted according to the requirements for each category of delay
set out in below.
Worked examples of selected traffic congestion procedures are provided in Appendix 8: Worked
examples.
Treatment of passing lanes
An exception to the calculation below is made in the case of driver frustration benefits as the results of
passing lane projects evaluated using the procedures in section 3.8. When a separate value for changes
in driver frustration is calculated using the valuation procedure in section 3.8, no additional allowance
shall be made for congestion or improvements in trip reliability. Similarly, if passing lanes are evaluated
using the values for congestion and/or reliability outlined in this section, then no allowance can be
included for driver frustration.
Bottleneck delay
For all bottleneck delay, the maximum increment for congestion from Table 13, Table 14 or Table 15
should be added to the base value of travel time.
Table 17: Volume to capacity (VC) ratios for level terrain, overtaking sight distance and
percentage of time delayed (PTD) following slow vehicles
Table 18: Volume to capacity (VC) ratios for rolling terrain, overtaking sight distance and
percentage of time delayed (PTD) following slow vehicles
PTD % Rolling terrain – percentage of overtaking sight distance
100 90 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0
0 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00
7.5 0.04 0.03 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.01 0.01 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00
15.0 0.07 0.06 0.05 0.04 0.03 0.02 0.01 0.01 0.00 0.00 0.00
22.5 0.11 0.09 0.07 0.06 0.05 0.03 0.02 0.02 0.01 0.01 0.01
30.0 0.15 0.12 0.10 0.08 0.06 0.05 0.04 0.03 0.03 0.02 0.02
37.5 0.18 0.15 0.13 0.11 0.10 0.09 0.07 0.06 0.06 0.05 0.04
45.0 0.23 0.20 0.18 0.16 0.15 0.13 0.12 0.11 0.10 0.09 0.08
52.5 0.30 0.27 0.25 0.23 0.21 0.20 0.18 0.17 0.16 0.15 0.13
60.0 0.38 0.36 0.33 0.32 0.30 0.28 0.27 0.25 0.24 0.23 0.21
67.5 0.49 0.47 0.44 0.42 0.41 0.39 0.38 0.36 0.35 0.34 0.32
75.0 0.62 0.60 0.58 0.56 0.54 0.53 0.52 0.51 0.49 0.48 0.47
82.5 0.78 0.76 0.74 0.73 0.71 0.70 0.69 0.68 0.67 0.67 0.66
90.0 0.97 0.96 0.94 0.93 0.92 0.92 0.91 0.91 0.90 0.90 0.89
Table 19: Volume to capacity (VC) ratios for mountainous terrain, overtaking sight distances and
PTD following slow vehicles
Mountainous terrain – percentage of overtaking sight distance
PTD %
100 90 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0
0 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00
7.5 0.03 0.03 0.02 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00
15.0 0.07 0.05 0.04 0.03 0.02 0.01 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00
22.5 0.10 0.08 0.06 0.04 0.03 0.02 0.01 0.01 0.00 0.00 0.00
30.0 0.14 0.10 0.07 0.06 0.04 0.03 0.02 0.02 0.01 0.01 0.01
37.5 0.17 0.13 0.11 0.08 0.07 0.05 0.04 0.03 0.03 0.02 0.02
45.0 0.22 0.18 0.15 0.13 0.11 0.09 0.08 0.06 0.05 0.05 0.04
52.5 0.28 0.24 0.21 0.18 0.16 0.14 0.13 0.11 0.10 0.09 0.08
60.0 0.36 0.32 0.29 0.26 0.24 0.22 0.20 0.18 0.16 0.15 0.13
67.5 0.46 0.42 0.39 0.36 0.34 0.31 0.29 0.27 0.26 0.24 0.22
75.0 0.58 0.55 0.52 0.49 0.47 0.45 0.43 0.41 0.39 0.37 0.35
82.5 0.73 0.70 0.68 0.65 0.63 0.62 0.60 0.58 0.57 0.55 0.53
90.0 0.91 0.89 0.87 0.86 0.84 0.83 0.82 0.81 0.80 0.79 0.78
Figure 2: Percentage of time delayed (PTD) two-lane rural roads level terrain
For improved frequency of services waiting time is valued at two times the value of VOT.
Using the existing headway/service frequency (minutes) and the appropriate trip purpose from Table 20,
identify the changes in wait time in minutes from improving service frequency. If the proposed new
headway/service frequency is significantly less than the existing (ie 20 minutes compared with 40
minutes) an average of the wait time benefit for the two frequencies should be used.
In addition to the wait and/or walk time to transfer time that applies to service frequency benefits, there is
a five-minute IVT ‘interchange penalty’.
Calculate the interchange reduction transport service user benefits for public transport using the
information in Chapter 2 to give the projected new patronage level, as follows:
Change in net total benefits for existing public transport service users:
Biexisting = IB × Q1
Apply the rule of half for the total benefits for new public transport service users:
Binew = IB × (Q2 - Q1) × ½
For improved frequency of services waiting time is valued at 2 times the value of VOT.
The regression coefficients vary between vehicle classes and road categories.
The regression equations were used to generate the corresponding VOC tables so the results will be
consistent, irrespective of which approach is used.
Minor differences will arise when calculating road category costs from individual vehicle class costs due
to the regression equations being developed from the road category data. Where high precision is
required, the vehicle class equations should be summed and used in preference to the road category
equations.
The total VOC are calculated by adding the following components:
VOC = base running costs by speed and gradient
+ road roughness costs (if appropriate)
+ road surface texture costs (if appropriate)
+ pavement elastic deflection costs (if appropriate)
+ congestion costs (if appropriate)
+ bottleneck costs (if appropriate)
+ speed change cycle costs (if appropriate).
All components except the base running costs are marginal costs that reflect the additional cost due to
that component.
Base VOC and VOC by speed and gradient
The base VOC value is comprised of costs for fuel, tyres, repairs and maintenance, oil, and the proportion
of depreciation related to vehicle use. Standing charges, ie those incurred irrespective of use, are
excluded from these costs. Such charges are included in the travel time costs for vehicle types (Table 15)
and the composite travel time values (Table 16).
The breakdown of the base VOC by component is given in Table 21.
Information for VOC by speed (between 10km/h and 120km/h) and gradients (between 0% and 12%) is
provided in Table A79 through to Table A88 in Appendix 4: Vehicle operating cost tables. Each table is
accompanied by a graph, and the tables and graphs are generated based on the regression coefficients
and equation in Table 22. The tables give calculated values for each 5km/h and percentage gradient.
The values are the average of the uphill and downhill gradient costs. While VOC values are provided for
all vehicle classes over the speed and gradient ranges, certain combinations of vehicle class, speed and
gradient do not occur in practice, for example sustained operation of laden heavy vehicles at high speed
on steep gradients. VOC estimates at these extremes are less reliable than those in the range of normal
operation.
Intermediate values should be interpolated or predicted using the regression equation. To use the graphs,
the line of average traffic speed on the X-axis shall be read upwards to where it intersects with the
appropriate gradient curve and then the running costs read off the Y-axis.
For all vehicle classes and road categories, the graph curves slope steeply upwards at low speeds. This
is because as vehicle speeds decrease the fuel consumption is governed by the minimum fuel
consumption of the vehicle. As vehicle speeds increase above 60–70km/h the graph curves start to rise
due to the effects of increasing aerodynamic drag.
Table A79 through to Table A84 provides VOC values for individual vehicle classes for use when an
evaluation requires costs for a particular vehicle class or road category, and where the traffic composition
does not fall into one of the four standard road categories. One set of tables is provided for each vehicle
class and these combine the VOCs for both urban and rural road categories.
Where a non-standard traffic composition is considered, the combined VOCs are estimated from the
costs of the individual vehicle classes, and the mean speed of each vehicle class shall be used rather
than the mean speed of the traffic stream as a whole.
Table A85 through to Table A88 provides the VOC values for standard traffic compositions in the four
road categories.
Buses are not included in these standard traffic compositions. If buses form a significant component of
the traffic stream, they shall be included in proportion to their representation.
The regression coefficients for running costs by speed and gradient are provided in Table 22.
Table 22: Running cost by speed and gradient regression coefficients (cents/km – July 2015)
Regression Vehicle class Road category
coefficient PC LCV MCV HCVI HCVII Bus Urban Urban Rural Rural
arterial other strategic other
a 22.63 18.462 28.169 0.8776 -171.45 -64.588 18.222 20.082 13.799 15.726
b (× 10-2) -24.113 -68.843 78.13 29.814 2370.3 229 21.902 0.386 73.448 48.929
c 26.888 47.745 63.905 153.83 352.54 167.92 37.498 35.466 48.56 44.724
d (× 10-4) -274.79 -112.69 2489.4 6744.4 9495.2 2018 62.387 59.274 523.5 396.59
e -13.253 -21.98 -28.198 -60.644 -116.34 -62.435 -16.96 -16.379 -20.743 -19.475
f (×10-2) 21.932 42.74 -21.638 -51.708 -1237.6 -29.155 -2.797 8.226 -31.062 -18.239
g (× 10-4) 12.11 9.643 -175.46 -389.28 -856.38 -231.53 -13.275 -10.433 -46.437 -35.85
h 1.618 2.652 3.464 6.9893 12.236 7.209 2.024 1.97 2.4347 2.3
i (× 10-3) -34.045 -60.444 -41.352 8.8574 1605.7 -134.22 -3.588 -19.127 30.333 14.275
j (×10-3) 8.162 12.404 61.017 97.128 350.59 121.09 17.38 15.29 27.957 23.961
VOCB = a + b × 10–2 × GR + c × ln(S) + d × 10–4 × GR2 + e × [ln(S)]2 + f × 10–2 × GR × ln(S) + g × 10–4 × GR3 +
Table 23: Additional VOC due to congestion regression coefficient by vehicle class (cents/km –
July 2015)
Road type Parameter Regression coefficient by vehicle class
PC LCV MCV HCVI HCVII Bus
Urban a 4.406 7.117 9.028 26.028 69.544 16.753
b -3.807 -2.706 -1.502 -0.296 0.864 -1.034
c 5.411 4.852 3.956 3.796 3.646 4.084
Two-lane a 3.861 6.016 7.485 24.224 70.565 13.073
highway b -9.174 -12.141 -0.630 0.574 2.083 -1.216
c 10.476 13.927 2.740 2.657 2.391 3.783
Motorway a 3.297 4.995 7.200 23.101 70.020 12.073
b -23.377 -27.764 -4.979 -3.897 -1.747 -6.636
c 24.510 29.323 7.131 7.125 6.209 9.135
Table 24: Additional VOC due to congestion regression coefficients by road category (cents/km –
July 2015)
Parameter Urban Rural two-lane Motorway
Strategic Other
a 9.211 7.704 6.979 7.084
b -1.904 -1.235 -1.563 -5.931
c 4.327 3.210 3.408 7.866
When considering congestion costs, the analyst must take into account the amount of time over the year
when traffic is at different levels of congestion (ie different VC ratio). A minimum of five different one-
hourly flow periods should be adopted, reflecting low to high flows, and the number of hours per year the
traffic is at each flow level calculated (summing to 8760 h/year).
• Determine the capacity of the road (see Appendix 3: Determining the capacity of road
Step 1 sections)
• Determine the traffic flow in pcu/hr and the corresponding VC ratio, for each of the
Step 2 hourly flow periods, (see Appendix 3: Calculating the volume to capacity ratio).
• Determine the speed for each of the hourly flow periods (see Appendix 3: Travel times
Step 3 and speed).
•Determine the unadjusted VOC (including roughness, texture and deflection) for each of
Step 4 the hourly flow period speeds, using the VOC tables,.
• Determine the congestion cost corresponding to the VC ratio for each of the hourly flow
Step 5 periods, from Table A84 through to Table A87.
• Determine the total VOC for each flow period as the sum of the unadjusted VOC and
Step 6 the congestion costs.
• Determine the total annual VOC by weighting the costs for each flow period by the
Step 7 percentage of the year that flow is experienced.
If the current average roughness is less than 100 NAASRA then there is no actual benefit. Benefits
calculated for pavements with initial roughness less than 100 NAASRA (3.8 IMI) must not be used in
any BCR calculation.
Table 25 provides the regression coefficients for predicting the roughness costs.
Table 25: Additional VOC due to roughness – regression coefficients (cents/km – July 2015)
Road category Vehicle Regression coefficients – July 2015
class a b c d e f g h
Urban PC -18.7340 60.2610 -70.3654 33.9581 -5.0051 0.0000 1.5563 6.1749
LCV -40.7374 125.2187 -138.5504 63.6311 -9.3864 0.0000 1.6364 10.9954
MCV -5.3807 32.0959 -56.0757 34.6890 -5.1747 0.0000 4.0409 10.5984
HCVI -11.7978 55.7938 -87.7229 51.5985 -7.6283 0.0000 5.2343 17.2817
HCVII -11.8486 57.4700 -93.8391 56.9026 -8.2739 0.0000 7.6731 11.0394
Bus 8.2152 -5.3126 -20.7624 21.1954 -3.1834 0.0000 4.8132 8.7991
Rural PC -218.0838 820.7923 -1196.8181 841.3470 -284.8488 37.7389 1.5899 5.7369
LCV -354.1077 1315.5128 -1894.7320 1318.2982 -443.1173 58.3627 1.6956 10.2224
MCV -385.1786 1489.6027 -2226.1600 1597.0918 -548.7579 73.5481 4.0733 10.1756
HCVI -615.5214 2362.7858 -3510.1728 2508.6149 -860.6664 115.2336 5.2263 17.3873
HCVII -548.4644 2126.7038 -3187.2917 2291.2819 -787.4948 105.6226 7.7594 9.9129
Bus -354.2902 1392.3483 -2110.1669 1530.5269 -529.6939 71.3944 4.8410 8.4383
Urban All -20.1635 65.2682 -76.7324 37.2454 -5.4904 0.0000 1.7726 6.9584
Rural strategic All -267.6627 1011.6399 -1481.0149 1044.7593 -354.6592 47.0895 2.0920 6.9956
Rural other All -261.5387 987.7279 -1444.9763 1018.7473 -345.6974 45.8860 2.0043 6.8654
2 3 4 5
VOCRI = min ( {a + b x ln(RI) + c x [ln(RI)] + d x [ln(RI)] + e x [ln(RI)] + f x [ln(RI)] }, {g x RI + h} )
Where: VOCRI = additional vehicle operating costs due to roughness in cents/km
RI = max (2.5, roughness in IRI m/km)
In = natural logarithm.
Road surface texture
A vehicle’s rolling resistance is influenced by the macrotexture of the road surface and impacts on fuel
and tyre consumption. The base VOC and VOC by speed and gradient provided in Appendix 4: Vehicle
operating cost tables are calculated on the basis of 0 texture.
The effect of surface texture on VOC is as follows:
1mm increase in surface macro texture = 0.20 cents/km/vehicle (all vehicle classes combined)
Macrotexture is expressed in millimetres either as a mean profile depth (MPD) or a sand circle (SS). The
conversion between the two measures are:
SS = 0.2 + 0.8 MPD
The additional VOC due to road surface texture is added to the VOC in Table A80 through to Table A88
and is applied to the total traffic volume using the road.
Pavement elastic deflection
Most road pavements in New Zealand are of a bituminous flexible construction. Pavement elastic
deformation under heavy wheel loads depends on the type and strength of the pavement layers and sub-
grade. It influences rolling resistance and therefore fuel and tyre consumption.
The pavement elastic deformation costs from Table 26 are added to the VOC in Table A81 through to
Table A88 for MCV, HCVI, HCVII and buses and the four road categories.
Use of these costs should be accompanied by an adequate statistical sample of Benkelman beam test
results for existing pavements, or Benkelman beam equivalent values from another recognised non-
destructive test method.
Table 26: Increase in VOC per vehicle – kilometre per 1mm increase in Benkelman beam
deflection (July 2015)
Vehicle class Cents/veh/km
MCV 2.5
HCVI 3.9
HCVII 5.3
Bus 3.9
Road category
Urban arterial 0.2
Urban other 0.21
Rural strategic 0.46
Rural other 0.39
Table 27: Additional VOC due to bottleneck delay by vehicle class (cents/minute – July 2015)
PC LCV MCV HCVI HCVII Bus
1.816 2.5599 3.062 4.41 4.41 3.245
Table 28: Additional VOC due to bottleneck delay by road category (cents/minute – July 2015)
Rural other Rural strategic Urban arterial Urban other
2.105 2.151 1.997 1.994
Table 29: Valuation of public transport (PT) user benefits/disbenefits due to a price change
Proposal Users Net benefits calculations description Net benefit calculation equation and data sources
For new PT Those who have It is based on the difference between the proposed Net user benefits = (Pmax - Pnew) × Qnew × ½
services transferred from other and the maximum user charge (at which no one
Where: Pnew is the proposed user charge
modes would use the service). The result is then divided in
half, based on the rule of half. Pmax is the maximum user charge
Those who are
completely new users Qnew is the projected number of
(generated trips) new service users (see Chapter 2)
For change to The calculation of PT user benefits for a price Bptotal = Bpexisting + Bpnew
existing PT change on an existing service is based on the
services difference between the existing average user charge
and the proposed average user charge.
Existing users Existing users receive the full benefit of the Bpexisting = (P1 – Pnew) × Q1
improvement.
New users (including both New users are considered to receive on average Bpnew = (P1 - Pnew) × (Q2 - Q1) × ½ (rule of half)
transferred users and one half of the existing user’s benefit based on the
generated trips) rule of half.
Where: Pnew is the proposed user charge
P1 is the existing average user
charge
Q1 is the existing number of
passengers (patronage)
Q2 is the projected total number of
service users (see Chapter 2)
The total reliability benefit cannot exceed any travel time saving.
Services running more than 10 minutes late should be treated as 10 minutes late.
The combined value assumes a 50:50 split between departure and in-vehicle time delay en route.
Calculate the user reliability benefits using the formula below:
Reliability benefit = EL × (VTT($/h)/60) × AML × NPT
where: EL is the equivalent time to a minute late ratio from Table 30
VTT is the vehicle travel time ($/h) from Table 15
AML is the reduction in average minutes late (minutes)
NPT is the number of passengers affected.
2 The procedures in Appendix 5: Passing lanes include a separate value for the reduction in driver frustration and the
effect of reducing travel time variability. When evaluating passing lanes using the procedures in Appendix 5: Passing
lanes, no additional allowance shall be made for congestion or improvements in trip reliability. Similarly, if passing
lanes are evaluated using the values for congestion and/or reliability outlined in this appendix, then no allowance can
be included for driver frustration.
The following travel time and driver frustration benefits are generated when passing lanes reduce the
amount of time drivers spend travelling in platoons. The demand for passing and consequently the
benefits, are a function of a number of parameters including:
Calculate the driver frustration savings, using graphs in Figure 6. If necessary, multiply by the traffic
growth correction factor in Table A128 and the driver frustration update factor from the most recent
update factors, available on the Waka Kotahi website.
Table 32: Vehicle feature values for public transport services – rail
Attribute Sub-attribute Valuation Comment
(IVT minutes)
Driver/staff Train attendant 1.6
Ride 1.2 Quiet and smooth
Facilities CCTV 2.0
On-board toilets 0.6
Information Interior 1.1 Frequent and audible train announcements
Seating Comfortable 1.5
Layout 0.7 Facing travel direction
Maintained 1.5 Clean and well maintained
Comfort Ventilation 1.5 Air conditioning
Table 33: Vehicle feature values for public transport services – bus
Attribute Sub-attribute Valuation (IVT Comment
minutes)
Boarding No steps 0.1 Difference between two steps up and no steps
No show 0.1 Two stream boarding, no show pass relative to single
pass file past driver
Driver Attitude 0.4 Very polite, helpful, cheerful, well presented
compared with business like and not very helpful
Ride 0.6 Very smooth ride (no jerkiness) compared with jerky
ride causing anxiety and irritation
Cleanliness Litter 0.4 No litter compared with lots of litter
Windows 0.3 Clean windows with no etchings compared with dirty
windows and etchings
Graffiti 0.2 No graffiti compared with lots of graffiti
Exterior 0.3 Very clean everywhere compared with some very
dirty areas
Interior 0.3 Very clean everywhere compared with some very
dirty areas
Facilities Clock 0.1 Clearly visible digital clock showing correct time
compared with no clock.
CCTV 0.7 CCTV, recorded, visible to driver, and driver panic
alarm compared with no CCTV
Information External 0.2 Large route number and destination front/side/rear,
plus line diagram on side relative to small route
number on front/side/rear
Interior 0.2 Easy to read route number and diagram display
compared with no information inside bus
Info of next 0.2 Electronic sign and announcements of next stop and
stop interchange compared with no information next stop
Seating Type/layout 0.1 Individual-shaped seats with headrests, all seats
facing forward compared with basic, double-bench
seats with some facing backwards
Tip-up 0.1 Tip-up seats in standing/wheelchair area compared
with all standing area in central aisle
Comfort Legroom 0.2 Space for small luggage compared with restricted
legroom and no space for small luggage
Ventilation 0.1 Push-opening windows giving more ventilation
compared with slide opening windows giving less
ventilation
1.0 Air conditioning
Information Terminals 0.1 Screen with real-time information for all buses from that
stop compared with current timetable and map for route
Maps 0.2 Small map showing local streets and key locations versus
no small map
Countdown 0.8 Up to the minute arrival times/disruptions, plus audio
signs/real-time compared with no countdown sign
information
Clock 0.1 Digital clock telling correct time compared with no clock
Contact number 0.1 Free-phone number shown at stop compared with no
number
Location of 0.1 One payphone attached to shelter compared with no
payphones payphone
Simple timetable 0.4 Simpler more user-friendly
Stations Up to 3.0 Includes bright lighting, CCTV, cleaned frequently,
customer service staff walking around at info desk, central
electronic sign giving departure times, snack bar, cash-
point, newsagent, landscaping, block paving and photo-
booths
Experience from other SP surveys indicates that the perceived benefits of multiple features are
less than the sum of individual components. When multiple features are combined, the values should
be divided by two to adjust for any overestimation.
Waka Kotahi NZ Transport Agency (2020b) provides interim methodology and parameter values for
pedestrian facilities improvements. The interim methodology may be used but is not incorporated until
New Zealand specific values are estimated.
Walking distances
Activities that involve mode change need to be careful not to claim unrealistic walking distances. Statistics
on walking used in this manual are based on the New Zealand Household Travel Survey. The average
pedestrian trip length is estimated at 1km.
Cycling distances
Statistics on cycling provided are based on the New Zealand Household Travel Survey. The current
average cycle trip length is estimated at 3km. This applies equally to new and existing users.
3. BENEFITS > 3.9 DYNAMIC WEBS AND LAND USE BENEFITS AND COSTS
3. BENEFITS > 3.9 DYNAMIC WEBS AND LAND USE BENEFITS AND COSTS
available. A qualitative approach may be undertaken if the project faces time or cost constraints or the
scale of the project dictates.
The required spatial concentration of economic activity for realising agglomeration benefits is only
likely to occur in the major industrial and urban centres of New Zealand. It is only the large and
complex urban transport activities that will provide the relevant conditions that justify an analysis of
agglomeration benefits.
This section sets out a step-by-step process for estimating agglomeration benefits of transport
investment.
The method requires transport modelling data for the urban area of influence. Generally this will be
extracted to a spreadsheet from a regional or sub-regional strategic transport network model, using the
model zoning system or an aggregation of zones appropriate to the activity (more detailed zoning in the
urban centre and around the locality of the activity, and coarser zoning for peripheral areas). The selected
zones should give a reasonable compromise between detail and practicality.
Table 37: Weighted average agglomeration elasticities for New Zealand by industry
ANZSIC 2006 Industry Agglomeration
elasticity (ε)
A Agriculture, forestry and fishing 0.032
B Mining 0.035
D Electricity, gas, water and waste services 0.035
C Manufacturing 0.061
E Construction 0.056
F Wholesale trade 0.086
G Retail trade 0.086
H Accommodation and food services 0.056
I Transport, postal and warehousing 0.057
J Information media and telecommunications 0.068
K Finance and insurance services 0.087
An intermediate step is to calculate the agglomeration elasticities for each study zone using evidence of
each zone’s sector composition of employment. This is done by calculating the weighted average of the
elasticities using employment proportion of each sector for each zone as weights.
∑𝑆 (𝜀𝑖𝑆 × 𝐸𝑖𝑆 ) where:
𝜀𝑖 = ∑𝑆 𝐸𝑖𝑆
ε = agglomeration elasticity
E = employment
This operation requires data on base year workplace-based employment by study zone for each of the
sectors for which agglomeration elasticities are provided, as well as total employment (for the remainder
of the economic sectors a zero elasticity is assumed). Employment growth forecasts and output forecasts
are required by sector for each assessment year.
B4: Transport model outputs
The transport model data required is origin–destination matrices of demand and generalised cost for:
• each modelled transport mode
• the following journey purposes/user segments:
o work travel purpose (including freight)
o commuting to and from work
o non-work travel purposes
• the do-minimum or option scenarios
• one or more future assessment years.
A typical scenario could include two variables for public transport and car modes, three purposes, two
scenarios and one future year, which produces 24 origin–destination matrices. When gathering and
preparing the transport data, there are a number of things to bear in mind:
• Coverage of all major modes: although the transport activity under consideration may only
affect one mode, all travel modes need to be included in the analysis, as it is the relative change
in travel costs that drives agglomeration benefits. If the transport model only represents a single
mode, it will be necessary to make assumptions on journey costs for other modes and the
proportion of demand by mode.
• Separately identified user groups: if the demand and cost data is not available separately for
the required journey purposes and/or user segments, they will need to be estimated. This is
feasible by adjusting the time-cost element of generalised cost for differences in values of time
between user groups.
• Complete cost matrices: for the analysis the cost matrices need to contain cost information for
all origin–destination movements where there is travel demand. This is to avoid weight being
given to origin–destination pairs where the costs are set arbitrarily high or low (transport model
matrices frequently contain zeros or very high cost on pairs where there is no cost information).
This includes intra-zonal movements. There should be no zeros or empty cells.
Where the available data does not cover all modes or there are missing cells, the matrices should be
complemented with evidence from other sources. Possible sources include:
• time, cost or demand data from other transport models
• distance and/or journey time data from GIS or journey planning tools
• assumptions on average time/cost per kilometre
• census travel to work data
• travel surveys.
Step C: Calculate weighted average costs for in-work and travel to work across all modes
The relevant measure of journey costs for the purpose of assessing agglomeration impacts is the
weighted average generalised cost for work travel purposes (including freight where relevant) and
commuting to and from work, across all modes.
Demand should be used as weights. So, for a given origin–destination pair, the relevant generalised cost
for the do-minimum or options:
where:
AGC is the average generalised cost
∗,𝑚,𝑝 𝑆,𝑚,𝑝 D is the demand
∑𝑚,𝑝 𝐷𝑖,𝑗 𝐺𝐶𝑖,𝑗
𝐴𝐺𝐶𝑖𝑗𝑆 = ∗,𝑚,𝑝
GC is the generalised cost
∑𝑚,𝑝 𝐷𝑖,𝑗 S is the do-minimum or option
m is the mode
p is purpose
I is origin
J is destination
Note: the superscript * on demand reflects that these weights need to be identical for both the do-
minimum and option, eg the sum of the do-minimum and option demands.
Step D: Calculate effective density by zones for each scenario
The effective density of employment is calculated for each scenario and assessment year using the AGC
from step C and the total employment by zone gathered in step B, using the following relationship:
𝐸𝑗𝑆 Where:
𝐸𝐷𝑖𝑆 = ∑ ED is effective density
𝐴𝐺𝐶𝑖𝑗𝑆 E is employment
𝑗
If the agglomeration analysis is undertaken by industrial sectors, this step will have to be repeated for
each of the sectors where there is agglomeration evidence (in other words there will be another subscript
for all variables in the two equations, except for the effective densities, since these are always calculated
based on total employment by sector).
Step F: Sum output increases across all zones in the study area
The final step in estimating the impact of the intervention on productivity is to sum the agglomeration
gains across the study zones:
where:
𝐴𝑔𝑔𝑙 = ∑𝑖 𝑑𝑃𝑅𝑖 Aggl is total agglomeration benefits from the
interventions.
The total annual commuting cost savings for workers living in zone i is calculated by multiplying the
change in commuting cost for each destination by the number of commuters and summing.
where:
dGif is total annual commuting cost savings for workers
living in zone (i) and forecast year (f)
𝑓 𝑂𝑃𝑇,𝑓 𝑂𝑃𝑇,𝑐,𝑓 𝐷𝑀,𝑐,𝑓
𝑑𝐺𝑖 = ∑ 𝑊𝑖𝑗 (𝐺𝑖𝑗 − 𝐺𝑖𝑗 ) WijOPT,f is the number of workers commuting from zone i
𝑗 to zone j in option (OPT) and forecast year (f)
GijOPT,c,f is the average generalised cost across
commuting purpose (c), forecast year (f), and option
(OPT), between origin zone (i) and destination zone (j)
do not value. A standard approach would be to suggest that benefit arises to the extent that the increase
in price is paid by foreigners, ie represents a terms of trade improvement, so the country is able to sell its
exports at higher price. This is an additional source of benefit, although one that is unlikely to be
quantitatively significant for any single transport project (Venables 2016).
Labour demand is more likely to impact through the national labour market and, as suggested above, is
likely to displace workers from other jobs.
where: Business user benefits is total conventional business user benefits from travel time and vehicle
operating cost savings
f is forecast year
τ is imperfect competition uplift factor.
This can typically add up to an additional 5% of wider economic benefits over conventional benefits.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 100
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Table 40 estimates the average value added per international visitor night on a regional basis. The full
methodology used to estimate these figures is available in Waka Kotahi NZ Transport Agency, 2019b.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 101
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Table 40: International visitor activity and estimated economic activity, by region ($2018)
Region International guest Estimated spending Estimated value
nights (000s, per guest night added per guest
unadjusted) (adjusted to match night (adjusted to
IVS) match IVS)
Northland 702 $112 $41
Auckland 3,503 $367 $143
Waikato 1,114 $178 $69
Bay of Plenty 1,521 $114 $46
Hawke’s Bay, Gisborne 388 $148 $56
Taranaki, Manawatū, Wanganui 454 $165 $60
Wellington 1,038 $228 $91
Nelson, Marlborough, Tasman 902 $122 $45
Canterbury 2,603 $164 $62
West Coast 912 $98 $35
Otago 3,758 $159 $63
Southland 700 $108 $39
Total 17,595 $194 $75
Sources: Statistics NZ International Visitor Survey, Accommodation Survey, Tourism Satellite Account,
and Annual Enterprise data; MBIE Monthly Regional Tourism Estimates.
The data indicates that there are regional variations in spending patterns and economic impacts, and
therefore displacement of activity between regions has real effects on national benefit levels. In addition,
it implies that, on average, each additional dollar of tourist spending results in around $0.39 in value
added.
The estimated value added data in Table 40 should be relied upon for calculating the economic benefits
of increased international tourist activity. The use of non-standard values will require submission of
sufficient supporting evidence and the agreement of Waka Kotahi.
For help, or to discuss project requirements, please contact the MBCM team through
[email protected].
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 102
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
3. BENEFITS > 3.14 COMPOSITE VALUE FOR ABATEMENT OF MARGINAL CONGESTION COSTS
Visitor spending must not be reported as a measure of economic benefits as this does not account for the
cost to serve visitor spending. Similarly, regional economic benefits must not be reported, as Waka Kotahi
takes a national view of economic benefits and costs and any displacement effects must be accounted
for.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 103
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
3. BENEFITS > 3.14 COMPOSITE VALUE FOR ABATEMENT OF MARGINAL CONGESTION COSTS
positive benefits to remaining road users. Some activities, however, may achieve their improved transport
service level by reducing the available road capacity for other road users. The level of traffic congestion to
remaining users may then be increased, creating a negative impact. Also, traffic congestion may be
increased where a proposed transport service increases the number of public transport vehicles on roads
shared with other traffic.
The effect of increased transport output on overall traffic congestion will depend on:
• the change in the number of public transport vehicles per hour per period
• their size and performance characteristics
• the reduction in the number of trips
• the do-minimum composition of road traffic flow.
A composite benefit is defined for valuation of benefits related to changes to road traffic that usually
include impact on network productivity and utilisation (travel time cost and vehicle operating cost), and
impact on social cost of deaths and serious injuries.
Impact on greenhouse gas emissions, which was included as part of the composite values in the previous
version of the MBCM, is no longer included in the values as it needs to be calculated using the new
procedure (see section 3.4) and reported separately in the AST.
Road traffic reduction benefits critical to the outcome of the evaluation may include:
• traffic volumes, particularly model results, growth rates and the assessment of diverted and
generated traffic and transport service users
• travel speeds
• crash reduction.
For each significant factor the following shall be listed:
• the assumptions and estimates on which the evaluation has been based
• an upper and lower bound of the range of the estimate
• the resultant BCR at the upper and lower bound of each estimate.
Extra caution for double counting is required when the composite value for abatement of marginal
congestion costs is used to calculate activities benefits.
With respect to transport services, road traffic reduction benefits shall generally be limited to peak
periods. The evaluator shall specify, and justify, the peak period times.
In some cases, for instance with most freight transport services, it may be appropriate to also consider
off-peak period road traffic reduction benefits.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 104
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Table 41: Diversion rates and composite benefit for abatement of marginal congestion costs for
major urban corridors (worksheet SP9.1)
Urban area Diversion rate (vehicle/km Road traffic reduction benefit
removed from road per new ($/vehicle/km per year removed
public transport passenger km) from road – 2008)
Auckland 0.725 (72.5%) $1.54
Wellington 0.777 (77.7%) $0.99
Christchurch/other 0.675 (67.5%) $0.34
• Simplified procedure for existing public transport services (SP10): road users benefit from road
traffic reduction is estimated using the composite benefit for abatement of marginal congestion
costs including travel time savings, impact on network productivity and utilisation (travel time cost
and vehicle operating cost), impact on greenhouse gas emissions and impact on social cost of
deaths and serious injuries. Table 42 below provides default values for use within SP10.
Often, changes to existing public transport services are limited to additional peak period services
that remove commuters from private vehicles. In such cases the cost of the service should only
include the capital costs and the maintenance and operating costs of providing the additional
peak period public transport services where there are road traffic reduction benefits.
Table 42: Composite benefit for abatement of marginal congestion costs for major urban corridors
by PT modes ($/additional passenger boarding) (worksheet SP10.1)
Urban area Mode Average trip Road traffic reduction benefits
length (km)
Peak Off peak
Auckland All 7.70 12.44 0.85
Rail 16.50 17.04 1.63
Bus/ferry 6.60 11.57 0.75
Wellington All 12.14 13.07 1.23
Rail 22.76 17.46 1.96
Bus/ferry 6.97 11.81 0.88
Christchurch All 8.05 2.67 1.22
Other All 7.86 2.03 0.99
• Walking and cycling activities: in addition to walking and cycling benefits a composite benefit, for
abatement of marginal congestion costs, of $0.10 (2008) per pedestrian or cyclist per kilometre of
new facility may be applied to pedestrians or cyclists using a new facility.
Valuation methods
There are two types of consumer preference surveys – revealed preference (RP) surveys and stated
preference (SP) surveys:
RP surveys observe actual behaviour under varying conditions, for example the modes of travel used by
household members relative to the level of service of public transport. This information is then analysed to
identify and quantify the factors that influence travel decisions.
SP methods ask individuals how they would respond to various situations. Two techniques used in SP
analyses are contingent valuation and conjoint analysis. Contingent valuation (attitudinal) surveys ask
respondents directly how they would respond to various situations, or ask them to rate or rank their
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 105
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
preferences for various levels of service, facility or situation. This often gives values several times higher
than what they would be in reality, because people often do not do what they say they would do. This
type of survey tends to be better suited to evaluating relative preferences and for estimating the maximum
possible response to an action, than to predicting actual changes in travel.
Conjoint analysis (hypothetical choice) surveys require respondents to make choices between
hypothetical alternatives with varying attributes. It is necessary to have forced trade-offs so that a better
environment might be coupled with higher costs or a higher travel time. This forces the respondent to
relate the value of each component of preference.
SP surveys need to be stratified by audience: current users versus potential users. Current users should
be asked to respond to questions about factors that would provide for a more comfortable or attractive
journey through different types of environments, facilities or levels of service.
For potential users, it is important to create scenarios based on constructed markets. For example,
questions could include what mode they would choose for work and non-work trips based on the quality
of the transport environment, including travel by private vehicle, public transport, walking and cycling. It
would query residents about the degree to which they perceive different levels of service or facilities
would improve the conditions of their commute, recreational activities and so forth. By measuring how
demand might change, one can ascertain the preferences of current non-users, some of whom would
become users if certain improvements were made.
Analysts may wish to consult other sources for guidance as to the design and implementation of SP
surveys to derive willingness-to-pay values. Waka Kotahi may be able to provide some assistance in this
regard.
Benefit transfer is also one of the common methods is used for economic evaluation and specifically for
environmental benefits:
Benefit transfer, also known as value transfer, is simply using results of previous studies of analogous
situations (source values) to provide information about values of the case under consideration (study
values). Benefit transfer can be inexpensive and rapid if suitable source studies are available. Source
values can be transferred to the study project as point estimates, value functions, or as meta-analyses.
Meta-analyses, which draw information from a large number of previous studies, provide useful
information on source study valuation contexts, and identify adjustments required to transfer source
estimates to the study case. Meta-analysis also provides an indication of the variability of value estimates
and so is recommended rather than point and value function transfers from individual sources or a small
number of studies.
Great care is required to match source and study scenarios. Non-market values are highly sensitive to
context and can vary because of differences in the nature of the resource, the availability and prices of
substitutes and complements, underlying preferences, cultural context, environmental value orientations,
socio-economic characteristics, demographics, population density, transport availability, and other
matters.
Even the most careful and comprehensive benefit transfer studies can be extremely inaccurate. Hence,
benefit transfer is recommended primarily as a useful aid in determining whether non-market values are
likely to be significant for the project under evaluation, and whether a primary valuation study is
warranted.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 106
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
database. A link to the research results and database will be provided when it is ready for publication later
in late 2021.
The methodology for estimating probability and cost of disruption may vary depending on the nature of
the disruption, availability of data, interdependency and criticality of infrastructures. There are some
methodologies developed from the relevant research (see McWha 2020 and Hughes 2020) that can be
referred to, but the analysis is more on a case-by-case basis as there has not been one methodology that
fits all situations.
Back to 1.7 Benefits: Monetisation >>
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 107
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Composite benefit values have been derived for a range of travel behaviour change (TBhC) activity types
and situations. The composite benefit values include benefits to the people changing their travel
behaviour as well as benefits to remaining road users and the general community, such as reduced
health costs and accident cost savings, vehicle operating cost (VOC) savings and environmental benefits.
Composite benefit values are the average annual benefit for all people in the workforce, school or
community targeted by the TBhC activity (and take account of the proportion that do not participate or
change their travel behaviour).
The composite benefits also incorporate the default diversion rate assumptions for each TBhC activity
type as well as the average trip length for each mode affected by the proposal. If evaluators consider they
have strong reasons why a different diversion rate is more appropriate for the situation they can
interpolate a composite benefit value (based on the values given below and the particular situation
compared with the default diversion rates) for workplace travel plans, or use a computer spreadsheet
programme (available from Waka Kotahi) to forecast a diversion rate and calculate a composite benefit
value for any TBhC proposal.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 108
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 109
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
4. EVALUATION PROCEDURES
4.1 Introduction to procedures
Predecessors of this manual split evaluation procedures for activities across dedicated chapters for the
simplified and full procedures, and individual appendices. In this manual, evaluation procedures have
been grouped according to the type of activity to be assessed and are designed to be read as a whole.
Relevant information and data has also been transferred from the appendices of the superseded
Economic evaluation manual (EEM) where appropriate.
Before undertaking an evaluation, in-depth consideration must be given to the problem that is to be
solved or mitigated. This initial work to define the problem and consider potential solutions is part of the
Business Case Approach undertaken by an approved organisation and is included in their regional land
transport plans (RLTPs). These procedures do not include this initial problem definitional work but rather
start following the problem definition. As a result of the evaluation the potential solutions and
improvement options may be adjusted or changed during the process due to the availability of additional
or new information as the process develops.
This section includes the evaluation procedures for the following major types of activities:
• walking and cycling
• roading activities
• public transport services
• travel demand management
• education, promotion and marketing
• freight activities
• private sector financing and road tolling.
Each evaluation procedure offers two methods for assessing activities, and the choice of an appropriate
assessment methodology will depend on an activity’s size, risk and complexity.
Table 46 illustrates the relationship between the individual simplified procedures and the types of
improvement activities that are covered by full procedures. While some simplified procedures are directly
relevant to a single type of activity, there are other simplified procedures that may be used to assess
multiple transport and non-transport improvement activities.
The simplified procedures are designed to simultaneously establish the project impacts and the
monetised benefits and costs of undertaking activities that are low-cost and have low levels of risk and
complexity. The full procedures are designed to first establish the impacts of proposed options and then
assign these impacts monetary values, in order to establish the monetary benefits, before calculating the
BCR and other economic indicators.
Back to section 1.8 Costs >>
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 110
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Education, promotion
Walking and cycling
Types of activities
Freight activities
Public transport
Travel demand
and marketing
Private sector
management
services
Simplified procedure
tolling
SP1 Road renewals
SP2 Structural bridge renewals
SP3 General road improvements
SP4 Seal extensions
SP5 Isolated intersection improvements
SP6 High productivity motor vehicle (HPMV)
route improvements
SP8 Freight transport services
SP9 New public transport services
SP10 Existing public transport services
SP11 Walking and cycling facilities
SP12 Travel behaviour change
SP13 Road safety promotion
The two simplified and full assessment methodologies are described below in more detail.
Simplified procedures
The simplified procedures are designed for the appraisal of activities that are low-cost and have low
levels of risk and complexity. Thresholds for activity value also apply (see Table 47).
This manual contains simplified procedures for the following types of sub-activities:
• SP1 Road renewals
• SP2 Structural bridge renewals
• SP3 General road improvements
• SP4 Seal extensions
• SP5 Isolated intersection improvements
• SP6 High productivity motor vehicle (HPMV) route improvements
• SP8 Freight transport services3
• SP9 New public transport services
• SP10 Existing public transport services
• SP11 Walking and cycling facilities
• SP12 Travel behaviour change
• SP13 Road safety promotion.
The criteria and thresholds applicable for deciding whether a proposal is of low-cost, risk or complexity
are described at the beginning of each evaluation procedure.
Each simplified procedure is a stand-alone procedure. They are designed to be applied directly to each
option being considered. Table 47 provides a summary of all 12 simplified procedures covered in this
manual.
3 There is no SP7. A gap has been left to accommodate future simplified procedures for roading or public transport
activities. Since two earlier manuals were combined into the EEM there has only been one new SP developed: SP6,
which was brought into play when the Vehicle Dimensions and Mass (VDAM) Rule 2016 was established and
allowed the use of high productivity motor vehicles (HPMV).
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 111
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Analysis which alters components of the simplified procedure should not be used as this will
compromise the assumptions on which the procedure is based. In these instances, the full procedures
should be used instead.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 112
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Full procedures
The full procedures are to be used to appraise economic efficiency when the assumptions contained in
the simplified procedures, including any cost limits, are exceeded.
The full procedures may be used for all types of land transport activities with appropriate adaptation. The
benefits and costs considered in the evaluation should be adjusted or added to as appropriate for the
activity type.
As much as possible, the full procedures are standardised to follow the same period of analysis and
utilise the Waka Kotahi worksheets, available on the MBCM page on the Waka Kotahi website.
Analysis period
The standard analysis period for improvement activities is 40 years from the year in which significant
benefits or costs commence, unless otherwise agreed with Waka Kotahi. For activities with short-lived
assets, or activities where benefits dissipate quickly, it may only be necessary to assess the activity over
a 5- to 10-year period.
There are three critical times to be set up for the analysis process:
1. time zero – the date that all future cost and benefit streams are discounted to
2. analysis period – the period, starting from time zero, for which all costs and benefits are
included in the BCR calculations
3. base date – the date used as a basis for determining the monetary unit values of costs and
benefits.
Where several options are being evaluated, the analysis period for all options shall be determined by the
option with the earliest benefit or cost. The start of construction/implementation shall be the earliest
feasible date, irrespective of expectations of funding.
Worksheets
The full procedures contain two worksheets to guide the calculations and encourage consistency of
analysis. The two worksheets are Crash cost savings and Transport modelling checks. These worksheets
are to be used as far as is practical when preparing evaluations. Non-standard worksheets may be
submitted with evaluation reports provided the necessary information can be readily obtained from such
worksheets and the information is referenced on the activity checklist.
The worksheets provided in this manual are designed to allow some flexibility in methods of calculation,
since no two activity evaluations are exactly the same.
Summary of the evaluation results will be reflected in the appraisal summary table (AST) and much of the
information required in AST and worksheets contributes to the Waka Kotahi funding allocation process.
The expectation is that the data entered in AST and worksheets can be transferred to Transport
Investment Online (TIO) and vice versa as appropriate.
Blank worksheets can be downloaded in MS Excel format from the MBCM page on the Waka Kotahi
website.
The provided templates must be used when using the simplified procedures. The completed templates
should be attached in TIO. The templates are standardised to allow automated uploading and data
extraction.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 113
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Cycling and walking promotion is addressed as part of the evaluation procedures for education,
promotion and marketing in section 4.6.
Activities that involve mode change need to be careful not to claim unrealistic walking distances.
Statistics on walking used in this manual are based on the New Zealand Travel Survey. The average
pedestrian trip length is estimated at 1km.
Statistics on cycling provided are based on the New Zealand Household Travel Survey. The current
average cycle trip length is estimated at 3km. This applies equally to new and existing users.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 114
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Table 49: Steps in the SP11 evaluation of walking and cycling activities
Step Description
1 Complete items 1 to 3 of Worksheet 1 – Evaluation summary
2 Complete Worksheet 2 – Cost of do-minimum
3 Complete Worksheet 3 – Cost of option(s)
4 Complete Worksheets 4 to 7 for the option(s) being evaluated
5 Complete Worksheet 8 – Incremental analysis (if more than one option is considered)
6 Select the preferred option and finalise Worksheet 1 for the preferred option
Table 50 provides the required benefits factor for different types of cycle facilities.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 115
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 116
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
• the location of the facility, the route length, and connectivity of walking and cycling paths or lanes
• the population served by the facilities, and
• any education, promotion and marketing.
Studies have shown there is a positive correlation between the number and quality of facilities that are
provided and the percentage of people who use cycling for commuting purposes. It has also been
observed that, in addition to having walking and cycling facilities, they must connect appropriate origins
and destinations, and use of the facilities must be promoted to encourage walking and cycling as
alternative commuting modes.
Education, promotion and marketing are significant drivers for generating demand for walking and cycling,
and any associated mode shift from private vehicles. The methodology for estimating travel impacts in
section 2.2 should be used to estimate the number of private vehicle trips diverted to new or improved
walking and cycling facilities when this is part of a package that includes TBhC activities.
Where a new or improved walking or cycling facility provides a significantly improved quality of service,
trips in addition to those diverted from private vehicles may be generated. The total demand for the facility
may be estimated using the procedures in section 2.2. Table 52 may be used to estimate the demand for
a new cycle facility when traffic counts have not been carried out, or the counts are considered unreliable.
Table 52 calculates the population within catchments surrounding the facility. It then applies a probability
factor to estimate the number of new cyclists who will use the facility by considering their distance from
the facility and the current mode share of commuting cyclists. If up-to-date local data is unavailable, Table
53 contains cycling commute shares for all territorial authority areas as reported in the 2013 census.
The likelihood multiplier is an adjustment for the likelihood of new cyclists using the facility in each
buffer. Cyclists further from the facility are less likely to use it.
The buffer distances are defined as <0.4km, 0.4km to <0.8km and 0.8km to ≤1.6km. These represent
the area from the facility which is likely to be affected by the proposal. When calculating the area of each
buffer, the areas of buffers between it and the facility need to be excluded.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 117
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
The cycling commute share is based on journey to work data from the 2013 New Zealand census and is
reported by territorial authority area. These indicators were prepared excluding ‘worked at home’ and ‘did
not go to work’ modes.
Back to 2.2 Forecasting demand: procedures for travel behaviour change activities >>
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 118
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 119
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
time that cyclists would spend travelling on each type of facility, and the incremental attractiveness of that
type of facility, when compared with a base case of 20 minutes of travel in traffic with road-side parking.
The study is the basis of the values in Table 35.
Stage 4: Calculate costs of walking and cycling do-minimum and options
In general, the costs of walking and cycling activities are limited to:
• planning, investigation and design fees
• costs of property required for the activity
• construction costs
• maintenance and renewal costs, including repair and reinstatement
• facility operating costs.
Stage 5: Discount benefits and costs
Refer to section 1.9 and Chapter 5 of this manual for the detailed information on undertaking discounting.
Benefits and costs generally arise throughout the life of projects, and to calculate their present worth or
present value they need to be discounted back to time zero. Based on a discount rate of 4% and an
analysis period of 40 years, sets of present-worth factors have been calculated to convert future benefits
and costs to their present values. (See Table 102, and Table A132, Table A133 and Table A134 from
Appendix 6: Discount factors. Discount rates of 3% and 6% are also provided in the tables for sensitivity
testing.)
Stage 6: Determine the benefit–cost ratios of the options
Refer to Chapter 6 for detailed information on developing BCRs.
Stage 7: Incremental cost–benefit analysis
Where alternatives and options are mutually exclusive, incremental cost–benefit analysis of the
alternatives and options is used to identify the optimal economic solution.
The incremental BCR indicates whether the incremental cost of higher-cost project alternatives and
options is justified by the incremental benefits gained (all other factors being equal). Conversely,
incremental analysis will identify whether a lower-cost alternative or option that realises proportionally
more benefits is a more optimal solution.
Refer to section 6.3 for detailed information on developing incremental BCRs.
Stage 8: Perform sensitivity and risk analysis
Refer to Chapter 7 of this manual for detailed information on sensitivity and risk analysis.
Assessing the sensitivity of impact evaluations and resulting benefits calculations to critical assumptions
or estimates shall be undertaken using sensitivity testing, which needs to be undertaken for the critical
inputs and assumptions used to choose the preferred option.
Sensitivity testing involves defining a range of potential values for an uncertain variable in evaluation and
reviewing the variation in the evaluation as the variable changes within the range. This will highlight the
sensitivity of the estimated final outcome to changes in input variables.
Inputs to walking and cycling facility evaluations that should be considered for sensitivity testing include:
• demand estimates, and
• major contributors to benefits.
Benefits critical to the outcome of the evaluation may include:
• pedestrian and cyclist volumes particularly those derived from model results
• growth rates and assessments of diverted and generated traffic, and
• crash reductions.
For each significant factor the following must be listed:
• the assumptions and estimates on which the evaluation has been based
• an upper and lower bound of the range of the estimate, and
• the resultant BCR at the upper and lower bound of each estimate.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 120
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
4. EVALUATION PROCEDURES > 4.3 EVALUATION OF ROAD RENEWAL AND IMPROVEMENT ACTIVITIES
The results of the sensitivity tests, along with an explanation of any assumptions or choice of test, must
be reported.
Stage 9: Verification of results
Verify completeness of information, accuracy of calculations and validity of assumptions.
For the more simple and relatively standardised improvement activities with an undiscounted whole-of-life
cost of $15 million or less, simplified procedures are provided for the analysis and these are explained
below. For the more complicated projects, and those with an undiscounted whole-of-life cost greater than
$15 million, the full procedures are provided as an alternative to the simplified procedures and are
explained later in this section.
The simplified procedures are designed to consider one option at a time. All suitable options for the
proposed works should be considered in order to select the optimal solution. In most situations this will
involve incremental analysis of the benefits and costs of the different options analysed. A description of all
options considered should be described in worksheet 1 and included in the incremental analysis; for all
other worksheets, only the details of the preferred option need to be included.
It is necessary for all the activities covered by SP1 to SP5 to determine the expected future traffic growth
rate. This can be done either by analysing the traffic count data, following the procedures in Appendix 3:
Traffic data and travel time estimation, for at least the last five years and preferably for the last 10 years,
or by using a default growth rate of zero percent. Simplified procedures SP1 and SP2 are for road
renewals and bridge renewals respectively. These renewal activities are a type of improvement when
compared to the do-nothing or do-minimum, but they are targeted at maintaining the status quo.
Procedure SP3 is for general road improvements, while SP4 is for seal extension works, and SP5 is for
isolated intersection improvements. If an intersection improvement is part of an overall corridor
improvement or is being undertaken with other road improvement works, then it should be considered as
part of a package or programme of works.
Refer to the Waka Kotahi Planning and Investment Knowledge Base (PIKB) for guidance on issues
relating to analysis of road activities, including selection of the preferred option using the Business Case
Approach.
The simplified procedure templates provided must be used when undertaking simplified evaluations. The
completed templates are to be included in Transport Investment Online (TIO). The templates are
standardised to allow automated uploading to and data extraction from TIO.
Each simplified procedure is a stand-alone procedure designed to be applied directly to each option being
considered. Input values may be obtained from:
• the default figures provided
• activity specific data collected, or
• the information in the appendices.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 121
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
4. EVALUATION PROCEDURES > 4.3 EVALUATION OF ROAD RENEWAL AND IMPROVEMENT ACTIVITIES
Analysis that alters components of the simplified procedure should not be used as this will compromise
the assumptions on which the procedures are based and full procedures should be used instead.
If the analyst has any problems with the simplified procedures templates or worksheets, please contact
[email protected].
SP1 for road renewal activities
SP1 provides a simplified method of appraising the economic efficiency of work to be funded under work
categories within the maintenance activity classes, for example pavement rehabilitation.
To be considered eligible for funding under these work categories, the activity must be shown to be the
long-term, least-cost option for the road controlling authority, and must not include geometric
improvements. SP 1 therefore stands apart from all other simplified procedures by solely comparing the
whole-of-life costs of each option and excluding any calculation of benefits.
Under these procedures the present-value cost of the option is determined and compared with the
existing maintenance strategy. An existing maintenance strategy commonly includes pavement
maintenance work such as dig-outs, reseals, and/or other localised repairs needed to ‘hold’ the condition
of an asset.
Guidance for completing the SP1 Road renewals (template worksheets) is provided below Table 54 and
Table 55.
Step Description
1 Complete items 1 to 3 of Worksheet 1 – Evaluation summary
2 Complete Worksheet 2 – Existing maintenance strategy
3 Complete Worksheet 3 – Cost of option(s)
Select preferred option – refer to work category 214: Sealed road pavement
4
rehabilitation on PIKB
5 Complete items 4 to 7 of Worksheet 1 – Evaluation summary
If road improvements are being considered in conjunction with the bridge renewal, then the improvements
are to be evaluated separately (using SP3, if applicable), when it is confirmed that bridge renewal is the
preferred option.
The procedure for analysing structural bridge renewals is somewhat different from other activities, in that
all options are identified and costed at the outset, including:
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 122
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
4. EVALUATION PROCEDURES > 4.3 EVALUATION OF ROAD RENEWAL AND IMPROVEMENT ACTIVITIES
Once this has been done, the decision chart (Figure 9) can be used to determine the appropriate course
of action and analysis procedure.
Note: This procedure does not allow for the possibility of total bridge failure. If this is a real possibility
when certain options are chosen, then account should be taken of the extra costs this would impose on
road users multiplied by the probability of failure occurring. The calculation of these probabilities should
be undertaken by the same engineers who make the decisions regarding posting the bridge.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 123
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
4. EVALUATION PROCEDURES > 4.3 EVALUATION OF ROAD RENEWAL AND IMPROVEMENT ACTIVITIES
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 124
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
4. EVALUATION PROCEDURES > 4.3 EVALUATION OF ROAD RENEWAL AND IMPROVEMENT ACTIVITIES
Guidance for completing the SP2 Structural bridge renewals (template worksheets) is provided below in
Table 56 and Table 57.
Table 57: Steps in the SP2 evaluation of structural bridge renewal activities
Step Description
1 Complete Worksheet 1 if building a ford is an option – if it is not an option leave blank
2 Complete items 1 to 3 of Worksheet 2 – Evaluation summary
3 Complete Worksheet 3 – Cost of option(s) and determine which option is do-minimum
4 Complete Worksheet 4 – HCV user costs – when there is an alternative route
5 Complete Worksheet 5 – HCV user costs – when there is no alternative route
6 Complete Worksheet 6 – Incremental analysis (if more than one option is possible)
7 Select the preferred option and finalise Worksheet 2 for the preferred option*
Table 58 provides freight cost factors for use within this simplified procedure .
Guidance for completing the SP3 Road improvement activities (template worksheets) is provided below in
Table 59 and Table 60.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 125
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
4. EVALUATION PROCEDURES > 4.3 EVALUATION OF ROAD RENEWAL AND IMPROVEMENT ACTIVITIES
The procedures are designed to consider one option at a time. All suitable options for the proposed works
should be considered in order to select the optimal solution. In most situations this will involve incremental
analysis of the benefits and costs of the different options analysed. A description of all options considered
should be provided in worksheet SP4-1 and included in the incremental analysis; for all other worksheets,
only the details for the preferred option need to be included.
Guidance for completing the SP4 Seal extensions (template worksheets) is provided below in Table 61
and Table 62.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 126
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
4. EVALUATION PROCEDURES > 4.3 EVALUATION OF ROAD RENEWAL AND IMPROVEMENT ACTIVITIES
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 127
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
4. EVALUATION PROCEDURES > 4.3 EVALUATION OF ROAD RENEWAL AND IMPROVEMENT ACTIVITIES
SP5-5 Vehicle operating cost Used for calculating vehicle operating cost (VOC)
savings savings.
SP5-6 Crash cost savings Used for calculating crash cost savings using crash-by-
crash analysis method (refer Appendix 2: Crash
analysis).
SP5-7 BCR and incremental analysis Used for comparison of the options considered.
Table 65: Multiplication factors for items with an estimated life of less than 40 years
Construction item Multiplying
factor (MF)
Traffic signs 2.5
Delineation (eg edge market posts, raised pavement markers, sight railing and 3.7
chevrons)
Spray plastic 5.7
Road markings 15.5
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 128
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
4. EVALUATION PROCEDURES > 4.3 EVALUATION OF ROAD RENEWAL AND IMPROVEMENT ACTIVITIES
These procedures cover the range of stages listed above, however, many of the actions for these stages
are covered in greater detail in other sections or appendices of this manual and in external documents for
which links have been provided. A significant focus of the road improvement procedures is on the
calculation of activity impacts, in particular stages 4 to 6 in Table 66.
These procedures are designed to calculate the impacts one at a time and then, after assigning monetary
values to the impacts, they can be added together, including any disbenefits, to establish the total benefit
of the options under consideration. To assist in this process a set of standardised worksheets have been
developed to help guide the analyst through an evaluation and to aid in the process of checking for
completeness and accuracy.
The following table outlines the stages of analysis when undertaking an evaluation of the impacts of road
improvements. The chapters and sections of this manual that apply to each stage of the analysis are
referenced in the table below.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 129
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
4. EVALUATION PROCEDURES > 4.3 EVALUATION OF ROAD RENEWAL AND IMPROVEMENT ACTIVITIES
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 130
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
4. EVALUATION PROCEDURES > 4.3 EVALUATION OF ROAD RENEWAL AND IMPROVEMENT ACTIVITIES
In some situations, the do-minimum can be the most effective solution to a problem and therefore it can
be the ’preferred option’.
For some situations the best outcomes may be delivered through the do-minimum option, eg lowering the
operating speed to a safe and appropriate level through the use of speed-limit signs and/or minor
infrastructure improvements that go with the new speed limits. In this case, the do-minimum will be the
preferred option.
For safety activities where reducing the speed limit is a potential option, the do-nothing scenario is the
existing baseline conditions of the network, based on the existing speed limit, operating speed,
infrastructure and services.
Where a road-controlling authority decides to introduce one or more interventions to address
unacceptable levels of collective and/or personal risk, to re-set the speed limit, and/or to manage speeds
on a particular piece of road, the do-minimum can include benefits and costs of implementing a new safe
and appropriate operating speed.
In such situations the do-minimum should be compared to both the do-nothing and the other activity
options in order to determine whether the do-minimum is the preferred option (ie the optimal solution), or
whether additional improvements are justified over and above the do-minimum, and if these additional
improvements are therefore the preferred option.
When undertaking safety interventions addressing speed the following information should be referenced:
• Land Transport Rule: Setting of Speed Limits 2017
• the Waka Kotahi Speed management guide, and
• the Waka Kotahi MegaMaps tool, which is used in conjunction with the Speed management
guide.
The crash costs associated with speed management interventions should be calculated using the
predictive crash cost models in Appendix 2: Crash analysis of this manual.
In cases where the do-minimum involves a large future expenditure, the option of undertaking the activity
now should be compared to the option of deferring the activity until this expenditure is due. Similarly, if the
capital cost of the activity is expected to increase for some reason other than normal inflation, again the
option of undertaking the activity now should be compared with the option of deferring construction and
incurring the higher cost.
The activity costs required for determining benefit–cost ratios (BCRs), including incremental benefit–cost
assessment (Chapter 6), and also first-year rate of return (section 1.10) is the difference between the
costs of the activity option and the costs of the do-minimum. The activity benefits are similarly the
differences between the benefit values calculated for the activity option and those of the do-minimum.
It follows that where a particular benefit or cost is unchanged among all the activity options and the do-
minimum, it does not require valuation or inclusion in the economic analysis. For completeness, it should
be noted in any funding application that the benefit or cost is unchanged.
Stage 1b: Describe the alternatives and options
Rigorous consideration of alternatives and options is a requirement of the Land Transport Management
Act 2003 (LTMA). To ensure these obligations are met, evaluators should carefully articulate the problem
or issue that they are seeking to resolve and avoid approaching the analysis with a preconceived solution
in mind.
Alternatives are different means of achieving the same objective as a proposed activity, while options are
variants of a proposed activity. These alternatives and options should not be constrained to a specific
mode, or even to transport solutions, as changes to existing policy may be suitable responses to the
identified problem. As a result, it may be necessary to apply other procedures contained within this
manual as part of the evaluation.
Stage 1c: Consider if an activity is stand-alone, part of a package or part of a programme
Waka Kotahi seeks to encourage, where appropriate, approved organisations to develop packages or
programmes of interrelated and complementary activities, either individually or in association with other
approved organisations.
This is particularly important to ensure that a wide range of options and alternatives are considered and
evaluated in full. Doing so may help avoid issues that arise from narrowing the scope too early such as:
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 131
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
4. EVALUATION PROCEDURES > 4.3 EVALUATION OF ROAD RENEWAL AND IMPROVEMENT ACTIVITIES
• neglecting options that differ in type or scale, eg a road realignment that may eliminate a bridge
renewal
• neglecting significant externalities, eg the impacts of change in traffic flow upon adjoining
properties
• inconsistencies with wider strategic policies and plans, eg the impacts of improvements to a
major urban arterial on downtown congestion.
Stage 2: Route and network information
Road improvement activities need to be divided into sections with similar geometric and traffic flow
characteristics, and with similar costs of construction and maintenance. In some cases it may be
necessary to separately consider individual traffic movements at intersections. In other cases, benefits
and disbenefits may differ by direction of travel, for example on continuous sections of grade, and in
these cases it will be necessary to consider each direction as a separate section.
For the do-minimum and for each activity option, the route should be divided into sections over which the
terrain, road width, road roughness, speed limit and traffic volumes (for all modes) are essentially
constant, and/or intersections.
For minor activities and for pre-selection studies, all time periods can be considered together. For
significant capital activities, it will be necessary to consider traffic variation with time of day and weekday
versus weekend and holiday periods.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 132
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
4. EVALUATION PROCEDURES > 4.3 EVALUATION OF ROAD RENEWAL AND IMPROVEMENT ACTIVITIES
• intermittent traffic
• suppressed traffic
• induced or generated traffic.
For activities with congested conditions it may be necessary to consider growth suppression or variable
matrix techniques (see Appendix 1: Demand estimation methods and guidance).
Irrespective of their capital cost, the effect of activities on traffic flows in the surrounding network should
also be assessed. For example, a traffic management scheme having a small capital cost may have
significant effects on traffic flows.
Stage 3: Vehicle, cycle and pedestrian demand estimate
There are two approaches that can be used for calculating transport demand for the different modes and
mode shift(s). The first approach is to use a transport model and the second approach is based on
willingness to pay surveys combined with data on current users together with information on existing or
proposed user charges. This second approach is set out in Chapter 2 of this manual.
Where there are congested networks and the potential for induced/generated traffic, refer to Appendix 1:
Demand estimation methods and guidance.
Note: if the analyst is not using a transport model to calculate travel times then they must refer to
Appendix 3: Traffic data and travel time estimation for the procedures on how to calculate travel times.
Model validation
The aspects of the models covered by the validation checks are as follows:
• activity model specification – including model type and parameters, data sources, trip matrices,
assignment methodology and forecasting checks
• a base-year assignment validation – comprising checks on link and screen-line flows, intersection
flows, journey times and assignment convergence
• strategic demand model checks – incorporating validation of the models and techniques used to
produce trip matrices.
Model reviewers may also use these checklists to confirm that appropriate documentation has been
provided for review purposes.
All activity benefits calculated using a traffic or transportation model shall be checked to show the results
are reasonable. The checks shall be done and reported at two levels – coarse checks and detailed
checks.
The objective of the course checks is to determine whether the travel time benefits calculated are of the
right order of magnitude. More information on the required coarse model checks is contained in the
Transport model development guidelines.
The objective of the detailed checks is to ensure the travel times on individual road sections, through
critical intersections, and for selected journeys through the network, are reasonable. This analysis shall
be undertaken for the first year of benefits and for a future year, and for both peak and off–peak periods if
appropriate.
Modelling congested networks and induced traffic
Guidelines are provided in Appendix 1: Demand estimation methods and guidance for modelling
situations where very high levels of congestion are anticipated over the economic life of the scheme.
Professional judgement should be used to determine the appropriate procedures to adopt. In cases
where there are excessive or unrealistic levels of congestion in the do-minimum network, a number of
techniques may be used to generate a realistic and stable representation of the do-minimum context.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 133
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
4. EVALUATION PROCEDURES > 4.3 EVALUATION OF ROAD RENEWAL AND IMPROVEMENT ACTIVITIES
These commonly involve upgrading the capacity of the do-minimum network or using some form of
growth constraint on the trip matrix, such as matrix capping.
The matrix derived from this process remains the same in both the do-minimum and activity option, and is
then used in the standard fixed trip matrix (FTM) evaluation procedure. Refer to Appendix 1: Demand
estimation methods and guidance for detailed growth constraint techniques.
In some situations, significant levels of congestion may be expected in the activity option across important
parts of the network (spatially) affecting a substantial proportion of the activity life (temporally). The
resulting induced travel may affect benefits as well as the choice of the activity option. The evaluation
should incorporate an analysis of induced traffic effects and Appendix 1: Demand estimation methods
and guidance contains procedures for evaluating these effects.
Note that the benefit calculations should include any negative impacts (disbenefits) during
implementation/construction.
The benefits that have currently (as at 2020) been ascribed standardised monetary values are listed
below. The benefits (ie the differences in the parameter outcomes between the do-minimum and the
options) are ascribed monetary values in Chapter 3 of this manual.
Parameters other than those listed below can be monetised, but the process and values ascribed to these
parameters must be agreed with Waka Kotahi before they are included in the analysis, and supporting
information to validate the inclusion of these parameters must be provided.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 134
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
4. EVALUATION PROCEDURES > 4.3 EVALUATION OF ROAD RENEWAL AND IMPROVEMENT ACTIVITIES
matter (PM10 and PM2.5), nitrogen dioxide (NO2), carbon monoxide (CO), sulphur dioxide (SO2), and
hydrocarbons (HCs).
Nitrogen dioxide (NO2) is a gas that causes increased susceptibility to infections and asthma. It reduces
lung development in children and has been associated with increasingly more serious health effects,
including reduced life expectancy (COMEAP 2015). Particulate matter (PM10, which is smaller than 10µm)
impacts predominantly on respiratory and cardiovascular systems. Effects can range from reduced lung
function, increased medication use, and more hospital admissions, through to reduced life expectancy
and death.
Refer to section 3.3 of this manual for information on the calculation and monetisation of the impacts of
vehicle emissions on human health.
Stage 4d: Impact on greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions
Greenhouse gases are pollutants that cause global warming and impact globally, eg carbon dioxide
(CO2), black carbon (BC) and methane (CH 4)
Note: Several harmful pollutants (especially BC) are direct climate pollutants, in that they have a direct
warming effect on the atmosphere. However, many of the remaining harmful pollutants, eg sulphur
dioxide (SO2) and carbon monoxide (CO), are indirect climate pollutants. This means they do not warm
the atmosphere themselves but react with other gases to increase greenhouse gas concentrations.
Therefore, initiatives which address harmful air pollutants typically yield both health and climate change
benefits.
Refer to section 3.4 of this manual for information on the calculation and monetisation of greenhouse gas
emissions.
Stage 4e: Impact of noise and vibration on health
Noise is a disturbing or otherwise unwelcome sound, which is transmitted as a longitudinal pressure wave
through the air or other medium as the result of the physical vibration of a source. Noise propagation is
affected by wind and intervening absorbing and reflecting surfaces, and is reduced with distance.
Road traffic noise sources include:
• engine and transmission vibration
• exhaust systems
• bodywork and load rattle
• air brake and friction brakes
• tyre/road surface contact
• horns, doors slamming, car audio systems
• aerodynamic noise.
Road traffic noise is generally continuous and long-term exposure can have significant adverse effects.
These can be categorised as disruptive impacts, such as sleep disturbance and speech interference, and
psychological impacts such as annoyance reaction and other behavioural impacts. While there is no
evidence of permanent hearing loss from road traffic noise, there is a great deal of evidence to show that
noise can cause adverse health effects in people, due mainly to stress-related factors.
Refer to section 3.5 of this manual for information on the calculation and monetisation of the impacts of
noise and vibration on human health.
Stage 4f: Impact on network productivity and utilisation
Changes in travel time (for all modes)
Travel times shall be estimated according to the procedures in Appendix 3: Traffic data and travel time
estimation of this manual. Definitions for classifying traffic data and default traffic data values are also
provided in Table A45, Table A46 and Table A47. Where a specific procedure is not given, the travel time
shall be determined according to a recognised procedure compatible with the manuals and procedures
referred to in Appendix 1: Demand estimation methods and guidance and Appendix 3: Traffic data and
travel time estimation.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 135
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
4. EVALUATION PROCEDURES > 4.3 EVALUATION OF ROAD RENEWAL AND IMPROVEMENT ACTIVITIES
The flow chart in Figure 10 shows the basic stages for estimating road section travel time (the stages are
slightly different for intersections).
It is necessary that the travel times used by the model to derive the flows must be consistent with the
travel times estimated by using the procedures in Appendix 3: Traffic data and travel time estimation
during evaluation. To adhere to this, it is suggested that the functions implied by the procedures be used
as a starting point, and modified as necessary to get a satisfactory validation.
Note that, wherever practical, measured travel time information shall be obtained in preference to the
default values given in the tables in this manual.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 136
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
4. EVALUATION PROCEDURES > 4.3 EVALUATION OF ROAD RENEWAL AND IMPROVEMENT ACTIVITIES
Refer to Appendix 3: Traffic data and travel time estimation of this manual, which sets out the procedures
for estimating travel times for the do-minimum and the options for various road and intersection types.
Additionally, refer to section 3.6 of this manual for information on the monetisation of travel time impacts.
Refer to section 3.6 of this manual for information on the calculation and monetisation of vehicle operating
costs.
Traffic composition
Appendix 4: Vehicle operating cost tables also provides VOC for the standard traffic compositions using
the four road categories defined in Table A46, namely: urban arterial, urban other, rural strategic, and
rural other. The road category costs contained in the tables in this appendix are for the ‘all time periods’
traffic mix.
Buses are not included in these standard traffic compositions. If buses form a significant component of
the traffic stream they shall be included in proportion to their representation.
Regression equations
To assist analysts, regression equations are provided (refer to Table 22, Table 23, Table 24 and Table
25) which can be used to predict the VOC when using spreadsheets or transport models. Note that the
regression coefficients vary between vehicle classes and road categories.
The regression equations were used to generate the corresponding VOC tables, so the results will be
consistent, irrespective of which approach is used.
Minor differences will arise when calculating road category costs from individual vehicle class costs due
to the regression equations being developed from the road category data. Where high precision is
required, the vehicle class equations should be summed and used in preference to the road category
equations.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 137
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
4. EVALUATION PROCEDURES > 4.3 EVALUATION OF ROAD RENEWAL AND IMPROVEMENT ACTIVITIES
Table 68: Recommendations on diversion rates to/from public transport from changes in car
travel costs
Trip journey time reliability is a different type of variability, which is much less predictable to the driver.
(For example, car drivers who make a particular journey at the same time every day find some days it
takes as little as 20 minutes, and on other days as much as 40 minutes.) Hence, when the car drivers
plan their trips, they have to consider not just the expected travel time but also its variability. Where an
activity improves trip reliability, the benefits apply to both work and non-work trips, and can be calculated
using the in this section.
Journey time reliability is measured by the unpredictable variations in journey times, which are
experienced for a journey undertaken at broadly the same time every day. The impact is related to the
day-to-day variations in traffic congestion, typically as a result of day-to-day variations in flow. This is
distinct from the variations in individual journey times, which occur within a particular period.
Journey time reliability is in principle calculated for a complete journey and the total network variability is
the sum of the travel time variability for all journeys on the network. In practice, models may not represent
the full length of journeys and this is accounted for in the procedure.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 138
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
4. EVALUATION PROCEDURES > 4.3 EVALUATION OF ROAD RENEWAL AND IMPROVEMENT ACTIVITIES
Travel journey time variability is expressed as the standard deviation of travel time. The sources of
variability are road sections and intersections. Reduced variability arises from a reduction in
congestion on links and at intersections along a route. For a single section or intersection approach
the standard deviation of travel time can be calculated using that section or intersection movement’s
VC ratio:
s - s0
Standard deviation of journey travel time = s0 +
b v -a
c (min)
1 +e
where: the VC ratio is represented by s, s0, b and a are taken from Table 69 below.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 139
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
4. EVALUATION PROCEDURES > 4.3 EVALUATION OF ROAD RENEWAL AND IMPROVEMENT ACTIVITIES
same as variations in individual journey times within a modelled period, a possible output of micro-
simulation models. The variation in individual journey times from such models will be influenced by
the driver, vehicle type and generation factors used in the stochastic processes used in the model.
For individual intersection upgrades, the turning movements can be used as a proxy origin-
destination matrix with the movement-weighted standard deviation being calculated for the
intersection.
For project areas with more than a single congested intersection or link, an estimate of the proportion
of trips that travel through more than one of these sources of variability must be made in order to
approximate the total study area variability.
For two sources of variability, the reliability estimate for each trip direction is the sum of:
Variability for trips which travel only through source x:
Fx SDx
and, for trips travelling through both source x and y: 2 2
Fx.y SDx + SDy
where: Fx is trips that travel through only source x
Fx.y is trips that travel through both x and y
SDx is standard deviation of travel time for trip at source x
SDy is standard deviation of travel time for trip at source y
For each of the three sources of variability, the reliability estimate is the sum of the individual
components below:
Through source x only: Fx SDx
Through sources x and y only: 2 2
Fx.y SDx + SDy
2 2
Through sources x and z only: SDx + SDz
Fx.z
2 2 2
Through sources x, y and z only: Fx.y,z SDx + SDy + SDz
where: Fx,y,z = trips that travel through all three sources x, y and z.
If traffic passes through more than three sources of significant congestion in the modelled area
then evaluators must estimate the trip matrix and perform the calculation using the aggregation of
journey variance method.
Rural two-lane roads
Table 70, Table 71 and Table 72 contain travel time variability values for rural two-lane roads of varying
terrain and the volume to capacity (VC) ratio (see Appendix 3: Calculating the volume to capacity ratio).
The time period used to calculate the VC ratio must contain a relatively constant level of traffic volume.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 140
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
4. EVALUATION PROCEDURES > 4.3 EVALUATION OF ROAD RENEWAL AND IMPROVEMENT ACTIVITIES
Table 70: Travel time variability – rural two lane road, level terrain
Standard deviation of travel time (minutes) – percent no-passing for level terrain
VC ratio 0% 20% 40% 60% 80% 100%
0.00 0.01 0.04 0.07 0.11 0.13 0.14
0.10 0.07 0.07 0.08 0.09 0.10 0.11
0.20 0.09 0.08 0.08 0.08 0.08 0.08
0.30 0.09 0.08 0.08 0.07 0.07 0.06
0.40 0.07 0.06 0.06 0.05 0.05 0.04
0.50 0.05 0.05 0.05 0.04 0.04 0.03
0.60 0.03 0.03 0.03 0.03 0.03 0.03
0.70 0.03 0.03 0.03 0.04 0.03 0.03
0.80 0.05 0.05 0.05 0.05 0.04 0.06
0.90 0.10 0.10 0.09 0.09 0.08 0.10
1.00 0.18 0.18 0.15 0.15 0.17 0.18
Table 71: Travel time reliability – rural two-lane road, rolling terrain
Standard deviation of travel time (minutes) – percent no-passing for rolling terrain
VC ratio 0% 20% 40% 60% 80% 100%
0.00 0.03 0.09 0.15 0.17 0.24 0.27
0.10 0.11 0.13 0.15 0.17 0.17 0.18
0.20 0.13 0.13 0.12 0.13 0.12 0.12
0.30 0.12 0.10 0.09 0.09 0.08 0.08
0.40 0.09 0.07 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.05
0.50 0.06 0.05 0.05 0.05 0.06 0.06
0.60 0.05 0.06 0.07 0.08 0.09 0.08
0.70 0.07 0.10 0.12 0.14 0.15 0.14
0.80 0.14 0.18 0.21 0.23 0.23 0.22
0.90 0.26 0.29 0.32 0.34 0.34 0.34
1.00 0.43 0.44 0.47 0.46 0.47 0.49
Table 72: Travel time variability – rural two-lane road, mountainous terrain
Standard deviation of travel time (minutes) – percent no-passing for mountainous terrain
VC ratio 0% 20% 40% 60% 80% 100%
0.00 0.13 0.25 0.32 0.40 0.51 0.65
0.10 0.18 0.21 0.26 0.28 0.32 0.33
0.20 0.17 0.17 0.20 0.21 0.20 0.18
0.30 0.15 0.15 0.17 0.16 0.15 0.13
0.40 0.14 0.15 0.16 0.16 0.15 0.15
0.50 0.15 0.18 0.18 0.18 0.18 0.20
0.60 0.21 0.23 0.22 0.23 0.24 0.26
0.70 0.28 0.30 0.29 0.30 0.32 0.34
0.80 0.37 0.36 0.37 0.38 0.41 0.43
0.90 0.43 0.40 0.44 0.45 0.50 0.55
1.00 0.43 0.39 0.50 0.51 0.59 0.73
7. Assess the percentage of variance occurring outside of the selected study area and select the
adjustment factor.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 141
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
4. EVALUATION PROCEDURES > 4.3 EVALUATION OF ROAD RENEWAL AND IMPROVEMENT ACTIVITIES
In many cases, an activity evaluation will consider a defined area that does not represent the full
length of most journeys. As a result, the changes in journey time reliability will be overestimated. In
these cases the variability estimates need to be adjusted. Table 73 below gives some illustrative
contexts where different factors might apply. An estimation of the variance of journey times that
occurs outside of the evaluation area must be made and the appropriate correction factor from Table
73 applied.
The trip time reliability benefit is adjusted by multiplying the calculated variability benefit by the factor.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 142
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
4. EVALUATION PROCEDURES > 4.3 EVALUATION OF ROAD RENEWAL AND IMPROVEMENT ACTIVITIES
The demand for passing and consequently the benefits, are a function of a number of parameters
including:
• Traffic variables
o traffic volume
o percentage of HCVs
o initial platooning
o directional split of traffic
o vehicle speed distributions
• Road variables
o terrain/alignment
o grades
o available passing lanes (sight distance)
o passing lane lengths and frequency.
An alternative method based on multiple simulations and the unified passing model is described in
Appendix 5: Passing lanes, and is available in the Provisional passing & overtaking guidelines on the
Waka Kotahi website. This method can be used to identify the most appropriate strategy for providing
improved vehicle passing options over a route, and assess the benefits of individual vehicle passing
options within those strategies.
Road user comfort from seal extension
Road user comfort benefits and productivity gains from sealing an unsealed road should also be taken
into account.
Stage 4: Wider economic impacts
Refer to sections 3.9 to 3.13 of this manual for information on the calculation of wider economic impacts.
Wider economic benefits (WEBs) are impacts that can result from transport investment that have been
used internationally to improve transport cost-benefit analysis. They can be thought of as impacts that are
additional to the conventional benefits to transport users (illustrated in the following diagram). WEBs
include changes to productivity, labour supply and imperfect competition, as well as regional economic
development impacts.
Great care is required to ensure that the estimates for wider economic benefits are truly additional to
conventional benefits to avoid double counting. As an example, business travel time savings can result in
productivity and output increases. These are a direct user benefit and any wider economic benefits for
increased productivity have to be additional to these direct user benefits.
In addition to, or in some cases as a consequence of direct impacts, there can be indirect impacts on the
economy. These may cause a redistribution or reallocation of resources or may cause the entry or exit of
firms. These are wider economic impacts and can include:
• economies of scale from improved transport that can encourage agglomeration or specialisation
of economic activity
• mitigating existing market failures by improving accessibility and therefore competition between
spatial markets
• increased output in imperfectly competitive markets by diminishing persistent externalities
• technology and knowledge transfer by connecting people and places and increasing the
interaction between economic actors.
New Zealand application of WEBs
The following wider economic benefits are applicable in the New Zealand context:
• agglomeration, where firms and workers cluster for some activities that are more efficient when
spatially concentrated
• imperfect competition, where a transport improvement causes output to increase in sectors where
there are price-cost margins
• increased labour supply, where a reduction in commuting costs removes a barrier for new
workers accessing areas of employment.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 143
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
4. EVALUATION PROCEDURES > 4.3 EVALUATION OF ROAD RENEWAL AND IMPROVEMENT ACTIVITIES
Start of project stage: During the project stage: At end of project stage:
• Identify risks. • Implement preferred • Report on outcomes of
• Assess risk management strategy. strategy.
strategies (reduction, • Assess implications for
mitigation, avoidance, next stage of project.
quantification through date
collection etc).
• Choose preferred strategy.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 144
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
4. EVALUATION PROCEDURES > 4.3 EVALUATION OF ROAD RENEWAL AND IMPROVEMENT ACTIVITIES
Land costs
Where land has to be acquired for road development, its resource cost shall be assumed to equate to its
market value for activity evaluation purposes. Similarly, land available for sale due to obsolescence of an
existing road shall be included as a cost saving.
Where land required for an activity is already owned by the road controlling authority, its market value at
the base date shall be included in the analysis. Land shall not be treated as a ‘sunk cost’, as the option of
alternative use nearly always exists.
Market value shall be assessed on the basis that the land is available indefinitely for other use. Small
isolated or irregularly shaped lots of land are often difficult to develop. If amalgamation with adjacent
property is impracticable, the resource cost of the land is its amenity value only. If amalgamation is
possible, the market value of the main property, with and without the addition of the small lot, shall be
assessed. The difference is the resource value of the lot, which in some cases may be considerably more
than the achievable sale price.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 145
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
4. EVALUATION PROCEDURES > 4.3 EVALUATION OF ROAD RENEWAL AND IMPROVEMENT ACTIVITIES
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 146
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Appendix 6: Discount factors). Discount rates of 3% and 6% are also provided in the tables for sensitivity
testing.
Stage 9: Determine the benefit–cost ratios of the options
Refer to Chapter 6 for detailed information on developing BCRs.
Stage 10: Incremental cost–benefit analysis
Where alternatives and options are mutually exclusive, incremental cost–benefit analysis of the
alternatives and options is used to identify the optimal economic solution.
The incremental BCR indicates whether the incremental cost of higher-cost project alternatives and
options is justified by the incremental benefits gained (all other factors being equal). Conversely,
incremental analysis will identify whether a lower-cost alternative or option that realises proportionally
more benefits is a more optimal solution.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 147
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
months. Where costs are common to both the do-minimum and the options they are not included in the
analysis. All costs are to be exclusive of GST.
Simplified procedures SP9 and SP10 adopt the following approaches:
• Benefits accrue to public transport users and road users.
• Public transport user benefits can include time savings, better reliability and better vehicle and PT
infrastructure quality.
• Road user benefits result from reduction in road traffic, and include travel time savings (including
congestion reduction), vehicle operating cost savings, crash cost savings, and environmental
benefits (including CO2 reduction). The road traffic reduction benefit values assume that the road
corridor has at least one point that operates at greater than 80% capacity during the peak period.
The simplified procedures for PT are for the evaluation of activities that have an undiscounted funding
gap of less than or equal to $15 million over the first three-year period of operation. If this criteria is not
met then the full procedures must be used.
The simplified procedures are designed to consider one option at a time. All suitable options for the
proposed works should be considered in order to select the optimal solution. In most situations this will
involve incremental analysis of the benefits and costs of the different options analysed. A description of all
options considered should be described in worksheet 1 and included in the incremental analysis; for all
other worksheets, only the details of the preferred option need to be included.
Refer to the Planning and Investment Knowledge Base (PIKB) for guidance on issues relating to analysis
of PT activities, including selection of the preferred option using the Business Case Approach.
The simplified procedure templates provided must be used when undertaking simplified evaluations. The
completed templates are to be included in Transport Investment Online (TIO). The templates are
standardised to allow automated uploading to and data extraction from TIO.
Each simplified procedure is a stand-alone procedure designed to be applied directly to each option being
considered. Input values may be obtained from:
• the default figures provided
• activity specific data collected, or
• the information in the appendices.
Analysis which alters components of the simplified procedure should not be used as this will compromise
the assumptions on which the procedures are based, and full procedures should be used instead.
If the analyst has any problems with the simplified procedures templates or worksheets, please contact
[email protected].
SP9 for new public transport services
Procedure SP9 provides a simplified method of appraising the economic efficiency of new public transport
services and associated capital infrastructure. The procedure assumes that benefits accrue to new public
transport users and to road users.
A description of all options considered should be described in worksheet SP9-1 and included in the
incremental analysis; for all other worksheets, only the details for the preferred option need to be
included.
Guidance for completing the SP9 New public transport services (template worksheets) is provided below
in Table 75 and Table 76.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 148
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Table 76: Steps in the SP9 evaluation of new public transport service activities
Step Description
1 Complete items 1 to 6 of Worksheet 1 – Evaluation summary
2 Complete Worksheet 2 – Service provider costs
3 Complete Worksheet 3 – Funding gap analysis
4 Complete Worksheet 4 – Public transport user benefits
5 Complete Worksheet 5 – Road traffic reduction benefits
6 Complete Worksheet 6 – Incremental analysis (if more than one option is considered)
7 Select the preferred option and finalise Worksheet 1 for the preferred option
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 149
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Table 78: Steps in the SP10 evaluation of new public transport service activities
Step Description
1 Complete items 1 to 7 of Worksheet 1 – Evaluation summary
2 Complete Worksheet 2 – Service provider costs
3 Complete Worksheet 3 – Funding gap analysis
4 Complete Worksheet 4 – Net benefits
5 Complete Worksheet 5 – Incremental analysis (if more than one option is considered)
6 Select the preferred option and finalise Worksheet 1 for the preferred option
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 150
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Table 79: Stages of analysis for the evaluation of public transport services
Stage Description Refer
1 Consider and describe: Section 1.4:
Counterfactuals
a. the do-minimum
Section 1.5:
b. improvement alternatives and options
Alternatives and
c. whether the improvement(s) should be part of a package
options
and/or programme of activities.
2 Forecast the PT demand either from a transport model or by using Current section and
PT demand elasticities including: Chapter 2: Demand
estimation and mode
• public transport direct elasticities – short run
share
• public transport direct elasticities – by market segment
• public transport direct elasticities – longer run (‘ramp-up’)
effects
• impacts of public transport initiatives on demand for
alternative modes (diversion rate)
• non-public transport cross-modal (diversion rate) effects on
public transport travel.
3 Measure and monetise the impacts (benefits and disbenefits) for the Chapter 3: Benefits
do-minimum and options, including:
• impact on social cost and incidence of crashes
• impact of mode on physical and mental health
• impact of air emissions on health
• impact of noise and vibration on health
• impact on system reliability
• impact on network productivity and utilisation
• impact on greenhouse gas emissions
• impact on user experience of the transport system
• wider economic impact (productivity)
• wider economic impact (labour supply)
• wider economic impact (imperfect competition)
• wider economic impact (regional economic development)
• wider economic impact (land use change)
• other impacts that can be monetised – these are not
included in this manual but can be included if there is
sufficient supporting evidence and the approach is accepted
by Waka Kotahi.
4 Undertake risk analysis when there are significant unpredictable Chapter 7: Sensitivity
events that may affect or be affected by the improvement activity. and risk analysis
5 Calculate the costs to the government of services for the do- Current section and
minimum and improvement options, including (but not exclusively): section 1.8: Costs
• land costs
• funding assistance from government
• maintenance, renewal and construction cost savings
• construction costs, including property, for any additional
infrastructure required
• maintenance costs not already included in service contracts.
Bus operating costs must also be calculated either from detailed
operating cost information or the standardised values in this section.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 151
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 152
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 153
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
The primary focus of the recommended elasticity and diversion rate values is on ‘short’ run demand
impacts, ie taken as patronage changes within roughly 12 months of any change in service attributes.
Estimates are also provided for ‘long run’ elasticity values, based on expected responses after 5–10
years (or more) following any attribute change.
All evidence indicates that the market responses (represented by elasticities) can differ substantially by
the time period analysed such as the time of day or day of the week. In particular, there are substantial
differences between peak period and off-peak period travel, with off-peak responses themselves then
differing between weekday interpeak, weekday evening and weekend periods. Recommended values for
different time periods are therefore provided where available.
The research evidence indicates that underlying demand elasticities for a given attribute, market segment
and time period etc show a strong similarity across urban areas in most developed countries. Given this,
the elasticity values recommended in this section draw firstly on New Zealand evidence and secondly on
Australian evidence, supplemented by evidence from other developed countries where appropriate
(principally where the New Zealand/Australian evidence is very limited).
The basic expression of elasticity is:
E = Proportional change in demand/proportional change in explanatory variable
= (∆ y/y)/(∆ x/x)
where: ∆ y is the change in the demand y, ∆ x is the change in the explanatory variable x.
Point elasticity: the above definition refers to a change ∆x which is vanishingly small, so may be
expressed mathematically as:
Ep = (∂y/y)/(∂x/x) = (∂y/∂x).x/y
This elasticity represents the slope of the demand curve (∂y/∂x) at a particular point multiplied by the ratio
of the explanatory variable (x) to the level of demand (y) at this point.
This is referred to as a point elasticity measure, representing the elasticity only at a particular point on the
demand curve. In practice, point elasticities cannot be computed from empirical data unless the shape of
the demand curve is known (or postulated) and its parameters may then be estimated from the observed
data. Therefore, other elasticity formulations, which do not require the slope of the demand curve are
often applied.
Arc elasticity: The arc elasticity concept is frequently employed in practical analysis, to estimate the
elasticity from observations for two points on the demand curve: for small changes it approximates the
point elasticity. If we assume a constant elasticity demand function over the range of change, the arc
elasticity can then be calculated as:
EA = ∆ ln y = ln y2 – ln y1 = ln(y2/y1)
∆ ln x ln x2 – ln x1 ln (x2/y2)
This is equivalent to (y2/y1) = (x2/x1)E, consistent with the constant elasticity demand function:
Y = k.(x)E
When applying the elasticity approach to public transport systems, the dependent variable is the demand
or patronage (P), while the independent variable is the attribute of the system that is being varied, eg
service level or fares (S). Hence the formula for the elasticity of patronage with respect to service
frequency is expressed as:
E = ln (P2/P1)/ln (S2/S1)
This (natural) logarithmic (ln) function has a number of advantages over alternative elasticity functions for
analysis and application purposes.5 It also assumes that the demand elasticity is constant over the range
5 A significant advantage is that, if S varies from S1 to S2 and then S3, the patronage estimates will be consistent
whether the change from S1 to S3 is calculated directly or via S2; and similarly, if S varies from S1 to S2 and then
back to S1, the formulation will show zero net patronage change.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 154
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
of changes under consideration. While this assumption is open to significant debate, it provides a
reasonable approximation except possibly in situations of very large changes in the independent variable
(eg fares or service levels).6
There are common issues that can arise during the estimation and application of elasticities. Table 80
provides some advice to assist analysts in estimating the patronage impacts, and hence demand
elasticities, from PT initiatives that have been or are being implemented. This advice is also relevant to
forecasting the likely impacts of initiatives being considered for implementation.
6 The evidence indicates that fare and service elasticities tend to increase with higher fares and with higher service
headways (lower frequencies).
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 155
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
evidence is that GC elasticities appear to be sensibly constant (for a given market) over a wide range of
journeys with different component costs and elasticities; on the other hand, individual component
elasticities tend to vary according to the proportionate contribution of the component to the total
generalised cost (eg in situations where fares are relatively high, the corresponding fares elasticity is
likely to be high).
The following points should be noted:
• Elasticities are generally sensitive to the market segment under consideration, particularly in
terms of the time period (peak, off-peak, etc) to which any attribute changes apply.
Disaggregation of elasticity values by time period and other market segments is provided in
Stage 2b below. The Table 81 values should generally only be used for assessing attribute
changes applying ‘across the board’, or where specific time period changes are not defined.
• The same elasticity estimates (eg as in Table 81) may be applied for all urban public transport
modes: the evidence indicates that there are minimal intrinsic differences between elasticities for
different PT modes, other than those relating to trip lengths, service frequencies etc.
• Fare elasticities should always be applied in real terms, ie after adjusting nominal fares before
and after a fare’s change for any effects of inflation.
One convenient property of generalised costs is that the generalised cost elasticity for a journey is the
absolute sum of all the elasticity estimates for the individual journey components. Table 81 includes a
best estimate GC elasticity of -1.30: it is seen that this is approximately equal to the sum of the absolute
values of the component elasticities.
Table 81: Overall (short run) direct elasticity estimates (at 12 months after service etc change)
Attribute Overall best estimatea Typical rangeb
Fare levelsc,d -0.35 -0.2 to -0.6
Service levelse +0.45 +0.2 to +0.7
In-vehicle timef -0.40 -0.1 to -0.7
Total generalised costg -1.30 -0.8 to -2.0
Notes:
a. These are best estimate short-run elasticities for each attribute for typical urban public transport
journeys, averaged over all market segments and time periods. More disaggregated estimates,
as given in Table 82 should be used where information is available. Positive values indicate that
demand increases when the attribute increases; negative values indicate the opposite (eg fare
increases result in reduced demand). The ‘short-run’ here refers to the impacts roughly 12
months after the change in the service attribute.
b. Represents the typical range of elasticity values found across different locations and market
segments/time periods (refer Table 82 for further details).
c. All fare elasticity estimates relate to fare changes in real terms (ie after netting off any effects of
inflation on fare levels).
d. In situations with competing PT modes or services, the estimates given here assume that the
fares on all such modes/services are adjusted in the same proportions (ie these are ‘conditional’
elasticities).
e. The service level attribute is often calculated as the number of in-service bus kilometres in the
area of interest. For situations where the route structure is unchanged but the levels of service on
the existing routes are adjusted, the service frequency (number of bus trips per hour) may be
taken as the measure of service level.
f. In-vehicle time may be taken as being the time that the ‘typical’ passenger spends on the service,
between initial vehicle boarding and final vehicle alighting.
In practice, the total generalised cost may not always include all journey attributes, depending on the
attributes of interest (ie the elasticity may be subject to change).
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 156
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 157
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Notes:
• Trip purpose/time period. Strong systematic variations in elasticities exist between trip
purposes and time periods (these two aspects being strongly correlated for all three variables).
• Mode. The literature indicates some differences between modes, for all three variables. However,
these differences appear largely to reflect differences in other attributes (eg trip length, service
frequency) rather than being intrinsic to the different modes.
• Base level of variable. Both fare elasticity and service elasticity vary strongly, although rather
less than proportionately, with the magnitude of the base fare or service frequency. This is
particularly significant in regard to service frequencies: a typical service elasticity would be
around 0.2 at high frequencies (every 10 minutes or better) increasing to around 0.5 or 0.6 or
more at lower frequencies (hourly or longer). These variations are broadly consistent with a
constant generalised cost elasticity formulation.
• Trip distance. Elasticities vary in a complex way with trip distance: this can be explained, in part,
by the availability of substitutes, with high elasticities for short trips having the alternative of
walking and, in part, by the importance of the component measure in the total trip generalised
cost.
• City size. Elasticities vary with city size, although the fare effect and the service level effect
appear to be opposite. However, data relating to this issue is rather limited.
• Magnitude and direction of changes. Most studies show no significant differences in fare
elasticities between fare increases and decreases, or between large and small fare changes.
Similarly, the limited evidence on service elasticities suggests no significant differences in
elasticities between service increases and decreases, or between large and small service
changes.
Table 83: Typical fare and service level (short-run) relative elasticities by time period
Time period Elasticities relative to overall average
Service levels Fares
All 100 100
Weekday peak 65 75
Weekday interpeak 100 110
Weekday evening 130
Weekend interpeak 150 150
Weekend evening 210 n/a
Sources: Wallis (2004), Wallis (2013)
Notes:
• Figures relative to the all periods averages given in Table 81.
• The literature indicates some differences between modes, for all three variables. However, these
differences appear largely to reflect differences in other attributes (eg trip length, service
frequency.
Stage 2c: Public transport direct elasticities – shorter and longer run effects
Strategic transport demand models generally assume that travel demand changes to a new equilibrium
level instantaneously in response to changes in the road network, public transport fares, etc. However,
this assumption is far from valid in practice. Typically, in the case of public transport services,
infrastructure, and fare changes, there is a rapid initial patronage response to the change, which then
continues to grow over time but at a gradually decreasing rate. The elasticity values in the prior sections
apply to the situation 12 months after the introduction of the change. This section outlines the extent of
demand responses (relative to the 12-month values) expected within both the initial 0–12 month period
and the ongoing subsequent responses, up to five years or longer.
The term ’ramp-up‘ is often applied, for public transport (and other modes) initiatives, to the pattern of
demand growth over time from the introduction of an initiative until the demand reaches its ‘equilibrium’
state (typically after five years or more). This ’ramp-up‘ effect refers only to the underlying growth in
demand towards equilibrium; any other changes that may occur over the ramp-up period (eg as a result
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 158
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Figure 13: Typical public transport patronage ramp-up profiles from service changes
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 159
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
be applied to the short run (12 months) elasticity estimates given in Table 82 and Table 83 to
derive estimates required for any specific time horizon following scheme implementation.
• The saturation (long run) patronage changes forecast relative to the 12-month changes (data
given in bottom row of table). It is seen that these are 104% (ie 4% more than the 12-month
figure), 112% and 206% for the three categories.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 160
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Two alternative approaches (simple ‘models’) are often used to estimate cross-modal demand effects of
public transport initiatives. These involve the application of:
• diversion rates, or
• cross-elasticity relationships.
The ‘diversion rate’ approach, as described below, is considered more appropriate for application here. 7
The ‘diversion rate’ to/from an alternative mode resulting from public transport initiatives is defined as the
proportion of the ‘new’ public transport passengers who previously made the trip in question by the
specified mode (eg as car drivers). In this context, the ‘new’ public transport passengers are those who
did not previously use public transport for their trip.
Research following the implementation of major urban public transport initiatives internationally (including
several projects in New Zealand and Australia) reached the following findings on the previous modes of
travel for users of these new initiatives:
• some 60%–70% of the new initiative users would have previously made the same or similar trip
by public transport
• for the remainder of the new initiative users their previous modes of travel are as summarised in
Table 85.8
These findings relate to typical results for major public transport initiatives. In addition, it should be noted
that:
• For public transport initiatives particularly oriented to attracting motorists, higher car driver
diversion rates are appropriate. These include initiatives such as park and ride facilities and
express bus services, each with diversion rates from car drivers of over 50% and in some cases
as high as 70–80%.9
• For those public transport initiatives with a more ‘social’ focus, lower car driver diversion rates are
appropriate. These include off-peak fare schemes and suburban bus route enhancements. For
such schemes, the diversion rates from car driver may be as low as 20–30%.
Table 85: Prior modes of new public transport passengers resulting from urban public transport
initiatives
Prior mode % of new PT trips Notes
Car (driver/passenger) c.50% Approximately 75% of
these previously car
drivers, 25% previously
car passengers.
Active modes (walk, cycle, c.10%–15% Depends very much on
etc) characteristics of the PT
initiative.
Other modes c.10%–15%
Did not make equivalent c.20%–25%
trip
Total new PT trips 100%
7 More information on the two approaches, their inter-relationships and their relative merits are given in Wallis
(2004).
8 More details of international research findings on this topic are given in Australian Transport Assessment and
Planning (2018a).
9 Initial research following the opening of the Auckland Northern Busway found that 56% of the busway users had
previously used other public transport services in the corridor, 44% were new public transport users for the trip in
question. Of this latter group, around 90% were previous car users (of which three-quarters were car drivers, one-
quarter car passengers).
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 161
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Note: The above should be taken as a guide only. Given the considerable range of results round in the
literature, it is recommended that the evaluator should consult with Waka Kotahi staff where good
estimates of the previous modes of new users of a public transport scheme are significant to the overall
evaluation.
Stage 2e: Impacts of car travel cost changes on public transport demand (diversion rate)
This section provides advice and recommendations on the proportion of previous car users changing their
travel mode in response to changes in car travel costs who switch to/from public transport. Car travel
costs in this context include fuel prices, other car operating costs, parking charges, toll charges and car
travel (in-vehicle) time.
As in the previous section, the focus is on diversion rates between car and alternative modes rather than
cross-elasticity values, but estimates are provided for the public transport mode only (ie the proportion of
deterred car users who switch to public transport). These estimates can provide the basis for sensitivity
tests on how forecasts of public transport patronage would be affected by plausible changes in car travel
costs.
Table 86 provides recommended values for the diversion rates to/from public transport in response to
changes in the various car travel cost components. The following comments may assist in interpretation
of these recommendations:
• Diversion rates are sensitive to two main factors:
1. The 'competitiveness' of the public transport service offered relative to car travel. For
example, much higher diversion rates apply to CBD-oriented trips than to typical inter-
suburban trips.
2. The ’trip purpose‘, where work trips typically have diversion rates around twice those for non-
work trips. In practice, the trip purpose/time period effect and the public transport service
effect are difficult to separate.
• Diversion rates are lower than average for shorter trips (where walking and cycling are
competitive modes), and higher for longer trips (where any car cost changes, eg resulting from
increases in fuel prices, comprise a relatively high proportion of the total trip generalised costs).
• Diversion rates for time components are believed to be lower than for cost components (although
evidence is limited on this point).
• Long-run and short-run diversion rates are assumed to be similar, although the evidence on this
is inconclusive: it seems likely that, in the longer run, the public transport diversion rates tend to
reduce, as people may well be able to take advantage of a wider range of behavioural changes
(eg change in home or employment location).
It is assumed that these diversion rates are equally applicable to increases and decreases (in real terms)
in car travel time and costs, although there is little evidence on this point.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 162
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Table 86: Recommendations on diversion rates to/from public transport from changes in car
travel costs
Car travel cost Typical diversion rates Comments on estimates by market segment
variable (% of deterred car
users switching to PT)
Fuel price/ 30% • Long versus short run: inconclusive, assume equal
vehicle operating • Time period/purpose: peak/work proportion approx.
costs twice off-peak/ non-work proportion
• PT service quality: higher proportions where high
level/ quality of PT service
• Trip length: higher for longer trips, lower for shorter
trips
Toll charges c.40% • Proportions depend on nature of scheme (all day
versus peak only, etc) and location (primarily CBD
trips, all trips, etc.)
• For area-wide/all-day scheme, would expect similar
diversion rates as for fuel prices/VOC
Parking Dependent on market • Regional CBD, work trips: 75%
charges segment • Regional CBD, non-work trips and suburban CBD
work trips: 50%
• Other areas: not defined, likely to be much lower.
In-vehicle time 20% • As for fuel prices/VOC (above).
Source: Wallis (2004)
Back to 2.2 Forecasting demand: procedures for travel behaviour change activities >>
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 163
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Parameters other than those listed below can be monetised, but the process and values ascribed to these
parameters must be agreed with Waka Kotahi before they are included in the analysis and supporting
information to validate the inclusion of these parameters must be provided.
Stage 3a: Impact on social cost and incidence of crashes
For the purposes of this manual, a crash is a transport related event involving one or more road vehicles
that occurs on the transport network that results in personal physical injury and/or damage to property.
Where road traffic is diverted onto new or improved PT services there is likely to be a reduction in the
quantum of crashes.
To undertake a crash analysis, the appropriate crash rates, crash prediction models and crash reduction
factors can be found in the Waka Kotahi Crash estimation compendium (2018).
Refer to section 3.1 and Appendix 2: Crash analysis of this manual for detailed information on the
calculation and monetisation of crash numbers and severities for the do-minimum, alternatives and
options, and the crash reductions that can be expected from the alternatives and options under
consideration.
For incremental service improvements, or where a new service is limited in scope, it may be
appropriate to use the compound road traffic reduction benefit value from Table 41 or Table 42, which
includes an allowance for a reduction in crashes per kilometre of vehicle traffic removed from the
network.
For incremental service improvements, or where a new service is limited in scope, it may be
appropriate to use the compound road traffic reduction benefit value from Table 41 or Table 42, which
includes an allowance for a reduction in GHG emissions per kilometre of vehicle traffic removed from
the network.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 164
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 165
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Figure 14: Flow chart for estimating road section travel time
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 166
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
For incremental service improvements, or where a new service is limited in scope, it may be appropriate
to use the compound road traffic reduction benefit value from Table 41 or Table 42 which includes an
allowance for a reduction in vehicle operating costs per kilometre of vehicle traffic removed from the
network.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 167
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 168
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Start of project stage: During the project stage: At end of project stage:
• Identify risks. • Implement preferred • Report on outcomes of
• Assess risk management strategy. strategy.
strategies (reduction, • Assess implications for
mitigation, avoidance, next stage of project.
quantification through date
collection etc).
• Choose preferred strategy.
Stage 5a: Calculate general costs of public transport do-minimum and options
The costs to government of services include:
• funding assistance from government
• maintenance, renewal and construction cost savings
• construction costs, including property, for any additional infrastructure required
• maintenance costs not already included in service contracts.
Land costs
Where land has to be acquired for PT infrastructure, its resource cost shall be assumed to equate to its
market value for activity evaluation purposes.
Where land required for an activity is already owned by the road controlling authority, its market value at
the base date shall be included in the analysis. Land shall not be treated as a ‘sunk cost’, as the option of
alternative use nearly always exists.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 169
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Market value shall be assessed on the basis that the land is available indefinitely for other use. Small
isolated or irregularly shaped lots of land are often difficult to develop. If amalgamation with adjacent
property is impracticable, the resource cost of the land is its amenity value only. If amalgamation is
possible, the market value of the main property, with and without the addition of the small lot, shall be
assessed. The difference is the resource value of the lot, which in some cases may be considerably more
than the achievable sale price.
Road maintenance, renewal and construction cost savings
Some service proposals will provide a cost saving to government if future planned road construction costs
are avoided. Cost savings may also occur if there is a reduction in road maintenance and renewal
expenditure from traffic being removed from the network by the implementation of new PT services.
Government cost savings have the effect of reducing the denominator of the BCR, potentially making a
transport service more attractive.
The proposed transport service and any other options are assessed to determine any planned road
construction savings and any road maintenance and renewal savings that will be made as compared to
the do-minimum roading option.
Care must be taken when claiming a cost saving from future road construction avoided. The year or years
in which the road construction would likely be funded must be assessed.
Note: Normally road construction cost savings should only be claimed if there are significant road traffic
reduction benefits associated with the transport service proposal.
Stage 5b: Calculate bus operating costs:
Where detailed operating cost information is not available, the following standardised bus unit operating
cost rates and guidance may be used to calculate operating costs. The operating costs specifically
exclude any infrastructure costs.
Costing variables and categories
Bus operating costs can be calculated based upon the following three variables, which are summarised in
Table 87:
• the time that the vehicle is in operation – bus hours
• the distance travelled in operation – bus kilometres
• the number of vehicles required to meet peak requirements – buses.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 170
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Cost categories
A range of unit costs can be applied to each operating cost variable to determine the gross operational
costs associated with providing the service. These are exclusive of any administration costs or system
facility costs, such as passenger information and enquiry services, that fall upon any local or regional
authority.
A description of the main bus unit cost categories and their associated variables are set out in Table 88.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 171
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Table 89: Unit cost rates, 2009/10 prices (standard diesel bus)
Cost category Units Cost rate Notes, comments
A. Operating costs – time $/bus hour 22.00
B. Operating costs – distance: $/bus km 0.425 Based on typical diesel
fuel consumption of 37
litres/100km and price of
$1.15/litre.
C. Operating costs – distance: $/bus km 0.452 Includes 0.152 for RUC
other (Type 2 vehicles, 2/11 tonnes
GVM); 0.300 for bus R&M,
tyres and tubes.
D. Operating costs – vehicles $/bus pa 5000
E. Operating costs – overheads % mark-up on 10%
items A–D
F. Profit margin % mark-up on 5% Typical of profit margins on
items A–E competitive urban bus
contracts in Australia.
G. Capital charges – vehicles $/bus pa 36,000 Based on typical new diesel
bus price of $375,000, life 18
years, depreciation rate
12.0% pa (DV), interest rate
7.5% pa (real).
Stage 6 – Discount benefits and costs and calculate BCRs
Refer to section 1.9 and Chapter 5 of this manual for the detailed information on undertaking discounting.
Benefits and costs generally arise throughout the life of projects and to calculate their present worth or
present value they need to be discounted back to time zero. Based on a discount rate of 4% and an
analysis period of 40 years, sets of present worth factors have been calculated to convert future benefits
and costs to their present values (see Table 102, and Table A132, Table A133 and Table A134 from
Appendix 6: Discount factors). Discount rates of 3% and 6% are also provided in the tables for sensitivity
testing.
For the evaluation of new or improved PT services, a shorter analysis period may be appropriate.
Stage 7: Funding gap analysis
This section provides guidance on the application of funding gap analysis to be used in the appraisal of
public transport options. The funding gap is the level of investment required to ensure that a public
transport service operator obtains a reasonable level of return.
Cash-flow and funding gap analysis is not necessary for determining the BCR of a PT activity, but is a key
component of the decision-making process.
Stage 7a: Calculate service provider costs
Service provider costs are calculated either from industry standard unit costs, or from cost estimates
provided by service providers. The costs include maintenance and operating costs for the new or
increased service.
If costs can be obtained, either from industry standard unit costs or other sources (eg the service
provider) then undertake a full analysis of service provider costs. If the service provider will only disclose
a ‘price’, net of user revenue, for providing the transport service then it can be assumed that the service
provider costs are equal to the ‘price’ plus user revenue for use in the evaluation.
Guidance on the estimation of bus operating costs, excluding infrastructure, is available in stage 5b.
Indicative New Zealand bus industry standard unit operating cost rates are also provided.
Indicative quotes may be used when costs cannot be obtained or calculated, but are most likely to be
used when there is a sole service provider. Estimates of service provider costs are not a commitment to
funding and therefore indicative quotes are acceptable during planning stages.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 172
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Service provider costs must be calculated for the do-minimum and for all options considered. These costs
must be exclusive of GST.
Activity costs
Cost details should include any of the following:
• investigation, design and supervision costs
• physical infrastructure construction and land acquisition costs
• vehicle, vessel or rolling stock acquisition costs.
• disruption costs during construction/implementation, if substantial.
• operating and maintenance costs
• costs of decommissioning and salvage values
• environmental mitigation costs
• contingency allowance.
In the case of the do-minimum, costs may include essential rehabilitation.
Where expenditure on an activity has already been incurred, it must still be included in the appraisal if the
item has a market value which can be realised, for example land.
Costs which have been irrevocably committed and have no salvage or realisable value, are termed ‘sunk
costs’ (these may include investigation, design or other costs already incurred), and must not be
accounted for in economic appraisal.
Disruption costs to the service provider during implementation may be included when these are expected
to be substantial.
Operating and maintenance costs
Estimate operating and maintenance costs for the service over the analysis period.
Maintenance costs should include routine and periodic maintenance costs, as well as any refurbishment
and replacement costs that occur in the appraisal period.
Treatment of depreciation
Depreciation is a non-cash item and must not be included as a separate item in the cash flows used to
estimate the net present value of a proposal in the financial analysis. Only actual cash flows associated
with maintenance and asset replacement, which already fully account for the depreciation of capital
assets, are to be included in the analysis.
Treatment of interest
Interest expenses associated with financing an activity often represent an actual cash cost outflow.
Despite this, interest charges should not be included in the annual cash flow as the required rate of return
used in the cash flow analysis already takes account of debt-financing interest.
If interest payments were to be included in discounted cash flows, the interest charges would be double
counted; therefore, the proposal’s funding gap would be overstated and the BCR understated.
Salvage value
In some instances, assets will have a longer lifespan than the appraisal period. The salvage value of
capital assets should be included where:
• items have a market value, and
• there is an alternative use (for example, a bus can provide urban passenger services or could be
used for school services or tours), or
• there is a scrap demand for items.
Stage 7b: Calculate service provider revenue
This section describes the information that should be included in the financial analysis of activity options
that generate revenue. The process for forecasting the revenue of an improved service is different from
that for a new service, and the methods for each type of service are described below.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 173
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 174
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 175
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 176
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 177
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
5 Quantify the costs of the improvement activities including: Section 1.8: Costs
• investigation and design
• property
• construction
• maintenance, renewal and operation
• risk management; mitigation of external impacts
• residual values.
If there is a service provider, determine service provider costs,
service provider revenue and the funding gap (see section 4.4).
Quantify the net costs to government of the funding gap.
6 Discount the monetised benefits and costs over the analysis period Chapter 5:
to obtain present values. Then use to calculate the benefit–cost Discounting
ratio(s).
7 Determine the benefit–cost ratios of the options. Chapter 6: Benefit–
cost ratios
8 Use incremental cost–benefit analysis to select the preferred option Chapter 6: Benefit–
for mutually exclusive options, cost ratios
9 Perform sensitivity tests on the preferred option to determine how Chapter 7:
robust the calculations are and whether a small change in one of the Sensitivity and risk
input parameters has a large change on the evaluation outcome(s). analysis
10 Verify completeness of information, accuracy of calculations and Current section
validity of assumptions.
Stage 1a: Describe the do-minimum
Generally, the do-minimum for TDM activities shall only include committed and funded transport activities
and work that is absolutely essential to preserve a minimum level of service. However, when TDM
activities are implemented as part of a wider package that includes roading or PT activities, the do-
minimum may need to be specified differently. For more guidance refer to the do-minimum descriptions
within the roading (section 4.3) and public transport (section 4.4) procedures.
Stage 1b: Scale and scope of TDM options
TDM activities, like most economic programmes, will eventually have diminishing marginal benefits. There
is an optimal level of implementation, beyond which incremental costs exceed incremental benefits. TDM
programmes need to track these incremental impacts and limit such programmes before the costs exceed
the benefits.
For example, ridesharing programmes may be extremely cost effective when properly implemented, but
once the potential rideshare market is satisfied there will be little additional benefit from attempting to
expand the rideshare programme with soft measures, eg by sending out more promotional material.
Instead, further expansion may require implementation of additional TDM strategies, such as commuter
financial incentives, to expand the size of the market.
Similarly, cycling improvements can be cost effective where there is latent demand for this mode, but it is
necessary to carefully evaluate investments in cycle paths to ensure that they are cost effective. There
may be better ways to support cycling, such as education and encouragement programmes.
Stage 1c: Packages and/programme activities
Most TDM programmes include a combination of positive and negative incentives. However, there are
cumulative and synergetic impacts, therefore it is important to evaluate TDM activities as a package,
rather than as stand-alone activities or an individual strategy.
The procedure for evaluating road improvement packages involving analysis of the timing of individual
components is not appropriate for TDM packages unless the package contains substantial infrastructure
or public transport components.
There are two types of TDM packages: TDM packages involving substantial infrastructure, and TDM
packages involving travel behaviour change infrastructure.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 178
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 179
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
• other monetised impacts (refer to section 1.7 and Chapter 3 of this manual)
• impacts during implementation/construction (primarily travel time delays).
If a TDM package contains substantial infrastructure or PT components, then a composite evaluation is
necessary. Road infrastructure components of a package should be evaluated using the procedures in
section 4.3 of this manual, while PT components should be evaluated using the procedures in section 4.4.
The results of the component evaluations are to be aggregated taking care to avoid double counting of
benefits.
For any travel behaviour change (TBhC) components in a package, the appropriate composite benefit
value is used to calculate the ‘new user’ benefits for the TBhC target population/area. Section 3.17
provides guidance as to the appropriate evaluation method to calculate benefits for existing users, and for
new users from the population outside the TBhC target population/area, for:
• new or improved public transport services
• new or improved walking or cycling facilities
• new or improved roading infrastructure of various types.
The numerator of the BCR for a composite TBhC package is the sum of the TBhC benefits and the non-
TBhC benefits.
Impacts that are financial transfers, such as the impact on business and retail profitability, and property
prices (other than where the change in property price is used as a proxy to value an impact) must not
be included in the economic efficiency calculation.
Impacts to businesses that are not direct travel time or vehicle operating cost impacts, are considered
transfers rather than national economic benefits. However, they can be an important factor in
assembling a strategic case for a TDM activity and obtaining funding for workplace based activity and
they should, therefore, be quantified and reported as part of the non-monetised evaluation (separately
from the economic efficiency calculation).
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 180
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
An activity’s operating cost is the cost of operating the new (or improved) facility or service. This is the
cost to government plus the net cost to the service provider (service provider cost minus service provider
revenue).
The cost of monitoring a TDM activity is not included in the cost–benefit evaluation of an activity, except
where an initial survey is an integral part of the activity and then it should be costed as such.
The marginal cost of carpooling is nearly zero if a vehicle has an extra seat that would otherwise travel
empty (there is a small increase in fuel consumption and emissions). The incremental cost does however
increase if a rideshare vehicle must drive out of its way to pick up passengers, or if a larger vehicle (eg a
van) is purchased just to carry passengers.
Similarly, if a public transport system has excess capacity, transfers from driving to public transport may
have minimal incremental cost. If peak travel results in increased operating costs (including extra
vehicles) then the net cost to government of this must be assessed.
Notes:
• The impact on mode choice of any increase in fare resulting from the purchase of extra vehicles
must also be evaluated.
• If increased patronage results in uncomfortably crowded vehicles, then this disbenefit should be
included in the evaluation.
• Irrespective of the TBhC package composition, the total costs for all components of the package
are included in the denominator of the BCR. Where a new or improved public transport service is
involved, the costs include the ‘funding assistance’ costs (ie the cost that needs to be funded by
local and central government if the activity is to proceed).
• A funding gap analysis is only necessary when a service provider is contracted to deliver a new
or improved service (refer to section 4.4 for the funding gap analysis procedure).
Stage 6: Discount benefits and costs
Refer section 1.9 and Chapter 5 of this manual for the details on undertaking discounting.
Benefits and costs generally arise throughout the life of projects and to calculate their present worth or
present value they need to be discounted back to time zero. Based on a discount rate of 4% and an
analysis period of 40 years, sets of present worth factors have been calculated to convert future benefits
and costs to their present values (see Table 102, and Table A132, Table A133 and Table A134 from
Appendix 6: Discount factors). Discount rates of 3% and 6% are also provided in the tables for sensitivity
testing.
For the evaluation of TDM activities, a shorter analysis period is likely to be appropriate.
Stage 7: Determine the benefit–cost ratios of the options
Refer to Chapter 6 for detailed information on developing BCRs.
Note: The numerator of the BCR for a composite TBhC package is the sum of the TBhC benefits and the
non-TBhC benefits.
Stage 8: Incremental cost–benefit analysis
Where alternatives and options are mutually exclusive, incremental cost–benefit analysis of the
alternatives and options is used to identify the optimal economic solution.
The incremental BCR indicates whether the incremental cost of higher-cost project alternatives and
options is justified by the incremental benefits gained (all other factors being equal). Conversely,
incremental analysis will identify whether a lower-cost alternative or option that realises proportionally
more benefits is a more optimal solution.
Refer to section 6.3 for detailed information on developing incremental BCRs.
Stage 9: Sensitivity testing on the preferred option
Inputs to TDM activity evaluations that should be considered for sensitivity testing include:
• road traffic volumes, particularly model results, growth rates and the assessment of generated
traffic
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 181
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
4. EVALUATION PROCEDURES > 4.6 EVALUATION OF EDUCATION, PROMOTION AND MARKETING ACTIVITIES
Table 92: Stages of analysis for evaluation of education, promotion and marketing activities
Stage Description Refer
1 Consider and describe: Section 1.4:
a. the do-minimum Counterfactuals
b. improvement alternatives and options
Section 1.5:
c. whether the improvement(s) should be part of a package and/or
Alternatives and
programme of activities.
options
2 Collect data to assess travel impacts: Current section
• target population and Chapter 2:
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 182
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
4. EVALUATION PROCEDURES > 4.6 EVALUATION OF EDUCATION, PROMOTION AND MARKETING ACTIVITIES
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 183
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
4. EVALUATION PROCEDURES > 4.6 EVALUATION OF EDUCATION, PROMOTION AND MARKETING ACTIVITIES
more guidance refer to the do-minimum descriptions within the roading (section 4.3) and public transport
(section 4.4) procedures.
Stage 1b: Scale and scope of education, promotion and marketing activities options
Overseas experience indicates that the most effective, and lowest cost, method for encouraging people to
change their travel behaviour is to provide them with customised information about what is available
locally. The scale of education, promotion and marketing activities is therefore usually limited, but the
scope of their impacts may be significant. Travel plans targeting workplaces, schools, or households and
communities are one such type of activity where, geographically, the scope is highly targeted but the
resulting travel behaviour changes affect the wider network.
The actual impact on travel is highly dependent on factors such as:
• actual features of the plan
• commitment of the target population
• availability of material that assists people’s understanding of the implications of different forms of
travel behaviour
• availability of suitably trained and experienced people to establish and manage the proposal.
Cost efficiencies and effectiveness are enhanced when school, business, household and community
initiatives are implemented simultaneously rather than separately in an area. These programmes should,
therefore, be implemented by geographic area rather than by type.
Stage 1c: Packages and/programme activities
Education, promotion and marketing activities are most effective at changing travel behaviour when
implemented alongside new or improved PT services or walking and cycling facilities, or in conjunction
with other TDM measures.
Consideration should be given to whether a proposed education, promotion and marketing activity is best
delivered as a part of a package or programme.
Stage 2: Demand estimates and modal share
General guidance on travel demand forecasting and mode change estimation is provided in Chapter 2 of
this manual.
TBhC activities tend to result in small impacts to a large number of people. These activities are more
difficult to evaluate than other activities because the impacts tend to be different for each participant,
whereas for road improvement activities most users tend to gain the same benefit.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 184
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
4. EVALUATION PROCEDURES > 4.6 EVALUATION OF EDUCATION, PROMOTION AND MARKETING ACTIVITIES
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 185
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
analysis period of 40 years, sets of present worth factors have been calculated to convert future benefits
and costs to their present values (see Table 102, and Table A132, Table A133 and Table A134 from
Appendix 6: Discount factors). Discount rates of 3% and 6% are also provided in the tables for sensitivity
testing.
For the evaluation of TBhC activities, a shorter analysis period is likely to be appropriate.
Stage 7: Determine the benefit–cost ratios of the options
Refer to Chapter 6 for detailed information on developing BCRs.
Stage 8: Incremental cost–benefit analysis
Where alternatives and options are mutually exclusive, incremental cost–benefit analysis of the
alternatives and options is used to identify the optimal economic solution.
The incremental BCR indicates whether the incremental cost of higher-cost project alternatives and
options is justified by the incremental benefits gained (all other factors being equal). Conversely,
incremental analysis will identify whether a lower-cost alternative or option that realises proportionally
more benefits is a more optimal solution.
Refer to section 6.3 for detailed information on developing incremental BCRs.
Stage 9: Sensitivity testing on the preferred option
Refer to Chapter 7 of this manual for detailed information on sensitivity on sensitivity testing. Possible
significant factors that should be considered for sensitivity testing include:
• demand estimates (refer to Chapter 2 of this manual for more details on sensitivity testing of
demand estimates)
• impact changes
• major contributors to impacts
• commencement of the proposal.
Stage 10: Verification of results
Verify completeness of information, accuracy of calculations and validity of assumptions.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 186
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Refer to the Planning and Investment Knowledge Base (PIKB) for guidance on issues relating to analysis
of PT activities, including selection of the preferred option using the Business Case Approach.
The simplified procedure templates provided must be used when undertaking simplified evaluations. The
completed templates are to be included in Transport Investment Online (TIO). The templates are
standardised to allow automated uploading to and data extraction from TIO.
Each simplified procedure is a stand-alone procedure designed to be applied directly to each option being
considered. Input values may be obtained from:
• the default figures provided
• activity specific data collected, or
• the information in the appendices.
Analysis that alters components of the simplified procedure should not be used as this will compromise
the assumptions on which the procedures are based and full procedures should be used instead.
If the analyst has any problems with the simplified procedures templates or worksheets, please contact
[email protected].
SP6 for high productivity motor vehicle (HPMV) route improvements
Procedure SP6 provides a simplified method of evaluating the economic efficiency of HPMV routes and
associated capital, maintenance and renewal costs. The procedure’s benefits are primarily derived from a
reduction in heavy vehicle trips, with associated reductions in vehicle operating costs, greenhouse gas
emissions, crash costs, and travel time costs.
It is assumed that the route from which heavy vehicles are removed is primarily rural, with a minimal
number of intersections. If the route includes a significant proportion of travel in urban areas, the crash
cost savings procedures described in Appendix 2: Crash analysis should be applied instead.
Only the additional costs required to allow passage of HPMVs on identified routes are included within this
simplified procedure. Where an HPMV activity will bring forward or increase planned maintenance or
bridge work these associated costs are redistributed accordingly within the cost tables. In some cases (eg
where pavements are weak), it may be necessary to compare the costs of the freight transport option with
a road reconstruction option for the affected road network.
Guidance for completing the SP6 High productivity motor vehicles (template worksheets) is provided
below in Table 93 and Table 94.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 187
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Table 94: Steps in the SP6 evaluation of HPMV route improvement activities
Step Description
1 Complete items 1 to 7 of Worksheet 1 – Evaluation summary
2 Complete Worksheet 2 – Cost of option(s)
3 Complete Worksheets 3 to 4 for the option(s) being evaluated
4 Complete Worksheet 5 – Incremental analysis (if more than one option is considered)
5 Select the preferred option and finalise Worksheet 1 for the preferred option
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 188
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
SP8-7 BCR and incremental analysis Used for comparison of the options
considered.
SP8-8 Feasibility evaluation Used as an alternative appraisal
methodology in the absence of congestion
or crash cost savings.
Step Description
1 Complete items 1 to 6 of Worksheet 1 – Evaluation summary
2 Complete Worksheet 2 – Service provider costs
3 Complete Worksheet 3 – Funding gap analysis
4 Complete Worksheet 4 – Freight service user benefits
5 Complete Worksheet 5 – Net cost savings to government
6 Complete Worksheet 6 – Road traffic reduction benefits
7 Complete Worksheet 7 – Incremental analysis (if more than one option is considered)
6 Complete Worksheet 8 – Feasibility evaluation (optional)
7 Select the preferred option and finalise Worksheet 1 for the preferred option
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 189
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 190
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 191
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
• inconsistencies with wider strategic policies and plans, eg investing in road improvements or
renewals when significant rail network renewals are planned.
If all transport system users are affected by improvements, then a multi-modal evaluation may be
necessary. This may involve analysing freight components and other transport system users separately,
using the relevant procedures in this section and the rest of Chapter 4, and aggregating the results.
Stage 2: Demand estimates
General guidance on travel demand forecasting and mode change estimation is provided in Chapter 2 of
this manual.
For freight service investments that are limited in scope or scale it may be appropriate to use the
standardised cross-price elasticities of demand between road and rail. The values in Table 98 are
indicative only and represent the percentage change in rail volume with respect to the percentage change
in rail to road price.
The elasticities depend primarily on the level of inter-modal competition. In New Zealand, where inter-
modal competition is likely to be significant, it is considered that freight price elasticities would more likely
be at the higher end of the ranges identified above. However, it should be noted that other factors may
influence a shipper’s decision. Transit time (generally used as a proxy for distance) appears to be a
significant determinant of mode choice, therefore, the greater the distance, the less likely truck transport
will be chosen.
For significant freight service investments, or where there is significant interaction between freight and
other transport system users, the use of models is encouraged.
Stage 3: Calculate freight service improvement impacts
This section provides guidance on the calculation of impacts on freight service users and the impact of
diverted road traffic on the wider network. Impacts for all other modes should still be calculated on the
route, network and/or transport system, by quantifying, for the do-minimum and options, the changes that
occur for the factors listed in the stages below when an improvement option is considered.
Note that the impact calculations should include any negative impacts (disbenefits) during
implementation/construction.
Freight service user impacts can be calculated by estimating the ‘consumer surplus’. This quantifies the
economic benefits or disbenefits experienced by freight service users after freight haulage rates have
been accounted for. Consumer surplus therefore measures the total economic value of the service to the
service users. Freight haulage rates are usually expressed in $/tonne.
Consumer surplus benefits can be supplemented or supplanted, where this is justified, to take into
account the calculation of freight service user benefits arising from reduced journey time, improved
reliability, and changes to the service quality.
For the calculation of travel time saving benefits, Table 15 contains values of time (VoT), expressed in
$/hour/vehicle, that should be used when vehicles and are used for work purposes to transport freight.
Section 3.6 contains more information on the VoT and adjustment factors that may be applied in highly
congested conditions.
Care needs to be taken to include any additional user costs, such as re-handling or inventory adjustment
costs, as a disbenefit in the evaluation. Additionally, user benefits for freight should also take into account
flexibility in options for frequency of transport and choice of service providers. In some cases, users
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 192
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
transferring freight from road to a rail or sea transport service mode will experience reduced flexibility in
the timing and route of services compared with using a road option. Any such reduced flexibility for the
transport service user must also be included as a disbenefit in evaluations.
The benefits that have currently (2020) been ascribed standardised monetary values are listed below.
The impacts (ie the differences in the parameter outcomes between the do-minimum and the options) are
ascribed monetary values in Chapter 3 of this manual in the list of stages required to complete an
economic analysis and calculate a BCR.
Parameters other than those listed below can be monetised but the process and values ascribed to these
parameters must be agreed with Waka Kotahi before they are included in the analysis, and supporting
information to validate the inclusion of these parameters must be provided.
Stage 3a: Impact on social cost and incidence of crashes
For the purposes of this manual, a crash is a transport related event involving one or more road vehicles
that occurs on the transport network that results in personal physical injury and/or damage to property.
Where freight is diverted from road based services to rail or shipping, there is likely to be a reduction in
the quantum of crashes. Likewise, a new or improved HPMV route may reduce the quantum of crashes if
the number of heavy vehicle trips is reduced.
To undertake a crash analysis, the appropriate crash rates, crash prediction models and crash reduction
factors can be found in the Waka Kotahi Crash estimation compendium (2018).
Refer to section 3.1 and Appendix 2: Crash analysis of this manual for detailed information on the
calculation and monetisation of crash numbers and severities for the do-minimum, alternatives and
options, and the crash reductions that can be expected from the alternatives and options under
consideration.
For minor route improvements, or where a new service is limited in scope, it may be appropriate to use
the compound road traffic reduction benefit value from Table 41 or Table 42 which includes an
allowance for a reduction in crashes per kilometre of vehicle traffic removed from the network.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 193
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
For minor route improvements, or where a new service is limited in scope, it may be appropriate to use
the compound road traffic reduction benefit value from Table 41 or Table 42 which includes an
allowance for a reduction in GHG emissions per kilometre of vehicle traffic removed from the network.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 194
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Figure 17: Flow chart for estimating road section travel time
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 195
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
For minor route improvements, or where a new service is limited in scope, it may be appropriate to use
the compound road traffic reduction benefit value from Table 41 or Table 42, which includes an
allowance for a reduction in vehicle operating costs per kilometre of vehicle traffic removed from the
network.
User costs
Where freight service users incur additional handling, inventory or other related costs, or face decreased
flexibility in freight schedules, these must be accounted for in the evaluation as disbenefits. This manual
does not include standardised values for the disbenefits.
Stage 3f: Impact on system reliability
Journey times tend to vary throughout the day, particularly between peak and off-peak periods, and
between weekdays and weekends. This type of variation is well known to regular drivers and is taken into
account in when calculating the travel time values (including congestion values).
Trip journey time reliability is a different type of variability, which is much less predictable to a transport
system user. For example, car drivers who make a particular journey at the same time every day find
some days it takes as little as 20 minutes, and on other days as much as 40 minutes. Hence, when the
car drivers plan their trips, they have to consider not just the expected travel time but also its variability.
Journey time reliability is measured by the unpredictable variations in journey times, which are
experienced for a journey undertaken at broadly the same time every day. The impact is related to the
day-to-day variations in traffic congestion, typically as a result of day-to-day variations in flow. This is
distinct from the variations in individual journey times, which occur within a particular period.
Journey time reliability is in principle calculated for a complete journey and the total network variability is
the sum of the travel time variability for all journeys on the network. In practice, models may not represent
the full length of journeys and this is accounted for in the reliability procedure for road based activities in
section 4.3.
Stage 3g: Impact of user experience of the transport system
There are two standard values related to this benefit in this manual as follows:
1. Impact on driver frustration derived from ‘time spend passing’. This is an indicator of changes that
passing lane generate in road users experience.
2. Impact on road users’ comfort and productivity due to sealing unsealed roads.
Driver frustration
Vehicle passing options may be provided through the construction of dedicated passing lanes, climbing
lanes, slow vehicle bays, and improved alignments.
Providing passing options releases vehicles from platoons of slower moving vehicles, allowing them to
travel along the road at their desired speed until they are once again constrained by platoons. Typically,
the evaluation of passing options has been undertaken by micro-simulation programmes, which use
various vehicle performance models together with terrain data to establish, in detail, the speeds of
vehicles at each location along the road. These assessments can be excessively complex, particularly
given the general magnitude of such activities.
The demand for passing and consequently the benefits, are a function of a number of parameters
including:
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 196
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
• traffic variables
o traffic volume
o percentage of HCVs
o initial platooning
o directional split of traffic
o vehicle speed distributions
• road variables
o terrain/alignment
o grades
o available passing lanes (sight distance)
o passing lane lengths and frequency.
An alternative method is based on multiple simulations and the unified passing model described in
Appendix 5: Passing lanes is available in the Provisional passing & overtaking guidelines on the Waka
Kotahi website. This method can be used to identify the most appropriate strategy for providing improved
vehicle passing options over a route and assess the benefits of individual vehicle passing options within
those strategies.
Road user comfort from seal extension
Road user comfort benefits and productivity gains from sealing an unsealed road should also be taken
into account. Simplified procedure SP4 Seal extensions provides information on productivity gains. A
value of 10 cents per vehicle per kilometre can be used for road user comfort, which takes account of the
other benefits associated with avoiding unsealed roads.
Stage 3h: Wider economic impacts
Only the most significant infrastructure improvements are likely to generate wider economic impacts
(WEBs). Generally, these would need to change the distribution or density of households and firms within
a major metro area or deliver significant improvements in accessibility between regions in order for wider
effects to arise.
Refer to sections 3.9 to 3.13 of this manual for information on the calculation of wider economic impacts.
WEBs are impacts that can result from transport investment that have been used internationally to
improve transport cost–benefit analysis. They can be thought of as impacts that are additional to the
conventional benefits to transport users. WEBs include productivity, labour supply, imperfect competition,
and land use changes.
Great care is required to ensure that the estimates for WEBs are truly additional to conventional benefits
to avoid double counting. As an example, business travel time savings can result in productivity and
output increases. These are a direct user benefit and any WEBs for increased productivity have to be
additional to these direct user benefits.
In addition to, or in some cases as a consequence of, direct impacts, there can be indirect impacts on the
economy. These may cause a redistribution or reallocation of resources or may cause the entry or exit of
firms. These are WEBs and can include:
• economies of scale from improved transport that can encourage agglomeration or specialisation
of economic activity
• mitigating existing market failures by improving accessibility and therefore competition between
spatial markets
• increased output in imperfectly competitive markets by diminishing persistent externalities
• technology and knowledge transfer by connecting people and places and increasing the
interaction between economic actors.
New Zealand application of WEBs
The following wider economic benefits are applicable to freight activities in the New Zealand context:
• agglomeration, where firms and workers cluster for some activities that are more efficient when
spatially concentrated
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 197
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
• imperfect competition, where a transport improvement causes output to increase in sectors where
there are price-cost margins
• increased labour supply, where a reduction in commuting costs removes a barrier for new
workers accessing areas of employment.
Stage 4 – Undertake risk analysis for significant unpredictable events
Refer to Chapter 7 of this manual for detailed procedures on risk analysis.
The purpose of considering risk is to develop ways of minimising, mitigating and managing it. Risk
analysis and risk management are continuous processes that start at the project inception stage and
proceed through to project completion, and ideally should involve all the relevant parties.
The extent of risk analysis needs to be appropriate to the stages of project development. The critical
project stages are from the rough order cost (ROC) stage through to preliminary assessed cost (PAC)
stage, and then to final estimate of cost (FEC) stage. It is intended that the scope and extent of analysis
will progress according to the stage of project development and be most comprehensive at the FEC
stage. The risk identified and evaluated in these various stages needs to be monitored and managed,
particularly in the final construction stage.
Start of project stage: During the project stage: At end of project stage:
• Identify risks. • Implement preferred • Report on outcomes of
• Assess risk management strategy. strategy.
strategies (reduction, • Assess implications for
mitigation, avoidance, next stage of project.
quantification through date
collection etc).
• Choose preferred strategy.
Stage 5a: Calculate general costs of freight service do-minimum and options
The costs to government of services include:
• funding assistance from government
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 198
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 199
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 200
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Service provider costs must be calculated for the do-minimum and for all options considered. These costs
must be exclusive of GST.
Activity costs
Cost details should include any of the following:
• investigation, design and supervision costs
• physical infrastructure construction and land acquisition costs
• vehicle, vessel or rolling stock acquisition costs
• disruption costs during construction/implementation, if substantial
• operating and maintenance costs
• costs of decommissioning and salvage values
• environmental mitigation costs
• contingency allowance.
In the case of the do-minimum, costs may include essential rehabilitation.
Where expenditure on an activity has already been incurred, it must still be included in the appraisal if the
item has a market value which can be realised, for example land.
Costs which have been irrevocably committed and have no salvage or realisable value, are termed ‘sunk
costs’ (these may include investigation, design or other costs already incurred), and must not be
accounted for in economic appraisal.
Disruption costs to the service provider during implementation may be included when these are expected
to be substantial.
Operating and maintenance costs
Estimate operating and maintenance costs for the service over the analysis period.
Maintenance costs should include routine and periodic maintenance costs, as well as any refurbishment
and replacement costs that occur in the appraisal period.
Treatment of depreciation
Depreciation is a non-cash item and must not be included as a separate item in the cash flows used to
estimate the net present value of a proposal in the financial analysis. Only actual cash flows associated
with maintenance and asset replacement, which already fully account for the depreciation of capital
assets, are to be included in the analysis.
Treatment of interest
Interest expenses associated with financing an activity often represent an actual cash cost outflow.
Despite this, interest charges should not be included in the annual cash flow as the required rate of return
used in the cash flow analysis already takes account of debt-financing interest.
If interest payments were to be included in discounted cash flows, the interest charges would be double
counted; therefore, the proposal’s funding gap would be overstated and the BCR understated.
Salvage value
In some instances, assets will have a longer lifespan than the appraisal period. The salvage value of
capital assets should be included where:
• items have a market value, and
• there is an alternative use, or
• there is a scrap demand for items.
Stage 7b: Calculate service provider revenue
This section describes the information that should be included in the financial analysis of activity options
that generate revenue. The process for forecasting the revenue of an improved service is different from
that for a new service, and the methods for each type of service are described below.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 201
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 202
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 203
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
4. EVALUATION PROCEDURES > 4.8 EVALUATION OF PRIVATE SECTOR FINANCING AND ROAD TOLLING
Tolls
Tolls are payment by road users for the right to travel on a particular road. In economic efficiency terms
the tolls can be viewed in three ways:
1. If the facility is government funded, the tolls are simply a transfer payment between those
motorists who pay them and the government.
2. If the facility is privately financed and the concessionaire (with its toll level proposal) is selected
by competitive tendering, then the toll charges also represent a true market price, ie the resource
cost, for that part of the activities. Any government contribution or expenditure is also part of the
activity cost.
3. Alternatively, tolls can be related to negative benefits (disbenefits). The effect of the toll is to
reduce overall public benefits. If a road user would achieve a benefit of say $3 by using a new toll
road, but must pay a toll of $2, then the net benefit is only $1 if the tolled road is used. The loss of
benefits by those who continue to use the ‘free’ route will be somewhere between zero (because
there would be no benefit in using the tolled route even if there was no toll) and the cost of the toll
($2).
The present value of gross toll collections is the same, regardless of which way they are viewed. Provided
that tolls are not double counted, the net present value of the activity (present value of benefits minus
present value of costs) is also independent of the way tolls are viewed.
In New Zealand, road tolling can currently only be used in conjunction with a new road and this will
generally be within a network of otherwise ‘free’ roads. This has implications for:
• traffic distribution/assignment
• environmental impacts
• economic efficiency
• financial – toll level and fundability of the new road
• design of the new road and toll facility.
The following are essential steps for consideration of a road tolling proposal:
• ensure that the need for the activity and the benefits to the community have been identified and
maximised
• explore alternative solutions, including non-capital options
• identify risks and returns and determine appropriate allocation among relevant parties
• establish the nature and extent of community support likely to be required through an effective
consultation process.
There are several approaches to setting charges for a toll road where other routes are ‘free’. Three of the
most common approaches are:
• a pricing policy where economic welfare as defined by the benefit–cost ratio (BCR) is maximised
• a revenue maximising pricing policy where service provider revenue is maximised
• a ‘network optimisation’ pricing level which seeks to optimise the performance of the network in
terms of total travel times or average network speeds.
In practice, all these three considerations and possibly others may need be considered in reaching a toll
regime which that meets the overall objectives of the proposal.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 204
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
4. EVALUATION PROCEDURES > 4.8 EVALUATION OF PRIVATE SECTOR FINANCING AND ROAD TOLLING
In principle, the economic efficiency evaluation of toll options is no different from that for other (non-
pricing) options for any proposal. However, the following issues warrant particular attention:
• the range of options considered
• the treatment of value of time savings
• the composition and application of BCRs.
Consumer surplus methodology must be used for evaluation of road tolling activities because
motorists’ behaviour in response to various levels of tolls (including no toll) must be determined and
therefore a measure of the willingness to pay. Stated preference (SP) surveys or possibly, revealed
preference (RP) data, need to be used to give a general cost equation (combining travel time, VOC
and toll charge).
Simplified procedures for private sector financing, and road tolling activities
A range of simplified procedures available in this manual may be used to evaluate private sector
financing, and road tolling activities with an undiscounted whole-of-life cost of less than or equal to $15
million. SP6 High productivity motor vehicles, SP8 Freight transport services, SP9 New public transport
services, SP10 Existing public transport services, SP12 Travel behaviour, and SP13 Safety promotion are
the simplified procedures most relevant to private sector financing, and road tolling activities. These
procedures have been discussed in detail elsewhere within Chapter 4. Table 46 may be referred to select
the appropriate procedure.
Full procedures for private sector financing, and road tolling activities
In cases where the simplified procedure assumptions are not appropriate, the full procedures should be
used.
The following table outlines the stages of analysis in the economic efficiency evaluation of private sector
financing, and road tolling activities. The chapters and sections of this manual that apply to each stage of
the analysis are referenced in Table 101.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 205
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
4. EVALUATION PROCEDURES > 4.8 EVALUATION OF PRIVATE SECTOR FINANCING AND ROAD TOLLING
Table 101: Stages of analysis for private sector financing, and road tolling activities
Stage Description Refer
1 Consider and describe: Current section
a. the do-minimum Section 1.4:
b. improvement alternatives and options. Counterfactuals
Section 1.5:
Alternatives and
options
2 Collect data to assess travel impacts: Current section
• target population and Chapter 2:
• demand estimates and modal share Demand estimation
• uptake and mode share
• level of diversion.
Where possible use transport models to assess the impacts and
undertake calibration of the transport models for the activities under
consideration.
3 Measure and monetise the impacts (benefits and disbenefits) for the Chapter 3: Benefits
do-minimum and options, including:
• impact on social cost and incidence of crashes
• impact of mode on physical and mental health
• impact of air emissions on health
• impact of noise and vibration on health
• impact on system reliability
• impact on network productivity and utilisation
• impact on greenhouse gas emissions
• impact on user experience of the transport system
• wider economic impact (productivity)
• wider economic impact (employment impact)
• wider economic impact (imperfect competition)
• wider economic impact (regional economic development)
• wider economic impact (land use change)
• other impacts that can be monetised – these are not
included in this manual but can be included if there is
sufficient supporting evidence and the approach is accepted
by Waka Kotahi.
4 Undertake risk analysis when there are significant unpredictable Chapter 7:
events that may affect or be affected by the improvement activity. Sensitivity and risk
analysis
5 Quantify the costs of the improvement activities including: Section 1.8: Costs
• investigation and design
• property
• construction
• maintenance, renewal and operation
• risk management; mitigation of external impacts
• residual values.
If there is a service provider, determine service provider costs,
service provider revenue and the funding gap. Quantify the net costs
to government of the funding gap.
6 Discount the monetised benefits and costs over the analysis period Chapter 5:
to obtain present values. Then use to calculate the benefit–cost Discounting
ratio(s).
7 Financial analysis to evaluate the viability of an activity by assessing Current section
its cash flows.
8 Determine the benefit–cost ratios of the options. Chapter 6: Benefit–
cost ratios
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 206
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
4. EVALUATION PROCEDURES > 4.8 EVALUATION OF PRIVATE SECTOR FINANCING AND ROAD TOLLING
9 Use incremental cost–benefit analysis to select the preferred option Chapter 6: Benefit–
for mutually exclusive options. cost ratios
10 Perform sensitivity tests on the preferred option to determine how Chapter 7:
robust the calculations are and whether a small change in one of the Sensitivity and risk
input parameters has a large change on the evaluation outcome(s). analysis
11 Verify completeness of information, accuracy of calculations and Current section
validity of assumptions.
Stage 1a: Describe the do-minimum
The do-minimum for evaluating activities with public sector financing and/or road tolling shall only include
committed and funded transport activities, the existing road network with minor improvements, and
potentially the provision of the new road at a much later date (if the purpose of tolling is to bring forward
the provision of the new road).
Stage 1b: Scale and scope of private sector financing, and road tolling options
Economic efficiency evaluation of road tolling activities must be undertaken with and without the tolls in
place, as alternatives and options are required to be considered under the Land Transport Management
Act 2003. Additionally, financial analysis of the toll options is required.
Financial analysis is used to determine the optimum tolls, choices of debt financing, optimum borrowing
and timeframe for implementing tolls. The imposition of tolls has consequences in terms of changing the
demand for the facility, diverting traffic onto other facilities, increasing the costs due to toll collection and
other issues.
Tolling must be evaluated as an option compared with the case of no tolls.
A number of other options aimed at optimisation of the transport system should also be assessed,
including:
• revenue maximisation tolls
• level of tolls and other measures maximising social welfare
• level of tolls and other measures maximising traffic diversion from sensitive areas
• level of tolls and other measures to optimise level of service.
When considering private sector financing options, only options that reduce public sector costs should
remain in the final set of options.
Timing of construction start is an important consideration for activities involving private sector financing
and/or road tolling. These strategies are often used to allow an earlier start for the activity than that
which would apply without these funding sources. The analysis period should be extended to capture
the activity benefits over the useful life of all the options.
With activities involving private sector financing, and particularly tolling, there is usually also an
incentive for early completion of the activity as revenue starts to accrue upon completion of the
proposal.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 207
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
4. EVALUATION PROCEDURES > 4.8 EVALUATION OF PRIVATE SECTOR FINANCING AND ROAD TOLLING
• modal shift
• trip generation/suppression.
The split of traffic between the toll road and alternative routes is likely to be sensitive to the level of
congestion on the road network and the mix of trip purposes by time of day/day of week. Therefore,
detailed traffic modelling must separately consider periods with differing levels of congestion. Expansion
or annualisation factors need to be applied separately to the results for each of these periods based on
the characteristics of the traffic that has the toll route as an option.
Some trips that would use the new route if it was ‘free’ will be deterred from its use by the charges and
will continue to use the existing network. Hence the extent of traffic reduction on existing roads, provided
by the new route is less than would be achieved if the new route were ‘free’.
Stage 3: Calculate private sector financing and road tolling activities impacts
Once traffic impacts have been determined, the calculation of national economic benefits follows in the
normal manner (see section 4.3 for the procedures required to evaluate road renewal and improvement
activities, and Chapter 3 for the relevant benefits) but using the disaggregated willingness-to-pay values
for travel time for benefits or disbenefits (see section 3.6).
Consumer surplus methodology must be used for evaluation of road tolling activities because motorists’
behaviour in response to various levels of tolls (including no toll) must be determined and therefore a
measure of the willingness to pay. Stated preference (SP) surveys or possibly, revealed preference (RP)
data, need to be used to give a general cost equation (combining travel time, VOC and toll charge).
For most transport activities, an average value of time is used in economic efficiency evaluations, ie the
same unit values are used for motorists from more affluent households and for those from less affluent
households. This is essentially an ‘equity’ approach (to avoid favouring activities used by higher income
groups). It also makes the economic evaluation easier. This averaging approach is not of major
consequence for most situations.
However, it has important implications for toll roads, particularly when comparing the economic merits of
tolled versus untolled options. An ‘equity’ value of time will substantially over-estimate the perceived
disbenefits of tolling. The extent of distortion is directly related to the spread of the behavioural value of
travel time.
Evaluation of toll roads (including tolling policies) must use a distribution of values of travel time
consistent with users’ willingness-to-pay values established through SP surveys or other means. A
consistent distribution of values of travel time must be used in both the traffic modelling and economic
efficiency evaluation.
When investigating options and alternatives, behavioural values can be used to calculate initial user
benefits, with the overall results adjusted to the average value of travel time between the behavioural and
equity values for consistency with other activities.
When users are required to pay tolls on a route, some will choose to avoid the toll by using alternative
routes if they are available. The toll charges change the benefits that would otherwise be received by
road users in the following ways:
• For those motorists who continue to use the toll road, benefits are reduced by the extent of the
toll charge, which is added to their generalised cost of travel.
• The benefits to users on the toll road may be increased due to less congestion on the tolled
facility
• For those who would have used the new road if it was not tolled but decide to divert to a ‘free’
road because of the toll, travel time and perhaps vehicle operating costs are likely to increase
• For those who would have continued to use alternative routes, even if the new road was not
tolled, benefits are likely to be reduced because of more congestion.
Environmental and community benefits may also change with a tolled road compared with leaving the
road untolled. Possibilities include:
• overall vehicle use
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 208
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
4. EVALUATION PROCEDURES > 4.8 EVALUATION OF PRIVATE SECTOR FINANCING AND ROAD TOLLING
• use of carpools
• level of public transport use
• options to develop public transport
• overall pollution
• degree of decentralisation
• local area traffic management
• timing of infrastructure provision.
It may not be possible to put values on all these items, but they need to be considered for a tolled facility.
The costs of dislocation and traffic disruption during construction should be included as negative benefits
for all options. These may be different for an untolled road compared to a tolled road (particularly if the
construction period is different).
In assessing the commercial feasibility of private sector funding or a debt facility the following must be
considered.
Stage 4: Undertake risk analysis for significant unpredictable events
Risks are different between options with and without private sector financing and/or operation. Technical
capacity, financial backing, business acumen, activity life and government exposure are very important
considerations where there is private sector involvement.
Identification, quantification and assignment of risks among relevant parties are essential for activities
involving private sector financing and for road tolling activities. This should include preparation of a risk
management plan.
For private sector financing, it is essential to ensure that the commercial arrangement with the private
sector is appropriate and that any probity and accountability requirements are met. The degree to which
risks can be shared with, or assumed by, private sector participants must be identified. Details of likely
contractual obligations as they affect pricing, ongoing risk to government, terms of the contract,
termination arrangements and debt and equity contributions of each party should be clearly specified.
Refer to Chapter 7 of this manual for detailed information on risk analysis.
Stage 5: Calculate costs for do-minimum and improvement options
Section 1.8 must be viewed from both an economic and financial point of view.
The public sector financing and/or toll charges reduce the effective activity costs to the government.
Even if an activity is totally funded by the private sector, there will still be some costs to government
agencies, such as contract preparation and ongoing contract management and monitoring. The cost of
these activities should be included in the cost of the option involving private sector financing.
Similarly, the additional cost of toll infrastructure and toll collection must be included in the tolling option.
Stage 6: Discount benefits and costs
Refer to section 1.9 and Chapter 5 of this manual for the detailed information on undertaking discounting.
Benefits and costs generally arise throughout the life of projects and to calculate their present worth or
present value they need to be discounted back to time zero. Based on a discount rate of 4% and an
analysis period of 40 years, sets of present worth factors have been calculated to convert future benefits
and costs to their present values (see Table 102, and Table A132, Table A133 and Table A134 from
Appendix 6: Discount factors). Discount rates of 3% and 6% are also provided in the tables for sensitivity
testing.
For the evaluation of private financing and road tolling, an adjusted analysis period may be most
appropriate especially where there are long-term financial obligations.
Stage 7: Financial evaluation
Where consideration is being given to private sector involvement in financing land transport infrastructure,
it is important to ensure that the involvement is commercially feasible and that it offers a more cost-
effective solution that the traditional public sector funding approach.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 209
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
4. EVALUATION PROCEDURES > 4.8 EVALUATION OF PRIVATE SECTOR FINANCING AND ROAD TOLLING
Financial analysis is a method to evaluate the viability of an activity by assessing its cash flows. This
differs from economic evaluation in the:
• scope of investigation
• range of input
• methodology used.
Financial analysis views the costs and revenues of the activity from a ‘commercial’ investment point of
view, ie the cash flow impact on government and any private sector party. By contrast economic
efficiency analysis also considers external benefits and costs of the activity whether or not they involve
monetary payments.
Other differences include:
• Market prices and valuations are used in assessing benefits and costs in financial analysis,
instead of measures such as willingness to pay and opportunity cost used in economic analysis.
Market prices include all applicable taxes, tariffs, trade mark-ups and commissions.
• The discount rate used in financial analysis represents the weighted average costs of debt and
equity capital rather than the estimated social opportunity cost of capital.
• The discount rate used in financial analysis and the cash flows to which it is applied are usually
specified in nominal terms (allowing for future inflation), as the costs of debt and equity are
observed only in nominal terms.
Undertaking an economic evaluation does not remove the need for a financial evaluation.
Cash flows to be measured
All incremental costs, revenues and risks associated with an activity and its best alternative should be
identified and measured as nominal cash flows in the period in which they occur. Cash flows should be on
an after-tax basis. An estimate of the asset’s salvage value must be included at the end of the analysis
period to represent the asset’s remaining service potential. The salvage value should not be such as to
bias the viability of the proposal.
Typical inward cash flows to be considered include:
• operating revenues
• subsidies from external parties
• operational savings occurring in other areas as a result of the proposal
• sale of surplus assets
• residual values of assets.
Typical cash outflows to be considered include:
• capital costs (including land, equipment, buildings)
• maintenance and operating costs
• taxes, where appropriate
• operating lease payments
• contract termination payments
• revenue losses to existing operations affected by the proposal
• the opportunity cost of resources (including land) that would otherwise be available for sale or
lease.
Treatment of specific items
Financing costs (interest) should be excluded in the cash flows because the opportunity cost of debt is
accounted for in the weighted average cost of capital (WACC) – the weighted average of the required
return on equity and the (interest) cost of any debt financing reflecting the appropriate risk and norms
associated with the industry.
Accounting, depreciation, economic multiplier effect and sunk costs should be excluded in the financial
analysis. The effect of dividend imputation needs to be considered in the financial analysis.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 210
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
4. EVALUATION PROCEDURES > 4.8 EVALUATION OF PRIVATE SECTOR FINANCING AND ROAD TOLLING
Operating leases should be evaluated in the form of a series of regular payments and compared to an
outright purchase alternative, with consideration for the value of options such as renewal or purchase
rights if these features are present. Financing leases do not form part of a financial analysis as these are
merely an alternative means of financing the proposal.
Weighted average cost of capital (WACC) is used in financial analysis. The WACC should reflect the
appropriate risk and norms associated with the industry.
Summary measures of commercial merit
The more common measures for evaluating the financial viability of an activity are, for example:
• net present value of cash flows
• net present value per $ of capital invested
• internal rate of return (IRR) of cash flows
• payback period
• profitability indices.
Measures used in commercial evaluations will vary between activities and private sector proponents.
Specialist advice should be sought on financial evaluations and detailed descriptions of these evaluations
are not included here.
Stage 8: Determine the benefit–cost ratios of the options
While the basic principles of economic appraisal apply to the evaluation of toll road activities and activities
involving private sector financing, some adjustment is required to the composition and application of
BCRs. Refer to Chapter 6 for detailed information on developing BCRs.
In present value calculations, all government costs and user costs and benefits are presumed to include
escalation. When this is the case, the discount rate is used to determine the present value of unescalated
costs and benefits in economic analysis, and no adjustment is made for inflation.
With private sector financed activities, a rise and fall clause relating to tolls is likely to be included in the
conditions. The gross toll collections for each vehicle category for each year of the activity will need to be
estimated. If tolls are regularly changed in line with general inflation in the economy, then the normal
inflation free discount rate can be used to determine present values only if the escalating effects of the
clauses are first removed from the cash flow estimates.
If tolls are not linked to the general economy inflation rate, some other analysis of the present value of toll
revenues may be required.
National benefit–cost ratio for a toll road
From the national economic point of view tolls are transfer payments and therefore not considered in the
BCRN, which is the same irrespective of whether the toll road is private sector funded or not.
present value of national economic benefits – present value
BCRG = of tolls
present value of net government costs
net direct and indirect benefits and disbenefits to all affected
National economic benefits =
transport users plus all other monetised impacts.
Net government costs = net costs to Waka Kotahi and approved organisations.
Tolls = gross toll collections.
The first-year rate of return (FYRR) for a tolled road activity is:
of national present value of economic benefits – present value
FYRR = of tolls
present value of net government costs
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 211
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
4. EVALUATION PROCEDURES > 4.8 EVALUATION OF PRIVATE SECTOR FINANCING AND ROAD TOLLING
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 212
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
5. DISCOUNTING > 4.8 EVALUATION OF PRIVATE SECTOR FINANCING AND ROAD TOLLING
5. DISCOUNTING
Benefits and costs generally arise throughout the life of projects and to calculate their present worth or
present value they need to be discounted back to time zero. The discount rate represents the rate at
which society is willing to trade off present benefits and costs against future benefits and costs.
The discount rate, effective from 1 July 2020, shall be 4% per annum. This is the rate calculated by Waka
Kotahi as being appropriate for transport investment and is subject to ongoing review.
Based on a discount rate of 4%, sets of present worth factors have been calculated to convert future
benefits and costs to their present values. Tables for discount rates of 3% and 6% are also provided for
use in sensitivity testing.
Some benefits and costs occur at a single point in time in which case single payment present worth
factors (SPPWF) shall be used to discount the amounts to their present value. The annual SSPWF table
for discount rates of 3%, 4% and 6% is provided in Table 102. A quarterly SSPWF table for the same
discount rates is provided in Table A132 of Appendix 6: Discount factors.
Other benefits and costs occur continuously over a number of years, in which case either uniform series
(USPWF) or arithmetic growth present worth factors (AGPWF) should be used to discount the amounts to
a present value, depending on whether the amounts are uniform or increase arithmetically over time (eg
traffic and patronage growth). USPWF and AGPWF tables for discount rates of 3%, 4% and 6% are
provided in Table A133 and Table A134 respectively of Appendix 6: Discount factors.
When discounting benefits or costs determined from a transportation model, the present worth factors
specified in this manual must be used. If necessary, adjust values to time zero equivalents. Traffic growth
rates may also require a similar adjustment to time zero.
When discounting crash benefits the traffic growth rate will need to be adjusted in accordance with the
procedures in Appendix 2: Crash analysis to determine the appropriate arithmetic growth rate to apply.
External impacts are assumed to remain constant so the uniform present worth series should be used to
obtain the present value of monetised impacts.
Worked examples of discounting using the SSPWF, USPWF and AGPWF are provided in Appendix 8:
Worked examples.
1 1
SPPWFin = =
(1 + i)n 1.04n
for a 4% discount rate, where: n is time in years after time zero, and
i is the discount rate expressed as a decimal, ie for 4% i = 0.04.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 213
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
5. DISCOUNTING > 4.8 EVALUATION OF PRIVATE SECTOR FINANCING AND ROAD TOLLING
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 214
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
5. DISCOUNTING > 4.8 EVALUATION OF PRIVATE SECTOR FINANCING AND ROAD TOLLING
(1- (1 + i)-n)
USPWFin =
loge(1 + i)
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 215
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
6. BENEFIT–COST RATIOS
The activity costs required for determining benefit–cost ratios (BCRs), incremental benefit–cost ratios,
and the first-year rate of return, are the difference between the costs of the activity option and the costs of
the do-minimum. The activity benefits are similarly the differences between the benefit values calculated
for the activity option and those of the do-minimum. In this sense, all of the BCRs calculated for transport
activities are incremental BCRs
It follows that where a particular benefit or cost is unchanged among all the activity options and the do-
minimum, it does not require valuation or inclusion in the economic analysis. For completeness, it should
be noted in any funding application that the benefit or cost is unchanged.
National economic benefits are defined as the net direct benefits and disbenefits experienced by transport
users, the net indirect benefits and disbenefits experienced as externalities by the population outside the
transport system, and all other monetised impacts.
Where the national economic benefits include wider economic benefits (WEBs) it is a requirement that the
national benefit–cost ratio is calculated with and without the WEBs included. This is described in more
detail below.
National economic costs are defined in one of two ways. Where there is no service provider, national
economic costs are the net cost to Waka Kotahi and approved organisations. Otherwise, national
economic costs are the net cost Waka Kotahi and approved organisations, plus net service provider
costs.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 216
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
incremental benefits
Incremental BCR =
incremental costs
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 217
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
5. If the incremental BCR is equal to or greater than the target incremental BCR, discard the lower-
cost option and use the second to lowest-cost option as the comparison basis with the next
higher-cost option.
6. If the incremental BCR is less than the target incremental BCR, discard the higher-cost option
and use the lower-cost option as the basis for comparison with the next higher-cost option.
7. Repeat the procedure from steps 2 to 6 until all options have been analysed.
8. Finally, select the option with the highest cost which has an incremental BCR equal to or greater
than the target incremental BCR.
A worked example of the incremental BCR procedure is provided in Appendix 8: Worked examples.
FYRR = present value of the activity benefits in first full year following completion × 100
present value of the activity costs over the analysis period
The FYRR is useful for sequencing activities when funding is constrained, but it should not be used to
evaluate whether an activity is economically efficient. The FYRR indicates the extent to which the benefits
of an activity arise immediately, or are dependent on future growth, but the overall economic efficiency
cannot be evaluated on the basis of the activity’s benefits in the first year of operation.
It is a requirement that the FYRR is calculated for the preferred option.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 218
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 219
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
7. SENSITIVITY AND RISK ANALYSIS > 7.3 DEMAND ESTIMATION SENSITIVITY TESTS
The results of the sensitivity tests, along with explanation of any assumptions or choice of test, should be
reported as upper and lower bounds on the BCR as a component of an activity’s economic case.
Discount rate
While the base evaluation uses the standard 4% discount rate, sensitivity testing should be carried out at
discount rates of 3% and 6%. In particular, sensitivity testing at the lower rate of 3% can be used for
activities with long-term future benefits that cannot be adequately captured with the standard discount
rate. Discounting at these other rates should be applied and reported as a standard sensitivity test for full
procedures using Table 102 (SPPWF) from Chapter 5 as well as Table A133 (USPWF) and Table A134
(AGPWF) from Appendix 6: Discount factors.
Demand estimation
As all forecast benefits and disbenefits are derived from future demand estimates, particular emphasis
should be placed on testing the drivers or demand. This is described in detail in section 7.3.
Safety improvements
Safety improvement activities are undertaken where a route or site (eg curve, railway crossing, bridge
etc) has a high occurrence of crashes, or when the risk of crashes is considered high.
Given the majority of benefits (and hence benefit–cost ratio) for such schemes arise from a reduction in
crashes, it is important that a robust assessment is undertaken. Analysts should avoid basing their
assessment on a small number of historical crashes or using unsuitable crash rates, crash prediction
models or crash reduction factors. It is also important to undertake sensitivity testing to understand how
sensitive the benefit–cost ratio is to the crash history, crash prediction and crash reduction factors.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 220
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
7. SENSITIVITY AND RISK ANALYSIS > 7.3 DEMAND ESTIMATION SENSITIVITY TESTS
• the analysis and outcomes are sensitive to the level of congestion, delays, and queueing
(particularly parts of the network being highly congested for significant lengths of time) – this can
relate to both the do-minimum and activity scenarios, but is often most pertinent in the do-
minimum scenario where the activity may reduce congestion
• economic outcomes are particularly sensitive to smaller changes in demand estimates; for
example, the level of development anticipated by certain years on a key approach to an
intersection improvement assessment.
Forecast horizons and uncertainty, provides some context around different scenarios, and where and
when the number and range of sensitivity tests may be important. This relates to producing short-,
medium- and long-term forecasts in different locations when assessing different scales of activities.
Appendix 1: Demand estimation methods and guidance provides guidance on techniques, methods and
considerations for developing demand estimates. Where these approaches and techniques can be used
to develop sensitivities, this is described and noted.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 221
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
7. SENSITIVITY AND RISK ANALYSIS > 7.3 DEMAND ESTIMATION SENSITIVITY TESTS
Table 103: Guidance on importance of sensitivity tests – project model and calculation focus
Factors affecting demand estimates Project model/calculation approaches
Network Short Spreadsheet Straightforward
project corridor/ or similar calculations
model (not intersection equations/
linked to/fed model (not models/
by regional linked to/fed calculations
model) by regional
model)
Elasticity methods, relationships and I I P U
values
Local land use changes P P P U
Section 2.12, below Table 2 provides some expanded information on each of the elements, methods and
approaches in the above table. The points below relate these considerations to potential methods and
approaches for developing sensitivity tests. In some cases, several of these elements may be varied
separately or together to produce a number of demand estimate sensitivities.
• Elasticity methods, relationships and values: sensitivity tests varying the elasticity value(s)
used are likely to be a good way to examine the response and suitability in relation to the specific
activity in the local context.
• Local land use changes: sensitivity tests could include running scenarios with and without
specific land use developments that are important to the activity demand scenario, faster and
slower rates of land use development uptake, etc.
• Local transport system and supply changes: sensitivity tests may be straightforward, for
example, testing with and without a local transport system change that effects the economic
assessment.
• Trip rates: increasing and decreasing trip rates produces straightforward demand estimate
sensitivity tests, particularly where an assumed trip rate has a direct effect on the economic
assessment.
• Distribution analysis: alterations to the distribution assumptions produce straightforward
demand estimate sensitivity tests, particularly where an assumed trip distribution has a direct
effect on the economic assessment.
• Factoring methods: varying factors is a straightforward approach to sensitivity tests and
analyses.
• Trend analysis: where medium- and longer-term forecasts are developed from trend analysis,
and the resulting demand estimates are important to the economic assessment, straightforward
sensitivity tests may be developed by varying the trend factor(s), and/or adjusting the magnitude
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 222
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
7. SENSITIVITY AND RISK ANALYSIS > 7.3 DEMAND ESTIMATION SENSITIVITY TESTS
of growth that occurs within certain timeframes (for example, large proportion of growth occurring
within an early timeframe and lower growth following this, and vice-versa).
• Engineering estimates of predicted facility use: varying the level of predicted facility use
produces sensitivity tests on the predicted outcomes.
Table 104 provides some high-level guidance on which elements may have a greater influence on and/or
produce greater levels of uncertainty in demand estimates in regional transport models. These
characteristics lead to guidance on altering these elements and inputs as sensitivity tests to produce a
range of demand estimates.
One, two, or several of these elements may be adjusted in isolation or combination to produce demand
estimate sensitivities.
Table 104: Guidance on importance of sensitivity tests – regional transport modelling focus
Factors affecting demand estimates Geographic context/transport environment
Major urban Moderate Small Township,
centre urban urban rural
(population centre centre corridor/
roughly greater (population (population area
than 500,000) roughly ~ 30,000– (population
between 100,000) roughly
100,000– less than
500,000) 30,000)
Population structure/make-up (particularly I I I P
age)
Household/family structure (retired, school- I I I P
age children, in workforce, etc)
Vehicle availability/access to a vehicle I I P P
Road congestion/delay I P P U
Road pricing/tolling I I I I
Route choice P P U U
Section 2.12, below Table 3, provides some expanded information on each of the elements, methods and
approaches in the above table. The points below relate these considerations to potential methods and
approaches for developing sensitivity tests. In some cases, several of these elements may be varied
separately or together to produce a number of demand estimate sensitivities. In all cases, the likelihood of
these elements changing should be assessed so that sensitivity tests are realistic.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 223
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
7. SENSITIVITY AND RISK ANALYSIS > 7.3 DEMAND ESTIMATION SENSITIVITY TESTS
• Population structure/make-up: as well as varying the overall population projection for a region
(for example, through Statistics NZ’s low, medium and high projections), the make-up and
structure of the population could be altered to produce sensitivities.
• Household/family structure: the ease of varying these input assumptions as sensitivity tests will
be dependent on the structure of the model. However, if significant changes in household/family
structure are anticipated, then sensitivity tests should be carried out varying the number of
shopping trips, work trips, etc.
• Vehicle availability/access to a vehicle: varying (for example, by reducing) vehicle
availability/access for households is a method for providing a sensitivity test on potential
changing future travel patterns (for example, less private vehicle trip-making as a result of climate
change policy, behaviour changes and/or technology changes).
• Access to alternative modes and infrastructure: sensitivity tests may involve factoring the
modal demand down; for example, reducing the car demand estimated for a road-based activity
to quantify the potential reduction in economic benefits.
• Public transport coverage/frequency/charges: sensitivity tests here may involve adjustment to
walk times (for example, due to increased micro-mobility), wait/transfer times (for example, due to
technology improvements that improve the reliability and accuracy of PT arrival times), and fares
(for example, due to climate change policy or behaviour changes).
• Residential density: sensitivity tests could involve changing where there are employment
opportunities and/or schools to represent closer opportunities to shop and work, and for
education. Realistic patterns should be considered.
• Parking: varying parking charges may produce a change in mode choice or a change in
destination choice, and may be an approach to developing sensitivity tests.
• Road pricing/tolling: sensitivity tests could involve altering monetary charges and elements that
influence the human response to cost changes. In Australia, there have been legal challenges on
toll road forecasts, particularly where consortia were bidding to secure the project. Practical
engineering considerations, quality reviews, and sensitivity tests are critical in these scenarios
There are several scenarios to consider in relation to developing demand sensitivity tests from regional
transport models:
• Specific activity economic assessment: when carrying out an economic assessment of a
specific type of transport activity (for example, public transport improvement or a new toll road), it
is sensible and advisable to carry out targeted sensitivity tests that will directly influence the
demand estimates associated with the activity (for example, parameters and assumptions
effecting PT mode choice and people’s responses to road pricing/tolling).
• General demand scenario development: a region may develop a set of demand estimates for
ongoing consideration and use in assessments, or more generalised demand scenarios may
need to be developed for significant projects in key locations (for example, a new bridge in a
major urban centre). These are grouped below in ‘themed’ demand scenarios, purely as
illustrative examples:
o Historical trip-making scenario: parameters, relationships, models and equations are
‘held’ as per the validated base model to produce medium- and long-term demand
forecasts.
o High PT uptake: parameters and assumptions that effect the relative attractiveness
(generalised cost) of PT travel versus private vehicle travel are adjusted to increase PT
mode share.
o Reduced overall trip-making: parameters and assumptions that effect the overall number
of trips made by trip purpose are adjusted to reflect significantly increased working and/or
shopping from home and/or higher uptake of e-mobility, etc. The result being fewer
overall trips being made across the network.
The NZ Modelling User Group (NZMUGS) has been developing considerations and information relating to
sensitivity tests, the content above draws from this work. Further background, references and information,
there are several discussion papers on forecasting and sensitivity tests available via the NZMUGS
webpage.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 224
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
7. SENSITIVITY AND RISK ANALYSIS > 7.3 DEMAND ESTIMATION SENSITIVITY TESTS
One recommendation from the NZMUGS work is the use of an uncertainty log, which is described further
below.
Uncertainty log
Various agencies around the world have introduced the concept of an uncertainty log in relation to
transport analysis. This is a record of the assumptions made in the model (and/or any calculations,
mathematical models, etc) that will affect demand and supply.
In the United Kingdom (UK), an uncertainty log is included in the Department for Transport guidance. The
UK guidance uses subtlety different definitions, particularly for forecasts and scenarios, than the MBCM.
For more information and background, see TAG Unit M4: Forecasting and uncertainty (UK Department of
Transport 2019).
The broad UK approach is to develop a core scenario, which is based on the most unbiased and realistic
set of assumptions. This forms a central case, and alternative scenarios are developed around this. This
concept could be applied to both the do-minimum and, in the case where the activity is anticipated to
have a more significant effect on travel demand (for example, a large PT scheme), the activity scenario.
Alternative scenarios are then developed around the core scenario. Importantly, the alternative scenarios
are developed based on key uncertainties in the core scenario.
The uncertainty log is used to summarise the significant assumptions and uncertainties in the
modelling/analysis and forecasting approach. The purpose of the log is to document the central
assumptions that underpin the core scenario and record the degree of uncertainty around these central
assumptions. These assumptions and uncertainties can then be used as the basis for the development of
alternative forecasts and/or model parameter sensitivity tests.
The uncertainty log extends to cover both elements of uncertainty in demand estimation (including base
and future years) and elements of uncertainty in the specification/settings/parameters in the model (for
example, vehicle route choice parameters). Another way to describe this is that broadly there are two
sources of uncertainty:
1. inputs (such as size of new housing development, future population, etc)
2. error in the model parameters and specifications (how these inputs propagate through the
model).
Along with the elements, considerations and methods that relate more directly to demand estimation
sensitivity tests as described in the sections above, the uncertainty log and associated sensitivities could
include factors such as:
• concerns or issues with the observed data that has been used to develop a model or carry out
analysis
• currency of the base year models, robustness of the base year calibration/validation, and
comments by the peer reviewer
• any specific identified areas of weakness in the base model; for example, a specific location in
the network where the modelled versus observed comparison is poor
• currency of the inputs used to develop travel demand estimations; for example, the population
projections, regional land use development plans or strategies used
• appropriateness and design of the model available for the assessment
• key parameters or settings that directly influence the model’s ability to predict a key outcome; for
example, balance of traffic volumes on competing routes, the operation (delays and queues) of a
particular network feature (for example, a key multi-lane roundabout), queues blocking back into
critical areas of the network, traffic signal coordination and associated measurement of delays
between scenarios, consistency and reliability of public transport travel times.
Whether these components are used to develop sensitivity tests or not in relation to an economic
assessment depends on how they are anticipated to affect the outcomes of the assessment. Greater
uncertainty in relation to these elements could result in an increased number of sensitivity tests being run;
for example, further future-year demand tests and/or changes to key model parameters.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 225
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 226
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Risk concepts
The risk procedures are designed around a common set of concepts, which are described in more detail
below.
Risk
The effect of uncertainty on objectives. An effect is a deviation from the expected. It can be positive,
negative or both, and can address, create or result in opportunities and threats. Risk is usually expressed
in terms of risk sources, potential events, their consequences, and their likelihood.
Risk source
An element which alone, or in combination with others, has the potential to give rise to risk.
Event
An occurrence or change of a particular set of circumstances. Events included changes that are expected
to occur, but do not, or changes that are not expected to occur but do so. Additionally, an event can be a
risk source.
Consequence
The outcome of an event affecting objectives. Consequences can be expressed qualitatively or
quantitatively. Any consequence can escalate through cascading and cumulative effects.
Likelihood
The chance of something happening. In risk management terminology, the word ‘likelihood’ is used to
refer to the chance of an event occurring, whether defined, measured or determined objectively or
subjectively, qualitatively or quantitatively, and described using general terms or mathematically (such as
a probability or a frequency over a given time period).
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 227
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Each risk is likely to have an individual definition and measurement of its consequences (both positive
and negative). Consequences can be expressed qualitatively or quantitatively.
The criteria used to distinguish different consequence ratings are based upon professional experience of
the key factors which affect levels of risk. Where there is any doubt as to the appropriate classification,
the general quantitative rule expressed in Table 106 should be used:
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 228
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 229
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Risk assessment
A risk assessment is the overall process of risk identification, risk analysis and risk evaluation. Risk
assessments are to be conducted using risk analysis worksheet 1 and risk analysis worksheet 2. Risk
treatments are to be captured in risk analysis worksheets 3.
Risk analysis worksheet 1 is used for both an abbreviated summary of risks for activities that are in the
early stages of evaluation, and for detailed reporting of risks for activities that are at the detailed (DBC) or
single-stage business case (SSBC) stage.
Risk analysis worksheet 2 is to be used to provide additional detailed information on the high and critical
risks identified in risk analysis worksheet 1 and an estimated quantifiable risk calculation.
Risk analysis worksheet 3 is the risk-adjusted benefits and costs and BCR risk tool.
All three risk analysis worksheets, and their associated instructions, are contained within this manual in
Appendix 7: Risk analysis worksheets.
Risk identification
The purpose of risk identification is to find, recognise and describe risks that might help or prevent an
activity achieving its objectives. Transport analysts may use a range of techniques to identify
uncertainties that affect one or more objectives. The following factors, and the relationship between these
factors, should be considered:
• tangible and intangible sources of risk
• causes and events
• threats and opportunities
• vulnerabilities and capabilities
• changes in the external and internal context
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 230
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 231
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
basis. Section 7.3 discusses the concept of an uncertainty log in relation to transport modelling, base year
and future year demand estimation. The uncertainty log is likely to feed this risk analysis.
For each possible risk, a brief description is provided as well as possible risk sources. As a general
principle, the consequence rating is extreme, severe, moderate, minor, or insignificant when the benefit
estimation deviation is >±50%, ±25%–50%, ±10%–25%, ±5%–10%, or <±5%.
Table 109: Benefit risks from base year models/source data used to develop demand estimations
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 232
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 233
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Table 110: Benefit risks from future year forecast demand estimations
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 234
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Local land use/ Local land use development areas • Development-related travel (or other
transport supply and/or local transport supply has a land use changes, such as density
changes large effect on activity scenario changes) contributes a notable
(including walking, cycling, PT proportion of, or has a significant
travel related to local influence on, predicted future-year travel
development(s)). volumes and/or direction of travel in the
vicinity of the activity. Associated
weaknesses/uncertainty in these
assumptions.
• Local transport supply changes
contribute to a notable proportion of, or
have a significant influence on,
predicted future-year travel volumes
and/or network operation in the vicinity
of the activity. Associated weaknesses/
uncertainty in these assumptions.
Other key trip Vehicle availability/access, • The assumption that historical trip-
making household/family structure, pricing making behaviours continue into future
assumptions/ (fuel, parking, tolls etc), technology may be important to test/review/
relationships influences etc are likely to effect consider in relation to the assessment.
future travel and trip-making. • Key assumptions (for example, parking
charges, tolls, road pricing and similar)
play an important role in relation to the
activity scenario and/or overall travel in
the region in the future.
Transport mode Diversion of trips from other • Activity may cause diversion of trips
diversion transport modes is a large portion from other transport modes (vehicle,
assumption of the activity demand estimation walking, cycling, PT) and redistribution
projection. of travel demand. If such diversions are
a significant part of demand estimates,
the risks are likely to be higher. These
risks will be further increased if there is
potential variability in the extent of
transport capacity to be provided as part
of the activity (for example, bus
frequency using a new PT corridor).
Note: Future-year demand estimation forecasts may be from calculations, trend analysis factors etc,
project models taking inputs from other sources/methods, and regional transport models.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 235
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 236
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 237
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Contingencies
Significant cost risks that cannot be realistically reduced by other means are covered by contingencies in
the cost estimate. The purpose of contingency is to increase the accuracy of cost estimates according to
the transport analyst’s best effort.
The overall contingency allocated should be specified and an indication given of the confidence attached
to the contingency, in terms of the likelihood of a cost over-run greater than the contingency.
Concerning the relevant contingencies, if the following six types are distinguished, then it is expected that
the contingency table focuses on items 4 to 6, while for most activities, items 1 and 3 would be allowed
for in uniform factors on costs; item 2 is excluded:
1. changes in scope definition arising from omissions
2. changes in scope definition arising from client instruction
3. estimating inaccuracy
4. identified risks which are not managed
5. known but undefined risks
6. unknown risks.
For more information on contingency please refer to SM014 – Cost estimation manual.
The reasonable contingency amount should be determined and justified according to the activity’s
uncertainty. An assessment of the required contingency is required.
As a general principle, a contingency of between 10%–20% of the total capital cost of an activity is
considered reasonable. If an activity has significant uncertainties, and a contingency above 20%, further
investigation, with a focus on resolving cost estimation uncertainties, should be prioritised rather than
proceeding to implementation with a higher contingency.
Risk treatments
Risk treatment involves an iterative process of:
• formulating and selecting risk treatment options
• planning and implementing risk treatment
• assessing the effectiveness of that treatment
• reporting and managing residual risks.
Risk treatments should be documented within an activity’s risk register according to SM030 Minimum
standard Z/44 – Risk management practice guide. The risk register template is available for use on all
transport activities. Some content of the risk management guide has been written to specifically apply to
Waka Kotahi state highway activities, but the concepts are generalisable to all transport activities.
Risk treatment options
The strategic directions available to treat risk will depend on the lifecycle of an activity. These include:
• avoiding the risk by deciding not to start or continue with the activity that gives rise to the risk
• taking or increasing the risk in order to pursue an opportunity
• removing the risk source
• changing the likelihood
• changing the consequences;
• sharing the risk (eg through contracts, buying insurance)
• retaining the risk by informed decision.
These strategic directions may in turn lead to the following actions:
• abandon the activity
• reformulate the activity to capture the majority of the benefits at reduced cost
• conduct further investigation to reduce one or more of the identified uncertainties (either physical
investigations of more detailed assessment of risks)
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 238
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
• defer further processing of the activity until information comes available that assists in reducing
the uncertainties
• defer further processing of the activity until the FYRR increases to the required cut-off level
• proceed to the next stage of processing, or to tender
• other justified actions.
Examples of risk treatment options are provided in Table 113.
When selecting risk treatment options, an organisation should consider the values, perceptions and
potential involvement of stakeholders and the most appropriate ways to communicate and consult with
them. Risk treatments, even if carefully designed and implemented, may not produce the expected
outcomes and can result in unintended consequences. Monitoring and review need to be an integral part
of the risk treatment implementation to provide assurance that the different forms of treatment become,
and remain, effective.
Monitoring and review
The purpose of monitoring and review is to provide assurance and continuously improve the quality and
effectiveness of process design, implementation and outcomes. Ongoing monitoring and periodic review
of the risk management process, and its outcomes, should be a planned part of the risk management
process with responsibilities clearly defined.
Monitoring and review should take place in all stages of the process. Monitoring and review includes
planning, gathering and analysing information, recording results and providing feedback.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 239
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 240
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 241
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 242
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
REFERENCES
REFERENCES
Akcelik R (1981). Traffic signals: Capacity and timing analysis. ARRB research report 123.
Australian Transport Assessment and Planning (2016). Australian Transport Assessment and Planning
guidelines. T5 Distributional (equity) effects.
https://www.atap.gov.au/sites/default/files/t5_distributional_equity_effects.pdf
Australian Transport Assessment and Planning (2018a). Australian Transport Assessment and Planning
guidelines. M1 – Public transport. https://www.atap.gov.au/sites/default/files/M1_Public_transport.pdf
Australian Transport Assessment and Planning (2018b). Australian Transport Assessment and Planning
guidelines. T2 Cost benefit analysis.
https://www.atap.gov.au/sites/default/files/t2_cost_benefit_analysis.pdf
Australian Transport Assessment and Planning (2018c). Australian Transport Assessment and Planning
guidelines. O2 – Optimism bias. https://www.atap.gov.au/sites/default/files/o2-optimsim-bias.pdf
Australian Transport Council (2006). National guidelines for transport system management in Australia 5:
background material.
https://www.transportinfrastructurecouncil.gov.au/sites/default/files/National_Guidelines_Volume_5.pdf
Austroads (1988). Guide to traffic engineering practice part 2: roadway capacity.
Austroads (1989). Rural road design – guide to the design of rural roads.
Austroads (1993). Guide to traffic engineering practice part 6: roundabouts.
Austroads (2003). Rural road design – guide to the geometric design of rural roads.
Austroads (2012). Guide to project evaluation part 4: project evaluation data.
https://austroads.com.au/publications/economics-and-financing/agpe04-12
Austroads (2020). Guide to traffic management part 3: traffic studies and analysis.
https://austroads.com.au/publications/traffic-management/agtm03
Balcombe et al (2004). The demand for public transport: a practical guide. TRL report 593.
https://trl.co.uk/sites/default/files/TRL593%20-%20The%20Demand%20for%20Public%20Transport.pdf
Barnes G, KJ Krizek, P Mogush and G Poindexter (2005). Guidelines for analysing the benefits and costs
of bicycle facilities.
http://citeseerx.ist.psu.edu/viewdoc/download?doi=10.1.1.522.6714&rep=rep1&type=pdf
Bein P, CJ Johnson and T Litman (1995). Monetization of environmental impacts on roads. Planning
services branch. Ministry of Transportation and Highways, Victoria, British Columbia.
Charles P (2011). ‘Optimism bias in transport planning’. Transport Futures Institute.
https://transportfutures.institute/optimism-bias/
Committee on the Medical Effects of Air Pollutants (COMEAP) (2015). Statement on the evidence for the
effects of nitrogen dioxide on health. https://www.gov.uk/government/publications/nitrogen-dioxide-health-
effects-of-exposure
DEFRA (2015). Valuing impacts on air quality: updates in valuing changes in emission of oxides of
nitrogen (NOx) and concentrations of nitrogen dioxide (NO2). http://qna.files.parliament.uk/qna-
attachments/419202%5Coriginal%5C676%20-%20HL2275%20Air-quality-econanalysis-nitrogen-interim-
guidance.pdf
Dravitzki V et al (2001). Traffic noise guidelines for low noise areas in New Zealand. Transfund New
Zealand research report 190. https://www.nzta.govt.nz/resources/research/reports/190/
Douglas Consulting Services and Abley Transportation Consultants 2011. Trips and parking related to
land use. NZ Transport Agency research report 453:
https://www.nzta.govt.nz/resources/research/reports/453/
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 243
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
REFERENCES
Duranton G and D Puga (2003). Micro-foundations of urban agglomeration economies. National Bureau
of Economic Research working paper 9931. https://www.nber.org/papers/w9931.pdf
Francis T, AP Roozenburg and SA Turner (2006). Predicting accident rates for cyclists and pedestrians.
Land Transport NZ research report 289. https://www.nzta.govt.nz/resources/research/reports/289/
Graham DJ and DC Mare (2009). Agglomeration elasticities in New Zealand. NZ Transport Agency
research report 376. https://www.nzta.govt.nz/resources/research/reports/376/
Heerdegen W (2013). The discount rate for the Economic Evaluation Manual 2013. NZ Transport Agency
EEM Technical Paper. https://www.nzta.govt.nz/assets/planning/investment/docs/research-paper-on-
discount-rate-revisions.pdf
Highways England (1996). Design manual for roads and bridges. Volume 12, Section 2, Part 1, Appendix
F. https://assets.highwaysengland.co.uk/roads/road-projects/a2-bean-ebbsfleet-junction-
improvements/Orders/I.8+DMRB+Part+1+Traffic+Appraisal.pdf
Hoban CJ et al (1991). A model for simulating traffic on two-lane roads: user guide and manual for
TRARR version 3.2, technical manual ATM 10B. Australian Road Research Board, Victoria.
Hughes J, A Wild and C Muzyk (2020). Developing a method for quantifying transport interdependencies.
Waka Kotahi NZ Transport Agency research report 671.
https://www.nzta.govt.nz/resources/research/reports/671/
Kennaird A (1995). Accident Trends in New Zealand. NZ Transport Agency Research Report 47.
https://www.nzta.govt.nz/resources/research/reports/47/
Kernohan D and L Rognlien (2011). Wider economic impacts of transport investments in New Zealand.
NZ Transport Agency research report 448. https://www.nzta.govt.nz/resources/research/reports/448
Koorey GF et al (1999). Assessing passing lanes – stage 2. Transfund NZ research report 146.
https://www.nzta.govt.nz/resources/research/reports/146/
Koorey G (2003). Assessment of rural road simulation modelling tools. Transfund NZ research report 245.
https://www.nzta.govt.nz/resources/research/reports/245/
Kuschel et al (2012). Updated health and air pollution in New Zealand study (HAPINZ). Prepared for the
Health Research Council of New Zealand, Ministry of Transport, Ministry for the Environment, NZ
Transport Agency.
Land Transport NZ (2006). Pedestrian planning and design guide.
https://www.nzta.govt.nz/assets/resources/pedestrian-planning-guide/docs/pedestrian-planning-guide.pdf
Land Transport NZ/Energy Efficiency and Conservation Authority (2004a). Travel behaviour change
evaluation procedures – technical report.
Land Transport NZ/Energy Efficiency and Conservation Authority (2004b). Travel behaviour change
guidance handbook.
Land Transport Safety Authority (2004). Cycle network and route planning guide.
https://www.nzta.govt.nz/assets/resources/cycle-network-and-route-planning/docs/cycle-network-and-
route-planning.pdf
McWha V and R Tooth (2020). Better measurement of the direct and indirect costs and benefits of
resilience. Waka Kotahi NZ Transport Agency research report 670.
https://www.nzta.govt.nz/resources/research/reports/670/
Ministry of Transport (2005a). Getting there – on foot, by cycle.
https://www.beehive.govt.nz/sites/default/files/Getting%20there.pdf
Ministry of Transport (2005b). Surface transport costs and charges: main report.
Ministry of Transport (2016). The social costs of road crashes and injuries 2015 update.
https://www.transport.govt.nz/assets/Uploads/Research/Documents/5eb1efb361/Social-cost-of-road-
crashes-and-injuries-2015-update.pdf
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 244
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
REFERENCES
Ministry of Transport (2017). The social costs of road crashes and injuries 2016 update.
https://www.transport.govt.nz/assets/Uploads/Research/Documents/da762d8ad1/Social-cost-of-road-
crashes-and-injuries-2016-update-final.pdf
MRCagney and Ian Wallis Associates (2012). TransLink service and infrastructure evaluation framework
(SIEF), Part 1 – ramp-up profiles. Report to TransLink Transit Authority.
New South Wales Department of State and Regional Development (1997). Guidelines for private sector
participation in the provision of public infrastructure.
New Zealand Modelling User Group (2017). ‘NZMUGs micro time-of-day choice research’.
https://drive.google.com/file/d/1j9DleWOsSIIrdPTqxY1q1ZV6UxKU1Hqq/view
NZ Transport Agency (2009). Pedestrian planning and design guide.
https://nzta.govt.nz/resources/pedestrian-planning-guide/
NZ Transport Agency (2011). High-risk rural roads guide. https://www.nzta.govt.nz/resources/high-risk-
rural-roads-guide/
NZ Transport Agency (2013). High-risk intersection guide. https://www.nzta.govt.nz/resources/high-risk-
intersections-guide/
NZ Transport Agency (2016). Crash estimation compendium.
https://www.nzta.govt.nz/assets/resources/economic-evaluation-manual/economic-evaluation-
manual/docs/crash-risk-factors-guidelines-compendium.pdf
NZ Transport Agency (2019). Transport model development guidelines.
https://www.nzta.govt.nz/resources/transport-model-development-guidelines/
O’Fallon C and C Sullivan (2006). Increasing cycling and walking: an analysis of readiness to change.
Land Transport NZ research report 294. https://www.nzta.govt.nz/resources/research/reports/294
Ortúzar JD and LG Willumsen (2011). Modelling transport. Fourth edition.
Raux C and S Souche (2004). ‘The acceptability of urban road pricing: a theoretical analysis applied to
experience in Lyon’. Journal of Transport Economics and Policy, 38(2).
https://www.ingentaconnect.com/content/lse/jtep/2004/00000038/00000002/art00002
Smith MG (2019). Urban transport modelling in New Zealand – data, practice and resourcing. NZ
Transport Agency research report 659. https://www.nzta.govt.nz/resources/research/reports/659
Statistics New Zealand (2007). Regional GDP concepts, sources and methods.
http://archive.stats.govt.nz/~/media/Statistics/browse-categories/economic-indicators/gross-domestic-
product/regional-gdp/regional-gdp-concepts-sources-methods.pdf
Tate FN (1995). Assessing passing lanes – stage 1. Transit NZ research project PR3-0097
Tinch R (1995). The valuation of environmental externalities. Report for the Department of Transport,
London.
Traffic Design Group (2001): Guide to estimation and monitoring of traffic counting and traffic growth.
https://www.nzta.govt.nz/resources/research/reports/205/
Thrush MJ (1996). Assessing passing opportunities. Transit NZ research report 60.
https://www.nzta.govt.nz/resources/research/reports/60
Tomecki AB, K Yushenko and A Ashford (2016). Considering a cost–benefit analysis framework for
intelligent transport systems. NZ Transport Agency research report 584.
https://www.nzta.govt.nz/resources/research/reports/584
Transit NZ (2003). Finance and toll projects: implementation guide.
Transit NZ (1994). Guide to estimating AADT and traffic growth.
Transportation Research Board (1994). Highway capacity manual. Third edition.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 245
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
REFERENCES
Transportation Research Board (2006). Guidelines for analysis of investments in bicycle facilities.
NCHRP report 552.
https://books.google.co.nz/books?hl=en&lr=&id=FTtEy3UwVRoC&oi=fnd&pg=PA1&dq=NCHRP+report+5
52&ots=D9rM_hsljH&sig=6Ow3zo0pvF4iP9Ja31Aj51Zg4II#v=onepage&q=NCHRP%20report%20552&f=
false
Treasury (2015a). Guide to social cost benefit analysis. https://treasury.govt.nz/sites/default/files/2015-
07/cba-guide-jul15.pdf
Treasury (2015b). The New Zealand PPP model and policy: setting the scene: a guide for public sector
entities. https://treasury.govt.nz/sites/default/files/2015-10/ppp-public-model-and-policy-sep15.pdf
UK Department of Transport (1988). Calculation of road traffic noise. http://bailey.persona-pi.com/Public-
Inquiries/M4-Newport/C%20-%20Core%20Documents/14.%20Noise%20and%20Vibration/14.2.1%20-
%20Department%20of%20Transport%20and%20Welsh%20Office%20Calculation%20of%20Road%20Tr
affic%20Noise.%201988.pdf
UK Department of Transport (2019). TAG Unit M4: Forecasting and uncertainty.
https://assets.publishing.service.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_data/file/93887
8/tag-m4-forecasting-and-uncertainty.pdf
US Department of Transportation, Federal Highway Administration (2000). Toolbox for regional policy
analysis. https://www.fhwa.dot.gov/planning/processes/tools/toolbox/
Vanclay F (2003). International principles for social impact assessment. Impact Assessment and Project
Appraisal, 21:1. https://www.tandfonline.com/doi/pdf/10.3152/147154603781766491
Venables AJ (2016). Incorporating wider economic impacts within cost–benefit appraisal. OECD
International Transport Forum discussion paper 2016-05. https://www.itf-
oecd.org/sites/default/files/docs/incorporating-wider-economic-impacts-cba.pdf
Victoria Transport Policy Institute. Online TDM encyclopaedia. www.vtpi.org/tdm/tdm12.htm
Waka Kotahi NZ Transport Agency (2019a). Discount rate and analysis period. A technical paper
prepared for the Investment Decision-Making Framework Review.
https://www.nzta.govt.nz/assets/planning-and-investment/docs/investment-decision-making-framework-
review-discount-rate-november-2019.pdf
Waka Kotahi NZ Transport Agency (2019b). Estimating economic benefits from increased international
tourist activity. A technical paper prepared for the Investment Decision-Making Framework Review.
https://www.nzta.govt.nz/assets/planning-and-investment/docs/investment-decision-making-framework-
review-tourism-benefits-november-2019.pdf
Waka Kotahi NZ Transport Agency (2020a). Health and active modes impacts. A technical paper
prepared for the Investment Decision-Making Framework Review.
https://www.nzta.govt.nz/assets/resources/MBCM-technical-papers-and-reports/health-and-active-modes-
impacts-march-2020.pdf
Waka Kotahi NZ Transport Agency (2020b). Impact on urban amenity in pedestrian environments. A
technical paper prepared for the Investment Decision-Making Framework Review.
https://www.nzta.govt.nz/assets/resources/MBCM-technical-papers-and-reports/impact-on-urban-
amenity-in-pedestrian-environments-march-2020.pdf
Waka Kotahi NZ Transport Agency (2020c). Transformative transport projects (dynamic WEBS and land
use benefits and costs). A technical paper prepared for the Investment Decision-Making Framework
Review. https://www.nzta.govt.nz/assets/resources/MBCM-technical-papers-and-reports/transformative-
transport-projects-may-2020.pdf
Waka Kotahi NZ Transport Agency (2021). Economic valuation of greenhouse gas emissions.
https://www.nzta.govt.nz/assets/resources/MBCM-technical-papers-and-reports/Technical-report-
Economic-evaluation-of-GHG-emissions-FINAL.pdf
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 246
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
REFERENCES
Wallis IP (2004). Review of passenger transport demand elasticities. Transfund NZ research report 248.
https://www.nzta.govt.nz/resources/research/reports/248
Wallis I (2005). Implications of selected urban road tolling policies for New Zealand. Land Transport NZ
research report 270. https://www.nzta.govt.nz/resources/research/reports/270
Wallis IP (2013). Experience with the development of off-peak bus services. NZ Transport Agency
research report 487. https://www.nzta.govt.nz/resources/research/reports/487
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 247
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
APPENDIX 1: DEMAND ESTIMATION METHODS AND GUIDANCE > BROAD APPROACHES TO DEMAND ESTIMATION
APPENDICES
Appendix 1: Demand estimation methods and guidance
Chapter 2: Demand estimation and mode share, provides background and guidance on different
elements relating to travel demand estimation.
This appendix provides guidance on techniques, methods and considerations for developing demand
estimates. This includes estimating and forecasting facility use by specific modes, general techniques and
guidance on developing demand estimates and forecasts, guidance on traffic modelling forecasts, the
specific areas of elasticity techniques and values, and evaluating congested networks (using fixed and
variable matrix techniques).
This appendix also contains guidance on developing a benefit–cost ratio (BCR) after variable trip matrix
methodologies have been used, and suggested checks to validate the methodology applied.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 248
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
APPENDIX 1: DEMAND ESTIMATION METHODS AND GUIDANCE > DEMAND ESTIMATION METHODOLOGIES AND
CONSIDERATIONS
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 249
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
APPENDIX 1: DEMAND ESTIMATION METHODS AND GUIDANCE > DEMAND ESTIMATION METHODOLOGIES AND
CONSIDERATIONS
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 250
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
APPENDIX 1: DEMAND ESTIMATION METHODS AND GUIDANCE > DEMAND ESTIMATION METHODOLOGIES AND
CONSIDERATIONS
well as the time of day and day of the week. The peak period of traffic generation for the activity also
needs to be taken into account, as this will not necessarily coincide with the peak period of movement on
the adjacent road network. Together, these factors mean that some degree of engineering judgement is
required when forecasting the likely level of traffic generation for a new activity.
There are a range of sources that can be used to inform decisions on expected traffic generation rates.
These include but are not limited to:
• NZ Transport Agency research report 453: Trips and parking related to land use. (Douglas
Consulting Services and Abley Transportation Consultants 2011)
• Institute of Traffic Engineers, Trip generation manual
• Transport for New South Wales, Guide to traffic generating developments
• TRICS (Trip Rate Information Computer System, UK based) and TDB (Trips Database Bureau,
NZ Transport Group)
• New Zealand census data.
Where it is practical to do so, it is recommended that reference to recent surveys for similar activities and
locations are adopted for any assessment. The TRICS/TDB source includes the most recent information
for New Zealand.
Trip rate and generation considerations
Some care needs to be taken when applying trip rate and/or generation methodologies across a study
area to estimate future demands for a network. Trip rates may be estimated from driveway surveys – as
such across a network they may not account for trip chaining (travel involving multiple purposes and
multiple destinations) and pass-by trips (such as an A to B trip becomes two trips A to C, C to B and the
original A to B trip is removed). Because of these behaviours and factors, wide-spread application of trip
rate and/or generation methods for multiple land-use developments in a network may overestimate traffic
volumes.
In section 2.15, Sense checking forecasts includes recommendations for reporting key information. This
includes the total study area demand growth and per annum demand growth rates by time period and,
where appropriate, vehicle classification and travel mode. These are useful checks to confirm the
appropriateness of trip rate applications, particularly when applied to multiple land use activities across a
study area.
Trip distribution considerations
There are several approaches to developing trip distributions associated with trips generated by a specific
land use activity; for example:
• develop from nearby location, ideally with similar land use
• first principle analysis using geo-located data; for example, census journey-to-work or journey-to-
education data, electronic tracking data such as from Bluetooth sensors/mobile phones,
commercial transaction data, or similar
• potentially can be developed from travel volume information (for example, a series of traffic
counts), although this is noted as being unlikely to be robust as the specific activity information
may not be easily isolated from movements associated with other activities in the network and/or
it can be difficult to identify the actual desired origin and destinations in this form of data.
In section 2.15, Sense checking forecasts includes recommendations on checks and reporting associated
with trip distributions. This includes summaries by time period and potentially vehicle classification and
travel mode of sector-to-sector growth, trip length distributions, and flow difference plots and/or
geographic location growth figures.
Elasticities
As described in section 2.1: Demand estimation and mode share: Key concepts, in transport demand
estimation elasticities typically describe a percentage change associated with a demand response linked
or related to a change in the transport system or environment.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 251
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
APPENDIX 1: DEMAND ESTIMATION METHODS AND GUIDANCE > DEMAND ESTIMATION METHODOLOGIES AND
CONSIDERATIONS
Cross elasticities refer to the percentage change in the consumption of a good resulting from a price
change in another, related, good. For example, an increase in the cost of driving tends to reduce demand
for parking and increases the demand for public transport travel.
Transport elasticities tend to increase over time, as consumers have more opportunities to take prices
into account when making long-term decisions. For example, if consumers anticipate that the future cost
of private vehicle use will be low, they are more likely to choose a suburban home located where there is
more dependency on using a private vehicle. Alternatively, if they anticipate significant increases in
driving costs, they may place a greater premium on having alternatives to private vehicle use, such as
access to public transport and shops within convenient walking distance.
These long-term decisions, in turn, affect the options that are available. It may take many years for the full
effect of a price change to be felt.
Long-run travel demand elasticities are typically two to three times short-run elasticities.
Calculating the potential demand for a new or improved service or facility using elasticities will generally
be based on willingness-to-pay values (derived from a stated preference survey) combined with data on
current users, and existing and proposed user charges.
Section 4.4: Evaluation of public transport service activities and section 4.7: Evaluation of freight activities
contain elasticity and cross-elasticity values that may be used for public transport or freight services
respectively.
Nature of demand
The demand for a new or improved service or facility depends on a number of factors such as:
• the current or base average user charge
• the nature of the change in service
• existing users’ willingness to pay for the new or changed service/facility, and
• the responsiveness of demand to changes in user charges (the user charge elasticity) or another
journey attribute (for example, in vehicle or walking time).
Factors affecting price elasticities
Even if stated preference surveys have been specifically conducted for an activity, caution needs to be
exercised when extrapolating the elasticities. Surveys may only cover a small range of price and quality
variations and therefore the calculated elasticities may not be valid for extreme changes of price or
quality.
The following factors can also affect how much a change in prices impacts travel activity.
Type of price change
• Vehicle purchase prices and registration fees can affect the number and type of vehicles
purchased.
• Fuel prices, emission fees, and government rebates for sustainable vehicles affect the type of
vehicle used.
• A toll on a road may shift some trips to other routes and destinations.
• Congestion pricing may shift travel times, encourage people to change mode or destination, and
reduce the total number of trips that occur.
• Residential parking fees are likely to affect vehicle ownership. A time-variable parking fee can
affect when trips occur.
Type of trip and traveller
• Commuting trips tend to be less sensitive to changes in prices than shopping or recreational trips.
• Weekday trips may have very different elasticities than weekend trips.
• Urban peak period trips tend to be price insensitive because congestion already discourages
lower-value trips.
• Travellers with higher incomes tend to be less price sensitive than lower-income travellers.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 252
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
APPENDIX 1: DEMAND ESTIMATION METHODS AND GUIDANCE > DEMAND ESTIMATION METHODOLOGIES AND
CONSIDERATIONS
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 253
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
APPENDIX 1: DEMAND ESTIMATION METHODS AND GUIDANCE > DEMAND ESTIMATION METHODOLOGIES AND
CONSIDERATIONS
Depending on how the regional transport model is applied, it may produce either fixed or variable trip
matrices. Fixed trip matrices are where the demand for each mode, for a given time period and year, are
the same for the do-minimum and activity options. Variable trip matrices are where the demand is
different for the do-minimum and activity options. The default mode for almost all regional transport
models in New Zealand will be to produce variable trip matrices. Changes to the demand, and whether
each change will require a variable or fixed trip matrix benefit procedure, are shown in Table A2. More
background on these issues is provided in section 2.13: Fixed trip matrix and variable trip matrix
assessments.
Table A2: Fixed or variable trip matrices from a regional transport model
Changes Variable trip matrix? Fixed trip matrix?
Change in total number of trips produced (pure induced Yes
traffic)?
Change in mode choice? Yes
Change in destination choice (distribution)? Yes
Change in macro time choice? Yes
Change in route choice? No
There may be situations where a fixed trip matrix approach is adopted using a regional transport model.
In this case, a demand is estimated, and the same demand is assigned to both the do-minimum and
activity. It is more conservative to estimate this demand using the do-minimum, and then assign it to the
activity. If the activity is used to estimate the demand, and this demand is assigned to the do-minimum,
there is a higher likelihood that the do-minimum may be unrealistically congested and as a result,
inappropriately high benefits are calculated.
Project models fed by regional models
As described in section 2.10 regional models are relatively prevalent in New Zealand and, as such, it is
common for project models to be developed with links to a regional model. Project models with these
links/systems are available in many of New Zealand’s major urban areas and regional centres. The
analyst should check the availability and suitability of any existing project models for a specific economic
assessment.
For certain assessments (for example, single-stage and detailed business cases) it is common to develop
a specific project model for the purpose of analysing the economic benefits of a certain activity. A model
of this nature is also likely to be used for other components of the assessment, such as option testing,
informing the design, and providing a variety of technical and detailed information to inform the
assessment.
If a regional model (or regional modelling system/structure) is available, then it would be generally be
expected to be used to inform demand estimates (for example, base-year travel patterns and future-year
forecast growth and travel changes) in any project modelling carried out in the region and in the example
of a project model developed for a specific assessment.
Rarely, if ever, will it be appropriate to use the regional future-year origin–destination (OD) demand
directly within a project model. This is because in most cases the development of the project model will
include refinement and adjustment to OD demand inputs inherited from a regional model, and these
refinements/adjustments should be carried through in some manner to the future-year project model
demands. There are a number of methods for developing growth forecasts in a project model which
account for this, several are described below.
In the descriptions below, RM is regional model and PM is project model.
• OD additive growth method: the difference between the regional model base year (or closest
forecast year to the project model base year) and regional model forecast year is added to the
project model base year for each OD value. Where the base years are different, often a linear
growth rate is assumed between the base and future years. For example, for a regional model
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 254
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
APPENDIX 1: DEMAND ESTIMATION METHODS AND GUIDANCE > DEMAND ESTIMATION METHODOLOGIES AND
CONSIDERATIONS
base year of 2018 and a future year of 2028, 8/10ths of the growth is added to the project model
2020 base year to create the project model 2028 forecast.
The possibility of this resulting in a negative value on an OD volume needs to be considered and
accounted for. One simple approach is to use the multiplicative method (described below) as a
substitute in any OD cells that result in negative values from the additive calculation. That is, if
the additive growth method results in negative values, multiply the project model OD base volume
by the percentage reduction predicted through the regional model.
An additive method is often a straightforward and low-risk approach. It is simple to review and
check, and in particular, reflects changing future travel patterns across the study area predicted
by the regional model (for example, larger levels of growth in one specific geographic area due to
greenfield land use development).
One weakness of the additive method is that it disconnects the growth change from an
associated trip rate basis.
• OD multiplicative growth method: the regional model future-year OD value is divided by the
regional model base-year OD value producing a factor/percentage growth which is applied to the
project model base year OD value. In the same manner as the additive method, if the project
model and regional model base years are different a proportion of the regional model future-year
growth is applied. For OD cells where there are zero trips in the regional model base year and
trips in the regional model future year, the additive approach will need to be used.
Generally, more care is required with this approach than the additive method. In particular, large
factor increases can be applied to high project model OD values resulting in inappropriately high
project model future-year OD values.
• OD combined additive and multiplicative growth method: combining the additive and
multiplicative methods is possible; for example, averaging the additive and multiplicative growth
estimates or a weighted average – purely as an illustrative example: 75% additive growth and
25% multiplicative growth.
• More complex methods, including trip-end approaches: other growth calculations are
possible, examples include:
o Furnessing (Furness iterative balancing) the predicted regional model trip end (matrix
row and column totals) growth with the row/column distribution in the base year OD
matrix
o applying the row or column growth only, and using the project model base year OD
distribution to distribute the trip growth through the matrix.
These approaches may be considered when there is an understood, or established, notable strength in
the distribution in the project model base year OD demand (for example, if the development of the project
model and base year OD demand made more extensive use of OD surveys and/or additional OD-style
observed data) and an understood or clear local weakness in the regional model distribution.
In all cases, as outlined Project/assignment transport demand forecast checks and reporting, various
checks and reporting would be anticipated in the development of growth forecasts for a project model.
Checking the sector-to-sector growth distribution (comparing the regional model to the project model)
would be particularly important for a more complex method, such as growth Furnessing.
Walking and cycling demand estimation
Procedures for estimating bicycle demands can be found in section 4.2. Table 52 may be used for
estimating the demands of a new cycle facility.
In addition, some regional transport models will estimate bicycle and walking demands and may be
appropriate to estimate active mode facility use. The regional transport models forecast aggregate
demand and may be too coarse for bicycle or pedestrian facility assessment. Therefore more detail is
provided in relation to walking and cycling in these sections than other aspects such as public transport,
where regional models may be more robust.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 255
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
APPENDIX 1: DEMAND ESTIMATION METHODS AND GUIDANCE > METHODS TO CALCULATE/ADJUST DEMAND IN
TRANSPORT MODELS
Several New Zealand urban centres have specific “cycle models”. If assessing a new facility, or a
significant upgrade to an existing facility, the suitability, ability and appropriateness of these tools to
provide cycle volume estimates for an assessment should be checked.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 256
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
APPENDIX 1: DEMAND ESTIMATION METHODS AND GUIDANCE > METHODS TO CALCULATE/ADJUST DEMAND IN
TRANSPORT MODELS
Level of diversion
The level of diversion is used for calculating user benefits for new and existing pedestrians/cyclists,
assuming the main change is a reduction/transfer from private vehicle, and hence road traffic reduction
benefits. Benefits arising from changing travel mode from private vehicle to PT are also considered,
depending on the PT measures included in the travel plan. Care should be taken to ensure that any
assumptions are compatible with the economic evaluation requirements.
When conducting initial evaluations for workplace and school travel plans the diversion rate should be
selected based on the analyst’s knowledge of the organisations involved and the area. For the final
evaluation for implementation funding the diversion rate will be based on the actual features of the
completed plan.
Workplace travel plans
There are two sets of diversion rates for workplace travel plans:
• standard – where no public transport improvements are proposed
• alternative – where there are proposed public transport improvements.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 257
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
APPENDIX 1: DEMAND ESTIMATION METHODS AND GUIDANCE > METHODS TO CALCULATE/ADJUST DEMAND IN
TRANSPORT MODELS
Within these two sets of diversion rates, a scoring system is used to select the appropriate profile for a
given workplace travel plan. The score, out of six, is assigned based on the responses to the questions in
Table A4.
Table A5: Scoring system for workplace travel plan diversion rates
Strategies for managing parking demand include activities such as parking charges, reduced supply of
parking spaces, parking ‘cash-out’ schemes, etc. Use the total score from above in Table A4. First, obtain
the reduction in the target population of car drivers assigned across the other modes of transport.
The standard diversion rate values are applicable in most situations where no significant public transport
measures are included in the workplace travel plan. The alternative ‘with public transport service
improvements’ diversion rate values are applicable when significant public transport service
improvements (including company provided transport), subsidy schemes, or other similar measures
(covered by the last two questions in Table A4) are part of the workplace travel plan.
School travel plans
There are two default diversion rate profiles for schools, one for primary and another for intermediate and
secondary schools. Assign the change in car passengers across public transport, cycling and walking.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 258
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
APPENDIX 1: DEMAND ESTIMATION METHODS AND GUIDANCE > METHODS TO CALCULATE/ADJUST DEMAND IN
TRANSPORT MODELS
Table A9: Steps to apply growth constraint to the do-minimum/activity trip matrix
Step Action
1 Determine whether to consider peak spreading (Table A67). If so, apply peak spreading
to modify the matrix and peak period.
If the matrix results in a realistic assignment to the do-minimum network, no further
capping need be considered. Otherwise go to step 2.
2 Select an appropriate method to cap the matrix:
Selected method Go to
Matrix scaling Applying the matrix scaling method
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 259
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
APPENDIX 1: DEMAND ESTIMATION METHODS AND GUIDANCE > METHODS TO CALCULATE/ADJUST DEMAND IN
TRANSPORT MODELS
Peak spreading and matrix scaling growth constraint techniques can be applied to the do-minimum and/or
the activity demand matrices to address an imbalance between supply and demand and produce specific
and varied demands. Additional analysis is likely to be required if different adjustments are applied to the
do-minimum and activity option, and advice on this is provided in the relevant sections.
Applying peak spreading
Peak spreading procedures may be used to spread traffic from the busiest part of the peak period to the
peak shoulders. Peak spreading is also called ‘micro time of day choice’. It is distinct from ‘macro time of
day choice’ where trips shift from a peak (morning or evening) to the interpeak or off peak due to
congestion.
Micro time of day choice methods may also be considered in assessing the activity, particularly in
situations where the activity enables destinations to be reached distinctly more quickly. This can result in
a peak contraction, and not accounting for this may misrepresent the travel time savings between the do-
minimum and the activity.
The procedure below is concentrated towards using peak spreading to reduce congestion in the do-
minimum.
Procedure
There are various existing procedures to calculate peak spreading. References include:
• Design manual for roads and bridges, Volume 12, Section 2, Part 1, Appendix F, ‘The application
of peak spreading’ (Highways England 1996)
• a UK Government-funded project that looked at demand and assignment modelling with a focus
on departure time choice resulting in a model called HADES (heterogeneous arrival and
departure times based on equilibrium scheduling theory)
• ‘NZMUGs micro time-of-day choice research’ (New Zealand Modelling User Group 2017).
Broadly there are two styles of transport modelling that effect the application of peak-spreading:
• Models where the total OD demand is considered over a longer peak period (at least two hours,
but often three to four hours) and the movement of traffic through these periods is controlled with
‘profiles’. Typically a number of profiles are developed and specified, often by vehicle
classification, in smaller time intervals (usually 5 to 15-minute increments). Microsimulation is one
example.
• Models where the OD demand is reflected in ‘peak periods’, such as peak one-hour or peak two-
hour OD matrices. Static assignment is one example.
For models where OD demand is profiled in shorter intervals across longer periods, the NZMUGs
research is notable as it demonstrates valid application of a micro time-of-day methodology in the New
Zealand context against observed data. Section 9.4 of the NZMUGs research provides a set of practical
considerations for applying peak spreading methods.
As a general guide, the following points should be kept in mind if peak spreading is applied to peak period
models:
• Decide whether to apply peak spreading uniformly or only to specific parts of the trip matrix. This
decision will depend on the extent and location of congestion in the network, and how realistic it
is for specific movements through the network to respond to congestion by adjusting their
departure times.
• Unless evidence suggests otherwise, it is recommended that the transfer of trips from the peak to
interpeak or off-peak periods be not more than 10% of the total peak period traffic, although this
will depend on the length of the time periods modelled, with shorter periods (for example, one
hour) likely to have greater volumes changing their travel times due to congestion.
• If appropriate, the traffic profile during the peak period may be adjusted, but it is advisable that
the reduction of the peak traffic intensity be no more than 10% unless evidence or justification
can be provided.
• It is recommended that information on local traffic profiles and trends in traffic growth for different
time periods, such as peak shoulder and business periods, be sought to support assumptions.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 260
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
APPENDIX 1: DEMAND ESTIMATION METHODS AND GUIDANCE > METHODS TO CALCULATE/ADJUST DEMAND IN
TRANSPORT MODELS
• It is preferable to apply the same consistent peak spreading adjustment to the demands applied
to both the do-minimum and activity. If different adjustments are warranted, then evidence and
justification should be reported. Checks should be carried out with the do-minimum peak period
adjustment, or profile, applied to both the do-minimum and the activity, and then the converse
(the activity peak period profile applied to both the do-minimum and activity). The resulting
benefits for each test should be compared to confirm the peak period adjustment is not
inappropriately inflating project benefits.
• If the peak spreading adjustment produces a change in total demand across the entire modelled
period for either the do-minimum or the activity, then variable trip matrix calculations will be
required (see Variable trip matrices). This will occur if the peak shoulders are not included in the
modelled period.
Applying the matrix scaling method
Matrix scaling procedures may be used to constrain growth in the trip matrix. If congestion is widespread,
the entire matrix may be scaled or, if congestion is confined to a particular area, only the corresponding
sections of the matrix need be scaled.
The final levels of congestion in the network due to the capped matrix should be sensible. When capping
the matrix with this procedure, only cap the matrix as much as needed. Excess capping is likely to reduce
computed project benefits unnecessarily.
Procedure
Follow the steps below to apply matrix scaling.
This should be applied consistently to the do-minimum and the activity such that the demand matrix is the
same in order for a fixed trip matrix technique to be appropriate. Varying the matrix scaling between the
do-minimum and activity will require a variable trip matrix technique described in Variable trip matrices. If
different scaling is applied to the do-minimum and activity demands, justification and evidence will be
required and must be reported.
Applying the incremental matrix capping method
The incremental matrix capping method may be used to constrain growth in selected cells of the matrix.
This method is also known as the ‘incremental loading’ method and should not be confused with
incremental assignment techniques.
Procedure
In the incremental matrix capping method, choose a series of forecast year matrices and assign these to
the do-minimum network in chronological order. Once an assignment results in average travel speeds
dropping below acceptable limits for a matrix cell (or group of cells), further traffic growth is prevented in
the affected cells as later matrices are applied.
This process effectively restricts the growth rate in selected matrix cells to levels corresponding to some
earlier year (at which an acceptably realistic traffic assignment could be obtained).
Follow the steps below to apply incremental matrix capping.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 261
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
APPENDIX 1: DEMAND ESTIMATION METHODS AND GUIDANCE > METHODS TO CALCULATE/ADJUST DEMAND IN
TRANSPORT MODELS
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 262
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
APPENDIX 1: DEMAND ESTIMATION METHODS AND GUIDANCE > METHODS TO CALCULATE/ADJUST DEMAND IN
TRANSPORT MODELS
• an elasticity formulation that expresses the necessary adjustment to the trip matrix as a result of
cost changes.
The pivot matrix and network will commonly be those for the base year, but it would be equally
appropriate to use the project opening year (if the network was expected to be relatively uncongested at
that time) as a pivot for forecasting trip matrices for later years in the project’s economic life.
Follow the steps below to apply elasticity methods.
As with all approaches to demand forecasting, the final matrix produced by the elasticity formulation must
reasonably represent the future year demand. It may be appropriate to exclude some matrix cells from
the elasticity adjustments – for example, those that exhibit negative growth (generally it is undesirable to
have cases where traffic volumes between an origin and destination pair decrease between successive
forecast years), unreasonably high growth or those that represent external trips.
Elasticities
Elasticities used with an elasticity method should reflect the sensitivity of demand to the user’s perceived
costs of travel, that is as used in the demand modelling process (not the resource costs, which typically
will be different – refer to Table A17).
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 263
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
APPENDIX 1: DEMAND ESTIMATION METHODS AND GUIDANCE > METHODS TO CALCULATE/ADJUST DEMAND IN
TRANSPORT MODELS
The elasticities should also be consistent with the basis on which the user costs are expressed. It is
preferable that user costs and elasticities are expressed in terms of generalised costs (a combination of
time costs and money costs), rather than in terms of time or money alone (but see below). The
generalised cost approach allows demand to respond to both time and money changes and is found to
give more consistent results over a range of situations.
The application of elasticity methods depends on the transport model being able to model travel costs
realistically, and elasticities consistent with these travel costs being able to be estimated. In general,
elasticities specific to a study area will not be available and values from other locations need to be used.
Table A14 provides a set of default long-run generalised cost elasticity values for use in New Zealand
(principally urban) situations.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 264
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
APPENDIX 1: DEMAND ESTIMATION METHODS AND GUIDANCE > METHODS TO CALCULATE/ADJUST DEMAND IN
TRANSPORT MODELS
Transport modelling checks worksheet. For a fixed trip matrix technique to be appropriate, the demands
must also be the same for the do-minimum and the activity.
Variable trip matrices
This section relates to cases where the demand is different in the do-minimum and activity/option for a
given forecast year. Where the activity introduces more capacity for a particular mode, the demand for
that mode with the activity will be higher than for the do-minimum. This is referred to as variable trip
matrices (VTM), that is, the demand varies between the do-minimum and the activity.
There are specific processes to calculate economic benefits where there are variable trip matrices, which
is described within this section.
Variable trip matrix methods are to be used for all complex improvements, unless:
• it can be demonstrated that:
o the congestion level expected throughout the analysis period in the do-minimum or option
will not be substantial, and
o the peak period public transport mode share changes (in the activity compared with the
do-minimum) by less than 5% based on total travel mode share -this will depend on
location and current mode shares, or
• preliminary evaluation shows that the fixed trip matrix benefits are unlikely to differ by more than
10% from those from a variable trip matrix approach, or
• Waka Kotahi approves the use of a fixed trip matrix approach for other reasons.
If the volume change between the do-minimum and activity increases typical peak period travel times by
more than 10%, then this is an indicator that variable trip matrix techniques may be required.
Variable matrix methods provide estimates of the effects of an activity on travel patterns (that is, the
difference between the do-minimum and option matrices) and on the benefits of the activity.
Procedure
Three variable matrix methods based on analytical techniques are recommended. These are:
• elasticity methods
• application of growth constraint techniques reducing the demand in the do-minimum and/or the
activity to produce equilibrium of supply and demand
• demand response models.
For demand response modelling approaches, where the source of data is from a regional transport
model, there may be the possibility that the regional transport model will not have sufficient sensitivity to
measure the impact on the trip matrix of a single scheme (unless the single scheme is significant in
nature), and the use of such models will therefore generally not generate a demand response that is
considered realistic. In examples where the scheme is considered significant enough to generate a
demand response, elasticity methods can be used to supplement the regional transport model.
Whatever method is applied, its results should be verified by comparison with an FTM evaluation based
on the do-minimum trip matrix.
Having decided that congestion will be significant in both the do-minimum and project option for a
forecast year, follow the steps below to apply variable matrix methods. If a variable trip matrix model (for
example, a regional transport model or a project model with demand response) is available, it should be
used.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 265
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
APPENDIX 1: DEMAND ESTIMATION METHODS AND GUIDANCE > METHODS TO CALCULATE/ADJUST DEMAND IN
TRANSPORT MODELS
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 266
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
APPENDIX 1: DEMAND ESTIMATION METHODS AND GUIDANCE > METHODS TO CALCULATE/ADJUST DEMAND IN
TRANSPORT MODELS
Refer also to Applying fixed trip matrix with elasticity methods for a discussion of suggested elasticities.
Method A procedure
For method A, the processes described in Table A13 are applied separately but consistently for the do-
minimum and activity option matrices. For example, if the method is pivoted on the base year matrices,
1
then steps 1–6 in Table A13 are applied first using the do-minimum network (in step 2 for 𝑐𝑖𝑗 and
1
subsequent steps) and then repeated using the activity option network (in step 2 for 𝑐𝑖𝑗 and subsequent
steps).
Method B procedure
Automated application of elasticity methods (for example, some traffic modelling software has built-in
capabilities such as ‘elastic assignment’ methods) may be used as an alternative to the manual method
given above.
For method B, the do-minimum matrix may be determined using any of the fixed trip matrix techniques in
Table A9.
As for FTM elasticity methods, the final matrix produced by the elasticity formulation (in either method A
or B) should be a reasonable representation of demand. It may be appropriate to exclude some matrix
cells from the elasticity adjustments – for example, those that exhibit negative growth, unreasonably high
growth or those that represent external trips. The convergence requirements for VTM methods are,
however, significantly more onerous: the stability and convergence requirements of the combined
VTM/assignment procedures are the same as for the simpler FTM assignment-only procedures (see the
Transport modelling checks worksheet, Base year assignment validation).
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 267
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
APPENDIX 1: DEMAND ESTIMATION METHODS AND GUIDANCE > METHODS TO CALCULATE/ADJUST DEMAND IN
TRANSPORT MODELS
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 268
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
APPENDIX 1: DEMAND ESTIMATION METHODS AND GUIDANCE > METHODS TO CALCULATE/ADJUST DEMAND IN
TRANSPORT MODELS
The resulting formula for the net project benefit is computed for each cell of the matrix individually (for a
given time period) and is:
1
Benefit = (𝑇 + 𝑇𝐷𝑀 ) × (𝑈𝐷𝑀 − 𝑈𝑂𝑃𝑇 ) + 𝑇𝑂𝑃𝑇 (𝑈𝑂𝑃𝑇 − 𝑅𝑂𝑃𝑇 ) − 𝑇𝐷𝑀 (𝑈𝐷𝑀 − 𝑅𝐷𝑀 )
2 𝑂𝑃𝑇
1
Benefit = (𝑅𝐷𝑀 𝑇𝐷𝑀 − 𝑅𝑂𝑃𝑇 𝑇𝑂𝑃𝑇 ) + (𝑈 + 𝑈𝑂𝑃𝑇 ) × (𝑇𝑂𝑃𝑇 − 𝑇𝐷𝑀 )
2 𝐷𝑀
Table A17: Guidelines for estimating user time and vehicle operating costs
Cost component Obtain resource costs from … To derive the user cost …
Value of time Table 13, Table 14, Table 15 and User cost = resource cost
(working) Table 16
Value of time (non- Table 13, Table 14, Table 15 and User cost = resource cost × 1.15
working) Table 16
Vehicle operating cost (in urban networks):
Tables and graphs Table A79 to Table A88 User cost = resource cost × 1.2
of cost by average
speed and gradient
Tables and graphs Table 25, Table A89, Table A90 and User cost = resource cost × 1.125
of additional costs Table A91
for roughness
Tables of fuel costs Table A92, Table A93, Table A94 and User cost = resource cost × 2.0
due to bottleneck Table A95
delay
Graphs of Table A96 to Table A115 User cost = resource cost × 1.9
additional costs for
speed change
cycles
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 269
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
APPENDIX 1: DEMAND ESTIMATION METHODS AND GUIDANCE > METHODS TO CALCULATE/ADJUST DEMAND IN
TRANSPORT MODELS
Matrix-based computation
For a variable matrix evaluation, adopt either of the following two methods to accumulate the net benefits
of project options:
1. a matrix-based analysis, where an average cost is computed for each origin–destination pair, or
2. a link-based analysis, where costs are computed separately for each link (or groups of links).
The first of these approaches enables benefits to be identified for particular travel movements, which may
be useful in identifying gainers and losers. The matrix-based analysis must be used where the model
includes time spent waiting queueing inside zones (for example, microsimulation models) and such
models must be run so that all trips complete. This is so that any differences in trip volumes and trip travel
times between the do-minimum and activity are not missed due to time spent waiting in the zone. This
applies for both FTM and VTM.
The second approach has the advantage that it allows benefits to be estimated for a region in the network
that is relatively self-contained, which can be useful for planning purposes.
Most network demand modelling software will allow benefits to be derived on a matrix (origin–destination)
basis without the need for the additional model runs needed for the second approach.
Create the matrices of trips and costs required to compute the benefits as itemised in Table A18.
Using matrix manipulations, compute the benefit matrix (for a single time period).
For a road activity with no tolls or a public transport activity with no fares, the formula for estimating net
benefits for any origin – destination (ij) pair will be:
𝐷𝑀 𝐷𝑀 𝑂𝑃𝑇 𝑂𝑃𝑇
1 𝐷𝑀
𝐵𝑖𝑗 = (𝑅𝑖𝑗 𝑇𝑖𝑗 − 𝑅𝑖𝑗 𝑇𝑖𝑗 ) + (𝑈 + 𝑈𝑖𝑗𝑂𝑃𝑇 ) × (𝑇𝑖𝑗𝑂𝑃𝑇 − 𝑇𝑖𝑗𝐷𝑀 )
2 𝑖𝑗
The total project benefit B is then given by the matrix total summed over all matrix cells.
In the case of public transport where a fare is paid by users, the net benefit for each ij pair will be:
Bij = [1/2(TDM + TOPT) (UDM - UOPT)] (perceived user benefits)
+ [(TDM PTRDM - TOPT PTROPT)] (change in public transport supply resource cost)
+ [(TOPT (OUOPT - OROPT) - TDM (OUDM - ORDM)] (change in other resource costs)
+ [TOPT FOPT - TDM FDM] (fare resource correction)
Where, for each ij pair:
T is the number of trips
U is the perceived cost/trip
F is the fare/trip (as included in the perceived cost of travel)
OU is the other perceived user cost/trip (eg generalised cost of travel time)
PTR is the resource cost of providing public transport/trip
OR is the other resource travel costs (eg travel time and environment)/trip.
Subscripts:
DM = do-minimum, OPT = option, U = F + OU, and R = PTR + OR
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 270
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
APPENDIX 1: DEMAND ESTIMATION METHODS AND GUIDANCE > METHODS TO CALCULATE/ADJUST DEMAND IN
TRANSPORT MODELS
Perceived user benefits are calculated on an origin–destination basis (ie for each ij pair in the transport
matrix), with the total perceived user benefit being the sum of perceived benefits for all ij pairs. Other
benefit components can be calculated on a network basis. Calculation of the change in public transport
supply resource costs will generally be based on changes in the service quantity provided across a
network between the do-minimum and option, rather than on a cost per passenger trip. Usually the
change in public transport supply costs will be treated as a cost, in which case the item should be
removed from the formula above.
The equivalent formula applies in road tolling activity, where tolls are part of the perceived cost of travel,
with the value of F being the toll rather than the public transport fare. In addition to tolls, the value of U
includes the perceived value of travel time and the motorists’ perceived vehicle operating costs when
making travel decisions. The equivalent to PTR will be the direct resource cost of vehicle use, and the OR
counterpart will be the resource value of travel time, environmental and social externalities of vehicle use.
Again, the total change in perceived user benefits will be the sum of the benefit for each ij pair. Other
impacts can be estimated drawing on aggregate resources used in the network (eg total vehicle – km and
person – hours of travel) and total toll revenue. Unlike changes in public transport supply resource cost,
changes in the resource cost of vehicle use are treated as a benefit and so should be included as part of
the benefit formula.
Link-based computation
Link-based computation of activity benefits is possible, with the change in resource costs determined by
calculating resource costs multiplied by trips summed over the network (‘change in resource costs’), with
the component ‘adjustment for variable trip matrix’ calculated based on network statistics that require
some extra analysis as detailed below.
First, the extra term can be expanded to four terms to read:
1
(𝑈𝑂𝑃𝑇 𝑇𝑂𝑃𝑇 − 𝑈𝐷𝑀 𝑇𝐷𝑀 + 𝑈𝐷𝑀 𝑇𝑂𝑃𝑇 − 𝑈𝑂𝑃𝑇 𝑇𝐷𝑀 )
2
I II III IV
where each of these four terms (I–IV) may be computed from network statistics.
• I: This is the total user cost for the option network, and may be calculated in the same manner as
the resource costs but using the cost weights in Table A17.
• II: This is the total user cost for the do-minimum network, and may be calculated in the same
manner as the resource costs but using the cost weights in Table A17.
Terms III and IV require a particular network/assignment procedure called a ‘crossload’.
• III: This term uses the do-minimum network, but the user costs must be weighted by the trips in
the activity option matrix; this is achieved by loading the activity option matrix on the do-minimum
network keeping the paths and link speeds unchanged (that is, there are no speed or path-
building iterations and the paths and speeds are those determined from assigning the do-
minimum matrix); network statistics are then extracted and processed using standard techniques.
• IV: This term uses the activity option network, but the user costs must be weighted by the trips in
the do-minimum matrix; this is achieved by loading the do-minimum matrix on the activity option
network keeping the paths and speeds unchanged; network statistics are then extracted and
processed using standard techniques.
For the computation of variable matrix benefits using link-based evaluation, the assignment software must
be able to handle ‘crossloading’.
Having summed items I–IV and halved the result to obtain the ‘adjustment for variable trip matrix’, then
add the change in resource costs, (𝑅𝐷𝑀 𝑇𝐷𝑀 − 𝑅𝑂𝑃𝑇 𝑇𝑂𝑃𝑇 ) as described above. The result should be
recorded as VOC savings. Note that for use with this procedure, the road user surplus and resource cost
formulas should be applied to travel time and vehicle operating costs only (other benefits are assumed to
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 271
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
APPENDIX 1: DEMAND ESTIMATION METHODS AND GUIDANCE > METHODS TO CALCULATE/ADJUST DEMAND IN
TRANSPORT MODELS
be unaffected by road user surplus issues). The remaining resource costs associated with crashes and
vehicle emissions will be recorded separately as Crash cost savings and Vehicle emission reductions.
Checking fixed or variable trip matrices
These checks are related to the procedures in Determining traffic volumes and may be used to check the
appropriateness of fixed trip matrix adjustments or variable trip matrix calculations for dealing with
suppressed and induced traffic, as well as changes in destination, modal, or macro time period choice.
The checks supplement the general model validation guidelines given in the Transport modelling checks
worksheet.
Suggested checks
Suggested checks include:
Table A19: Suggested checks for fixed and variable trip matrix calculations/adjustments
Method used Suggested information
The capacity of the do-minimum Demonstration that the capital cost of do-minimum
network was upgraded improvements is less than 10–15% of the project option cost.
Indication of adequate capacity (see below).
A growth suppression technique was Indication of adequate capacity (see below).
used (eg matrix scaling, incremental
matrix capping, shadow network, Details on the size and location of the suppressed travel.
elasticity method) Evidence, where feasible, of network performance before and
after growth suppression.
Details of the methodology applied.
Peak spreading was used Evidence of current variations in peak proportions:
• within the study area, in the base year and historically
• between cities or across New Zealand.
Based on this evidence, an indication that current traffic
profiles in the study area are more peaked than in other
locations or during other time periods.
Forecasts of a decline in peak period speeds relative to the
interpeak (because peak spreading is more likely to occur
when peak speeds deteriorate faster than interpeak speeds).
Alternatively, for models that cover longer time periods (more
than one hour) and predict behaviour for small time
increments, comparison of speeds at congested times
compared with uncongested where the peak spreading is to be
applied.
A variable matrix technique was used Indication of adequate capacity.
(eg, elasticity method on both the do-
minimum and activity option or a Differences between the do-minimum and activity option
demand response model was matrices.
applied) Evidence of the convergence of the method (ie stable
estimates of costs and matrices), or other evidence to justify
reliance on forecasts (see Transport modelling checks, Base
year assignment validation).
Details of the methodology applied.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 272
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
APPENDIX 1: DEMAND ESTIMATION METHODS AND GUIDANCE > METHODS TO CALCULATE/ADJUST DEMAND IN
TRANSPORT MODELS
these effects may be ignored where reasonable. For models that gridlock and will not produce viable
outputs, growth constraint techniques (peak spreading or matrix scaling) will need to be applied to
estimate benefits.
* Level of service (LOS) F is when forced or breakdown flow occurs or has reached a point that most
users would consider unsatisfactory. At LOS F, the amount of traffic trying to pass a point exceeds that
which can pass it. Queuing, delays and flow breakdown occur at these flow levels (Source: Guide to
traffic management part 3 (Austroads 2020)).
Back to 3.6 Impact on network productivity and utilisation: Travel time estimation procedures >>
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 273
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 274
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 275
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 276
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
equivalent five-year history. If the crashes in this equivalent five-year period meet the criterion above,
then method A may be used.
Where a site does not meet these minimum requirements, then method C (the weighted procedure)
should generally be used. Method C still gives some consideration to the historical crash record but this is
combined with a prediction from rate or crash prediction model which has been developed for similar
sites.
An issue arises when there are no suitable crash rates or crash prediction models available to use
method C. In such circumstances there needs to be a discussion with Waka Kotahi, who may agree to
method A being used even though the threshold for crash numbers have not been meet. A primary
consideration in this situation is whether a recognised crash investigation specialist considers that the site
has significant safety deficiency (eg high-crash-risk sites) and therefore needs to be improved.
Fundamental change
When there is a fundamental change along a route or at a site, method B is generally used for analysis of
the option, while method C or A can be used for the do-minimum depending on the number of crashes
that have occurred at the site.
Where there is a fundamental change at a site but no crash rates or crash prediction models are available
for the do-minimum, method A may be used (subject to Waka Kotahi approval) for the do-minimum. While
method B is used for the option cases, providing that models are available. Refer to Definitions for more
information on a fundamental change.
Availability of crash rates and models
Details on the available crash rates and crash prediction models are found in the Crash estimation
compendium. Crash rates and crash prediction models, other than those specified in this compendium,
may be used if the robustness of these rates or models can be demonstrated to Waka Kotahi or their
nominated peer reviewer.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 277
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Method A overview
Crash-by-crash analysis is based on the crash history of the site and is dependent on the number of
reported crashes. The analysis uses the individual crash severity (see Definitions) categories (fatal,
serious, minor, non-injury) and these can be further disaggregated by movement category and/or type of
vehicle involved.
In the first stage of the analysis, using the Crash cost savings worksheet in the full procedures, the do-
minimum total estimated number of crashes per annum is calculated. Costs are assigned using the crash
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 278
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
costs from Table A28 to Table A31 for 50km/h speed limit areas and from Table A32 to Table A35 for
100km/h speed limit areas.
The number of crashes predicted for a project option is determined from an expected reduction in the do-
minimum crash numbers, based on guidance provided in the Crash estimation compendium. The forecast
percentage of crash reductions for the project option can be applied either globally or varied for each
crash type and severity (eg fatal, serious, minor and non-injury).
Costs are taken from Table A29 to Table A35, as appropriate to the site. Where the mean speed of traffic
for the do-minimum and/or options differs from that provided in the tables, an adjustment should be made
to the costs using the formula found in Adjusting crash costs to reflect mean speeds.
Changes in crash severity
Options, such as crash barriers, in some cases can reduce the crash severity at a site. In this situation
different crash reductions are applied to each historical crash depending on type and severity (eg fatal,
serious, minor and non-injury).
Use of local crash data
Waka Kotahi and local authorities have set up systems that involve the collection of local contact crash
data (also called ‘contractor reported’ or ‘unreported to police’ crashes) from contractors, local residents
and network management personnel. The quality of this data varies and caution should be taken when
using it in crash analysis.
Local contact crash data can be used in a crash-by-crash analysis (method A) where the data is
supported by sufficient evidence to be audited and there is reasoned justification provided as to why it
should be used to supplement information from CAS. Evidence might include a second independent
report of the crash, confirmation of crashes by the local police or by local network contractors or
consultants.
If local contact crash information is used for an analysis then under-reporting factors must not be
included in the calculations of injury or non-injury crash costs.
Redistribution of fatal and serious crash costs
The difference between occurrences of a fatal or serious crash at a site is influenced by random chance.
The severity of a crash can be influenced by various factors, including the roadside environment and the
location of major hazards like large trees and power poles. Given fatal crashes are rare events that have
a high cost, fatal and serious crashes are redistributed in accordance with the fatal to serious ratios in
Table A23, Table A24 and Table A25 for each crash type. This method applies for up to two fatal crashes
and unlimited serious crashes at each site. The exception is when three or more fatal crashes occur at a
site where the crash costs do not need to be redistributed at the site.
Vehicle involvement
In assigning costs to crashes using method A, crashes are classified by ‘vehicle involvement’ according to
the highest ranked ‘vehicle’ involved in a crash (refer to Definitions for further details).
Adjustment for under-reporting
Only a proportion of non-fatal crashes that occur are recorded on TCR and in CAS. This is referred to as
under-reporting. It is generally assumed that all fatal crashes are reported.
To counteract the effect of under-reporting when using method A, factors are applied to reported crash
numbers (TCR numbers) to estimate the total number of crashes that actually occur. Table A26 provides
factors for converting from reported injury to total injury crashes, while Table A27 provides factors for
converting from reported non-injury to total non-injury crashes.
If local contact crash information has been used, then under-reporting factors must not be included in the
calculations of injury or non-injury crash costs.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 279
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Method B overview
Method B crash rate analysis involves determining a typical crash rate (refer to Definitions) per annum as
the basis for calculating the crash cost savings for a project. Typical crash rates have been calculated
using either a crash rate or crash prediction model provided in the Crash estimation compendium, which
have been derived using information from similar types of sites elsewhere.
In some cases, the rates and models used for the do-minimum and the option scenarios already account
for the proposed improvement/treatment of the site (eg an intersection treatment to change from priority
or a roundabout to signalised; the construction of a two-lane rural bridge to replace a single-lane bridge).
In others, it may be necessary to apply a crash modifying factor (CMF) from the Crash estimation
compendium to the option crash rate or model to take account of the site treatment/improvement (eg
various mid-block pedestrian treatments; construction of a cycle lane).
In crash rate analysis, it is not possible to differentiate crashes other than by speed limit category,
therefore the crash costs are taken from Table A36, Table A37 and Table A38, and are for ‘all vehicles
and all movements combined’. Where the mean speed of traffic for the do-minimum and/or options differs
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 280
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
from that provided in the tables, an adjustment should be made to the costs using the formula found in
Adjusting crash costs to reflect mean speeds.
Only reported injury crashes are considered when using crash rate analysis because of the inconsistency
in non-injury reporting rates between districts. The crash costs in Table A36, Table A37 and Table A38
take into account the typical number of unreported injury crashes, the number of non-injury crashes, and
the proportion of crashes of each severity (refer to Definitions) per reported injury crash.
Refer to the calculation of future crash benefits section below for details on calculating future safety
benefits when using crash prediction models. Use the Crash cost savings worksheet.
Changes in crash severity
Changes in crash severity can be calculated using method B when methods A and C are not appropriate
for the option case. Refer to the Crash estimation compendium for the crash modifying factors for
treatments that impact on crash severity (eg safety barriers).
Calculation of future crash benefits
In most crash prediction models the relationship between traffic volume and number of crashes is non-
linear. When using crash prediction models, a prediction should be produced every five years through to
the end of the analysis period. Intermediate crash costs can be interpolated. If traffic volumes fall above
or below the traffic volume ranges specified by the model, the predictions must be capped at the lowest or
highest flow allowed for analysis purposes. The Crash cost savings worksheet should be used.
When using crash rates, future predictions are not required as the relationship between crash numbers
and traffic volumes is linear. In such circumstances, only future traffic volumes need to be checked that
they are within any ranges specified; otherwise, the benefits need to be capped. The Crash cost savings
worksheet.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 281
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Method C overview
The weighted crash procedure uses both historical crash data relating to a particular site, and the typical
crash rate (refer to Definitions) for the site. The typical crash rate is calculated using the appropriate crash
rates or crash prediction models and crash modifying factors (CMFs) in the Crash estimation
compendium.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 282
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
The historical data is converted into a site-specific crash rate (refer to Definitions) by dividing the reported
crashes by the number of years of data. The site-specific crash rate is then combined with the typical
crash rate, resulting in a weighted crash rate (refer to Definitions) for the do-minimum and the option(s).
Crash cost savings for the do-minimum and option(s) are calculated using the costs provided in Table
A36, Table A37 and Table A38. Where the mean speed of traffic for the do-minimum and options differs
from that provided in the tables, an adjustment should be made to the costs using the formula found in
Adjusting crash costs to reflect mean speeds.
The weighted crash procedure also allows analysis of sites with no crash history (refer to Definitions), if
the site has been in existence for more than three years with no major changes and the site is assessed
to have a high crash risk.
Weighted crash rate for the do-minimum
The do-minimum weighted crash rate (refer to Definitions) is calculated using the following equation:
AW,dm = w × AT + (1 – w) × AS
where: AW,dm is the do-minimum weighted crash rate
AT is the typical crash rate calculated from the appropriate crash rate or crash prediction model
for the do-minimum
AS is the site-specific crash rate (from historical crash data)
w is the weighting factor
Weighting factor (w)
When w = 1, the method simplifies to a crash rate or crash prediction model (method B).
When w = 0, the method simplifies to a crash-by-crash analysis (method A). w is calculated using the
following equation; where k is specified in the Crash estimation compendium:
K
w=
k + AT(km) × Y
Where: k is a dispersion parameter (refer to Definitions)
AT(km) is typical annual crash rate per site or kilometre (for mid-blocks)
Y is the number of years of crash records
For mid-block sections, the typical crash rate (AT) must be divided by the length of the mid-block because
the mid-block k values provided in the Crash estimation compendium are on a per kilometre basis. In all
other situations AT is for the full length of the mid-block section.
Reliability of crash history
An assessment of the reliability of both the site-specific crash rate and the typical crash rate is required
for method C. The reliability factor for the site-specific crash rate is αX and the reliability factor for the
typical crash rate is αM.
The main factor influencing the reliability of the site-specific crash rate is whether crashes are correctly
coded at the site. Crashes may be missing or incorrectly coded within the site. For example, a crash may
be incorrectly coded within a series of back-to-back curves, where it is not always easy to accurately
locate the exact curve the crash occurred on.
When the historical crash data is reliable, αX should equal 1.0 (this is the default setting). When it is
unreliable, αX should be between 1.0 and 2.0, with 2.0 being very unreliable data.
Reliability factors (αX, αM)
The reliability of the typical crash rate information presented in the Crash estimation compendium is an
issue when a crash rate or crash prediction model is used for:
• a different type of site, or part of a site, than that the rate or model was derived for – for example,
a four-arm traffic signal model might be used for a five-arm traffic signalised intersection (the
prediction would then be approximately 125% of that given by the model), and
• a ‘non-standard’ intersection, mid-block or other site or part of a site – an example of a ‘non-
standard’ intersection would be one with many traffic signal phases (say five or six) or greater
than four approach lanes or a priority seagull.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 283
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
In both situations αM should be increased above 1.0 (the default value). A value of 2.0 would represent
poor reliability.
Weighted crash rate for project option
Method C can only be used for the project option when it does not bring about a fundamental change in a
site (refer to Definitions). In this case, the site-specific historic crash data is still relevant for the project
option analysis. The project option weighted crash rate is calculated by increasing or decreasing the
typical crash rate of the project option by the same proportion used to adjust the do-minimum typical
crash rate to the do- minimum weighted crash rate.
AW,opt = AT,opt × AW,dm / AT,dm
where: AW,opt is the weighted crash rate for the option case
AW,dm is the weighted crash rate for the do-minimum
AT,opt is the typical crash rate calculated from the crash rate or crash prediction model
for the option case. Note: It may be necessary to apply a crash modification factor (CMF)
from the Crash estimation compendium if the crash rate or crash prediction model does
not already take the treatment / improvement into account
AT,dm is the typical crash rate calculated from crash rate or crash prediction model for
the do-minimum
Crash trends
This section provides guidance on the adjustment of crash numbers for general crash trends.
General crash trends
Since 1985 there has been a downward trend in reported traffic crashes. At the same time crash numbers
have decreased and traffic volumes have increased, indicating that crash rates per vehicle have
decreased at a greater rate than crash numbers (Kennaird, 1995).
The combination of these two factors means that typical crash rates (refer to Definitions) established from
past research and site-specific crash numbers need to be adjusted in order to give a realistic estimate of
the likely crash situation at a project site in the future.
The adjustment to crash numbers is a two-stage procedure, with the first being to modify the crash
numbers at time zero. The second being to modify the growth rate used for discounting crash benefits to
take account of the forecast continued trend after time zero.
There have been differences between the crash trends in 50km/h areas compared with 70km/h and
above areas. Therefore, different factors are used to modify the crash numbers for the different posted
speed limit areas.
Table A21 provides factors to convert historic average crash numbers to time zero for method A. For
method B, an equation is provided to adjust the rate to time zero.
Table A22 provides factors to modify the predicted future traffic growth rate when discounting the crash
cost savings.
Adjustment to time zero
Crash numbers and rates for project evaluation are to be determined for time zero. This requires
adjusting the observed or predicted number of crashes assessed at the mid-point of the crash analysis
period to time zero (normally five years). The procedure differs if using the crash history (method A and
C) or crash rate analysis (methods B and C).
Method A adjustment
This procedure should be followed if using method A and C. From Table A21, select the appropriate
adjustment factor for the site based on its traffic growth rate and posted speed limit. For example, for a
project where the posted speed limit is 50km/h and the traffic growth rate is 2% at time zero, the crash
numbers will be factored by 0.90 to adjust the crash numbers to time zero.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 284
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Method B adjustment
This procedure should be followed if using method B and C. As the crash rates and crash prediction
models in the Crash estimation compendium use historical crash data, the predicted number of crashes
needs to be adjusted for crash trends:
A = AT × (1 + ft (yz – 2006))
where: A is the crash rate adjusted for crash trends
AT is the typical rate found from models or rates
ft is the factor for adjusting the typical rate:
• -0.01 for sites with speed limits 60km/h and below
• -0.02 for sites with speed limits 70km/h and above
yz is year zero of the analysis period
Adjusting traffic growth rate for discounting
When discounting the crash cost savings from time zero forwards, the predicted growth rate is adjusted to
reflect the predicted continued trend in crashes. Table A22 provides the adjustments to use for the
different speed limit areas.
Using the factors in Table A22 it is possible for the crash growth rate used for discounting to be negative
if the predicted traffic growth rate at the site is less than 1% in 50km/h areas or 2% in 70km/h and above
areas. For example, if the site is in a 50km/h posted speed area and the traffic growth rate for the site is
1.5% then the growth rate to use for discounting crash costs is 1.5 - 1 = 0.5, ie 0.5% is entered in the
discounting equation.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 285
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Where the mean speed of the do-minimum and/or project options differ from these speeds, the crash
costs are adjusted using the one of the following formulae:
for 50 < V < 70km/h: CV = C50 + (C70 - C50)(V - 50)/20
for 70 < V < 100km/h: CV = C70 + (C100 - C70)(V - 70)/30
where: CV is the cost of crashes for the mean speed V
C50 is the cost of crashes in 50km/h speed limit areas
C70 is the cost of crashes in 70km/h speed limit areas
C100 is the cost of crashes in 100km/h speed limit area
V is the mean speed of traffic in km/h
Calculation of mean speed
If the road section has a design speed based on the 85th percentile speed, then to convert the design
speed to the mean speed use the approximation of dividing the 85th percentile speed by 1.13 (or
multiplying by 0.885) and round the result to the nearest whole kilometre per hour.
Mean speed should be established over a section length of at least one kilometre.
Tables
Introduction
Table A23 through to Table A44 are for use in the Crash cost savings worksheet provided on the Waka
Kotahi website. These tables are used for calculating annual crash costs, depending on which of the
crash analysis procedures are used.
Table A23 through to Table A35 and Table A39 to Table A44 are for use with method A crash-by-crash
analysis, while Table A36 to Table A38 are for use with methods B and C crash rate analysis and the
weighted crash procedure.
• Table A23, Table A24 and Table A25 – ratio of fatal to serious crash severities by movement for
different speed limits.
• Table A26 – factors for converting from reported injury crashes to total injury crashes.
• Table A27 – factors for converting from reported minor injury crashes to total non-injury crashes.
• Table A28, Table A29, Table A30 and Table A31 – cost per crash by movement and vehicle
involvement for fatal, serious, minor and non-injury crashes in 50km/h speed limit areas for use
with method A, crash-by-crash analysis.
• Table A32, Table A33, Table A34 and Table A35 – cost per crash by movement and vehicle
involvement for fatal, serious, minor and non-injury crashes in 100km/h speed limit areas for use
with method A, crash-by-crash analysis.
• Table A36, Table A37 and Table A38 – cost per reported injury crash for methods B and C.
• Table A39 – ratio of fatal and serious/all injury factors by crash type, ONRC grouped and by
alignment type 80–100km/h.
• Table A40 – ratio of fatal and serious/all injury factors by crash type, ONRC grouped and by
alignment type 60–70km/h.
• Table A41 – ratio of fatal and serious/all injury factors by crash type, ONRC grouped and by
alignment type 40–50km/h.
• Table A42 – ratio of fatal and serious/all injury as a function of crash type by ONRC for 80–
100km/h.
• Table A43 – ratio of fatal and serious/all injury as a function of crash type by ONRC for 60–
70km/h.
• Table A44 – ratio of fatal and serious/all injury as a function of crash type by ONRC for 40–
50km/h.
Refer to Definitions for more information.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 286
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Table A23: Ratio of fatal to serious crash severities by movement for 50km/h speed limit areas
Movement category CAS movement codes Fatal/ Serious/
(fatal + serious) (fatal + serious)
Head on AB, B 0.08 0.92
Hit object E 0.06 0.94
Lost control off road AD, CB, CC, CO, D 0.13 0.87
Lost control on road CA 0.05 0.95
Miscellaneous Q 0.13 0.87
Overtaking AA, AC, AE-AO, GE 0.04 0.96
Pedestrian N, P 0.08 0.92
Rear end, crossing FB, FC, GD 0.07 0.93
Rear end, queuing FD, FE, FF, FO 0.07 0.93
Rear end, slow vehicle FA, GA-GC, GO 0.05 0.95
Crossing, direct H 0.05 0.95
Crossing, turning J, K, L, M 0.03 0.97
All movements 0.07 0.93
Table A24: Ratio of fatal to serious crash severities by movement for 70km/h speed limit areas
Movement category CAS movement codes Fatal/ Serious/
(fatal + serious) (fatal + serious)
Head on AB, B 0.24 0.76
Hit object E 0.11 0.89
Lost control off road AD, CB, CC, CO, D 0.10 0.90
Lost control on road CA 0.10 0.90
Miscellaneous Q 0.20 0.80
Overtaking AA, AC, AE-AO, GE 0.08 0.92
Pedestrian N, P 0.26 0.74
Rear end, crossing FB, FC, GD 0.11 0.89
Rear end, queuing FD, FE, FF, FO 0.11 0.89
Rear end, slow vehicle FA, GA-GC, GO 0.10 0.90
Crossing, direct H 0.09 0.91
Crossing, turning J, K, L, M 0.10 0.90
All movements 0.14 0.86
Table A25: Ratio of fatal to serious crash severities by movement for 100km/h speed limit areas
Movement category CAS movement codes Fatal/ Serious/
(fatal + serious) (fatal + serious)
Head on AB, B 0.36 0.64
Hit object E 0.16 0.84
Lost control off road AD, CB, CC, CO, D 0.17 0.83
Lost control on road CA 0.14 0.86
Miscellaneous Q 0.26 0.74
Overtaking AA, AC, AE-AO, GE 0.12 0.88
Pedestrian N, P 0.44 0.56
Rear end, crossing FB, FC, GD 0.14 0.86
Rear end, queuing FD, FE, FF, FO 0.14 0.86
Rear end, slow vehicle FA, GA-GC, GO 0.14 0.86
Crossing, direct H 0.13 0.87
Crossing, turning J,K,L,M 0.16 0.84
All movements 0.20 0.80
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 287
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Table A26: Factors for converting from reported injury crashes to total injury crash
Speed-limit area Injured person category Fatal Serious Minor
50, 60 and 70km/h speed limit Pedestrian 4.5
1.0 1.5
Other 2.75
80 and 100km/h speed limit Pedestrian 7.5
1.0 1.9
(excluding motorways) Other 4.5
100km/h speed limit remote Pedestrian 13.0
1.0 2.3
rural area Other 7.5
Motorway All 1.0 1.9 1.9
All All 1.0 1.7 3.6
Table A27: Factor for converting from reported non-injury crashes to total non-injury crashes
Speed-limit area 50, 60 or 70km/h 80 or 100km/h Motorway
All movements 7 18.5 7
Table A28: Cost per crash by movement and vehicle involvement for fatal injury crashes in
50km/h speed limit areas
50km/h speed limit fatal injury Total cost per crash by vehicle type ($M 2015)
crashes
Movement CAS movement Cycle Motorcycle Bus Truck Car, van All
category codes and other vehicles
Head on AB, B 4.1 4.2 4.15 4.15 5.4 4.55
Hit object E 4.1 4.2 4.15 4.15 4.8 4.4
Lost control off AD, CB, CC, CO, 4.1 4.2 4.15 4.15 5.15 5.0
road D
Lost control on CA 4.1 4.2 4.15 4.15 4.8 4.6
road
Miscellaneous Q 4.1 4.2 4.15 4.15 4.1 4.1
Overtaking AA, AC, AE-AO, 4.1 4.2 4.15 4.15 4.8 4.1
GE
Pedestrian N, P 4.1 4.2 4.15 4.1 4.1 4.1
Rear end, crossing FB, FC, GD 4.1 4.2 4.15 4.15 4.8 4.6
Rear end, queuing FD, FE, FF, FO 4.1 4.2 4.15 4.15 4.8 4.6
Rear end, slow FA, GA-GC, GO 4.1 4.2 4.15 4.15 4.8 4.6
vehicle
Crossing, direct H 4.1 4.2 4.15 4.15 4.95 4.6
Crossing, turning J, K, L, M 4.1 4.15 4.15 4.15 4.8 4.5
All movements 4.1 4.2 4.15 4.15 4.8 4.6
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 288
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Table A29: Cost per crash by movement and vehicle involvement for serious injury crashes in
50km/h speed limit areas
50km/h speed limit serious Total cost per crash by vehicle type ($000 2015)
injury crashes
Movement CAS Cycle Motorcycle Bus Truck Car, van and All vehicles
category movement other
codes
Head on AB, B 430 430 445 460 650 585
Hit object E 430 460 475 465 445 445
Lost control off AD, CB, 430 445 475 505 525 505
road CC, CO, D
Lost control on CA 430 430 475 485 520 465
road
Miscellaneous Q 435 430 475 430 495 475
Overtaking AA, AC, AE- 430 430 475 485 515 440
AO, GE
Pedestrian N, P 475 495 430 465 435 440
Rear end, FB, FC, GD 435 430 475 445 460 450
crossing
Rear end, FD, FE, FF, 435 430 475 505 460 460
queuing FO
Rear end, slow FA, GA-GC, 430 445 475 485 525 465
vehicle GO
Crossing, direct H 435 450 475 490 520 490
Crossing, J, K, L, M 440 445 470 535 490 475
turning
All movements 435 445 475 485 495 475
Table A30: Cost per crash by movement and vehicle involvement for minor injury crashes in
50km/h speed limit areas
50km/h speed limit Total cost per crash by vehicle type ($000 2015)
minor injury crashes
CAS
Movement Car, van All
movement Cycle Motorcycle Bus Truck
category and other vehicles
codes
Head on AB, B 24 26 24 28 35 32
Hit object E 24 24 25 26 25 25
Lost control off AD, CB, CC,
26 24 30 26 28 27
road CO, D
Lost control on CA
24 24 28 27 28 26
road
Miscellaneous Q 23 26 26 25 26 26
Overtaking AA, AC, AE-
24 24 27 24 31 26
AO, GE
Pedestrian N, P 36 31 24 24 24 25
Rear end, crossing FB, FC, GD 24 25 28 31 30 30
Rear end, queuing FD, FE, FF,
24 24 35 30 29 29
FO
Rear end, slow FA, GA-GC,
23 24 27 26 30 26
vehicle GO
Crossing, direct H 24 25 31 30 31 31
Crossing, turning J, K, L, M 24 24 28 27 30 31
All movements 24 24 28 27 29 28
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 289
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Table A31: Cost per crash by movement and vehicle involvement for non-injury crashes in 50km/h
speed limit areas
50km/h speed limit non- Total cost per crash by vehicle type ($000 2015)
injury crashes
Movement CAS Cycle Motorcycle Bus Truck Car, van All
category movement and other vehicles
codes
Head on AB, B 1.3 1.4 5.7 7.9 2.7 3.2
Hit object E 1.3 1.4 6.6 7.8 2.6 3.4
Lost control AD, CB, 1.2 1.8 2.7 7 1.7 1.8
off road CC, CO, D
Lost control CA 1 1.5 1.4 7.3 2.0 2.2
on road
Miscellaneous Q 1.3 1.4 7.3 7.1 2.1 3.4
Overtaking AA, AC, AE- 2 1.7 4.2 8 2.8 3.8
AO, GE
Pedestrian N, P 0.7 1.5 0.3 6.5 1.5 1.6
Rear end, FB, FC, GD 1.8 1.5 3.4 7.8 2.6 2.9
crossing
Rear end, FD, FE, FF, 1.6 1.5 4.6 7.9 2.6 2.9
queuing FO
Rear end, FA, GA-GC, 1.4 1.5 4 7.9 2.7 3.4
slow vehicle GO
Crossing, H 1.3 1.4 4.5 8 2.6 2.8
direct
Crossing, J, K, L, M 1.3 1.5 3.3 7.8 2.6 2.9
turning
All 1.4 1.5 3.7 7.8 2.5 2.8
movements
Table A32: Cost per crash by movement and vehicle involvement for fatal injury crashes in
100km/h speed limit areas
100km/h speed limit fatal injury Total cost per crash by vehicle type ($M 2015)
crashes
Movement category CAS Cycle Motorcycle Bus Truck Car, van All
movement and vehicles
codes other
Head on AB, B 4.45 4.7 6.5 5.05 5.7 5.4
Hit object E 4.1 4.4 5.9 4.75 4.15 4.15
Lost control off road AD, CB, CC, 4.1 4.1 5.9 4.3 4.7 4.6
CO, D
Lost control on road CA 4.1 4.4 5.9 4.75 4.85 5.05
Miscellaneous Q 4.1 4.4 5.9 4.65 4.55 4.55
Overtaking AA, AC, AE- 4.1 5.1 5.9 4.75 4.6 4.6
AO, GE
Pedestrian N, P 4.1 4.4 5.9 4.35 4.1 4.25
Rear end, crossing FB, FC, GD 4.1 4.4 5.9 4.75 4.95 4.25
Rear end, queuing FD, FE, FF, FO 4.1 4.4 5.9 4.75 4.95 4.3
Rear end, slow FA, GA-GC, 4.1 4.4 5.9 4.75 4.95 4.3
vehicle GO
Crossing, direct H 4.1 4.4 5.9 4.15 4.65 4.65
Crossing, turning J, K, L, M 4.1 4.15 5.9 5.0 4.5 4.65
All movements 4.1 4.4 5.9 4.75 4.95 4.85
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 290
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Table A33: Cost per crash by movement and vehicle involvement for serious injury crashes in
100km/h speed limit areas
100km/h speed limit Total cost per crash by vehicle type ($000 2015)
serious injury crashes
Movement CAS Cycle Motorcycle Bus Truck Car, van All
category movement and other vehicles
codes
Head on AB, B 465 450 670 550 675 610
Hit object E 430 465 615 505 525 500
Lost control off AD, CB, CC, 475 455 800 475 520 505
road CO, D
Lost control on CA 465 430 615 505 485 475
road
Miscellaneous Q 465 485 615 490 500 495
Overtaking AA, AC, AE- 465 465 615 495 545 500
AO, GE
Pedestrian N, P 465 455 615 505 440 435
Rear end, FB, FC, GD 465 475 615 505 550 525
crossing
Rear end, FD, FE, FF, 465 455 615 505 525 500
queuing FO
Rear end, slow FA, GA-GC, 450 470 615 505 505 525
vehicle GO
Crossing, H 560 435 615 520 595 525
direct
Crossing, J, K, L, M 430 460 615 485 575 525
turning
All movements 465 455 615 505 550 525
Table A34: Cost per crash by movement and vehicle involvement for minor injury crashes in
100km/h speed limit areas
100km/h speed limit Total cost per crash by vehicle type ($000 2015)
minor injury crashes
Movement CAS Cycle Motorcycle Bus Truck Car, van All
category movement and other vehicles
codes
Head on AB, B 27 27 26 31 37 36
Hit object E 23 24 33 27 27 27
Lost control off AD, CB, CC, 25 25 35 26 29 28
road CO, D
Lost control on CA 28 25 33 30 30 28
road
Miscellaneous Q 25 26 33 28 27 27
Overtaking AA, AC, AE- 26 25 33 27 32 29
AO, GE
Pedestrian N, P 25 25 33 23 24 24
Rear end, FB, FC, GD 25 26 33 34 35 34
crossing
Rear end, FD, FE, FF, FO 25 27 38 30 31 31
queuing
Rear end, slow FA, GA-GC, 25 28 30 29 34 32
vehicle GO
Crossing, direct H 23, 23 23 32 37 35
Crossing, J, K, L, M 24 27 42 30 36 35
turning
All movements 25 25 33 28 31 30
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 291
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Table A35: Cost per crash by movement and vehicle involvement for non-injury crashes in
100km/h speed limit areas
100km/h speed limit Total cost per crash by vehicle type ($000 2015)
non-injury crashes
Movement CAS movement Cycle Motorcycle Bus Truck Car, van All
category codes and other vehicles
Head on AB, B 1.7 2.2 5.8 10.3 3.3 4.7
Hit object E 1.7 2.2 4.3 9.1 2.0 3.3
Lost control AD, CB, CC, 1.7 1.8 1.4 8.4 1.7 2.1
off road CO, D
Lost control CA 1.7 1.8 1.0 8.9 2.3 3.4
on road
Miscellaneous Q 1.7 1.8 9.0 8.7 2.2 5.0
Overtaking AA, AC, AE- 1.7 2.0 5.4 9.9 3.3 5.3
AO, GE
Pedestrian N, P 1.7 2.0 3.9 9 1.9 3.7
Rear end, FB, FC, GD 1.7 1.8 6.9 10.4 3.3 4.0
crossing
Rear end, FD, FE, FF, FO 1.7 2.5 5.9 10 3.3 3.9
queuing
Rear end, FA, GA-GC, 1.7 1.8 7.0 10.1 3.3 4.4
slow vehicle GO
Crossing, H 1.7 2.0 6.6 10.2 3.4 4.2
direct
Crossing, J, K, L, M 1.7 1.8 4.3 10 3.3 4.2
turning
All 1.7 2.0 3.9 9.5 2.4 3.2
movements
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 292
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Table A37: Cost per reported injury crash for special sites ($000 2015)
Crash site/type Cost per reported injury crash by speed limit area ($000 2015)
50km/h 70km/h 100km/h near 100km/h remote
rural rural
Motorway crashes 290 NA
Rural railway crossing N/A N/A 1315 1785
crashes
Rural bridge crashes N/A N/A 570 880
Table A38: Cost per reported injury crash by mode ($000 2015)
Crash site/type Cost per reported injury crash by speed limit area ($000 2015)
50km/h 70km/h 100km/h near 100km/h remote
rural rural
Heavy vehicle crashes 330 550 760 1155
Cycle crashes 235 520 645 945
Pedestrian crashes 325 940 1375 1810
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 293
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Table A39: Ratio of fatal and serious/all injury factors by crash type, ONRC grouped and by alignment type, 80–100km/h
80km/h– Crossing Crossing Head Hit Loc Loc Misc Over- Pedestrian Rear end Rear end Rear
100km/h direct turning on object off on taking crossing queueing end
road road slowing
vehicle
National Straight 0.27 0.26 0.56 0.15 0.18 0.24 0.11 0.13 0.64 0.16 0.05 0.12
strategic (high and
volume) curved
Winding 0.38
and
tortuous
National and Straight 0.3 0.31 0.58 0.24 0.24 0.23 0.27 0.25 0.73 0.29 0.08 0.23
regional and
strategic curved
Winding 0.32 0.41 0.25 0.23 0.25 0.36
and
tortuous
Arterial and Straight 0.35 0.27 0.55 0.2 0.25 0.3 0.39 0.26 0.59 0.2 0.08 0.26
primary collector and
curved
Winding 0.22 0.43 0.22 0.24 0.36 0.33 0.62 0.14
and
tortuous
Secondary Straight 0.38 0.31 0.47 0.3 0.3 0.38 0.49 0.22 0.56 0.18 0.06 0.3
collector and and
access curved
Winding 0.28 0.37 0.27 0.31 0.31 0.61 0.28 0.59 0.5
and
tortuous
All 0.35 0.29 0.51 0.23 0.26 0.29 0.35 0.21 0.62 0.22 0.06 0.23
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 294
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Table A40: Ratio of fatal and serious/all injury factors by crash type, ONRC grouped and by alignment type, 60–70km/h
60km/h–70km/h Crossing Crossing Head Hit Loc Loc Misc Over- Pedestrian Rear end Rear end Rear
direct turning on object off on taking crossing queueing end
road road slowing
vehicle
National strategic Straight 0.18 0.17 0.53 0.19 0.31 0.29 0.24 0.43 0.5 0.1 0.23
(high volume) and
curved
Winding 0.3
and
tortuous
National and Straight 0.09 0.16 0.51 0.21 0.44 0.11 0.5 0.05 0.22
regional strategic and
curved
Winding 0.17 0.16 0.29 0.6 0.41
and
tortuous
Arterial and Straight 0.19 0.36 0.16 0.24 0.29 0.47 0.5 0.02 0.1
primary collector and
curved
Winding 0.35 0.25 0.46 0.22 0.36 0.33 0.6 0.5
and
tortuous
Secondary Straight 0.17 0.25 0.38 0.21 0.24 0.13 0.46 0.5 0.17
collector and and
access curved
Winding 0.26 0.4 0.25 0.35
and
tortuous
All 0.18 0.43 0.17 0.24 0.22 0.45 0.5 0.05 0.17
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 295
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Table A41: Ratio of fatal and serious/all injury factors by crash type, ONRC grouped and by alignment type 40–50km/h
40km/h–50km/h Crossing Crossing Head Hit Loc Loc Misc Over- Pedestrian Rear end Rear end Rear
direct turning on object off on taking crossing queueing end
road road slowing
vehicle
National strategic Straight 0.14 0.15 0.24 0.19 0.15 0.22 0.13 0.27 0.08 0.03 0.12
(high volume) and curved
Winding 0.27 0.67 0.25
and
tortuous
National and Straight 0.16 0.13 0.23 0.14 0.21 0.14 0.3 0.15 0.5 0.04 0.03 0.11
regional strategic and curved
Winding 0.13 0.17 0.33 0.22 0.26 0.15
and
tortuous
Arterial and Straight 0.15 0.14 0.24 0.14 0.19 0.22 0.35 0.15 0.29 0.05 0.04 0.1
primary collector and curved
Winding 0.17 0.17 0.26 0.21 0.22 0.23 0.22 0.25 0.25
and
tortuous
Secondary Straight 0.13 0.14 0.23 0.14 0.22 0.27 0.43 0.15 0.29 0.06 0.04 0.15
collector and and curved
access
Winding 0.15 0.23 0.14 0.17 0.24 0.32 0.32 0.35 0.29 0.1
and
tortuous
All 0.14 0.14 0.23 0.14 0.21 0.23 0.38 0.16 0.28 0.05 0.04 0.12
Note: blanks indicate insufficient data and that ‘all’ value for the applicable speed should be used.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 296
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Table A42: Ratio of fatal and serious/all injury as a function of crash type by ONRC for 80–100km/h
80–100 km/h National National Regional Arterial Primary Secondary Access All
strategic (high strategic strategic collector collector
volume)
Crossing direct 0.26 0.39 0.26 0.31 0.42 0.38 0.37 0.35
Crossing 0.27 0.35 0.3 0.26 0.28 0.31 0.31 0.29
turning
Head on 0.56 0.57 0.55 0.53 0.51 0.45 0.39 0.51
Hit object 0.15 0.27 0.23 0.17 0.23 0.28 0.32 0.23
Loc off road 0.18 0.25 0.23 0.24 0.26 0.3 0.32 0.26
Loc on road 0.24 0.22 0.24 0.26 0.35 0.33 0.4 0.29
Misc 0.11 0.25 0.28 0.35 0.39 0.45 0.59 0.35
Overtaking 0.13 0.3 0.22 0.24 0.3 0.27 0.15 0.21
Pedestrian 0.64 0.8 0.66 0.6 0.58 0.53 0.65 0.62
Rear end 0.16 0.27 0.29 0.18 0.22 0.21 0 0.22
crossing
Rear end 0.05 0.09 0.08 0.07 0.09 0.07 0.06 0.06
queuing
Rear end slow 0.12 0.22 0.25 0.24 0.27 0.36 0.19 0.23
vehicle
All 0.15 0.3 0.28 0.26 0.29 0.31 0.31 0.27
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 297
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Table A43: Ratio of fatal and serious/all injury as a function of crash type by ONRC for 60–70km/h
60–70 km/h National National Regional Arterial Primary Secondary Access All
strategic (high strategic strategic collector collector
volume)
Crossing direct 0.18 0 0.11 0.19 0.14 0.35 0.17
Crossing 0.17 0.13 0.16 0.19 0.22 0.23 0.3 0.18
turning
Head on 0.52 0.71 0.41 0.37 0.41 0.32 0.48 0.43
Hit object 0.18 0.18 0.13 0.21 0.16 0.33 0.17
Loc off road 0.3 0.21 0.21 0.24 0.24 0.22 0.29 0.24
Loc on road 0.28 0.33 0.46 0.34 0.14 0.5 0.33 0.35
Misc 0.4 0 0.67 0.25 0.4 0.33 0.33
Overtaking 0.25 0.18 0.11 0.27 0.35 0.15 0.22
Pedestrian 0.44 0.63 0.39 0.41 0.58 0.42 0.58 0.45
Rear end 0.12 0.09 0.1 0.1 0.06 0.11 0.2 0.1
crossing
Rear end 0.1 0.05 0.05 0.04 0.02 0.05 0.05
queuing
Rear end slow 0.21 0.25 0.22 0.1 0.09 0.19 0.29 0.17
vehicle
All 0.21 0.21 0.18 0.2 0.24 0.23 0.3 0.21
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 298
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Table A44: Ratio of fatal and serious/all injury as a function of crash type by ONRC for 40–50km/h
40–50 km/h National National Regional Arterial Primary Secondary Access All
strategic (high strategic strategic collector collector
volume)
Crossing direct 0.13 0.18 0.15 0.15 0.13 0.12 0.16 0.14
Crossing 0.15 0.14 0.13 0.14 0.15 0.14 0.15 0.14
turning
Head on 0.3 0.35 0.24 0.24 0.25 0.19 0.23 0.23
Hit object 0.19 0.15 0.14 0.14 0.14 0.16 0.13 0.14
Loc off road 0.16 0.24 0.2 0.19 0.2 0.23 0.23 0.21
Loc on road 0.21 0.3 0.08 0.2 0.24 0.28 0.27 0.23
Misc 0.22 0.6 0.25 0.35 0.3 0.35 0.48 0.38
Overtaking 0.12 0.18 0.15 0.13 0.23 0.16 0.18 0.16
Pedestrian 0.27 0.28 0.25 0.25 0.28 0.28 0.29 0.26
Rear end 0.08 0.04 0.04 0.04 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.05
crossing
Rear end 0.03 0.03 0.03 0.04 0.04 0.04 0.04 0.04
queuing
Rear end slow 0.11 0.05 0.12 0.11 0.12 0.16 0.12 0.12
vehicle
All 0.15 0.16 0.14 0.15 0.18 0.18 0.2 0.17
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 299
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Definitions
Regression to For the purpose of crash analysis, generally a minimum of the past five years of
the mean reported crash history is used. This reduces the error caused by regression to the
mean.
The principle of regression to the mean states that when an earlier measurement is
either extremely high or extremely low, then the expected value of later
measurements will be closer to the true mean than the observed value of the first.
The effect of regression to the mean can be reduced by using a longer crash
history when investigating crashes at a site, and by ensuring that there is a
commonality amongst crashes at the site.
Defining In assigning costs to crashes using method A, crashes are classified by ‘vehicle
crashes by involvement’ according to the highest ranked ‘vehicle’ involved in a crash. The
vehicle ranking from highest vehicle to lowest vehicle is:
involvement
• pedestrian
• bicycle
• motorcycle including moped
• bus
• truck
• cars, light commercial vehicles and any other.
For example, a crash involving a truck and a bicycle is categorised as a ‘cycle
crash’.
Dispersion ‘k’ is a dispersion parameter of the negative binomial distribution, which is the
parameter probability distribution assumed for the crash data. ‘k’ values for different sites are
provided in the Crash estimation compendium.
Generally, the higher the value of k the higher the accuracy of a crash prediction
model (and vice versa). The accuracy is, however, also relative to the typical crash
rate at a site (ie a low k value) may be acceptable at a site with a low typical crash
rate but unacceptable at a site with a high typical crash rate.
Fundamental An option results in a fundamental change in a site when the types of crash or the
change in a site level of crash severity is expected to change significantly. The following list gives
examples of site changes that would result in a fundamental change:
• a completely new site is being provided (such as a new road or
intersection)
• realignment of a road (other than an isolated curve)
• removal or significant modification of road elements (eg grade separation
of a railway crossing and conversion of a single-lane bridge to a two-lane
bridge)
• change in intersection form of control
• flush median installed on an urban road with multiple accesses
• adding lanes, including passing lanes.
Options that are not normally regarded as resulting in fundamental changes
include:
• upgrade of a single or S-bend to a higher-design speed curve or S-bend
• shoulder widening on rural roads (in the absence of road realignment)
• signage and delineation improvements, including lighting
• traffic volume changes (in the absence of other improvements)
• road resurfacing and shape corrections
• minor improvement works.
Intersection Crashes occurring within the area of priority controlled intersections, roundabouts
crashes and traffic signals on the primary road network, and up to 50 metres from the
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 300
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
influence of the intersection in a 50km/h speed limit area and up to 200 metres in
an 80km/h and above area.
Remote and Remote rural roads are sites carrying less than 1000 vpd and more than 20
near rural roads kilometres away from a town with a population of 3000 or more. Other rural sites
are considered to be ‘near rural’.
Severity In method A, crashes are categorised by the most severe injury sustained. The four
severity categories are:
• Fatal: when death ensues within 30 days of the crash.
• Serious: injuries requiring medical attention or admission to hospital,
including fractures, concussion and severe cuts.
• Minor: injuries other than serious, which require first aid or cause
discomfort or pain, including bruising and sprains.
• Non-injury: when no injuries occur, sometimes referred to as ‘property
damage only’ (PDO) crashes.
The crash reports from police officers recorded in CAS are to be used to classify
crash severity in preference to hospital records.
Site A site is the specific road infrastructure for which an evaluation is carried out. A site
can be a bridge, intersection, mid-block, curve, S-bend etc, or any combination of
these (eg a mid-block and an intersection). In the case of combinations, a site may
have to be broken into parts for the purpose of evaluation.
Types of crash A crash rate is the average number of injury crashes per year, measured over a
rate period of time (normally five calendar years). Caution is required when using the
latest three to six months CAS data as the data set may not be complete.
Site-specific crash rate (AS)
The crash rate for a specific site based on reported injury crashes on the record of
TCRs prepared by the police and compiled by Waka Kotahi (normally five years of
data). These are available from CAS.
Typical crash rate (AT)
The crash rate for a typical or generic site (eg a bridge with characteristics similar
to the site being evaluated). Typical crash rates are determined using either a
crash rate or a crash prediction model from the Crash estimation compendium,
depending on the type of site, or part of a site, being evaluated.
Weighted crash rate (AW)
The crash rate produced when using the weighted crash procedure.
Back to 3.1 Impact on social cost of deaths and serious injuries >>
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 301
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
APPENDIX 3: TRAFFIC DATA AND TRAVEL TIME ESTIMATION > TRAFFIC COMPOSITION
Traffic composition
Vehicle classes
The definitions for vehicle classes are provided in Table A45.
Back to 3.6 Impact on network productivity and utilisation: Vehicle operating costs
>>
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 302
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
APPENDIX 3: TRAFFIC DATA AND TRAVEL TIME ESTIMATION > TRAFFIC COMPOSITION
Road categories
Road categories for the traffic data classifications in this appendix are provided in Table A46.
Back to 3.6 Impact on network productivity and utilisation: Vehicle operating costs
>>
Standard traffic composition
Table A47 provides standard traffic compositions. For larger projects or sites with unusual traffic
characteristics, classification counts are required. Bus numbers are site dependent and are not
included in the standard traffic composition.
Road category and time period Traffic composition by vehicle class (%)
Car LCV MCV HCVI HCVII
Urban arterial
Morning commuter peak 85 10 2 1 2
Daytime inter-peak 84 11 2 1 2
Afternoon commuter peak 84 11 2 2 1
Evening/night-time 85 9 2 1 3
Weekday all periods 85 10 2 1 2
Weekend/holiday 87 8 3 1 1
All periods 85 10 2 1 2
Urban other
Weekday 86 8 3 2 1
Weekend/holiday 87 9 2 1 1
All periods 86 8 3 2 1
Rural strategic
Weekday 75 12 4 4 5
Weekend/holiday 83 5 5 4 3
All periods 78 10 4 4 4
Rural other
Weekday 78 11 3 4 4
Weekend/holiday 84 6 4 4 2
All periods 81 9 3 4 3
Traffic composition data is not provided for strategic routes on the fringes of large population centres
(ie populations greater than 40,000). Such routes are characterised by predominantly rural strategic
traffic mixes but with high commuter peaks more typical of an urban arterial road. On these routes
individual surveys of traffic composition will normally be required. Also traffic stream compositions are
likely to vary throughout the day, and the result of a single period survey may not accurately reflect
the daily traffic composition – if this is the case more surveys through the day will be required.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 303
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
APPENDIX 3: TRAFFIC DATA AND TRAVEL TIME ESTIMATION > SEPARATING AN ACTIVITY INTO ITS COMPONENT
SECTIONS
Sections must be chosen so as to ensure conservation of vehicle movements (ie the sum of the flows
into a section must equal the sum of the flows out).
Section lengths may be divided into sub-sections when it comes to calculating vehicle operating
costs.
Guidance for motorways and multi-lane roads
Each motorway section or multi-lane road section shall consist of a length of road with:
• uniform design speed
• one direction of travel
• uniform number of through lanes
• boundaries which generally extend between major interchanges where significant flows leave
or join the section.
Guidance for two-lane rural roads
Each two-lane rural road section shall be at least 1km and not more than 5km in length. The two-lane
rural road section to be analysed may be longer than the activity length.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 304
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
APPENDIX 3: TRAFFIC DATA AND TRAVEL TIME ESTIMATION > VEHICLE OCCUPANCY AND TRAVEL PURPOSE
Procedure
Follow the steps below to divide the year into time periods.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 305
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
APPENDIX 3: TRAFFIC DATA AND TRAVEL TIME ESTIMATION > VEHICLE OCCUPANCY AND TRAVEL PURPOSE
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 306
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
APPENDIX 3: TRAFFIC DATA AND TRAVEL TIME ESTIMATION > VEHICLE OCCUPANCY AND TRAVEL PURPOSE
Traffic volumes are generally expressed in terms of annual average daily traffic (AADT), annual average
weekday, average weekend/holiday, average hour, or average quarter hour volumes. The methods given
below for determining traffic volumes based on traffic counts are derived from:
• Guide to estimating AADT and traffic growth (Transit NZ 1994)
• Guide to estimation and monitoring of traffic counting and traffic growth (Traffic Design Group
2001).
General information and background on demand estimation and forecasting can be found in Chapter 2:
Demand estimation and mode share. Information on transport model availability in New Zealand and high
level background on model capability can be found in section 2.10. Wherever properly
calibrated/validated transportation models are available in a study area, they should generally be used to
assess the effects of the activity on traffic volumes and predict future traffic volumes.
As well as the normal calibration/validation required to ensure that the models are operating satisfactorily,
they should also be calibrated/validated in the local area containing the activity. See the Transport model
development guidelines (NZ Transport Agency 2019), and particularly reference to model type D:
Transport Agency scheme assessment/project evaluation, which outlines calibration/validation principles
within the area of influence/focus for an assessment of an activity.
For background on when differences between the do-minimum and activity demands may occur, see
section 2.13: Fixed trip matrix and variable trip matrix assessments and for procedures for developing
demands and applying fixed trip matrix and variable trip matrix techniques see Fixed trip matrices and
Variable trip matrices in Appendix 1.
Method for estimating AADT
To estimate AADT from a sample count it is necessary to adjust the count data for a number of factors.
Count data shall be checked for consistency and reasonableness and axle pair counts (eg from tube
counters) shall be corrected by applying an adjustment factor to convert from axle pair counts vehicle
counts.
Daily counts for less than a week shall be adjusted by applying day factors (for the appropriate typical
traffic pattern) to derive weekly average daily traffic. Weekly average daily traffic figures shall then be
adjusted by applying the appropriate week factors to derive AADTs. If more than one week is counted,
the AADT shall be determined for each week, and then averaged.
To determine day and week factors, the appropriate traffic pattern control group shall be identified from
the Guide to estimating AADT and traffic growth. Alternatively, these factors may be derived from rigorous
local traffic counting programmes.
Method for estimating weekday or weekend/holiday volumes
The weekday, Saturday and Sunday/holiday volumes shall be derived from AADTs by applying locally
derived day factors where these are available, or the factors in the Guide to estimating AADT and traffic
growth if local data is not available. The Saturday and Sunday/holiday volumes so obtained shall be
averaged to derive an average weekend/holiday daily volume.
Method for estimating hourly or quarter hourly directional volumes
Where traffic volumes are required for shorter time periods than a day, these shall be obtained from
directional counts.
Counts done to produce estimates of the AADT will usually have been obtained from traffic counters that
record volumes by 60 or 15 minute intervals. Week factors shall be applied to these counts to obtain
estimates of 60 or 15 minute traffic volumes.
For intersection volumes, manual counts of turning movements should be consistent with the
requirements of NZS 5431:1973 clause 5.4.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 307
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
APPENDIX 3: TRAFFIC DATA AND TRAVEL TIME ESTIMATION > TRAFFIC GROWTH RATES
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 308
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
APPENDIX 3: TRAFFIC DATA AND TRAVEL TIME ESTIMATION > TRAVEL TIMES AND SPEED
for the transport model would need to cover any potential significant re-assignment changes from the
effects described in the bullet points above.
Induced demand, redistributed trips, mode-shifted trips, or macro-time shifted trips
Activities that reduce the cost of travel can induce new trips, redistribute trips, result in a change of travel
mode, or macro-time shift trips from one discrete time period to another. See section 2.13: Fixed trip
matrix and variable trip matrix assessments. In cases where these potential effects are expected to
significantly affect the evaluation, then a variable matrix approach should be adopted (see Variable trip
matrices in Appendix 1).
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 309
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
APPENDIX 3: TRAFFIC DATA AND TRAVEL TIME ESTIMATION > THE STAGES FOR ESTIMATING TRAVEL TIME
Start
Determine traffic volumes for each time period Spread the peak
Calculate the free speed travel times
Yes
Is the section an ‘other’ urban road?
No
Yes
Is the section a two-lane rural road?
No
No
Are vehicles interactions significant?
Yes
Yes
Should peak spreading be considered?
No
End
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 310
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
APPENDIX 3: TRAFFIC DATA AND TRAVEL TIME ESTIMATION > DETERMINING TRAFFIC VOLUMES
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 311
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
APPENDIX 3: TRAFFIC DATA AND TRAVEL TIME ESTIMATION > CALCULATING FREE SPEED TRAVEL TIME
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 312
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
APPENDIX 3: TRAFFIC DATA AND TRAVEL TIME ESTIMATION > DETERMINING THE FREE SPEED OF TWO-LANE RURAL
ROADS
Example calculation
Below is an example calculation for the free speed of a multi-lane road section where measured speeds
are not available.
Example:
Posted speed limit = 70km/h
Median divided = yes
Lane width = 3.5m
Lateral clearance = 1.0m
Access points density = 10 per km
Basic free speed = 80km/h
Dividing median speed reduction = 0km/h
Lane width speed reduction = 0km/h
Lateral clearance speed reduction = 4km/h
Access point speed reduction = 10 × 0.4 = 4km/h
Free speed = 80 – 0 – 0 – 4 – 4 = 72km/h
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 313
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
APPENDIX 3: TRAFFIC DATA AND TRAVEL TIME ESTIMATION > DETERMINING THE FREE SPEED OF TWO-LANE RURAL
ROADS
The procedure adopted in this section provides a realistic but approximate method for assessing travel
times. Alternatively, the Transportation Research Board (1994) Highway capacity manual (HCM) provides
a more detailed methodology for the evaluation of local improvements, such as design speed increases,
and climbing and passing lanes, and the computer programme TRARR may be used for detailed
analyses.
The definition of design speed used in this section is that used by the HCM and the Austroads (1988)
Guide to traffic engineering practice part 2 roadway capacity.
Procedure
The free speed of a two-lane rural road is determined by the speed environment that can be
approximated by the average design speed of the road section under consideration and the associated
approaches.
Follow the steps below to determine the free speed of a two-lane rural road section.
Table A55: Steps to determine the free speed of a two-lane rural road
Step Action
1 Obtain the following basic data for the road section:
• length of road section
• centreline length of each curve including transitions
• length of each straight (tangent)
• design speed of the straights (tangents)
• design speed of the curves.
2 Calculate the travel time for each curve and straight, as per steps 3 and 4.
Note: It is acceptable to assume an abrupt change in speed where straights and curves meet.
3 Calculate the travel time on curves (including transitions).
Example:
Curve 1 length = 0.200km
Curve 1 design speed = 80km/h
Curve 1 travel time = 0.2/80 × 60 = 0.150 minutes
Curve 2 length = 0.150km
Curve 2 design speed = 70km/h
Curve 2 travel time = 0.15/70 × 60 = 0.129 minutes
Curve 3 length = 0.100km
Curve 3 design speed = 70km/h
Curve 3 travel time = 0.10/70 × 60 = 0.086 minutes
Total curve travel times = 0.150 + 0.129 + 0.086 = 0.365 minutes
4 Calculate the travel time on the straights (tangents)
Note: Unless constrained by other design criteria the design speed for straights (tangents)
should be assumed to be 100km/h in severe terrain and a maximum of 120km/h in gentler
country (Austroads (1989) Rural road design).
Example:
Tangent length = 0.550km
Tangent design speed = 120km/h
Tangent travel time = 0.550/120 × 60
= 0.275 minutes
5 Calculate the total travel time on the road section.
Example:
Travel time on curves = 0.365 minutes
Travel time on straights = 0.275 minutes
Total travel time = 0.365 + 0.275
= 0.640 minutes
6 Calculate the average design speed for the road section.
Example:
Road section length = 1km
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 314
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
APPENDIX 3: TRAFFIC DATA AND TRAVEL TIME ESTIMATION > DETERMINING THE FREE SPEED OF OTHER RURAL
ROADS
Step Action
Total travel time = 0.640 minutes
Average design speed = 1.000/0.640 × 60
= 93.75km/h
7 Determine the free speed as follows:
If the average design speed is … Then the free speed is…
above 100km/h 105km/h
below 100km/h 105km/h minus 13km/h for every 18km/h
reduction in design speed below 100km/h
Example:
Average design speed = 93.75km/h
Free speed = 105 - ([(100 – 93.75) / 18] × 13)
= 100.5km/h
Table A56: Steps to determine the free speed of an 'other urban road'
Step Action
1 Determine the classification of the other urban road section as follows:
If the design category of the And the functional category Then the road classification
road section is … is … is …
suburban principal Class I
suburban minor Class II
intermediate principal Class II
intermediate minor Class II or III
urban principal Class II or III
urban minor Class III
Design category
Criterion Suburban Intermediate Urban
Driveway/access Low density Moderate density High density
density
Arterial type Multi-lane divided, Multi-lane divided or Undivided one-
undivided or two-lane undivided, one-way, way, two-way,
with shoulders two-lane two or more
lanes
Parking No Some Significant
Separate right-turn Yes Usually Some
lanes
Signals/km 0.6–3.0 2–6 4–8
Pedestrian activity Little Some Usually
Roadside Low to medium Medium to moderate High
development density
Functional category
Criterion Principal Minor
Mobility function Very important Important
Access function Very minor Substantial
Points connected Motorways, important Principal arterials
activity centres, major traffic
generators
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 315
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
APPENDIX 3: TRAFFIC DATA AND TRAVEL TIME ESTIMATION > DETERMINING THE CAPACITY OF ROAD SECTIONS
Step Action
Predominant trips served Relatively long trips Trips of moderate length
between major points and within relatively small
through-trips entering, geographical areas
leaving, and passing
through the city
2 Determine the free speed for the road section as follows:
If the road classification is … Then the range of likely And a typical free speed
free speeds are between would be …
…
Class I 60 and 65km/h 63km/h
Class II 50 and 60km/h 55km/h
Class III 45 and 55km/h 50km/h
Table A57: Steps to select the appropriate procedure for determining the capacity of road
sections
Step Action
1 Select the appropriate procedure for determining the capacity of each road section as
follows:
If the road section is … Then go to …
a motorway section Determining the capacity of motorways
a multi-lane road Determining the capacity of multi-lane roads
a two-lane rural road Determining the capacity of two-lane rural
roads
other urban road Calculating the time period total average
travel time
It is not necessary to determine capacity for
travel time. However, the capacities below
are required when determining the additional
congestion vehicle operating cost.
Road class Capacity
Class I 1200 veh/lane/hour
Class II 900 veh/lane/hour
Class III 600 veh/lane/hour
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 316
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
APPENDIX 3: TRAFFIC DATA AND TRAVEL TIME ESTIMATION > DETERMINING THE CAPACITY OF MOTORWAYS
2 Once the capacity has been determined go to Determining whether vehicle interactions are
significant.
Table A58: Steps to determine the capacity of a motorway section with separate motorway
components in each direction of travel
Step Action
1 Determine the basic capacity for the motorway section as follows:
If the road section has ... Then use a basic capacity of …
2 through lanes 4500 pcu/h
3 through lanes 6900 pcu/h
4 through lanes 9600 pcu/h
2 Determine the passenger car equivalent to be used for trucks for the motorway section as
follows:
If the terrain type is … Then use a passenger car equivalent for
trucks (Et) of …
level 1.7 pcu
rolling 4.0 pcu
mountainous 8.0 pcu
3 Calculate the adjustment factor for trucks using the passenger car equivalent for trucks (E t)
determined in step 2.
Adjustment factor (ft) = 1/ (1 + Pt × (Et - 1))
where Pt = the proportion of trucks in the traffic
stream during the peak period.
Example:
Terrain type = rolling
Proportion of trucks (Pt) = 0.12
Pcu for trucks (Et) = 4.0 pcu
Adjustment factor (ft) = 1/(1 + 0.12 × (4.0 - 1 ))
= 0.735
4 Calculate the motorway section capacity by multiplying the basic capacity, determined in step
1, by the adjustment factor for trucks (ft) determined in step 3.
Motorway section capacity = basic capacity × ft
Example:
Through lanes = 3 lanes
Basic capacity = 6900 pcu/h
Adjustment factor (ft) = 0.735
Motorway section capacity = 6900 × 0.735
= 5072veh/h
Using field measurements
If actual field measurements at the site give a different capacity from that which is determined above, then
the field measurements should be used. However, if field measurements are used, then the analyst must
prove that the measurements are representative of the average capacity in a variety of conditions.
Accounting for auxiliary lanes
Auxiliary lanes within road sections may contribute to the road’s capacity in which case the detailed
procedures of the HCM shall be used. Otherwise the auxiliary lanes shall be considered not to contribute
to the capacity.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 317
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
APPENDIX 3: TRAFFIC DATA AND TRAVEL TIME ESTIMATION > DETERMINING THE CAPACITY OF MULTI-LANE ROADS
Step Action
1 Obtain ‘the sum of the basic free speed reductions’ for the multi-lane road section, as
determined in Table A57.
Example:
Free speed reductions for:
dividing median = 0km/h
lane width = 0km/h
lateral clearance = 4km/h
access points = 4km/h
Sum of the basic free speed reductions
= 8km/h
Note: If the free speed for the multi-lane road section was measured rather than estimated,
then use step 1 of the procedure in Table A57 to determine the multi-lane road basic free
speed, and subtract the measured free speed to obtain the equivalent of ‘the sum of the
basic free speed reductions’.
2 Determine the capacity of the multi-lane road section as follows:
If the sum of the basic free speed reduction Then use a capacity of …
is …
zero 2200 veh/h per lane
2200 veh/h per lane minus 10veh/h per lane
between 0 and 30km/h for every km/h of basic free speed
reductions
above 30km/h 1900 veh/h per lane
Example:
Sum of the basic free speed reductions = 8km/h
Road section capacity = 2200 - 8 × 10
= 2120 veh/h per lane
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 318
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
APPENDIX 3: TRAFFIC DATA AND TRAVEL TIME ESTIMATION > DETERMINING THE CAPACITY OF TWO-LANE RURAL
ROADS
Step Action
1 Determine the adjustment factor for traffic directional distribution during the time period as
follows:
If the directional distribution is … Then use an adjustment factor of:
100/0 0.71
90/10 0.77
80/20 0.83
70/30 0.89
60/40 0.94
50/50 1.00
2 Determine the total roadway width. The total roadway width equals the lane width(s) plus
sealed shoulder width. Round to the nearest metre.
3 With the total roadway width determined in step 2 determine the adjustment factor for
trafficable width as follows:
If the total roadway width is… Then use an adjustment factor of:
8m or greater 1.00
7m 0.91
6m 0.82
5m 0.73
4m 0.65
less than 4m 0.60
4 Determine the passenger car equivalent for trucks for the road section as follows:
If the terrain type is… Then use a passenger car equivalent for
trucks (Et ) of:
level 2.2 pcu
rolling 5.0 pcu
mountainous 10.0 pcu
5 Calculate the adjustment factor for trucks using the passenger car equivalent for trucks (E t)
determined in step 4.
Adjustment factor (ft) = 1/(1 + Pt × (Et- 1 ))
Where Pt is the proportion of trucks in the traffic stream during the time period
Example:
Terrain type = rolling
Proportion of trucks (Pt) = 0.10
pcu for trucks (Et) = 5.0 pcu
Adjustment factor (ft) = 1/[1 + 0.10 × (5.0 – 1))]
= 0.714
6 Calculate the road section capacity by multiplying the ideal two-way capacity of 2800veh/h by
the adjustment factors determined in steps 1, 3 and 5.
Road section capacity = Ideal capacity × adjustment factor for directional
distribution × adjustment factor for trafficable width × ft
Example:
Directional distribution = 70/30
Trafficable width = 7m
Adjustment factors:
directional distribution = 0.89
trafficable width = 0.91
trucks = 0.714
Road section capacity = 2800 × 0.89 × 0.91 × 0.714
= 1620 veh/h
7 Calculate the peak direction capacity using the road section capacity determined in step 6.
Peak direction capacity = road section capacity x proportion of traffic in the
peak direction
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 319
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
APPENDIX 3: TRAFFIC DATA AND TRAVEL TIME ESTIMATION > DETERMINING WHETHER VEHICLE INTERACTIONS ARE
SIGNIFICANT
Step Action
Example:
Proportion of traffic in
peak direction = 0.7
Peak direction capacity = 1620 × 0.7
= 1134 veh/h
Table A61: Steps to determine whether the effects of vehicle interactions are significant
Step Action
1 Use the capacity for the road section determined in Table A57.
2 Take a time period with its corresponding traffic volume (demand) as determined in Table A52.
3 Calculate the volume to capacity ratio.
Example:
Time period = 0700 to 0900
Time period traffic vol = 6202 vehicles
Traffic flow = 6202/2
= 3101 veh/h
Capacity = 4300 veh/h
Volume to capacity ratio = 3101/4300
= 0.72
4 Determine whether the effects of vehicle interactions are significant as follows:
If the road section is a … And the volume to Then vehicle interactions …
capacity ratio is …
motorway section greater than 0.7 shall be considered (continue to
Types of delays)
motorway section 0.7 or less are not considered (go to Table
A68)
multi-lane road greater than 0.7 shall be considered (continue to
Types of delays)
multi-lane road 0.7 or less are not considered (go to Table
A68)
two-lane rural road greater than 0.7 shall be considered (continue to
Types of delays)
two-lane rural road 0.7 or less are not considered (go to Table
A68)
5 Repeat steps 2 to 4 for any other time periods in which traffic volumes are likely to result in
significant vehicle interactions.
Types of delays
This section describes the difference between vehicle interaction delay and bottleneck delay, explaining
why the two types of delay require different procedures to calculate their levels.
The diagram below shows approximately when vehicle interaction (or random) delay and bottleneck (or
over-saturation) delay occur.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 320
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
APPENDIX 3: TRAFFIC DATA AND TRAVEL TIME ESTIMATION > AVERAGE PEAK INTERVAL TRAFFIC INTENSITY
Delay
Over-saturation delay
Random delay
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 321
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
APPENDIX 3: TRAFFIC DATA AND TRAVEL TIME ESTIMATION > DETERMINING THE PEAK INTERVAL
Peak interval
Demand
Time period
Time
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 322
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
APPENDIX 3: TRAFFIC DATA AND TRAVEL TIME ESTIMATION > DETERMINING THE PEAK INTERVAL
Procedure
Follow the steps below to determine the peak interval.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 323
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
APPENDIX 3: TRAFFIC DATA AND TRAVEL TIME ESTIMATION > CALCULATING THE AVERAGE PEAK INTERVAL TRAFFIC
INTENSITY
Step Action
8 Calculate the peak interval end, which is the notional time at which the flow rate fell below the
average time period traffic intensity (Ftp).
Peak interval end = ti + (vi-1 - Ftp)/(vi-1 - vi) x interval
Example:
Peak interval end = 8:30 + (1140 - 1070)/(1140 - 1020) × 15
= 8:38.8
9 Calculate the length of the peak interval.
Example:
Peak interval start = 7:32.8
Peak interval end = 8:38.8
Length of peak interval = 8:38.8 - 7:32.8
= 66.0 minutes
Table A63: Steps to calculate the average peak interval traffic intensity
Step Action
1 Calculate the peak interval traffic volume.
Example:
Peak interval start = 7:32.8
Peak interval end = 8:38.8
Volume 7:30–7:45 = 1200 vehicles
Volume 7:45–8:00 = 1280 vehicles
Volume 8.00–8.15 = 1240 vehicles
Volume 8:15–8:30 = 1140 vehicles
Volume 8:30–8:45 = 1020 vehicles
Peak interval traffic vol = (7:45 - 7:32.8)/15 × 1200 + 1280 +
1240 + 1140 + (8:38.8 - 8:30)/15 × 1020
= 5234 vehicles
2 Calculate the average peak interval traffic intensity (Fpi).
Example:
Length of peak interval = 66.0 minutes
Average peak interval traffic intensity (Fpi)
= 5234 × 60/66.0
= 4758 veh/h
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 324
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
APPENDIX 3: TRAFFIC DATA AND TRAVEL TIME ESTIMATION > CALCULATING THE VOLUME TO CAPACITY RATIO
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 325
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
APPENDIX 3: TRAFFIC DATA AND TRAVEL TIME ESTIMATION > CALCULATING THE ADDITIONAL TRAVEL TIME
Step Action
3 Determine the peak interval additional travel time factor from the tables below, using the VC
ratio determined in Table A64 for two-lane rural roads only.
Additional travel time factor for level terrain
Percent no-passing
VC ratio
0 20 40 60 80 100
0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00
0.10 0.04 0.04 0.05 0.05 0.06 0.06
0.20 0.08 0.08 0.09 0.10 0.10 0.11
0.30 0.11 0.12 0.12 0.13 0.14 0.14
0.40 0.14 0.14 0.15 0.16 0.16 0.17
0.50 0.16 0.16 0.17 0.18 0.18 0.19
0.60 0.18 0.19 0.19 0.20 0.20 0.21
0.70 0.21 0.21 0.21 0.22 0.22 0.23
0.80 0.24 0.24 0.24 0.25 0.25 0.25
0.90 0.27 0.27 0.28 0.28 0.28 0.28
1.00 0.32 0.32 0.32 0.32 0.32 0.32
Additional travel time factor for rolling terrain
Percent no-passing
VC ratio
0 20 40 60 80 100
0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.02
0.10 0.06 0.06 0.07 0.08 0.09 0.09
0.20 0.11 0.12 0.13 0.13 0.14 0.15
0.30 0.14 0.15 0.16 0.17 0.18 0.18
0.40 0.16 0.17 0.19 0.20 0.20 0.20
0.50 0.18 0.19 0.21 0.22 0.23 0.23
0.60 0.20 0.22 0.24 0.25 0.26 0.26
0.70 0.23 0.26 0.28 0.30 0.31 0.31
0.80 0.29 0.32 0.35 0.37 0.38 0.39
0.90 0.38 0.42 0.45 0.47 0.49 0.50
1.00 0.50 0.55 0.59 0.62 0.64 0.65
Additional travel time factor for mountainous terrain
Percent no-passing
VC ratio
0 20 40 60 80 100
0.00 0.00 0.00 0.01 0.02 0.03 0.03
0.10 0.06 0.09 0.11 0.12 0.13 0.14
0.20 0.13 0.16 0.19 0.20 0.22 0.23
0.30 0.19 0.22 0.25 0.27 0.29 0.30
0.40 0.24 0.28 0.31 0.33 0.35 0.37
0.50 0.29 0.33 0.36 0.39 0.42 0.44
0.60 0.35 0.40 0.43 0.47 0.50 0.53
0.70 0.43 0.48 0.52 0.56 0.59 0.63
0.80 0.54 0.59 0.64 0.68 0.72 0.75
0.90 0.68 0.73 0.78 0.83 0.87 0.92
1.00 0.86 0.92 0.98 1.03 1.07 1.12
Alternatively calculate Fdr directly using the expression:
Fdr = min(a + b.PNP + d.PNp2 g.PNP3 + c.VC ratio + e.VC ratio2 + h.VC ratio3 + f.PNP.VC ratio
+ i.PNP.VC ratio2 + j.PNP2.VC ratio ,0)
where: VC ratio is the volume to capacity flow ratio
PNP is the percent no-passing
And the coefficients a to j are given below.
Coefficient Level terrain Rolling terrain Mountainous terrain
a -1.906 × 10-2 -2.658 × 10-2 -3.039 × 10-2
b 1.420 × 10-4 1.640 × 10-4 1.480 × 10-3
c 0.617 1.008 1.059
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 326
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
APPENDIX 3: TRAFFIC DATA AND TRAVEL TIME ESTIMATION > CALCULATING BOTTLENECK DELAY
Step Action
d 3.260 × 10-6 3.610 × 10-6 1.378 × 10-5
e -0.771 -1.918 -1.515
f 6.43 × 10-4 6.220 × 10-4 1.570 × 10-3
g -2.42 × 10-8 -9.470 × 10-9 5.260 × 10-8
h 0.496 1.440 1.346
i -8.70 × 10-4 -1.748 × 10-3 2.897 × 10-4
j -6.49 × 10-7 -1.320 × 10-5 -1.379 × 10-6
4 Calculate the peak interval additional travel time by multiplying the free speed travel time in
Table A53 by the factor from step 2 or 3.
Peak interval additional = free speed travel time x peak interval
travel time additional travel time factor (Fdr)
Example 1: (motorway or multi-lane highway):
Free speed travel time = 0.571 mins/km
VC ratio = 0.938
Fdr (from step 2) = 0.27 × (0.938 - 0.70)
= 0.0643
Peak interval additional travel time = 0.571 × 0.0643
= 0.037 mins/km
Time period additional travel time = peak interval additional travel time
= 0.037 mins/km
Example 2: (two-lane rural road):
Free speed travel time = 0.636 mins/km
Terrain type = rolling
Percent no-passing = 60%
VC ratio = 1.10
Fdr (from tables in step 3) = 0.62
Peak interval additional travel time = 0.636 × 0.62
= 0.394 mins/km
Time period additional travel time = peak interval additional travel time
= 0.394 mins/km
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 327
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
APPENDIX 3: TRAFFIC DATA AND TRAVEL TIME ESTIMATION > CALCULATING BOTTLENECK DELAY
Step Action
7:30–7:45 591
7:45–8:00 600
8:00–8:15 591
8:15–8:30 475
8:30–8:45 264
8:45–9:00 250
9:00–9:15 234
5 At each time interval, calculate the cumulative demand with a running total of observed
traffic volume since the time period start.
Cumulative demand at time interval = sum of observed traffic volume since time period
start.
Example from step 4:
Cumulative demand for time interval 8:00–8:15 = 264 + 475 + 591 + 600 + 591
= 2521
6 At each time interval, calculate the vehicles discharged. If the traffic volume for the time
interval is below the road section capacity then all the traffic is discharged. Only the number
of vehicles equivalent to the road section capacity is discharged if the traffic volume
exceeds capacity.
Example from step 4:
Time interval = 8:00–8:15
Capacity = 500 vehicles
Traffic volume = 591 vehicles
Vehicles discharged = minimum of traffic volume or
capacity
= minimum (591, 500)
= 500
7 At each time interval, calculate the cumulative discharge with a running total of vehicles
discharged since the time period start.
Cumulative discharge at time interval = sum of vehicles discharged since
time period start
8 At each time interval, calculate the queue at the end of the interval when traffic volume
exceeds capacity.
Example from step 4:
Time interval = 7:30–7:45
Traffic volume = 591 vehicles
Capacity = 500 vehicles
Queue at end of interval
= traffic volume - capacity, if traffic volume >
capacity
= 0, if traffic volume ≤ capacity
= 591 - 500
= 91 vehicles
9 At each time interval, calculate the queue at the start of the interval. This is the queue at the
end of the previous interval.
Time interval = 7:30–7:45
Queue at start of interval
= queue at end of previous interval
= 91 vehicles
10 At each time interval, calculate the average delay in vehicle minutes.
Average delay = interval time step × (queue at end of interval
+ queue at start of interval)/2
11 Sum the average delays over the entire time period to obtain the time period total delay.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 328
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
APPENDIX 3: TRAFFIC DATA AND TRAVEL TIME ESTIMATION > DETERMINING WHETHER TO CONSIDER PEAK
SPREADING
Step Action
12 Calculate the time period average delay per vehicle from the time period total delay divided
by the cumulative discharge of vehicles at the time period end.
Average delay per vehicle = total delay/cumulative discharge of vehicles
at the time period end
A worked example of the bottleneck delay procedure is provided in Appendix 8: Worked examples.
Step Action
1 Calculate the average delay per delayed vehicle, using the time period average delay per
vehicle determined in Table A66.
Average delay per delayed vehicle
= Time period average delay per vehicle x
(Time period traffic volume/sum of traffic volumes of intervals with an end queue)
Example (using the calculating bottleneck delay example in Appendix 8: Worked examples):
Average delay per delayed vehicle
= 3.37 × (3744 / (591 + 600 + 591 + 475 + 264))
= 3.37 × (3744 / 2521)
= 5.0mins/veh
2 Determine whether peak spreading should be considered as follows:
If the average minutes delay And there is … Then peak spreading …
per delayed vehicle is …
between 0 and 15 does not need to be
considered
between 15 and 25 an alternative route does not need to be
considered
between 15 and 25 no alternative route shall be considered, see
Applying variable trip matrix
with growth constraint
techniques
25 or greater shall be considered, see
Applying variable trip matrix
with growth constraint
techniques
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 329
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
APPENDIX 3: TRAFFIC DATA AND TRAVEL TIME ESTIMATION > DETERMINING THE ADDITIONAL TRAVEL TIME
RESULTING FROM SPEED CHANGE CYCLES
Determining the additional travel time resulting from speed change cycles
If vehicles are required to slow to negotiate some isolated feature and then accelerate back to cruise
speed the travel time estimated above must be increased to account for the time lost during this speed
change cycle. Where the initial cruise speed and the minimum speed are available, tables in Appendix 4:
Vehicle operating cost tables provide the amount of additional travel time in seconds for speed change
cycles.
In the absence of measured data, the additional travel time that occurs as a result of having to slow for
substandard horizontal curves can be approximated using this procedure.
Procedure
Follow the steps below to determine the additional travel time resulting from speed change cycles
associated with substandard curves.
Table A68: Steps to determine the additional travel time of speed change cycles from substandard
curves
Step Action
1 Determine the curve negotiating speed for each vehicle type in the traffic mix.
The desired negotiation speed for an isolated curve (S c) is related to the ideal approach
speed (Sa) and the curve radius (R) by the following equation:
Sc = a0 + a1.Sa + a2 / R
where: Sa = f1.FS
Fs is the average free speed determined from Table A53 and Table A56 and the
coefficients f1,a0, a1, and a2 are as follows:
Vehicle type f1 a0 a1 a2
Car 1.00 45.21 0.5833 -3892
LCV 0.97 54.51 0.4531 -3337
MCV 0.89 51.77 0.4744 -3245
HCVI 0.91 59.16 0.4068 -3506
HCVII 0.91 69.57 0.3085 -3768
Bus 0.91 59.16 0.4068 -3506
Example:
A horizontal curve of radius 100m exists within a road section where the free speed is
estimated at 94.33km/h.
Ideal approach speed = 0.89 × 94.33
For MCV = 84km/h
Desired negotiation speed for MCV
= 51.77 + 0.4744 × 84 - 3245/100
= 59km/h
2 Determine the initial operating speed of the road section. The operating speed is the sum
of the free speed travel time and the time period additional travel time all divided by the
section length. This accounts for the reduction in the ideal approach speed as a result of
traffic interactions.
Initial operating speed = length/(TTFS + TTATT)
Example:
1km at free speed travel time
= 0.636mins/km
1km additional travel time for vehicle interactions (from Table A65)
= 0.636 × 0.2
= 0.127 mins/km
Initial operating speed = 1.00/(0.636 + 0.127) × 60
= 1.00/0.763 × 60
= 79km/h
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 330
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
APPENDIX 3: TRAFFIC DATA AND TRAVEL TIME ESTIMATION > CALCULATING THE TIME PERIOD TOTAL AVERAGE
TRAVEL TIME
Step Action
3 The additional travel time associated with speed change cycles is then determined from
the appropriate table in Appendix 4: Vehicle operating cost tables.
Note: Where the desired negotiating speed is greater than the operating speed no speed
change will occur.
Example:
Using Table A100
Initial cruise speed for all vehicles = 79km/h
Curve speed for MCV = 59km/h
MCV additional travel time per speed change = 2.0 seconds
4 Calculate the total speed change cycle travel time for a road section with the additional
following information.
Traffic volume for the time period
Traffic composition (default values available in Table A47)
For each vehicle type:
proportion in traffic from traffic composition
number of vehicles = traffic volume × proportion in traffic
additional travel time = number of vehicles × additional travel time for
speed change cycles
Sum over all vehicle types to obtain the total additional travel time.
Table A69: Steps to calculate the time period total average travel time per vehicle
Step Action
1 Use the following previously calculated values:
• free speed travel time (Table A53)
• time period additional travel time (Table A65)
• time period average delay per vehicle (Table A66)
• additional travel time due to speed changes (Table A68).
Notes:
‘Other urban roads’ only have a free speed travel time. ‘Other urban roads’ do not exhibit
reductions in travel times with increasing traffic volumes. All delays due to increasing traffic
volumes can be attributed to intersections as calculated in the procedures for traffic signals,
priority intersections and roundabouts below.
Time period additional travel time is only calculated if the VC ratio exceeds 0.7 (see Table
A61).
Bottleneck delay is only calculated if demand exceeds capacity at some time during the
time period.
2 Multiply the free speed travel time and the time period additional travel time by the road
section length.
3 Sum the values in step 2 with the bottleneck delay and additional travel time due to speed
change to get the time period total average travel time per vehicle.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 331
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
APPENDIX 3: TRAFFIC DATA AND TRAVEL TIME ESTIMATION > TRAFFIC SIGNALS
Traffic signals
Travel time delays associated with traffic signals are the result of a complex interaction between arrivals
on opposing phases, the response of the signal controller to detector impulses and external control
commands, and vehicle driver responses. The physical layout, location and phasing strategy also affect
operations.
Commonly available analysis procedures are based on simplifying assumptions that reduce an essentially
dynamic and stochastic process to a deterministic approximation of real events. Reliable estimates of
delay require the careful selection of values for the governing variables and a thorough understanding of
traffic operations at each site.
While the procedures of the HCM provide a useful guide, the more commonly understood methods of
Akcelik R (1981) should be followed.
This appendix uses HCM to derive a major modification to the ARR 123 methods to account for the
proximity of other signals including linking or coordination.
Capacity or saturation flow rate
The average delay to all vehicles, irrespective of the turns made, shall be the basis of the analysis. For
this reason, the methodology is approach based, not movement based.
Ideally, saturation flow rates for each approach should be determined from direct observation at the site.
Approach saturation flow rates for the relevant lane groups can be estimated as specified below.
The procedure consists of adjusting an ideal saturation flow rate of 2000 passenger cars units per hour of
green by the factors tabulated in Table A70, Table A71, Table A73 and Table A74.
Parking movements refers to the number of such movements, in and out, within a length of 50m on either
side of the intersection.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 332
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
APPENDIX 3: TRAFFIC DATA AND TRAVEL TIME ESTIMATION > TRAFFIC SIGNALS
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 333
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
APPENDIX 3: TRAFFIC DATA AND TRAVEL TIME ESTIMATION > TRAFFIC SIGNALS
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 334
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
APPENDIX 3: TRAFFIC DATA AND TRAVEL TIME ESTIMATION > PRIORITY INTERSECTIONS
Priority intersections
Priority intersections include all intersections where entry is not controlled by traffic signals. Roundabouts
are a particular class, and are separately considered in a procedure below.
Travel time delays are only incurred by movements where the priority of entry is controlled by stop signs,
give way signs, or by the general intersection driving rules. Three levels of priority are involved:
1. movements that have priority
2. movements that yield the right-of-way to the priority flows
3. movements that must give way to both the above categories.
Only priority levels 2 and 3 will experience delays.
Minimum headway in conflicting flow
The distribution of headways in the opposing traffic streams in turn depends on other variables, and is
influenced by the proximity of signal controlled intersections. When the priority intersection is remote from
traffic signals and the conflicting flows well below the capacities of their approach roadways, the
distribution of headways in the conflicting traffic flows can be assumed to be random with a minimum
headway of either 2.0 seconds (single-lane conflict) or 0.5 seconds in other cases.
Capacity
The capacity of a non-priority movement shall be determined as a function of the following variables:
• the distribution of headways, being the time between successive users of the conflict area
• the critical gap in the opposing traffic flow through which a non-priority movement vehicle will
move
• the follow-up headway being the time interval between successive vehicles which use the same
gap in the opposing traffic stream.
The capacity of the non-priority movement shall be then estimated from:
c = (3600 / Tf) × exp (-V × To / 3600)
where: c is capacity
To is Tg – Hm (Hm = 0.5 or 2.0)
Hm is minimum headway in conflicting flow
Tg is critical gap
Tf is follow-up headway
V is conflicting volume during peak interval, veh/h.
To, Tg, Hm and Tf are expressed in seconds, and c and V are expressed in vehicles per hour.
Critical gap and follow up headways
The critical gap (Tg) and follow-up headway (Tf) are related and depend on the speed of the conflicting
traffic flow, the class of control, and the movement type. In the absence of actual values determined by
observations at the site or similar sites elsewhere in New Zealand, the values in Table A77 should be
used.
Where the turning movement is required to cross more than one lane, a further 0.5 seconds shall be
added to the values of the table.
If the left turn from a minor road is provided with an acceleration lane, the critical gap of the table shall be
reduced by 1.0 seconds.
The follow-up headway is related to the critical gap, by the expression: Tf = 2.0 + 0.2 Tg
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 335
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Roundabouts
Roundabouts are a special case of a priority intersection. Delays at each approach can be estimated in a
manner similar to that given in the procedure for priority intersections, ie each approach can be
considered as an independent elemental intersection with one-way conflicting flows circulating round the
central island.
Procedure
The procedures and methods of Austroads (1993) Guide to traffic engineering practice part 6:
roundabouts shall be used to obtain the capacities of each approach lane.
The VC ratio for each approach lane shall be estimated as the expected average flow during the peak
interval using that lane divided by the capacity.
The peak interval travel time is equivalent to the peak interval average delay for each lane. The peak
interval delay shall be estimated from Table A78 up to a maximum VC ratio of 1.05, and the average peak
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 336
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
period delay for the approach shall be estimated as the weighted average of the individual approach
lanes.
The performance of a roundabout becomes indeterminate for high flows, much beyond the capacity of an
approach, due to a tendency for the flows to ‘lock’ round the central island.
The time period total average travel time is the average delay during the time period, and shall be
estimated from the peak interval delay.
Where a traffic model has been used to calculate delays at roundabouts, the provisions of the procedure
for traffic signals also apply.
Back to 3.6 Impact on network productivity and utilisation: Travel time estimation procedures >>
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 337
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 338
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Table A80: LCV VOC by speed and gradient (cents/km – July 2015)
Speed Gradient in percent (both directions)
(km/h) 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
10 44.2 44.2 44.3 44.3 44.5 44.7 44.9 45.2 45.6 46.1 46.7 47.3 48.1
15 39.2 39.3 39.4 39.5 39.8 40.0 40.4 40.8 41.4 42.0 42.7 43.5 44.4
20 35.5 35.6 35.7 35.9 36.2 36.6 37.0 37.5 38.1 38.8 39.6 40.5 41.5
25 32.9 33.0 33.1 33.3 33.6 34.0 34.5 35.0 35.7 36.4 37.3 38.3 39.4
30 30.9 31.0 31.2 31.4 31.8 32.2 32.7 33.2 33.9 34.7 35.7 36.7 37.8
35 29.6 29.7 29.8 30.1 30.4 30.8 31.4 32.0 32.7 33.5 34.5 35.6 36.8
40 28.6 28.7 28.9 29.2 29.5 29.9 30.5 31.1 31.8 32.7 33.7 34.8 36.0
45 28.0 28.1 28.3 28.5 28.9 29.3 29.9 30.5 31.3 32.2 33.2 34.3 35.6
50 27.6 27.7 27.9 28.2 28.5 29.0 29.5 30.2 31.0 31.9 32.9 34.1 35.4
55 27.5 27.6 27.8 28.0 28.4 28.8 29.4 30.1 30.9 31.8 32.8 34.0 35.3
60 27.5 27.6 27.8 28.0 28.4 28.9 29.4 30.1 30.9 31.9 32.9 34.1 35.5
65 27.7 27.8 27.9 28.2 28.6 29.0 29.6 30.3 31.1 32.0 33.1 34.3 35.7
70 28.0 28.0 28.2 28.5 28.8 29.3 29.9 30.6 31.4 32.3 33.4 34.7 36.0
75 28.3 28.4 28.6 28.8 29.2 29.7 30.2 30.9 31.8 32.7 33.8 35.1 36.4
80 28.8 28.9 29.0 29.3 29.6 30.1 30.7 31.4 32.2 33.2 34.3 35.5 36.9
85 29.3 29.4 29.5 29.8 30.1 30.6 31.2 31.9 32.7 33.7 34.8 36.1 37.5
90 29.9 30.0 30.1 30.4 30.7 31.2 31.8 32.5 33.3 34.3 35.4 36.7 38.1
95 30.5 30.6 30.7 31.0 31.3 31.8 32.4 33.1 34.0 34.9 36.1 37.3 38.8
100 31.2 31.3 31.4 31.7 32.0 32.5 33.1 33.8 34.6 35.6 36.7 38.0 39.5
105 31.9 32.0 32.1 32.4 32.7 33.2 33.8 34.5 35.3 36.3 37.5 38.8 40.2
110 32.7 32.7 32.9 33.1 33.4 33.9 34.5 35.2 36.1 37.1 38.2 39.5 41.0
115 33.5 33.5 33.6 33.9 34.2 34.7 35.3 36.0 36.8 37.8 39.0 40.3 41.7
120 34.3 34.3 34.4 34.7 35.0 35.5 36.1 36.8 37.6 38.6 39.8 41.1 42.5
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 339
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Table A81: MCV VOC by speed and gradient (cents/km – July 2015)
Speed Gradient in percent (both directions)
(km/h) 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
10 68.1 68.5 69.6 71.3 73.5 76.0 78.7 81.6 84.6 87.4 90.1 92.6 94.6
15 63.2 63.5 64.5 66.2 68.3 70.8 73.7 76.7 79.9 83.0 86.0 88.8 91.3
20 59.7 59.9 60.8 62.4 64.5 67.1 70.0 73.1 76.4 79.7 82.9 85.9 88.7
25 57.2 57.3 58.2 59.7 61.9 64.5 67.4 70.6 74.0 77.4 80.8 84.0 86.9
30 55.6 55.6 56.4 58.0 60.1 62.7 65.7 68.9 72.4 75.9 79.4 82.7 85.8
35 54.6 54.6 55.3 56.8 58.9 61.5 64.5 67.8 71.4 75.0 78.5 82.0 85.3
40 54.1 54.0 54.7 56.1 58.2 60.8 63.9 67.2 70.8 74.5 78.1 81.7 85.1
45 53.9 53.7 54.4 55.8 57.9 60.5 63.6 67.0 70.6 74.3 78.1 81.7 85.2
50 54.0 53.8 54.4 55.8 57.9 60.5 63.6 67.0 70.7 74.4 78.3 82.0 85.5
55 54.4 54.1 54.7 56.1 58.1 60.7 63.8 67.3 71.0 74.8 78.7 82.5 86.1
60 54.9 54.6 55.1 56.5 58.5 61.2 64.3 67.7 71.4 75.3 79.2 83.1 86.8
65 55.5 55.2 55.7 57.1 59.1 61.7 64.8 68.3 72.1 76.0 79.9 83.9 87.6
70 56.3 55.9 56.5 57.8 59.8 62.4 65.5 69.0 72.8 76.7 80.8 84.7 88.6
75 57.2 56.8 57.3 58.6 60.6 63.2 66.3 69.9 73.7 77.6 81.7 85.7 89.6
80 58.2 57.8 58.2 59.5 61.5 64.1 67.2 70.8 74.6 78.6 82.7 86.8 90.7
85 59.3 58.8 59.2 60.5 62.5 65.1 68.2 71.8 75.6 79.6 83.8 87.9 91.9
90 60.4 59.9 60.3 61.5 63.5 66.1 69.3 72.8 76.7 80.7 84.9 89.1 93.1
95 61.6 61.0 61.4 62.6 64.6 67.2 70.4 73.9 77.8 81.9 86.1 90.3 94.4
100 62.8 62.2 62.6 63.8 65.8 68.4 71.5 75.1 79.0 83.1 87.3 91.5 95.6
105 64.0 63.4 63.8 65.0 66.9 69.5 72.7 76.3 80.2 84.3 88.5 92.8 97.0
110 65.3 64.7 65.0 66.2 68.1 70.7 73.9 77.5 81.4 85.5 89.8 94.1 98.3
115 66.6 65.9 66.3 67.4 69.4 72.0 75.1 78.7 82.7 86.8 91.1 95.5 99.7
120 67.9 67.2 67.5 68.7 70.6 73.2 76.4 80.0 83.9 88.1 92.5 96.8 101.1
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 340
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Table A82: HCVI VOC by speed and gradient (cents/km – July 2015)
Speed Gradient in percent (both directions)
(km/h) 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
10 118.9 118.9 120.5 123.4 127.4 132.2 137.7 143.6 149.7 155.6 161.3 166.4 170.8
15 111.5 111.4 112.9 115.8 119.9 124.9 130.6 136.9 143.3 149.7 156.0 161.7 166.8
20 105.4 105.1 106.6 109.5 113.6 118.8 124.7 131.1 137.9 144.7 151.3 157.5 163.1
25 100.8 100.5 101.9 104.8 109.0 114.2 120.3 126.9 133.8 140.9 147.8 154.4 160.4
30 97.5 97.2 98.5 101.5 105.7 111.0 117.2 123.9 131.1 138.3 145.5 152.4 158.7
35 95.3 94.9 96.2 99.2 103.4 108.8 115.1 122.0 129.2 136.7 144.1 151.2 157.8
40 94.0 93.5 94.8 97.7 102.0 107.5 113.8 120.8 128.2 135.8 143.4 150.7 157.5
45 93.2 92.7 94.0 96.9 101.3 106.8 113.2 120.2 127.8 135.5 143.3 150.8 157.8
50 93.0 92.4 93.7 96.7 101.0 106.6 113.0 120.2 127.9 135.7 143.6 151.3 158.5
55 93.2 92.6 93.9 96.9 101.2 106.8 113.3 120.6 128.3 136.3 144.4 152.2 159.6
60 93.8 93.2 94.5 97.4 101.8 107.4 114.0 121.3 129.1 137.2 145.4 153.4 160.9
65 94.7 94.0 95.3 98.2 102.6 108.3 114.9 122.3 130.2 138.4 146.7 154.8 162.4
70 95.8 95.1 96.3 99.3 103.7 109.4 116.1 123.5 131.5 139.8 148.2 156.4 164.2
75 97.1 96.4 97.6 100.6 105.0 110.7 117.4 125.0 133.0 141.4 149.9 158.2 166.1
80 98.6 97.8 99.1 102.0 106.5 112.2 119.0 126.5 134.7 143.1 151.7 160.1 168.1
85 100.2 99.5 100.7 103.6 108.1 113.9 120.7 128.3 136.5 145.0 153.6 162.1 170.3
90 102.0 101.2 102.4 105.4 109.9 115.6 122.5 130.1 138.4 147.0 155.7 164.3 172.6
95 103.8 103.0 104.2 107.2 111.7 117.5 124.4 132.1 140.4 149.1 157.8 166.5 174.9
100 105.8 105.0 106.2 109.1 113.7 119.5 126.4 134.1 142.5 151.2 160.1 168.9 177.3
105 107.8 107.0 108.2 111.2 115.7 121.5 128.5 136.2 144.7 153.4 162.4 171.2 179.8
110 109.9 109.1 110.3 113.2 117.8 123.7 130.6 138.4 146.9 155.7 164.7 173.7 182.3
115 112.1 111.2 112.4 115.4 119.9 125.8 132.8 140.7 149.2 158.1 167.1 176.1 184.8
120 114.3 113.4 114.6 117.6 122.1 128.1 135.1 143.0 151.5 160.5 169.6 178.6 187.4
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 341
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Table A83: HCVII VOC by speed and gradient (cents/km – July 2015)
Speed Gradient in percent (both directions)
(km/h) 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
10 172.9 178.2 186.6 197.5 210.4 224.7 239.9 255.6 271.2 286.2 300.1 312.3 322.5
15 173.1 176.8 183.9 193.7 205.8 219.6 234.7 250.5 266.5 282.1 296.9 310.4 322.1
20 169.5 172.5 178.9 188.3 200.2 214.0 229.3 245.4 262.0 278.4 294.3 309.0 322.0
25 166.0 168.5 174.6 183.9 195.8 209.8 225.3 242.0 259.2 276.4 293.2 309.0 323.3
30 163.2 165.4 171.5 180.7 192.7 207.0 222.9 240.1 257.9 275.9 293.6 310.4 325.9
35 161.3 163.4 169.4 178.7 190.9 205.5 221.8 239.5 257.9 276.7 295.2 313.0 329.5
40 160.1 162.2 168.2 177.7 190.1 205.0 221.8 239.9 259.0 278.4 297.8 316.4 333.9
45 159.7 161.7 167.8 177.5 190.2 205.4 222.5 241.2 260.9 281.0 301.0 320.5 338.9
50 159.8 161.9 168.1 178.0 190.9 206.4 224.0 243.2 263.4 284.1 304.9 325.1 344.4
55 160.5 162.6 169.0 179.0 192.2 208.1 226.1 245.7 266.4 287.8 309.2 330.2 350.2
60 161.5 163.8 170.3 180.5 194.0 210.2 228.6 248.7 269.9 291.8 313.9 335.6 356.4
65 163.0 165.3 172.0 182.4 196.2 212.7 231.5 252.0 273.7 296.2 318.8 341.2 362.7
70 164.7 167.2 174.0 184.7 198.7 215.5 234.7 256.6 277.8 300.8 324.1 347.0 369.2
75 166.8 169.3 176.3 187.2 201.5 218.6 238.1 259.5 282.2 305.7 329.5 353.0 375.9
80 169.0 171.7 178.9 190.0 204.5 222.0 241.8 263.6 286.7 310.7 335.0 359.2 382.6
85 171.5 174.3 181.6 193.0 207.8 225.5 245.7 267.8 291.4 315.8 340.7 365.4 389.5
90 174.1 177.1 184.6 196.1 211.2 229.2 249.7 272.2 296.2 321.1 346.4 371.7 396.3
95 176.9 180.0 187.7 199.4 214.7 233.1 253.9 276.8 301.1 326.5 352.3 378.1 403.3
100 179.8 183.0 190.9 202.9 218.4 237.0 258.2 281.4 306.2 331.9 358.2 384.5 410.2
105 182.8 186.2 194.2 206.4 222.2 241.1 262.6 286.1 311.3 337.4 364.2 390.9 417.2
110 186.0 189.5 197.7 210.1 226.1 245.2 267.0 290.9 316.4 343.0 370.2 397.4 424.1
115 189.2 192.8 201.2 213.8 230.0 249.5 271.5 295.8 321.6 348.6 376.2 403.8 431.1
120 192.5 196.3 204.8 217.6 234.1 253.8 276.1 300.7 326.9 354.2 382.2 410.3 438.0
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 342
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Table A84: Bus VOC by speed and gradient (cents/km – July 2015)
Speed Gradient in percent (both directions)
(km/h) 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
10 79.0 80.4 82.6 85.5 88.9 92.7 96.8 101.0 105.2 109.3 113.0 116.4 119.1
15 75.4 76.5 78.4 81.1 84.5 88.4 92.6 97.1 101.6 106.1 110.4 114.4 117.9
20 72.0 72.7 74.5 77.0 80.4 84.2 88.5 93.2 97.9 102.7 107.4 111.8 115.8
25 69.5 70.0 71.6 74.0 77.3 81.2 85.5 90.2 95.2 100.1 105.1 109.8 114.2
30 67.9 68.3 69.7 72.1 75.2 79.1 83.5 88.3 93.3 98.5 103.6 108.6 113.2
35 67.2 67.4 68.7 70.9 74.1 77.9 82.3 87.1 92.3 97.6 102.8 108.0 112.9
40 67.1 67.1 68.3 70.5 73.6 77.4 81.8 86.7 91.9 97.3 102.7 108.0 113.2
45 67.6 67.4 68.5 70.6 73.6 77.4 81.8 86.7 92.0 97.5 103.0 108.5 113.8
50 68.4 68.2 69.1 71.2 74.1 77.9 82.3 87.2 92.6 98.1 103.8 109.4 114.8
55 69.6 69.3 70.1 72.1 75.0 78.7 83.2 88.1 93.5 99.1 104.8 110.6 116.1
60 71.1 70.6 71.4 73.3 76.2 79.9 84.3 89.3 94.7 100.3 106.2 112.0 117.7
65 72.8 72.2 72.9 74.8 77.6 81.3 85.7 90.7 96.1 101.8 107.7 113.6 119.5
70 74.7 74.0 74.6 76.4 79.2 82.9 87.3 92.3 97.7 103.5 109.5 115.5 121.4
75 76.8 76.0 76.5 78.3 81.0 84.6 89.0 94.0 99.5 105.3 111.4 117.5 123.5
80 79.0 78.1 78.6 80.2 82.9 86.6 90.9 96.0 101.5 107.3 113.4 119.6 125.6
85 81.3 80.3 80.7 82.3 85.0 88.6 93.0 98.0 103.5 109.4 115.5 121.8 127.9
90 83.7 82.6 83.0 84.5 87.2 90.7 95.1 100.1 105.7 111.6 117.8 124.1 130.3
95 86.1 85.1 85.3 86.8 89.4 93.0 97.3 102.4 107.9 113.9 120.1 126.4 132.7
100 88.7 87.5 87.7 89.2 91.8 95.3 99.6 104.7 110.2 116.2 122.5 128.9 135.3
105 91.3 90.1 90.2 91.6 94.2 97.7 102.0 107.0 112.6 118.6 124.9 131.4 137.8
110 93.9 92.6 92.8 94.1 96.6 100.1 104.4 109.5 115.1 121.1 127.4 133.9 140.4
115 96.6 95.3 95.3 96.7 99.1 102.6 106.9 111.9 117.5 123.6 130.0 136.5 143.0
120 99.4 97.9 97.9 99.2 101.7 105.1 109.4 114.4 120.1 126.2 132.5 139.1 145.7
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 343
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Table A85: Urban arterial VOC by speed and gradient (cents/km – July 2015)
Speed Gradient in percent (both directions)
(km/h) 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
10 39.4 39.5 39.8 40.1 40.6 41.0 41.5 42.1 42.7 43.4 44.0 44.7 45.3
15 35.6 35.8 36.0 36.4 36.8 37.3 37.9 38.6 39.3 40.0 40.8 41.6 42.4
20 32.8 32.9 33.2 33.6 34.0 34.6 35.2 35.9 36.6 37.4 38.3 39.2 40.1
25 30.7 30.9 31.1 31.5 32.0 32.6 33.2 33.9 34.7 35.6 36.5 37.5 38.5
30 29.2 29.3 29.6 30.0 30.5 31.1 31.8 32.5 33.4 34.3 35.2 36.2 37.3
35 28.1 28.3 28.5 28.9 29.4 30.0 30.7 31.5 32.4 33.3 34.3 35.4 36.5
40 27.4 27.5 27.8 28.2 28.7 29.3 30.0 30.8 31.7 32.7 33.7 34.8 36.0
45 26.9 27.0 27.3 27.7 28.2 28.8 29.5 30.4 31.3 32.3 33.4 34.5 35.7
50 26.5 26.7 26.9 27.3 27.9 28.5 29.3 30.1 31.0 32.1 33.2 34.4 35.6
55 26.4 26.5 26.8 27.2 27.7 28.4 29.1 30.0 31.0 32.0 33.1 34.3 35.6
60 26.4 26.5 26.8 27.2 27.7 28.4 29.1 30.0 31.0 32.1 33.2 34.5 35.7
65 26.5 26.6 26.8 27.2 27.8 28.5 29.2 30.1 31.1 32.2 33.4 34.7 36.0
70 26.6 26.7 27.0 27.4 28.0 28.6 29.4 30.3 31.4 32.5 33.7 34.9 36.3
75 26.9 27.0 27.3 27.7 28.2 28.9 29.7 30.6 31.6 32.8 34.0 35.3 36.7
80 27.2 27.3 27.6 28.0 28.5 29.2 30.0 31.0 32.0 33.1 34.4 35.7 37.1
85 27.6 27.7 27.9 28.3 28.9 29.6 30.4 31.4 32.4 33.6 34.8 36.1 37.6
90 28.0 28.1 28.3 28.8 29.3 30.0 30.8 31.8 32.9 34.0 35.3 36.6 38.1
95 28.4 28.5 28.8 29.2 29.8 30.5 31.3 32.3 33.3 34.5 35.8 37.2 38.6
100 28.9 29.0 29.3 29.7 30.3 31.0 31.8 32.8 33.9 35.1 36.4 37.7 39.2
105 29.4 29.5 29.8 30.2 30.8 31.5 32.3 33.3 34.4 35.6 36.9 38.3 39.8
110 30.0 30.1 30.3 30.8 31.3 32.0 32.9 33.9 35.0 36.2 37.5 38.9 40.4
115 30.5 30.6 30.9 31.3 31.9 32.6 33.5 34.5 35.6 36.8 38.1 39.6 41.1
120 31.1 31.2 31.5 31.9 32.5 33.2 34.1 35.1 36.2 37.4 38.8 40.2 41.7
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 344
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Table A86: Urban other VOC by speed and gradient (cents/km – July 2015)
Speed Gradient in percent (both directions)
(km/h) 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
10 39.0 39.1 39.3 39.6 39.9 40.3 40.8 41.3 41.8 42.3 42.9 43.6 44.2
15 35.1 35.3 35.5 35.8 36.2 36.6 37.1 37.7 38.3 39.0 39.7 40.4 41.2
20 32.3 32.4 32.6 33.0 33.4 33.8 34.4 35.0 35.7 36.4 37.2 38.0 38.9
25 30.2 30.3 30.6 30.9 31.3 31.8 32.4 33.1 33.8 34.6 35.4 36.3 37.2
30 28.7 28.8 29.1 29.4 29.8 30.4 31.0 31.6 32.4 33.2 34.1 35.0 36.0
35 27.7 27.8 28.0 28.3 28.8 29.3 29.9 30.6 31.4 32.3 33.2 34.2 35.2
40 26.9 27.0 27.2 27.6 28.0 28.6 29.2 29.9 30.7 31.6 32.6 33.6 34.6
45 26.4 26.5 26.7 27.1 27.5 28.1 28.7 29.5 30.3 31.2 32.2 33.2 34.3
50 26.1 26.2 26.4 26.7 27.2 27.8 28.4 29.2 30.0 30.9 31.9 33.0 34.1
55 25.9 26.0 26.2 26.6 27.0 27.6 28.3 29.0 29.9 30.8 31.9 33.0 34.1
60 25.9 26.0 26.2 26.6 27.0 27.6 28.3 29.0 29.9 30.9 31.9 33.0 34.2
65 26.0 26.1 26.3 26.6 27.1 27.7 28.4 29.1 30.0 31.0 32.1 33.2 34.4
70 26.2 26.2 26.4 26.8 27.3 27.8 28.5 29.3 30.2 31.2 32.3 33.4 34.7
75 26.4 26.5 26.7 27.0 27.5 28.1 28.8 29.6 30.5 31.5 32.6 33.7 35.0
80 26.7 26.8 27.0 27.3 27.8 28.4 29.1 29.9 30.8 31.8 32.9 34.1 35.4
85 27.1 27.1 27.3 27.7 28.2 28.7 29.5 30.3 31.2 32.2 33.3 34.5 35.8
90 27.5 27.5 27.7 28.1 28.6 29.2 29.9 30.7 31.6 32.7 33.8 35.0 36.3
95 27.9 28.0 28.2 28.5 29.0 29.6 30.3 31.1 32.1 33.1 34.3 35.5 36.8
100 28.4 28.5 28.7 29.0 29.5 30.1 30.8 31.6 32.6 33.6 34.8 36.0 37.3
105 28.9 29.0 29.2 29.5 30.0 30.6 31.3 32.1 33.1 34.2 35.3 36.6 37.9
110 29.5 29.5 29.7 30.0 30.5 31.1 31.8 32.7 33.6 34.7 35.9 37.1 38.5
115 30.0 30.1 30.2 30.6 31.1 31.7 32.4 33.2 34.2 35.3 36.4 37.7 39.1
120 30.6 30.6 30.8 31.1 31.6 32.2 33.0 33.8 34.8 35.9 37.0 38.3 39.7
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 345
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Table A87: Rural strategic VOC by speed and gradient (cents/km – July 2015)
Speed Gradient in percent (both directions)
(km/h) 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
10 45.4 45.7 46.1 46.8 47.6 48.6 49.6 50.7 51.9 53.0 54.2 55.3 56.3
15 41.5 41.8 42.2 42.9 43.7 44.7 45.8 47.0 48.3 49.6 50.9 52.1 53.3
20 38.6 38.8 39.2 39.9 40.8 41.8 42.9 44.2 45.5 46.9 48.3 49.7 51.1
25 36.4 36.6 37.0 37.7 38.6 39.6 40.8 42.1 43.5 45.0 46.5 48.0 49.4
30 34.8 35.0 35.4 36.1 37.0 38.0 39.3 40.6 42.1 43.6 45.2 46.8 48.4
35 33.7 33.8 34.3 34.9 35.8 36.9 38.2 39.6 41.1 42.7 44.3 46.0 47.7
40 32.9 33.0 33.5 34.2 35.1 36.2 37.5 38.9 40.5 42.1 43.8 45.5 47.3
45 32.4 32.5 33.0 33.6 34.6 35.7 37.0 38.5 40.1 41.8 43.5 45.3 47.1
50 32.1 32.2 32.7 33.4 34.3 35.5 36.8 38.3 39.9 41.6 43.4 45.3 47.1
55 32.0 32.1 32.5 33.3 34.2 35.4 36.7 38.3 39.9 41.7 43.5 45.4 47.3
60 32.0 32.1 32.6 33.3 34.3 35.4 36.8 38.4 40.1 41.9 43.7 45.7 47.6
65 32.1 32.3 32.7 33.4 34.4 35.6 37.0 38.6 40.3 42.2 44.1 46.1 48.1
70 32.4 32.5 33.0 33.7 34.7 35.9 37.3 38.9 40.7 42.5 44.5 46.5 48.6
75 32.7 32.9 33.3 34.0 35.0 36.3 37.7 39.3 41.1 43.0 45.0 47.0 49.1
80 33.1 33.3 33.7 34.5 35.5 36.7 38.2 39.8 41.6 43.5 45.5 47.6 49.8
85 33.6 33.7 34.2 34.9 36.0 37.2 38.7 40.3 42.2 44.1 46.2 48.3 50.4
90 34.1 34.3 34.7 35.5 36.5 37.8 39.2 40.9 42.8 44.7 46.8 49.0 51.2
95 34.7 34.8 35.3 36.0 37.1 38.4 39.9 41.5 43.4 45.4 47.5 49.7 51.9
100 35.3 35.4 35.9 36.6 37.7 39.0 40.5 42.2 44.1 46.1 48.2 50.5 52.7
105 35.9 36.1 36.5 37.3 38.3 39.6 41.2 42.9 44.8 46.8 49.0 51.2 53.5
110 36.6 36.7 37.2 38.0 39.0 40.3 41.9 43.6 45.5 47.6 49.8 52.0 54.4
115 37.3 37.4 37.9 38.7 39.7 41.1 42.6 44.4 46.3 48.4 50.6 52.9 55.2
120 38.0 38.1 38.6 39.4 40.5 41.8 43.4 45.1 47.1 49.2 51.4 53.7 56.1
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 346
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Table A88: Rural other VOC by speed and gradient (cents/km – July 2015)
Speed Gradient in percent (both directions)
(km/h) 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
10 43.5 43.8 44.2 44.7 45.4 46.2 47.0 48.0 48.9 49.9 50.9 51.8 52.7
15 39.7 39.9 40.3 40.8 41.5 42.4 43.3 44.3 45.3 46.4 47.6 48.7 49.8
20 36.8 36.9 37.3 37.9 38.6 39.4 40.4 41.5 42.6 43.8 45.0 46.2 47.5
25 34.6 34.8 35.1 35.7 36.4 37.3 38.3 39.4 40.6 41.9 43.2 44.5 45.8
30 33.0 33.2 33.6 34.1 34.9 35.8 36.8 38.0 39.2 40.5 41.9 43.3 44.7
35 31.9 32.1 32.4 33.0 33.8 34.7 35.8 36.9 38.2 39.6 41.0 42.5 43.9
40 31.1 31.3 31.6 32.2 33.0 33.9 35.0 36.3 37.6 39.0 40.5 42.0 43.5
45 30.6 30.7 31.1 31.7 32.5 33.5 34.6 35.8 37.2 38.6 40.1 41.7 43.3
50 30.3 30.4 30.8 31.4 32.2 33.2 34.3 35.6 37.0 38.5 40.0 41.6 43.3
55 30.2 30.3 30.7 31.3 32.1 33.1 34.2 35.5 36.9 38.5 40.1 41.7 43.4
60 30.2 30.3 30.7 31.3 32.1 33.1 34.2 35.5 37.0 38.6 40.2 41.9 43.6
65 30.3 30.4 30.8 31.4 32.2 33.3 34.4 35.8 37.3 38.8 40.5 42.2 44.0
70 30.6 30.7 31.0 31.7 32.5 33.5 34.7 36.1 37.6 39.2 40.8 42.6 44.4
75 30.9 31.0 31.3 32.0 32.8 33.8 35.1 36.4 37.9 39.6 41.3 43.1 44.9
80 31.2 31.4 31.7 32.3 33.2 34.2 35.5 36.9 38.4 40.0 41.8 43.6 45.5
85 31.7 31.8 32.2 32.8 33.6 34.7 35.9 37.3 38.9 40.5 42.3 44.2 46.1
90 32.2 32.3 32.6 33.3 34.1 35.2 36.4 37.9 39.4 41.1 42.9 44.8 46.7
95 32.7 32.8 33.2 33.8 34.7 35.7 37.0 38.4 40.0 41.7 43.5 45.4 47.4
100 33.3 33.4 33.7 34.4 35.2 36.3 37.6 39.0 40.6 42.4 44.2 46.1 48.1
105 33.9 34.0 34.3 35.0 35.8 36.9 38.2 39.7 41.3 43.0 44.9 46.8 48.8
110 34.5 34.6 35.0 35.6 36.5 37.6 38.9 40.3 42.0 43.7 45.6 47.6 49.6
115 35.1 35.2 35.6 36.3 37.1 38.2 39.6 41.0 42.7 44.5 46.3 48.3 50.4
120 35.8 35.9 36.3 36.9 37.8 38.9 40.3 41.7 43.4 45.2 47.1 49.1 51.2
Back to 3.4 Impact on greenhouse gas emissions: Assessment of CO2 emissions >>
Back to 3.6 Impact on network productivity and utilisation: Travel time estimation procedures >>
Back to 3.6 Impact on network productivity and utilisation: Vehicle operating cost >>
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 347
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Table A89: Urban additional VOC due to roughness by vehicle class (cents/km – July 2015)
Roughness Additional VOC in cents/km by vehicle class
IRI (m/km) NAASRA Passenger LCV MCV HCVI HCVII Bus
(count/km) car
0–2.5 0–66 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0. 0.0 0.0
3.0 79 0.3 0.3 0.7 0.9 1.4 0.8
3.5 92 0.8 0.7 2.3 3.1 4.4 2.8
4.0 106 1.6 1.4 4.7 6.3 8.5 5.7
4.5 119 2.7 2.6 7.6 10.2 13.6 9.1
5.0 132 4.0 4.2 10.9 14.7 19.3 12.9
5.5 145 5.5 6.0 14.5 19.6 25.4 16.9
6.0 158 7.1 8.1 18.3 24.7 31.9 21.2
6.5 172 8.8 10.3 22.2 30.0 38.6 25.5
7.0 185 10.5 12.6 26.1 35.4 45.3 29.8
7.5 198 12.3 14.9 30.1 40.8 52.1 34.1
8.0 211 14.1 17.2 34.0 46.2 58.8 38.5
8.5 224 15.8 19.5 37.9 51.6 65.5 42.7
9.0 238 17.5 21.7 41.8 56.8 72.2 46.9
9.5 251 19.2 23.9 45.6 62.0 78.7 51.1
10.0 264 20.8 26.0 49.2 67.1 85.0 55.2
10.5 277 22.4 28.0 52.8 72.0 91.3 59.2
11.0 290 23.3 29.0 55.0 74.9 95.4 61.7
11.5 304 24.1 29.8 57.1 77.5 99.3 64.2
12.0 317 24.9 30.6 59.1 80.1 103.1 66.6
12.5 330 25.6 31.5 61.1 82.7 107.0 69.0
13.0 343 26.4 32.3 63.1 85.3 110.8 71.4
13.5 356 27.2 33.1 65.2 87.9 114.6 73.8
14.0 370 28.0 33.9 67.2 90.6 118.5 76.2
14.5 383 28.7 34.7 69.2 93.2 122.3 78.6
15.0 396 29.5 35.5 71.2 95.8 126.1 81.0
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 348
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Table A90: Rural additional VOC due to roughness by vehicle class (cents/km – July 2015)
Roughness Additional VOC in cents/km by vehicle class
IRI (m/km) NAASRA Passenger LCV MCV HCVI HCVII Bus
(count/km) car
0–2.5 0–66 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0
3.0 79 0.2 0.2 0.5 0.7 1.1 0.6
3.5 92 0.9 0.9 2.5 3.5 4.8 3.1
4.0 106 2.4 2.7 6.4 8.8 11.1 7.4
4.5 119 4.4 5.3 11.2 15.5 18.9 12.7
5.0 132 6.6 8.2 16.3 22.7 27.3 18.2
5.5 145 8.9 11.1 21.3 29.8 35.6 23.7
6.0 158 11.0 14.0 26.2 36.6 43.7 29.0
6.5 172 13.2 16.9 31.0 43.2 51.7 34.2
7.0 185 15.3 19.8 35.7 49.8 59.7 39.4
7.5 198 17.6 22.8 40.6 56.6 67.9 44.7
8.0 211 18.5 23.8 42.8 59.2 72.0 47.2
8.5 224 19.3 24.6 44.8 61.8 75.9 49.6
9.0 238 20.0 25.5 46.8 64.4 79.7 52.0
9.5 251 20.8 26.3 48.9 67.0 83.6 54.4
10.0 264 21.6 27.2 50.9 69.7 87.5 56.8
10.5 277 22.4 28.0 52.9 72.3 91.4 59.3
11.0 290 23.2 28.9 55.0 74.9 95.3 61.7
11.5 304 24.0 29.7 57.0 77.5 99.1 64.1
12.0 317 24.8 30.6 59.1 80.1 103.0 66.5
12.5 330 25.6 31.4 61.1 82.7 106.9 69.0
13.0 343 26.4 32.3 63.1 85.3 110.8 71.4
13.5 356 27.2 33.1 65.2 87.9 114.7 73.8
14.0 370 28.0 34.0 67.2 90.6 118.5 76.2
14.5 383 28.8 34.8 69.2 93.2 122.4 78.6
15.0 396 29.6 35.7 71.3 95.8 126.3 81.1
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 349
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Table A91: Additional VOC due to roughness by road category (cents/km – July 2015)
Roughness Additional VOC in cents/km by road category
IRI (m/km) NAASRA Urban Rural strategic Rural others
(count/km)
0–2.5 0–66 0.0 0.0 0.0
3.0 79 0.3 0.3 0.3
3.5 92 0.9 1.2 1.2
4.0 106 1.8 3.2 3.1
4.5 119 3.0 5.8 5.6
5.0 132 4.6 8.6 8.3
5.5 145 6.3 11.5 11.1
6.0 158 8.1 14.3 13.8
6.5 172 10.0 17.0 16.4
7.0 185 12.0 19.7 19.1
7.5 198 14.0 22.6 21.8
8.0 211 16.0 23.7 22.9
8.5 224 18.0 24.8 23.9
9.0 238 19.9 25.8 24.9
9.5 251 21.8 26.9 25.9
10.0 264 23.7 27.9 26.9
10.5 277 25.4 29.0 27.9
11.0 290 26.5 30.0 28.9
11.5 304 27.3 31.1 29.9
12.0 317 28.2 32.1 30.9
12.5 330 29.1 33.1 31.9
13.0 343 30.0 34.2 32.9
13.5 356 30.9 35.2 33.9
14.0 370 31.8 36.3 34.9
14.5 383 32.7 37.3 35.9
15.0 396 33.5 38.4 36.9
Back to 3.4 Impact on greenhouse gas emissions: Assessment of CO2 emissions >>
Back to 3.6 Impact on network productivity and utilisation: Vehicle operating cost >>
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 350
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Table A92: Urban arterial and urban other – additional VOC due to congestion by vehicle class
(cents/km – July 2015)
VC ratio Additional VOC in cents/km by vehicle class
Passenger LCV MCV HCVI HCVII Bus
car
0.00 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0
0.05 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.2 0.5 0.1
0.10 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.3 1.0 0.2
0.15 0.0 0.1 0.2 0.6 1.7 0.3
0.20 0.0 0.1 0.3 0.8 2.5 0.4
0.25 0.1 0.2 0.4 1.2 3.5 0.6
0.30 0.1 0.2 0.5 1.6 4.7 0.9
0.35 0.1 0.3 0.7 2.1 6.1 1.1
0.40 0.2 0.4 0.9 2.7 7.8 1.5
0.45 0.2 0.5 1.1 3.4 9.9 1.9
0.50 0.3 0.7 1.4 4.2 12.3 2.4
0.55 0.4 0.9 1.7 5.3 15.3 3.0
0.60 0.5 1.2 2.2 6.5 18.8 3.8
0.65 0.7 1.5 2.7 8.0 23.0 4.7
0.70 1.0 1.9 3.3 9.9 28.1 5.8
0.75 1.3 2.5 4.1 12.1 34.2 7.3
0.80 1.7 3.2 5.0 14.8 41.5 9.0
0.85 2.2 4.1 6.2 18.0 50.3 11.1
0.90 2.9 5.2 7.6 21.9 60.8 13.7
0.95 3.8 6.6 9.0 26.0 69.5 16.8
1.00 4.4 7.1 9.0 26.0 69.5 16.8
1.05 4.4 7.1 9.0 26.0 69.5 16.8
1.10 4.4 7.1 9.0 26.0 69.5 16.8
1.15 4.4 7.1 9.0 26.0 69.5 16.8
1.20 4.4 7.1 9.0 26.0 69.5 16.8
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 351
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Table A93: Rural strategic and rural other – additional VOC due to congestion by vehicle class
(cents/km – July 2015)
VC ratio Additional VOC in cents/km by vehicle class
Passenger LCV MCV HCVI HCVII Bus
car
0.00 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0
0.05 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.3 1.0 0.1
0.10 0.0 0.0 0.2 0.5 2.2 0.1
0.15 0.0 0.0 0.3 0.9 3.5 0.2
0.20 0.0 0.0 0.4 1.2 4.9 0.3
0.25 0.0 0.0 0.5 1.7 6.6 0.5
0.30 0.0 0.0 0.7 2.2 8.4 0.6
0.35 0.0 0.0 0.9 2.7 10.5 0.8
0.40 0.0 0.0 1.1 3.4 12.9 1.0
0.45 0.0 0.0 1.3 4.1 15.5 1.3
0.50 0.0 0.0 1.6 4.9 18.5 1.7
0.55 0.0 0.0 1.9 5.9 21.9 2.1
0.60 0.1 0.0 2.2 7.0 25.7 2.6
0.65 0.1 0.0 2.6 8.2 30.0 3.2
0.70 0.2 0.1 3.1 9.6 34.8 3.9
0.75 0.3 0.2 3.6 11.2 40.2 4.8
0.80 0.5 0.4 4.2 13.1 46.4 5.8
0.85 0.8 0.7 4.9 15.2 53.3 7.1
0.90 1.3 1.5 5.7 17.6 61.1 8.6
0.95 2.2 3.0 6.7 20.4 69.8 10.5
1.00 3.7 6.0 7.5 23.5 70.6 12.7
1.05 3.9 6.0 7.5 24.2 70.6 13.1
1.10 3.9 6.0 7.5 24.2 70.6 13.1
1.15 3.9 6.0 7.5 24.2 70.6 13.1
1.20 3.9 6.0 7.5 24.2 70.6 13.1
Additional cost in cents/km
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 352
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Table A94: Motorway – additional VOC due to congestion by vehicle class (cents/km – July 2015)
VC ratio Additional VOC in cents/km by vehicle class
Passenger LCV MCV HCVI HCVII Bus
car
0.00 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0
0.05 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.0
0.10 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.2 0.0
0.15 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.3 0.0
0.20 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.4 0.0
0.25 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.6 0.0
0.30 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.2 0.9 0.0
0.35 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.2 1.4 0.0
0.40 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.3 1.9 0.0
0.45 0.0 0.0 0.2 0.5 2.7 0.1
0.50 0.0 0.0 0.2 0.7 3.7 0.1
0.55 0.0 0.0 0.3 1.0 5.1 0.2
0.60 0.0 0.0 0.5 1.4 7.1 0.3
0.65 0.0 0.0 0.7 2.1 9.7 0.5
0.70 0.0 0.0 1.0 3.0 13.3 0.8
0.75 0.0 0.0 1.4 4.2 18.2 1.2
0.80 0.0 0.0 2.1 6.0 24.9 2.0
0.85 0.1 0.1 2.9 8.6 34.0 3.1
0.90 0.3 0.3 4.2 12.3 46.4 4.9
0.95 0.9 1.1 6.0 17.6 63.4 7.7
1.00 3.1 4.8 7.2 23.1 70.0 12.1
1.05 3.3 5.0 7.2 23.1 70.0 12.1
1.10 3.3 5.0 7.2 23.1 70.0 12.1
1.15 3.3 5.0 7.2 23.1 70.0 12.1
1.20 3.3 5.0 7.2 23.1 70.0 12.1
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 353
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Table A95: Additional VOC due to congestion by road category (cents/km – July 2015)
VC ratio Additional cost in cents/km
Urban Rural two-lane Rural two-lane Motorway
strategic other
0.00 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0
0.05 0.0 0.1 0.0 0.0
0.10 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.0
0.15 0.1 0.2 0.1 0.0
0.20 0.2 0.3 0.2 0.0
0.25 0.3 0.4 0.3 0.0
0.30 0.4 0.5 0.4 0.0
0.35 0.5 0.6 0.5 0.0
0.40 0.7 0.8 0.6 0.1
0.45 0.9 0.9 0.8 0.1
0.50 1.1 1.2 0.9 0.1
0.55 1.5 1.4 1.2 0.2
0.60 1.8 1.7 1.4 0.3
0.65 2.3 2.1 1.7 0.4
0.70 2.9 2.5 2.1 0.7
0.75 3.7 2.9 2.5 1.0
0.80 4.6 3.5 3.0 1.4
0.85 5.7 4.2 3.6 2.1
0.90 7.2 4.9 4.3 3.2
0.95 8.9 5.8 5.1 4.7
1.00 9.2 6.9 6.1 6.9
1.05 9.2 7.7 7.0 7.1
1.10 9.2 7.7 7.0 7.1
1.15 9.2 7.7 7.0 7.1
1.20 9.2 7.7 7.0 7.1
Back to 3.4 Impact on greenhouse gas emissions: Assessment of CO2 emissions >>
Back to 3.6 Impact on network productivity and utilisation: Vehicle operating cost >>
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 354
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Table A96: Passenger car additional travel time due to speed change cycles (seconds/speed cycle)
Initial Additional travel time in seconds/speed cycle by final speed
speed
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100 105 110 115
(km/h)
5 2.2
10 4.1 1.1
15 5.8 2.8 0.8
20 7.4 4.4 2.1 0.6
25 8.9 6.0 3.6 1.7 0.5
30 10.4 7.5 5.1 3.0 1.5 0.4
35 11.8 9.0 6.5 4.4 2.6 1.3 0.4
40 13.1 10.4 8.0 5.8 3.9 2.3 1.1 0.3
45 13.7 11.4 9.2 7.2 5.2 3.5 2.1 1.0 0.3
50 14.3 12.1 10.0 8.1 6.3 4.7 3.2 1.9 0.9 0.3
55 14.9 12.8 10.8 8.9 7.2 5.6 4.2 2.9 1.8 0.9 0.2
60 15.4 13.4 11.5 9.7 8.1 6.5 5.1 3.8 2.6 1.7 0.8 0.2
65 15.9 14.0 12.2 10.5 8.9 7.4 5.9 4.6 3.5 2.4 1.5 0.8 0.2
70 16.4 14.6 12.9 11.2 9.6 8.2 6.8 5.5 4.3 3.2 2.2 1.4 0.7 0.2
75 16.9 15.2 13.5 11.9 10.4 8.9 7.5 6.2 5.0 3.9 2.9 2.0 1.3 0.7 0.2
80 17.4 15.7 14.1 12.5 11.1 9.6 8.3 7.0 5.8 4.7 3.7 2.7 1.9 1.2 0.6 0.2
85 17.8 16.2 14.7 13.2 11.7 10.3 9.0 7.7 6.6 5.4 4.4 3.4 2.5 1.8 1.1 0.6 0.2
90 18.3 16.7 15.2 13.8 12.4 11.0 9.7 8.5 7.3 6.2 5.1 4.1 3.2 2.4 1.7 1.0 0.5 0.2
95 18.8 17.2 15.8 14.4 13.0 11.7 10.4 9.1 8.0 6.9 5.8 4.8 3.9 3.0 2.3 1.6 1.0 0.5 0.2
100 19.2 17.7 16.3 14.9 13.6 12.3 11.0 9.8 8.7 7.5 6.5 5.5 4.6 3.7 2.9 2.1 1.5 0.9 0.5 0.2
105 19.6 18.2 16.8 15.5 14.2 12.9 11.7 10.5 9.3 8.2 7.2 6.2 5.2 4.3 3.5 2.7 2.0 1.4 0.9 0.5 0.1
110 20.1 18.7 17.3 16.0 14.7 13.5 12.3 11.1 10.0 8.9 7.8 6.8 5.9 5.0 4.1 3.3 2.6 1.9 1.3 0.8 0.4 0.1
115 20.5 19.1 17.8 16.5 15.3 14.0 12.9 11.7 10.6 9.5 8.5 7.5 6.5 5.6 4.7 3.9 3.2 2.5 1.8 1.3 0.8 0.4 0.1
120 20.9 19.6 18.3 17.0 15.8 14.6 13.4 12.3 11.2 10.1 9.1 8.1 7.1 6.2 5.4 4.5 3.8 3.0 2.4 1.8 1.2 0.8 0.4 0.1
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 355
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Table A97: Passenger car additional VOC due to speed change cycles (cents/speed cycle – July 2015)
Initial Additional travel time in seconds/speed cycle by final speed
speed
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100 105 110 115
(km/h)
5 0.1
10 0.1 0.0
15 0.2 0.1 0.0
20 0.3 0.2 0.1 0.0
25 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0.1
30 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0.1
35 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0.1
40 0.7 0.6 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.2 0.1 0.1
45 0.9 0.8 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.2 0.1 0.1
50 1.0 0.9 0.9 0.8 0.7 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.1 0.1
55 1.2 1.1 1.0 0.9 0.8 0.7 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.1 0.1
60 1.3 1.3 1.2 1.1 1.0 0.8 0.7 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.1 0.1
65 1.5 1.5 1.4 1.3 1.2 1.0 0.9 0.7 0.6 0.4 0.3 0.1 0.1
70 1.7 1.6 1.6 1.5 1.4 1.2 1.0 0.9 0.7 0.6 0.4 0.3 0.1 0.1
75 1.9 1.8 1.8 1.7 1.6 1.4 1.2 1.1 0.9 0.7 0.6 0.4 0.3 0.1 0.1
80 2.1 2.0 2.0 1.9 1.7 1.6 1.4 1.3 1.1 0.9 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.3 0.1 0.1
85 2.3 2.3 2.2 2.1 1.9 1.8 1.6 1.5 1.3 1.1 0.9 0.8 0.6 0.5 0.3 0.1 0.0
90 2.5 2.5 2.4 2.3 2.2 2.0 1.8 1.6 1.5 1.3 1.1 1.0 0.8 0.6 0.5 0.3 0.1 0.0
95 2.8 2.7 2.6 2.5 2.4 2.2 2.0 1.8 1.7 1.5 1.3 1.2 1.0 0.8 0.6 0.5 0.3 0.1 0.0
100 3.0 2.9 2.8 2.7 2.6 2.4 2.2 2.0 1.9 1.7 1.5 1.3 1.2 1.0 0.8 0.6 0.5 0.3 0.1 0.0
105 3.2 3.1 3.0 2.9 2.8 2.6 2.4 2.2 2.1 1.9 1.7 1.5 1.3 1.2 1.0 0.8 0.6 0.5 0.3 0.1 0.0
110 3.5 3.4 3.3 3.1 3.0 2.8 2.6 2.4 2.3 2.1 1.9 1.7 1.5 1.3 1.2 1.0 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.3 0.1 0.0
115 3.7 3.6 3.5 3.3 3.2 3.0 2.8 2.6 2.4 2.3 2.1 1.9 1.7 1.5 1.3 1.2 1.0 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.3 0.1 0.0
120 3.9 3.8 3.7 3.6 3.4 3.2 3.0 2.8 2.6 2.4 2.2 2.0 1.9 1.7 1.5 1.3 1.1 1.0 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.3 0.1 0.0
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 356
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Table A98: LCV additional travel time due to speed change cycles (seconds/speed cycle)
Initial Additional travel time in seconds/speed cycle by final speed
speed
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100 105 110 115
(km/h)
5 2.4
10 4.4 1.2
15 6.2 3.0 0.8
20 8.0 4.8 2.3 0.6
25 9.6 6.5 3.9 1.8 0.5
30 11.1 8.1 5.4 3.3 1.6 0.4
35 12.6 9.7 7.0 4.7 2.8 1.4 0.4
40 14.1 11.2 8.6 6.2 4.2 2.5 1.2 0.3
45 14.8 12.2 9.9 7.7 5.6 3.8 2.3 1.1 0.3
50 15.4 13.0 10.8 8.7 6.8 5.1 3.5 2.1 1.0 0.3
55 16.0 13.8 11.6 9.6 7.8 6.1 4.5 3.1 1.9 0.9 0.3
60 16.6 14.5 12.5 10.5 8.7 7.0 5.5 4.1 2.8 1.8 0.9 0.2
65 17.2 15.2 13.2 11.4 9.6 8.0 6.4 5.0 3.7 2.6 1.6 0.8 0.2
70 17.8 15.9 14.0 12.2 10.5 8.8 7.3 5.9 4.6 3.4 2.4 1.5 0.8 0.2
75 18.4 16.5 14.7 12.9 11.3 9.7 8.2 6.8 5.5 4.3 3.2 2.2 1.4 0.7 0.2
80 18.9 17.1 15.4 13.7 12.0 10.5 9.0 7.6 6.3 5.1 4.0 3.0 2.1 1.3 0.7 0.2
85 19.5 17.7 16.0 14.4 12.8 11.3 9.8 8.4 7.1 5.9 4.8 3.7 2.8 1.9 1.2 0.6 0.2
90 20.0 18.3 16.7 15.1 13.5 12.0 10.6 9.2 7.9 6.7 5.6 4.5 3.5 2.6 1.8 1.1 0.6 0.2
95 20.5 18.9 17.3 15.7 14.2 12.7 11.3 10.0 8.7 7.5 6.3 5.2 4.2 3.3 2.5 1.7 1.1 0.5 0.2
100 21.0 19.4 17.9 16.3 14.9 13.4 12.1 10.7 9.5 8.3 7.1 6.0 5.0 4.0 3.1 2.3 1.6 1.0 0.5 0.2
105 21.5 20.0 18.4 17.0 15.5 14.1 12.8 11.5 10.2 9.0 7.8 6.7 5.7 4.7 3.8 3.0 2.2 1.5 1.0 0.5 0.2
110 22.0 20.5 19.0 17.6 16.2 14.8 13.5 12.2 10.9 9.7 8.6 7.5 6.4 5.4 4.5 3.6 2.8 2.1 1.5 0.9 0.5 0.1
115 22.5 21.0 19.6 18.2 16.8 15.4 14.1 12.9 11.6 10.4 9.3 8.2 7.1 6.1 5.2 4.3 3.5 2.7 2.0 1.4 0.9 0.4 0.1
120 23.0 21.5 20.1 18.7 17.4 16.1 14.8 13.5 12.3 11.1 10.0 8.9 7.9 6.8 5.9 5.0 4.1 3.3 2.6 1.9 1.3 0.8 0.4 0.1
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 357
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Table A99: LCV additional VOC due to speed change cycles (cents/speed cycle – July 2015)
Initial Additional VOC in cents/speed cycle by final speed
speed
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100 105 110 115
(km/h)
5 0.1
10 0.2 0.1
15 0.3 0.2 0.1
20 0.4 0.3 0.1 0.1
25 0.6 0.5 0.3 0.2 0.1
30 0.8 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.2 0.1
35 1.0 0.9 0.7 0.6 0.4 0.2 0.1
40 1.2 1.1 0.9 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.3 0.1
45 1.4 1.3 1.2 1.0 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.3 0.1
50 1.7 1.6 1.4 1.3 1.1 0.9 0.6 0.5 0.3 0.1
55 1.9 1.8 1.7 1.6 1.4 1.1 0.9 0.7 0.5 0.3 0.1
60 2.2 2.1 2.0 1.8 1.7 1.4 1.2 0.9 0.7 0.5 0.3 0.1
65 2.5 2.4 2.3 2.1 1.9 1.7 1.5 1.2 1.0 0.7 0.5 0.3 0.1
70 2.8 2.7 2.6 2.4 2.3 2.0 1.8 1.5 1.3 1.0 0.8 0.5 0.3 0.1
75 3.2 3.1 2.9 2.8 2.6 2.3 2.1 1.8 1.6 1.3 1.0 0.8 0.5 0.3 0.1
80 3.5 3.4 3.3 3.1 2.9 2.6 2.4 2.1 1.9 1.6 1.3 1.1 0.8 0.5 0.3 0.1
85 3.8 3.7 3.6 3.4 3.2 3.0 2.7 2.4 2.2 1.9 1.6 1.4 1.1 0.8 0.5 0.3 0.1
90 4.2 4.1 3.9 3.7 3.5 3.3 3.0 2.7 2.5 2.2 1.9 1.7 1.4 1.1 0.8 0.6 0.3 0.1
95 4.6 4.4 4.3 4.1 3.9 3.6 3.3 3.0 2.8 2.5 2.2 1.9 1.7 1.4 1.1 0.8 0.6 0.3 0.1
100 4.9 4.8 4.6 4.4 4.2 3.9 3.6 3.4 3.1 2.8 2.5 2.2 2.0 1.7 1.4 1.1 0.8 0.5 0.3 0.1
105 5.3 5.1 4.9 4.7 4.5 4.2 3.9 3.6 3.4 3.1 2.8 2.5 2.2 1.9 1.7 1.4 1.1 0.8 0.5 0.3 0.1
110 5.6 5.5 5.3 5.1 4.8 4.5 4.2 3.9 3.6 3.3 3.1 2.8 2.5 2.2 1.9 1.6 1.4 1.1 0.8 0.5 0.3 0.1
115 6.0 5.8 5.6 5.4 5.1 4.8 4.5 4.2 3.9 3.6 3.3 3.0 2.7 2.4 2.2 1.9 1.6 1.3 1.1 0.8 0.5 0.2 0.1
120 6.3 6.1 5.9 5.7 5.4 5.1 4.7 4.4 4.1 3.8 3.5 3.2 2.9 2.7 2.4 2.1 1.8 1.6 1.3 1.0 0.7 0.5 0.2 0.1
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 358
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Table A100: MCV additional travel time due to speed change cycles (seconds/speed cycle)
Initial Additional travel time in seconds/speed cycle by final speed
speed
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100 105 110 115
(km/h)
5 2.5
10 4.6 1.3
15 6.5 3.1 0.9
20 8.3 5.0 2.4 0.7
25 10.0 6.8 4.0 1.9 0.5
30 11.6 8.5 5.7 3.4 1.6 0.5
35 13.2 10.1 7.3 5.0 3.0 1.4 0.4
40 14.7 11.7 9.0 6.5 4.4 2.6 1.3 0.4
45 15.4 12.8 10.3 8.1 5.9 4.0 2.4 1.1 0.3
50 16.1 13.6 11.3 9.1 7.1 5.3 3.6 2.2 1.0 0.3
55 16.8 14.4 12.2 10.1 8.1 6.4 4.7 3.3 2.0 1.0 0.3
60 17.4 15.2 13.0 11.0 9.1 7.4 5.7 4.3 3.0 1.9 0.9 0.3
65 18.0 15.9 13.8 11.9 10.1 8.3 6.7 5.2 3.9 2.7 1.7 0.8 0.2
70 18.6 16.6 14.6 12.7 10.9 9.2 7.7 6.2 4.8 3.6 2.5 1.6 0.8 0.2
75 19.2 17.3 15.4 13.5 11.8 10.1 8.6 7.1 5.7 4.5 3.3 2.3 1.4 0.7 0.2
80 19.8 17.9 16.1 14.3 12.6 11.0 9.4 8.0 6.6 5.3 4.2 3.1 2.1 1.3 0.7 0.2
85 20.4 18.5 16.7 15.0 13.4 11.8 10.3 8.8 7.5 6.2 5.0 3.9 2.9 2.0 1.3 0.6 0.2
90 20.9 19.1 17.4 15.7 14.1 12.6 11.1 9.7 8.3 7.0 5.8 4.7 3.7 2.7 1.9 1.2 0.6 0.2
95 21.5 19.7 18.1 16.4 14.9 13.3 11.9 10.5 9.1 7.8 6.6 5.5 4.4 3.5 2.6 1.8 1.1 0.6 0.2
100 22.0 20.3 18.7 17.1 15.6 14.1 12.6 11.2 9.9 8.6 7.4 6.3 5.2 4.2 3.3 2.4 1.7 1.1 0.5 0.2
105 22.5 20.9 19.3 17.7 16.2 14.8 13.4 12.0 10.7 9.4 8.2 7.1 6.0 4.9 4.0 3.1 2.3 1.6 1.0 0.5 0.2
110 23.0 21.4 19.9 18.4 16.9 15.5 14.1 12.7 11.4 10.2 9.0 7.8 6.7 5.7 4.7 3.8 3.0 2.2 1.5 1.0 0.5 0.2
115 23.5 22.0 20.5 19.0 17.5 16.1 14.8 13.4 12.2 10.9 9.7 8.6 7.5 6.4 5.4 4.5 3.6 2.8 2.1 1.5 0.9 0.5 0.1
120 24.0 22.5 21.0 19.6 18.2 16.8 15.4 14.1 12.9 11.6 10.5 9.3 8.2 7.2 6.2 5.2 4.3 3.5 2.7 2.0 1.4 0.9 0.4 0.1
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 359
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Table A101: MCV additional VOC due to speed change cycles (cents/speed cycle – July 2015)
Initial Additional VOC in cents/speed cycle by final speed
speed
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100 105 110 115
(km/h)
5 0.2
10 0.4 0.2
15 0.7 0.4 0.2
20 1.0 0.8 0.5 0.3
25 1.5 1.3 1.0 0.7 0.3
30 2.0 1.8 1.5 1.2 0.8 0.4
35 2.7 2.4 2.2 1.8 1.4 1.0 0.5
40 3.4 3.2 2.9 2.5 2.1 1.6 1.1 0.5
45 4.2 4.0 3.7 3.3 2.9 2.3 1.8 1.2 0.6
50 5.2 4.9 4.6 4.2 3.8 3.2 2.6 2.0 1.3 0.7
55 6.2 6.0 5.7 5.3 4.8 4.2 3.5 2.8 2.1 1.4 0.7
60 7.4 7.1 6.8 6.4 5.9 5.3 4.6 3.9 3.1 2.3 1.5 0.7
65 8.6 8.4 8.0 7.6 7.1 6.5 5.8 5.1 4.3 3.4 2.5 1.6 0.8
70 9.9 9.7 9.4 8.9 8.4 7.8 7.1 6.3 5.5 4.6 3.7 2.7 1.7 0.8
75 11.4 11.1 10.8 10.3 9.8 9.2 8.5 7.7 6.9 6.0 5.0 4.0 2.9 1.8 0.8
80 12.9 12.7 12.3 11.8 11.3 10.6 9.9 9.1 8.3 7.4 6.4 5.3 4.2 3.1 1.9 0.8
85 14.6 14.3 13.9 13.4 12.9 12.2 11.5 10.7 9.8 8.9 7.9 6.8 5.7 4.5 3.3 2.0 0.8
90 16.3 16.0 15.6 15.1 14.5 13.9 13.1 12.3 11.4 10.5 9.5 8.4 7.2 6.0 4.8 3.4 2.1 0.8
95 18.2 17.8 17.4 16.9 16.3 15.6 14.8 14.0 13.1 12.1 11.1 10.0 8.9 7.7 6.4 5.0 3.6 2.2 0.8
100 20.1 19.7 19.3 18.8 18.1 17.4 16.6 15.8 14.9 13.9 12.9 11.8 10.6 9.3 8.0 6.7 5.3 3.8 2.3 0.9
105 22.2 21.8 21.3 20.7 20.1 19.3 18.5 17.6 16.7 15.7 14.7 13.5 12.4 11.1 9.8 8.4 7.0 5.5 3.9 2.4 0.9
110 24.3 23.9 23.4 22.8 22.1 21.3 20.5 19.6 18.6 17.6 16.6 15.4 14.2 13.0 11.6 10.3 8.8 7.3 5.7 4.1 2.5 0.9
115 26.5 26.1 25.5 24.9 24.2 23.4 22.5 21.6 20.6 19.6 18.5 17.4 16.1 14.9 13.5 12.2 10.7 9.2 7.6 5.9 4.2 2.5 0.9
120 28.9 28.4 27.8 27.1 26.4 25.5 24.6 23.7 22.7 21.6 20.5 19.4 18.1 16.8 15.5 14.1 12.6 11.1 9.5 7.9 6.1 4.4 2.6 0.9
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 360
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Table A102: HCVI additional travel time due to speed change cycles (seconds/speed cycle)
Initial Additional travel time in seconds/speed cycle by final speed
speed
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100 105 110 115
(km/h)
5 2.9
10 5.3 1.5
15 7.6 3.6 1.0
20 9.6 5.7 2.8 0.8
25 11.6 7.8 4.7 2.2 0.6
30 13.5 9.8 6.6 3.9 1.9 0.5
35 15.3 11.7 8.5 5.7 3.4 1.6 0.5
40 17.0 13.5 10.3 7.5 5.1 3.0 1.5 0.4
45 17.8 14.8 11.9 9.3 6.8 4.6 2.7 1.3 0.4
50 18.6 15.8 13.0 10.5 8.2 6.1 4.2 2.5 1.2 0.3
55 19.4 16.7 14.1 11.7 9.4 7.3 5.5 3.8 2.3 1.1 0.3
60 20.1 17.5 15.1 12.7 10.6 8.5 6.6 4.9 3.4 2.1 1.0 0.3
65 20.9 18.4 16.0 13.8 11.6 9.6 7.8 6.1 4.5 3.1 2.0 1.0 0.3
70 21.6 19.2 16.9 14.7 12.7 10.7 8.9 7.1 5.6 4.1 2.9 1.8 0.9 0.3
75 22.3 20.0 17.8 15.7 13.6 11.7 9.9 8.2 6.6 5.2 3.8 2.7 1.7 0.9 0.2
80 22.9 20.7 18.6 16.5 14.6 12.7 10.9 9.2 7.6 6.2 4.8 3.6 2.5 1.5 0.8 0.2
85 23.6 21.5 19.4 17.4 15.5 13.6 11.9 10.2 8.6 7.2 5.8 4.5 3.3 2.3 1.4 0.7 0.2
90 24.2 22.2 20.2 18.2 16.4 14.6 12.8 11.2 9.6 8.1 6.7 5.4 4.2 3.1 2.2 1.4 0.7 0.2
95 24.9 22.9 20.9 19.0 17.2 15.4 13.7 12.1 10.6 9.1 7.7 6.4 5.1 4.0 3.0 2.1 1.3 0.7 0.2
100 25.5 23.5 21.6 19.8 18.0 16.3 14.6 13.0 11.5 10.0 8.6 7.3 6.0 4.9 3.8 2.8 2.0 1.2 0.6 0.2
105 26.1 24.2 22.4 20.6 18.8 17.1 15.5 13.9 12.4 10.9 9.5 8.2 6.9 5.7 4.6 3.6 2.7 1.9 1.2 0.6 0.2
110 26.7 24.8 23.0 21.3 19.6 17.9 16.3 14.7 13.2 11.8 10.4 9.1 7.8 6.6 5.5 4.4 3.4 2.6 1.8 1.1 0.6 0.2
115 27.3 25.5 23.7 22.0 20.3 18.7 17.1 15.6 14.1 12.7 11.3 9.9 8.7 7.4 6.3 5.2 4.2 3.3 2.4 1.7 1.1 0.5 0.2
120 27.8 26.1 24.4 22.7 21.1 19.5 17.9 16.4 14.9 13.5 12.1 10.8 9.5 8.3 7.1 6.0 5.0 4.0 3.2 2.3 1.6 1.0 0.5 0.2
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 361
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Table A103: HCVI additional VOC due to speed change cycles (cents/speed cycle – July 2015)
Initial Additional VOC in cents/speed cycle by final speed
speed
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100 105 110 115
(km/h)
5 0.3
10 0.6 0.3
15 1.1 0.8 0.4
20 1.7 1.4 0.9 0.5
25 2.7 2.3 1.8 1.3 0.6
30 3.8 3.4 3.0 2.3 1.6 0.8
35 5.1 4.7 4.2 3.6 2.8 1.9 0.9
40 6.5 6.2 5.7 5.0 4.2 3.2 2.1 1.0
45 8.3 7.9 7.3 6.6 5.7 4.7 3.5 2.4 1.2
50 10.2 9.8 9.3 8.5 7.5 6.3 5.1 3.9 2.6 1.3
55 12.4 12.0 11.4 10.6 9.7 8.4 7.1 5.6 4.2 2.8 1.4
60 14.7 14.3 13.8 13.0 12.0 10.7 9.3 7.8 6.2 4.5 3.0 1.4
65 17.3 16.9 16.3 15.5 14.5 13.2 11.8 10.2 8.6 6.8 4.9 3.1 1.5
70 20.1 19.6 19.0 18.2 17.2 15.8 14.4 12.8 11.1 9.3 7.4 5.4 3.3 1.6
75 23.0 22.6 21.9 21.1 20.0 18.7 17.2 15.6 13.9 12.0 10.1 8.0 5.8 3.5 1.6
80 26.2 25.7 25.0 24.2 23.1 21.7 20.2 18.6 16.8 14.9 12.9 10.8 8.5 6.2 3.7 1.6
85 29.5 29.0 28.3 27.4 26.3 24.9 23.4 21.7 20.0 18.0 16.0 13.8 11.5 9.1 6.5 4.0 1.6
90 33.1 32.6 31.8 30.9 29.7 28.3 26.7 25.1 23.2 21.3 19.2 17.0 14.7 12.2 9.6 6.9 4.2 1.6
95 36.9 36.3 35.5 34.5 33.3 31.9 30.3 28.5 26.7 24.7 22.6 20.4 18.0 15.5 12.9 10.1 7.3 4.4 1.6
100 40.8 40.2 39.4 38.3 37.1 35.6 34.0 32.2 30.3 28.3 26.2 23.9 21.5 19.0 16.3 13.5 10.6 7.6 4.6 1.7
105 45.0 44.3 43.4 42.3 41.0 39.5 37.8 36.0 34.1 32.0 29.9 27.6 25.2 22.6 19.9 17.1 14.2 11.1 8.0 4.8 1.7
110 49.4 48.6 47.6 46.5 45.2 43.6 41.8 40.0 38.0 35.9 33.7 31.4 29.0 26.4 23.7 20.9 17.9 14.8 11.6 8.3 4.9 1.8
115 53.9 53.1 52.1 50.9 49.5 47.8 46.0 44.1 42.1 40.0 37.7 35.4 32.9 30.3 27.6 24.7 21.7 18.6 15.4 12.0 8.6 5.1 1.8
120 58.7 57.8 56.7 55.4 53.9 52.2 50.4 48.4 46.3 44.2 41.9 39.5 37.0 34.4 31.6 28.7 25.7 22.6 19.4 16.0 12.5 8.9 5.3 1.9
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 362
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Table A104: HCVII additional travel time due to speed change cycles (seconds/speed cycle)
Initial Additional travel time in seconds/speed cycle by final speed
speed
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100 105 110 115
(km/h)
5 3.2
10 6.0 1.6
15 8.4 4.0 1.1
20 10.7 6.4 3.1 0.9
25 12.9 8.7 5.2 2.5 0.7
30 15.0 10.9 7.3 4.4 2.1 0.6
35 17.0 13.0 9.4 6.4 3.8 1.8 0.5
40 18.9 15.0 11.5 8.4 5.7 3.4 1.6 0.5
45 19.9 16.5 13.3 10.4 7.5 5.1 3.1 1.5 0.4
50 20.8 17.6 14.6 11.7 9.2 6.8 4.6 2.8 1.3 0.4
55 21.7 18.6 15.7 13.0 10.5 8.2 6.1 4.2 2.6 1.2 0.3
60 22.5 19.6 16.9 14.2 11.8 9.5 7.4 5.5 3.8 2.4 1.2 0.3
65 23.4 20.6 17.9 15.4 13.0 10.8 8.7 6.8 5.0 3.5 2.2 1.1 0.3
70 24.2 21.5 18.9 16.5 14.2 12.0 9.9 8.0 6.2 4.6 3.2 2.0 1.0 0.3
75 24.9 22.4 19.9 17.5 15.3 13.1 11.1 9.2 7.4 5.8 4.3 3.0 1.9 0.9 0.3
80 25.7 23.2 20.8 18.5 16.3 14.2 12.2 10.3 8.6 6.9 5.4 4.0 2.8 1.7 0.9 0.3
85 26.5 24.1 21.8 19.5 17.4 15.3 13.3 11.5 9.7 8.0 6.5 5.0 3.7 2.6 1.6 0.8 0.3
90 27.2 24.9 22.6 20.5 18.4 16.3 14.4 12.5 10.8 9.1 7.5 6.1 4.7 3.5 2.4 1.5 0.8 0.2
95 27.9 25.7 23.5 21.4 19.3 17.3 15.4 13.6 11.8 10.2 8.6 7.1 5.7 4.5 3.3 2.3 1.4 0.7 0.2
100 28.6 26.4 24.3 22.2 20.2 18.3 16.4 14.6 12.9 11.2 9.6 8.2 6.8 5.4 4.2 3.2 2.2 1.4 0.7 0.2
105 29.3 27.2 25.1 23.1 21.1 19.2 17.4 15.6 13.9 12.2 10.7 9.2 7.8 6.4 5.2 4.0 3.0 2.1 1.3 0.7 0.2
110 30.0 27.9 25.9 23.9 22.0 20.1 18.3 16.6 14.9 13.2 11.7 10.2 8.8 7.4 6.1 4.9 3.9 2.9 2.0 1.2 0.6 0.2
115 30.7 28.7 26.7 24.7 22.9 21.0 19.2 17.5 15.8 14.2 12.7 11.2 9.7 8.4 7.1 5.9 4.7 3.7 2.7 1.9 1.2 0.6 0.2
120 31.3 29.4 27.4 25.5 23.7 21.9 20.1 18.4 16.8 15.2 13.6 12.1 10.7 9.3 8.0 6.8 5.6 4.5 3.5 2.6 1.8 1.1 0.6 0.2
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 363
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Table A105: HCVII additional VOC due to speed change cycles (cents/speed cycle – July 2015)
Initial Additional VOC in cents/speed cycle by final speed
speed
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100 105 110 115
(km/h)
5 0.4
10 1.1 0.6
15 2.2 1.7 0.9
20 3.7 3.2 2.3 1.2
25 5.8 5.3 4.4 3.2 1.7
30 8.4 7.8 6.9 5.6 4.0 2.1
35 11.4 10.8 9.9 8.6 6.9 4.8 2.4
40 14.9 14.3 13.3 12.0 10.2 8.0 5.5 2.8
45 19.3 18.6 17.4 15.9 14.1 11.8 9.2 6.3 3.2
50 24.3 23.6 22.4 20.8 18.7 16.1 13.4 10.4 7.1 3.6
55 29.9 29.2 28.0 26.3 24.2 21.6 18.5 15.1 11.5 7.8 3.9
60 36.2 35.5 34.2 32.5 30.3 27.6 24.5 20.9 17.0 12.7 8.5 4.2
65 43.2 42.4 41.1 39.4 37.1 34.3 31.1 27.5 23.4 19.0 14.1 9.2 4.6
70 50.9 50.0 48.7 46.9 44.6 41.7 38.4 34.7 30.6 26.0 21.0 15.6 9.9 4.8
75 59.3 58.4 57.0 55.1 52.7 49.8 46.4 42.6 38.4 33.7 28.6 23.0 17.1 10.9 5.1
80 68.5 67.5 66.0 64.1 61.6 58.6 55.2 51.3 46.9 42.1 36.9 31.2 25.1 18.6 11.8 5.4
85 78.5 77.4 75.8 73.8 71.3 68.2 64.6 60.6 56.2 51.3 45.9 40.1 33.9 27.2 20.1 12.7 5.6
90 89.3 88.1 86.4 84.3 81.6 78.5 74.8 70.7 66.2 61.2 55.8 49.8 43.4 36.6 29.3 21.7 13.7 5.8
95 100.9 99.6 97.8 95.6 92.8 89.5 85.8 81.6 77.0 71.9 66.3 60.3 53.8 46.8 39.4 31.5 23.2 14.7 6.1
100 113.4 112.0 110.1 107.7 104.9 101.4 97.6 93.3 88.6 83.4 77.7 71.5 64.9 57.8 50.2 42.2 33.7 24.8 15.6 6.5
105 126.8 125.2 123.2 120.7 117.7 114.2 110.2 105.8 100.9 95.6 89.8 83.6 76.8 69.6 61.9 53.7 45.0 35.9 26.4 16.6 6.9
110 141.1 139.4 137.2 134.6 131.5 127.8 123.7 119.1 114.1 108.7 102.8 96.4 89.5 82.2 74.4 66.0 57.2 47.9 38.2 28.0 17.6 7.3
115 156.4 154.5 152.2 149.4 146.1 142.3 138.0 133.3 128.2 122.6 116.6 110.1 103.1 95.6 87.6 79.2 70.2 60.8 50.9 40.5 29.7 18.6 7.7
120 172.7 170.6 168.1 165.2 161.7 157.7 153.3 148.4 143.2 137.4 131.2 124.6 117.5 109.9 101.8 93.2 84.1 74.5 64.4 53.8 42.8 31.3 19.6 8.1
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 364
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Table A106: Bus additional travel time due to speed change cycles (seconds/speed cycle)
Initial Additional travel time in seconds/speed cycle by final speed
speed
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100 105 110 115
(km/h)
5 2.5
10 4.6 1.3
15 6.5 3.1 0.9
20 8.3 5.0 2.4 0.7
25 10.0 6.8 4.0 1.9 0.5
30 11.6 8.5 5.7 3.4 1.6 0.5
35 13.2 10.1 7.3 5.0 3.0 1.4 0.4
40 14.7 11.7 9.0 6.5 4.4 2.6 1.3 0.4
45 15.4 12.8 10.3 8.1 5.9 4.0 2.4 1.1 0.3
50 16.1 13.6 11.3 9.1 7.1 5.3 3.6 2.2 1.0 0.3
55 16.8 14.4 12.2 10.1 8.1 6.4 4.7 3.3 2.0 1.0 0.3
60 17.4 15.2 13.0 11.0 9.1 7.4 5.7 4.3 3.0 1.9 0.9 0.3
65 18.0 15.9 13.8 11.9 10.1 8.3 6.7 5.2 3.9 2.7 1.7 0.8 0.2
70 18.6 16.6 14.6 12.7 10.9 9.2 7.7 6.2 4.8 3.6 2.5 1.6 0.8 0.2
75 19.2 17.3 15.4 13.5 11.8 10.1 8.6 7.1 5.7 4.5 3.3 2.3 1.4 0.7 0.2
80 19.8 17.9 16.1 14.3 12.6 11.0 9.4 8.0 6.6 5.3 4.2 3.1 2.1 1.3 0.7 0.2
85 20.4 18.5 16.7 15.0 13.4 11.8 10.3 8.8 7.5 6.2 5.0 3.9 2.9 2.0 1.3 0.6 0.2
90 20.9 19.1 17.4 15.7 14.1 12.6 11.1 9.7 8.3 7.0 5.8 4.7 3.7 2.7 1.9 1.2 0.6 0.2
95 21.5 19.7 18.1 16.4 14.9 13.3 11.9 10.5 9.1 7.8 6.6 5.5 4.4 3.5 2.6 1.8 1.1 0.6 0.2
100 22.0 20.3 18.7 17.1 15.6 14.1 12.6 11.2 9.9 8.6 7.4 6.3 5.2 4.2 3.3 2.4 1.7 1.1 0.5 0.2
105 22.5 20.9 19.3 17.7 16.2 14.8 13.4 12.0 10.7 9.4 8.2 7.1 6.0 4.9 4.0 3.1 2.3 1.6 1.0 0.5 0.2
110 23.0 21.4 19.9 18.4 16.9 15.5 14.1 12.7 11.4 10.2 9.0 7.8 6.7 5.7 4.7 3.8 3.0 2.2 1.5 1.0 0.5 0.2
115 23.5 22.0 20.5 19.0 17.5 16.1 14.8 13.4 12.2 10.9 9.7 8.6 7.5 6.4 5.4 4.5 3.6 2.8 2.1 1.5 0.9 0.5 0.1
120 24.0 22.5 21.0 19.6 18.2 16.8 15.4 14.1 12.9 11.6 10.5 9.3 8.2 7.2 6.2 5.2 4.3 3.5 2.7 2.0 1.4 0.9 0.4 0.1
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 365
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Table A107: Bus additional VOC due to speed change cycles (cents/speed cycle – July 2015)
Initial Additional VOC in cents/speed cycle by final speed
speed
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100 105 110 115
(km/h)
5 0.2
10 0.5 0.2
15 0.8 0.6 0.3
20 1.3 1.1 0.8 0.4
25 2.0 1.7 1.4 1.0 0.5
30 2.7 2.5 2.1 1.7 1.2 0.6
35 3.6 3.3 3.0 2.5 2.0 1.4 0.7
40 4.5 4.3 3.9 3.5 2.9 2.3 1.5 0.8
45 5.7 5.4 5.0 4.5 3.9 3.3 2.5 1.7 0.9
50 7.0 6.7 6.3 5.8 5.1 4.4 3.6 2.7 1.9 0.9
55 8.4 8.1 7.7 7.2 6.5 5.7 4.9 3.9 2.9 2.0 1.0
60 10.0 9.7 9.3 8.7 8.0 7.2 6.3 5.3 4.3 3.1 2.1 1.0
65 11.7 11.4 10.9 10.3 9.6 8.8 7.9 6.9 5.8 4.6 3.4 2.2 1.1
70 13.5 13.2 12.7 12.1 11.4 10.5 9.6 8.6 7.5 6.3 5.0 3.6 2.2 1.1
75 15.5 15.1 14.6 14.0 13.2 12.4 11.4 10.4 9.2 8.0 6.7 5.3 3.9 2.3 1.1
80 17.6 17.1 16.6 15.9 15.2 14.3 13.3 12.3 11.1 9.9 8.6 7.1 5.6 4.1 2.5 1.0
85 19.7 19.3 18.7 18.0 17.2 16.3 15.3 14.3 13.1 11.8 10.5 9.1 7.5 6.0 4.3 2.6 1.0
90 22.1 21.6 20.9 20.2 19.4 18.5 17.4 16.3 15.1 13.9 12.5 11.1 9.5 7.9 6.2 4.5 2.7 1.0
95 24.5 23.9 23.3 22.5 21.7 20.7 19.6 18.5 17.3 16.0 14.6 13.2 11.6 10.0 8.3 6.5 4.7 2.8 1.0
100 27.0 26.4 25.7 24.9 24.0 23.0 21.9 20.7 19.5 18.2 16.8 15.3 13.8 12.1 10.4 8.6 6.8 4.8 2.8 1.0
105 29.7 29.0 28.2 27.4 26.4 25.4 24.2 23.0 21.8 20.4 19.0 17.5 16.0 14.3 12.6 10.8 8.9 7.0 5.0 2.9 1.0
110 32.4 31.7 30.9 30.0 28.9 27.8 26.7 25.4 24.1 22.7 21.3 19.8 18.2 16.6 14.8 13.1 11.2 9.2 7.2 5.1 3.0 1.0
115 35.3 34.5 33.6 32.6 31.5 30.4 29.1 27.8 26.5 25.1 23.6 22.1 20.5 18.8 17.1 15.3 13.4 11.5 9.5 7.4 5.2 3.0 1.0
120 38.2 37.3 36.3 35.3 34.2 32.9 31.6 30.3 28.9 27.5 26.0 24.4 22.8 21.1 19.4 17.6 15.7 13.8 11.8 9.7 7.5 5.3 3.0 1.0
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 366
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Table A108: Urban arterial additional travel time due to speed change cycles (seconds/speed cycle)
Initial Additional travel time in seconds/speed cycle by final speed
speed
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100 105 110 115
(km/h)
5 2.3
10 4.2 1.2
15 6.0 2.8 0.8
20 7.6 4.5 2.2 0.6
25 9.1 6.1 3.7 1.8 0.5
30 10.6 7.7 5.2 3.1 1.5 0.4
35 12.0 9.2 6.7 4.5 2.7 1.3 0.4
40 13.4 10.7 8.2 5.9 4.0 2.4 1.2 0.3
45 14.0 11.6 9.4 7.3 5.3 3.6 2.2 1.0 0.3
50 14.6 12.4 10.2 8.3 6.5 4.8 3.3 2.0 1.0 0.3
55 15.2 13.1 11.0 9.2 7.4 5.8 4.3 3.0 1.8 0.9 0.2
60 15.7 13.7 11.8 10.0 8.3 6.7 5.2 3.9 2.7 1.7 0.8 0.2
65 16.3 14.3 12.5 10.7 9.1 7.5 6.1 4.7 3.5 2.5 1.5 0.8 0.2
70 16.8 14.9 13.2 11.5 9.9 8.3 6.9 5.6 4.4 3.2 2.3 1.4 0.7 0.2
75 17.3 15.5 13.8 12.2 10.6 9.1 7.7 6.4 5.2 4.0 3.0 2.1 1.3 0.7 0.2
80 17.8 16.1 14.4 12.9 11.3 9.9 8.5 7.2 5.9 4.8 3.7 2.8 1.9 1.2 0.6 0.2
85 18.3 16.6 15.0 13.5 12.0 10.6 9.2 7.9 6.7 5.6 4.5 3.5 2.6 1.8 1.1 0.6 0.2
90 18.8 17.2 15.6 14.1 12.7 11.3 9.9 8.7 7.5 6.3 5.2 4.2 3.3 2.4 1.7 1.1 0.5 0.2
95 19.2 17.7 16.2 14.7 13.3 12.0 10.6 9.4 8.2 7.0 5.9 4.9 4.0 3.1 2.3 1.6 1.0 0.5 0.2
100 19.7 18.2 16.7 15.3 13.9 12.6 11.3 10.1 8.9 7.7 6.7 5.6 4.7 3.8 2.9 2.2 1.5 1.0 0.5 0.2
105 20.1 18.7 17.3 15.9 14.5 13.2 12.0 10.7 9.6 8.4 7.3 6.3 5.3 4.4 3.6 2.8 2.1 1.4 0.9 0.5 0.1
110 20.6 19.2 17.8 16.4 15.1 13.8 12.6 11.4 10.2 9.1 8.0 7.0 6.0 5.1 4.2 3.4 2.7 2.0 1.4 0.9 0.4 0.1
115 21.0 19.6 18.3 17.0 15.7 14.4 13.2 12.0 10.9 9.8 8.7 7.7 6.7 5.7 4.9 4.0 3.3 2.5 1.9 1.3 0.8 0.4 0.1
120 21.4 20.1 18.8 17.5 16.2 15.0 13.8 12.6 11.5 10.4 9.3 8.3 7.3 6.4 5.5 4.7 3.9 3.1 2.4 1.8 1.3 0.8 0.4 0.1
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 367
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Table A109: Urban arterial additional VOC due to speed change cycles (cents/speed cycle – July 2015)
Initial Additional VOC in cents/speed cycle by final speed
speed
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100 105 110 115
(km/h)
5 0.1
10 0.2 0.1
15 0.3 0.2 0.1
20 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1
25 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1
30 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.1
35 0.9 0.8 0.7 0.6 0.4 0.3 0.1
40 1.2 1.1 1.0 0.8 0.7 0.5 0.3 0.1
45 1.4 1.3 1.2 1.1 0.9 0.7 0.5 0.3 0.2
50 1.7 1.6 1.5 1.4 1.2 1.0 0.7 0.5 0.3 0.2
55 2.0 1.9 1.8 1.7 1.5 1.3 1.0 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2
60 2.4 2.3 2.2 2.0 1.9 1.6 1.4 1.1 0.9 0.6 0.4 0.2
65 2.8 2.7 2.6 2.4 2.2 2.0 1.7 1.5 1.2 0.9 0.7 0.4 0.2
70 3.2 3.1 2.9 2.8 2.6 2.4 2.1 1.9 1.6 1.3 1.0 0.7 0.4 0.2
75 3.6 3.5 3.4 3.2 3.0 2.8 2.5 2.3 2.0 1.7 1.4 1.1 0.7 0.4 0.2
80 4.0 3.9 3.8 3.7 3.5 3.2 3.0 2.7 2.4 2.1 1.8 1.5 1.1 0.8 0.5 0.2
85 4.5 4.4 4.3 4.1 3.9 3.7 3.4 3.1 2.8 2.5 2.2 1.9 1.5 1.2 0.8 0.5 0.2
90 5.0 4.9 4.8 4.6 4.4 4.1 3.9 3.6 3.3 3.0 2.7 2.3 2.0 1.6 1.2 0.9 0.5 0.2
95 5.6 5.4 5.3 5.1 4.9 4.6 4.4 4.1 3.8 3.5 3.1 2.8 2.4 2.1 1.7 1.3 0.9 0.5 0.2
100 6.1 6.0 5.8 5.7 5.4 5.2 4.9 4.6 4.3 3.9 3.6 3.3 2.9 2.5 2.2 1.8 1.4 1.0 0.6 0.2
105 6.7 6.6 6.4 6.2 6.0 5.7 5.4 5.1 4.8 4.5 4.1 3.8 3.4 3.0 2.6 2.2 1.8 1.4 1.0 0.6 0.2
110 7.3 7.2 7.0 6.8 6.5 6.3 5.9 5.6 5.3 5.0 4.6 4.3 3.9 3.5 3.1 2.7 2.3 1.9 1.5 1.0 0.6 0.2
115 7.9 7.8 7.6 7.4 7.1 6.8 6.5 6.2 5.9 5.5 5.2 4.8 4.4 4.0 3.6 3.2 2.8 2.4 1.9 1.5 1.0 0.6 0.2
120 8.6 8.4 8.2 8.0 7.7 7.4 7.1 6.8 6.4 6.1 5.7 5.3 5.0 4.6 4.2 3.8 3.3 2.9 2.5 2.0 1.5 1.1 0.6 0.2
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 368
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Table A110: Urban other additional travel time due to speed change cycles (seconds/speed cycle)
Initial Additional travel time in seconds/speed cycle by final speed
speed
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100 105 110 115
(km/h)
5 2.3
10 4.2 1.2
15 5.9 2.8 0.8
20 7.6 4.5 2.2 0.6
25 9.1 6.1 3.7 1.8 0.5
30 10.6 7.7 5.2 3.1 1.5 0.4
35 12.0 9.2 6.7 4.5 2.7 1.3 0.4
40 13.4 10.6 8.1 5.9 4.0 2.4 1.2 0.3
45 14.0 11.6 9.4 7.3 5.3 3.6 2.2 1.0 0.3
50 14.6 12.3 10.2 8.3 6.5 4.8 3.3 2.0 1.0 0.3
55 15.2 13.0 11.0 9.1 7.4 5.8 4.3 3.0 1.8 0.9 0.2
60 15.7 13.7 11.8 10.0 8.2 6.7 5.2 3.9 2.7 1.7 0.8 0.2
65 16.2 14.3 12.5 10.7 9.1 7.5 6.1 4.7 3.5 2.5 1.5 0.8 0.2
70 16.8 14.9 13.2 11.5 9.9 8.3 6.9 5.6 4.3 3.2 2.3 1.4 0.7 0.2
75 17.3 15.5 13.8 12.2 10.6 9.1 7.7 6.4 5.2 4.0 3.0 2.1 1.3 0.7 0.2
80 17.8 16.1 14.4 12.8 11.3 9.9 8.5 7.2 5.9 4.8 3.7 2.8 1.9 1.2 0.6 0.2
85 18.3 16.6 15.0 13.5 12.0 10.6 9.2 7.9 6.7 5.5 4.5 3.5 2.6 1.8 1.1 0.6 0.2
90 18.7 17.1 15.6 14.1 12.7 11.3 9.9 8.7 7.4 6.3 5.2 4.2 3.3 2.4 1.7 1.1 0.5 0.2
95 19.2 17.6 16.1 14.7 13.3 11.9 10.6 9.4 8.2 7.0 5.9 4.9 4.0 3.1 2.3 1.6 1.0 0.5 0.2
100 19.6 18.1 16.7 15.3 13.9 12.6 11.3 10.0 8.9 7.7 6.6 5.6 4.7 3.8 2.9 2.2 1.5 0.9 0.5 0.2
105 20.1 18.6 17.2 15.8 14.5 13.2 11.9 10.7 9.5 8.4 7.3 6.3 5.3 4.4 3.6 2.8 2.1 1.4 0.9 0.5 0.1
110 20.5 19.1 17.7 16.4 15.1 13.8 12.6 11.4 10.2 9.1 8.0 7.0 6.0 5.1 4.2 3.4 2.7 2.0 1.4 0.9 0.4 0.1
115 21.0 19.6 18.2 16.9 15.6 14.4 13.2 12.0 10.8 9.7 8.7 7.6 6.7 5.7 4.9 4.0 3.3 2.5 1.9 1.3 0.8 0.4 0.1
120 21.4 20.0 18.7 17.4 16.2 15.0 13.8 12.6 11.5 10.4 9.3 8.3 7.3 6.4 5.5 4.6 3.9 3.1 2.4 1.8 1.3 0.8 0.4 0.1
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 369
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Table A111: Urban other additional VOC due to speed change cycles (cents/speed cycle – July 2015)
Initial Additional VOC in cents/speed cycle by final speed
speed
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100 105 110 115
(km/h)
5 0.1
10 0.2 0.1
15 0.3 0.1 0.1
20 0.4 0.2 0.1 0.1
25 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1
30 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.2 0.1
35 0.9 0.8 0.7 0.6 0.4 0.3 0.1
40 1.1 1.0 0.9 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.3 0.1
45 1.3 1.2 1.1 1.0 0.8 0.7 0.5 0.3 0.1
50 1.6 1.5 1.4 1.3 1.1 0.9 0.7 0.5 0.3 0.1
55 1.9 1.8 1.7 1.6 1.4 1.2 0.9 0.7 0.5 0.3 0.2
60 2.2 2.1 2.0 1.9 1.7 1.5 1.3 1.0 0.8 0.5 0.3 0.2
65 2.5 2.5 2.4 2.2 2.0 1.8 1.6 1.3 1.1 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2
70 2.9 2.8 2.7 2.6 2.4 2.2 1.9 1.7 1.4 1.2 0.9 0.6 0.4 0.2
75 3.3 3.2 3.1 2.9 2.8 2.5 2.3 2.0 1.8 1.5 1.2 0.9 0.7 0.4 0.2
80 3.7 3.6 3.5 3.3 3.2 2.9 2.7 2.4 2.1 1.9 1.6 1.3 1.0 0.7 0.4 0.2
85 4.1 4.0 3.9 3.7 3.6 3.3 3.1 2.8 2.5 2.3 2.0 1.7 1.4 1.0 0.7 0.4 0.2
90 4.6 4.5 4.3 4.2 4.0 3.7 3.5 3.2 2.9 2.7 2.4 2.1 1.7 1.4 1.1 0.8 0.4 0.2
95 5.0 4.9 4.8 4.6 4.4 4.2 3.9 3.6 3.4 3.1 2.8 2.5 2.1 1.8 1.5 1.1 0.8 0.4 0.2
100 5.5 5.4 5.3 5.1 4.9 4.6 4.4 4.1 3.8 3.5 3.2 2.9 2.6 2.2 1.9 1.5 1.2 0.8 0.5 0.2
105 6.0 5.9 5.7 5.6 5.4 5.1 4.8 4.5 4.2 3.9 3.6 3.3 3.0 2.6 2.3 1.9 1.6 1.2 0.8 0.5 0.2
110 6.5 6.4 6.2 6.1 5.8 5.6 5.3 5.0 4.7 4.4 4.1 3.7 3.4 3.1 2.7 2.4 2.0 1.6 1.2 0.9 0.5 0.2
115 7.1 6.9 6.8 6.6 6.3 6.0 5.8 5.5 5.1 4.8 4.5 4.2 3.9 3.5 3.2 2.8 2.4 2.0 1.7 1.3 0.9 0.5 0.2
120 7.6 7.5 7.3 7.1 6.8 6.5 6.2 5.9 5.6 5.3 5.0 4.6 4.3 3.9 3.6 3.2 2.9 2.5 2.1 1.7 1.3 0.9 0.5 0.2
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 370
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Table A112: Rural strategic additional travel time due to speed change cycles (seconds/speed cycle)
Initial Additional travel time in seconds/speed cycle by final speed
speed
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100 105 110 115
(km/h)
5 2.3
10 4.3 1.2
15 6.1 2.9 0.8
20 7.7 4.6 2.2 0.6
25 9.3 6.3 3.7 1.8 0.5
30 10.8 7.9 5.3 3.2 1.5 0.4
35 12.3 9.4 6.8 4.6 2.8 1.3 0.4
40 13.7 10.9 8.3 6.0 4.1 2.4 1.2 0.3
45 14.3 11.9 9.6 7.5 5.4 3.7 2.2 1.1 0.3
50 14.9 12.6 10.5 8.4 6.6 4.9 3.4 2.0 1.0 0.3
55 15.5 13.3 11.3 9.3 7.5 5.9 4.4 3.1 1.9 0.9 0.3
60 16.1 14.0 12.0 10.2 8.4 6.8 5.3 4.0 2.8 1.7 0.8 0.2
65 16.6 14.6 12.8 11.0 9.3 7.7 6.2 4.8 3.6 2.5 1.6 0.8 0.2
70 17.2 15.3 13.5 11.7 10.1 8.5 7.1 5.7 4.4 3.3 2.3 1.4 0.7 0.2
75 17.7 15.9 14.1 12.4 10.8 9.3 7.9 6.5 5.3 4.1 3.1 2.1 1.3 0.7 0.2
80 18.2 16.4 14.8 13.1 11.6 10.1 8.7 7.3 6.1 4.9 3.8 2.8 2.0 1.2 0.6 0.2
85 18.7 17.0 15.4 13.8 12.3 10.8 9.4 8.1 6.9 5.7 4.6 3.6 2.7 1.9 1.2 0.6 0.2
90 19.2 17.5 16.0 14.4 13.0 11.5 10.2 8.9 7.6 6.4 5.3 4.3 3.4 2.5 1.7 1.1 0.6 0.2
95 19.7 18.1 16.5 15.0 13.6 12.2 10.9 9.6 8.4 7.2 6.1 5.0 4.1 3.2 2.4 1.6 1.0 0.5 0.2
100 20.1 18.6 17.1 15.6 14.2 12.9 11.6 10.3 9.1 7.9 6.8 5.8 4.8 3.8 3.0 2.2 1.6 1.0 0.5 0.2
105 20.6 19.1 17.6 16.2 14.8 13.5 12.2 11.0 9.8 8.6 7.5 6.5 5.5 4.5 3.7 2.9 2.1 1.5 0.9 0.5 0.1
110 21.0 19.6 18.2 16.8 15.4 14.1 12.9 11.6 10.4 9.3 8.2 7.2 6.2 5.2 4.3 3.5 2.7 2.0 1.4 0.9 0.5 0.1
115 21.5 20.1 18.7 17.3 16.0 14.7 13.5 12.3 11.1 10.0 8.9 7.8 6.8 5.9 5.0 4.1 3.3 2.6 1.9 1.3 0.8 0.4 0.1
120 21.9 20.5 19.2 17.9 16.6 15.3 14.1 12.9 11.7 10.6 9.5 8.5 7.5 6.5 5.6 4.8 3.9 3.2 2.5 1.9 1.3 0.8 0.4 0.1
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 371
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Table A113: Rural strategic additional VOC due to speed change cycles (cents/speed cycle – July 2015)
Initial Additional VOC in cents/speed cycle by final speed
speed
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100 105 110 115
(km/h)
5 0.1
10 0.2 0.1
15 0.3 0.2 0.1
20 0.5 0.4 0.2 0.1
25 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.3 0.2
30 1.0 0.9 0.7 0.6 0.4 0.2
35 1.3 1.2 1.1 0.9 0.7 0.4 0.2
40 1.7 1.6 1.4 1.2 1.0 0.7 0.5 0.2
45 2.1 2.0 1.8 1.6 1.4 1.1 0.8 0.5 0.3
50 2.5 2.4 2.3 2.1 1.8 1.5 1.2 0.9 0.6 0.3
55 3.0 2.9 2.8 2.6 2.3 2.0 1.7 1.3 1.0 0.6 0.3
60 3.6 3.5 3.3 3.1 2.9 2.5 2.2 1.8 1.4 1.0 0.7 0.3
65 4.2 4.1 3.9 3.7 3.5 3.1 2.8 2.4 2.0 1.6 1.1 0.7 0.3
70 4.9 4.7 4.6 4.4 4.1 3.8 3.4 3.0 2.6 2.1 1.7 1.2 0.7 0.3
75 5.6 5.4 5.3 5.0 4.8 4.4 4.1 3.7 3.2 2.8 2.3 1.8 1.3 0.8 0.4
80 6.3 6.2 6.0 5.8 5.5 5.1 4.8 4.4 3.9 3.5 3.0 2.5 1.9 1.4 0.8 0.4
85 7.1 7.0 6.8 6.5 6.3 5.9 5.5 5.1 4.7 4.2 3.7 3.2 2.6 2.1 1.5 0.9 0.4
90 8.0 7.8 7.6 7.4 7.1 6.7 6.3 5.9 5.4 5.0 4.5 3.9 3.4 2.8 2.2 1.6 0.9 0.4
95 8.9 8.7 8.5 8.2 7.9 7.5 7.1 6.7 6.3 5.8 5.3 4.7 4.2 3.6 2.9 2.3 1.7 1.0 0.4
100 9.8 9.6 9.4 9.1 8.8 8.4 8.0 7.6 7.1 6.6 6.1 5.6 5.0 4.4 3.8 3.1 2.4 1.7 1.0 0.4
105 10.8 10.6 10.4 10.1 9.8 9.4 8.9 8.5 8.0 7.5 7.0 6.4 5.8 5.2 4.6 3.9 3.3 2.5 1.8 1.1 0.4
110 11.9 11.6 11.4 11.1 10.8 10.3 9.9 9.4 9.0 8.4 7.9 7.3 6.7 6.1 5.5 4.8 4.1 3.4 2.7 1.9 1.1 0.4
115 13.0 12.7 12.5 12.2 11.8 11.4 10.9 10.4 9.9 9.4 8.9 8.3 7.7 7.1 6.4 5.7 5.0 4.3 3.5 2.8 2.0 1.2 0.5
120 14.1 13.9 13.6 13.2 12.9 12.4 11.9 11.5 10.9 10.4 9.8 9.3 8.6 8.0 7.4 6.7 6.0 5.2 4.5 3.7 2.9 2.0 1.2 0.5
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 372
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Table A114: Rural other additional travel time due to speed change cycles (seconds/speed cycle)
Initial Additional travel time in seconds/speed cycle by final speed
speed
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100 105 110 115
(km/h)
5 2.3
10 4.3 1.2
15 6.0 2.9 0.8
20 7.7 4.6 2.2 0.6
25 9.2 6.2 3.7 1.8 0.5
30 10.7 7.8 5.3 3.1 1.5 0.4
35 12.2 9.3 6.8 4.6 2.7 1.3 0.4
40 13.6 10.8 8.3 6.0 4.1 2.4 1.2 0.3
45 14.2 11.8 9.5 7.4 5.4 3.7 2.2 1.1 0.3
50 14.8 12.5 10.4 8.4 6.6 4.9 3.3 2.0 1.0 0.3
55 15.4 13.2 11.2 9.3 7.5 5.8 4.4 3.0 1.8 0.9 0.3
60 16.0 13.9 12.0 10.1 8.4 6.8 5.3 3.9 2.7 1.7 0.8 0.2
65 16.5 14.5 12.7 10.9 9.2 7.6 6.2 4.8 3.6 2.5 1.6 0.8 0.2
70 17.0 15.2 13.4 11.6 10.0 8.5 7.0 5.7 4.4 3.3 2.3 1.4 0.7 0.2
75 17.6 15.8 14.0 12.4 10.8 9.3 7.8 6.5 5.2 4.1 3.0 2.1 1.3 0.7 0.2
80 18.1 16.3 14.7 13.0 11.5 10.0 8.6 7.3 6.0 4.9 3.8 2.8 2.0 1.2 0.6 0.2
85 18.6 16.9 15.3 13.7 12.2 10.7 9.4 8.1 6.8 5.6 4.6 3.6 2.6 1.8 1.1 0.6 0.2
90 19.0 17.4 15.8 14.3 12.9 11.4 10.1 8.8 7.6 6.4 5.3 4.3 3.3 2.5 1.7 1.1 0.6 0.2
95 19.5 17.9 16.4 14.9 13.5 12.1 10.8 9.5 8.3 7.1 6.0 5.0 4.0 3.1 2.3 1.6 1.0 0.5 0.2
100 20.0 18.5 17.0 15.5 14.1 12.8 11.5 10.2 9.0 7.9 6.8 5.7 4.7 3.8 3.0 2.2 1.5 1.0 0.5 0.2
105 20.4 19.0 17.5 16.1 14.7 13.4 12.1 10.9 9.7 8.6 7.5 6.4 5.4 4.5 3.6 2.8 2.1 1.5 0.9 0.5 0.1
110 20.9 19.4 18.0 16.7 15.3 14.0 12.8 11.6 10.4 9.2 8.1 7.1 6.1 5.2 4.3 3.5 2.7 2.0 1.4 0.9 0.4 0.1
115 21.3 19.9 18.6 17.2 15.9 14.6 13.4 12.2 11.0 9.9 8.8 7.8 6.8 5.8 4.9 4.1 3.3 2.6 1.9 1.3 0.8 0.4 0.1
120 21.8 20.4 19.1 17.7 16.5 15.2 14.0 12.8 11.7 10.6 9.5 8.4 7.4 6.5 5.6 4.7 3.9 3.2 2.5 1.8 1.3 0.8 0.4 0.1
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 373
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Table A115: Rural other additional VOC due to speed change cycles (cents/speed cycle – July 2008)
Initial Additional VOC in cents/speed cycle by final speed
speed
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100 105 110 115
(km/h)
5 0.1
10 0.2 0.1
15 0.3 0.2 0.1
20 0.5 0.3 0.2 0.1
25 0.7 0.6 0.4 0.3 0.1
30 0.9 0.8 0.7 0.5 0.3 0.2
35 1.2 1.1 0.9 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2
40 1.5 1.4 1.3 1.1 0.9 0.7 0.4 0.2
45 1.9 1.7 1.6 1.4 1.2 1.0 0.7 0.5 0.2
50 2.3 2.2 2.0 1.8 1.6 1.3 1.0 0.8 0.5 0.2
55 2.7 2.6 2.5 2.3 2.0 1.7 1.4 1.1 0.8 0.5 0.3
60 3.2 3.1 2.9 2.7 2.5 2.2 1.9 1.6 1.2 0.9 0.6 0.3
65 3.7 3.6 3.5 3.3 3.0 2.7 2.4 2.1 1.7 1.3 1.0 0.6 0.3
70 4.3 4.2 4.0 3.8 3.6 3.3 2.9 2.6 2.2 1.8 1.4 1.0 0.6 0.3
75 4.9 4.8 4.6 4.4 4.2 3.9 3.5 3.2 2.8 2.4 2.0 1.5 1.1 0.7 0.3
80 5.5 5.4 5.2 5.0 4.8 4.5 4.1 3.8 3.4 3.0 2.6 2.1 1.7 1.2 0.7 0.3
85 6.2 6.1 5.9 5.7 5.4 5.1 4.8 4.4 4.0 3.6 3.2 2.7 2.2 1.8 1.2 0.7 0.3
90 6.9 6.8 6.6 6.4 6.1 5.8 5.5 5.1 4.7 4.3 3.8 3.4 2.9 2.4 1.9 1.3 0.8 0.3
95 7.7 7.6 7.4 7.1 6.9 6.5 6.2 5.8 5.4 5.0 4.5 4.0 3.5 3.0 2.5 1.9 1.4 0.8 0.3
100 8.5 8.3 8.2 7.9 7.6 7.3 6.9 6.5 6.1 5.7 5.2 4.7 4.2 3.7 3.2 2.6 2.0 1.5 0.9 0.3
105 9.4 9.2 9.0 8.7 8.4 8.1 7.7 7.3 6.9 6.4 6.0 5.5 5.0 4.4 3.9 3.3 2.7 2.1 1.5 0.9 0.3
110 10.2 10.1 9.8 9.6 9.3 8.9 8.5 8.1 7.7 7.2 6.7 6.2 5.7 5.2 4.6 4.1 3.5 2.9 2.2 1.6 0.9 0.4
115 11.2 11.0 10.7 10.5 10.1 9.7 9.3 8.9 8.5 8.0 7.5 7.0 6.5 6.0 5.4 4.8 4.2 3.6 3.0 2.3 1.6 1.0 0.4
120 12.1 11.9 11.7 11.4 11.0 10.6 10.2 9.8 9.3 8.8 8.4 7.8 7.3 6.8 6.2 5.6 5.0 4.4 3.7 3.1 2.4 1.7 1.0 0.4
Back to 3.6 Impact on network productivity and utilisation: Vehicle operating cost >>
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 374
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Running distance
Passing lanes free impeded vehicles from slow moving platoons, and in doing so they improve levels of
service, reduce travel times and driver frustration. These benefits will be greatest at locations where road
and traffic conditions result in significant passing demand.
In hilly and mountainous terrain, passing lanes (and climbing lanes) may not be viable, particularly on
lower volume roads. In these situations, other improvement options, such as slow vehicle bays and
shoulder widening, should be considered. The benefit of full-length passing lanes in less severe terrain
can also be low, when traffic volumes are low. Improving sight lines through clearance of vegetation and
vertical or horizontal realignment may increase the available passing opportunities and generate other
safety benefits.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 375
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Start analysis
No
Are passing opportunities Consider alternative options such as:
the only option to address
safety and efficiency • realignment
deficiencies? • road widening
• removal of roadside hazards
Yes
Yes
Evaluate other options
using MBCM procedures
Yes
Yes
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 376
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Background
Travel time and driver frustration savings
Travel time and driver frustration benefits are generated when passing lanes reduce the amount of time
drivers spend travelling in platoons. The demand for passing and consequently the benefits, are a
function of a number of parameters including:
• traffic variables:
o traffic volume
o percentage of HCVs
o initial platooning
o directional split of traffic
o vehicle speed distributions
• road variables:
o terrain/alignment
o grades
o available passing lanes (sight distance)
o passing lane lengths and frequency.
The downstream distance over which road user benefits accrue reduces as traffic volumes, the proportion
of slower vehicles (HCVs), and the speed differential between fast and slow vehicles increase. Features
that re-platoon the traffic stream, such as urban areas and major intersections, may limit the available
benefits. While passing lanes also have an impact on the passing opportunities available to traffic
travelling in the opposite direction (where passing is not prohibited), these impacts are typically quite
small and are ignored.
These procedures provide graphs of travel time and driver frustration benefits, which are used or
incorporated into graphs of BCR for different input parameters. These graphs were developed from a
simulation model, which simulates two traffic streams (fast and slow vehicles) travelling along sections of
highway. The simulations are used to determine the demand for passing lanes. The travel time benefits of
passing lanes are then assessed using the ‘unified passing model’ developed by Werner and Morrall
(1984). The changes observed in the level of platooning determine the driver frustration benefits, while
the reduction in travel time is a benefit in its own right. It is also used to determine the change in mean
travel speed and the subsequent change in vehicle operating costs.
Crash rates
A crash rate analysis has been undertaken to produce the crash reduction benefit graphs shown in Figure
A16 to Figure A19. The typical crash rate by terrain type is taken from Table A36. The crash rate at the
passing lane and downstream of the passing lane is less than the typical rate and varies depending on
proximity to the passing lane. The maximum reduction is along the passing lane where the reduction in
the typical rate is 25%. The reduction in the crash rate reduces linearly to zero from the end of the
passing lane to either the location where vehicle platooning returns to normal (generally 5–10km
downstream), or where another passing lane begins.
Table A116 shows the crash rate before the installation of a passing site. The typical crash rates for hilly
terrain have been interpolated as mid-way between the crash rates for rolling and mountainous terrain.
If the passing lane forms part of a rural realignment or there are five or more injury crashes or two or
more serious and fatal crashes in any 1km section (up to 10km downstream of the passing lane) then
crash-by crash analysis may be suitable. To determine if such an analysis is appropriate refer to Figure
A1.
In the majority of cases crash benefits should only be claimed up to 5km downstream of a passing lane,
unless a rural simulation analysis indicates that vehicle platooning will not return to normal until more than
5km downstream. No upstream crash benefits can be included unless international or local research is
produced to justify such benefits.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 377
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Table A116: Crash rates for rural mid-block locations (/108 veh/km)
Hourly flow as % Roads with low volumes of recreational Roads with high volumes of recreational
of AADT traffic traffic
Hours/year % hours % AADT Hours/year % hours % AADT
0.9 3979 45.42 9.7% 3797 43.35 9.3%
3.5 933 10.65 8.9% 2062 23.54 19.8%
7.0 3210 36.64 61.6% 1819 20.76 34.9%
10.5 541 6.18 15.6% 822 9.38 23.6%
14.0 97 1.11 3.7% 96 1.10 3.7%
17.5 10 0.11 0.5% 120 1.37 5.8%
21.0 – – – 6 0.07 0.4%
25.0 – – – 38 0.43 2.6%
Total 8760 100% 100% 8760 100% 100%
Traffic growth
The procedures have been developed using a traffic growth of 2%. Adjustment factors are produced to
modify benefit graphs when the traffic growth is 0%, 1%, 3% and 4%. Where the traffic growth does not
correspond to these values an appropriate adjustment factor can be calculated using interpolation or
extrapolation.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 378
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Speed
The variation in traffic speed of individual vehicles within each traffic stream is expressed in terms of the
coefficient of variation (standard deviation divided by the mean) of all vehicle speeds. The procedure
assumes the coefficient of variation (COV) to be 13.5% for both traffic streams.
In situations where road geometry or terrain type has a significant impact on the speeds of particular
vehicle types, it is likely that the COV will increase. In such cases the simplified model will underpredict
the benefits of releasing faster vehicles from platoons. Similarly, on long flat straights where there is likely
to be less variation in speed the model can be expected to overpredict the travel time benefits. The
adjustment in equation 2 (Table A126) can be applied when the COV is above or below 13.5%.
Construction costs
The construction costs presented here, and used in the analysis for determining the appropriate passing
lane strategy, are based on the average costs of constructing a 1km passing lane in each of the terrain
categories. These average costs are generally weighted to the lower end of the reported range, as in
most instances passing lanes are located to avoid costly items, such as bridges.
Average construction and maintenance costs have been calculated for each of the terrain types, using
real costs from a number of projects and from data collected for passing lane research. The construction
costs per linear metre from these projects determined the cost categories shown in Table A118. Table
A119 relates each of the four terrain types to the cost categories, together with the unit and total
construction costs used in the analysis. All costs include the end tapers.
Terrain type Cost category Unit cost (per m) Total cost (for 1km)
Flat Easy/average $250 $250,000
Rolling Average $320 $320,000
Hilly Average/difficult $500 $500,000
Mountainous Difficult $800 $800,000
Note, however, that cost estimates vary widely depending on site-specific and therefore standardised and
average costs should be used with caution.
Where the estimated cost of construction differs significantly from that assumed in Table A119, an
adjustment to the BCR could be made using equation 3 (Table A126).
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 379
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Be aware that the analysis of data from selected passing lane sites indicated:
• passing lanes generally cost between $120 and $800 per linear metre, but can cost up to $1700
in some cases. Specific cost estimates should be prepared for each site under consideration
• significant savings in both design and construction costs are possible if two or three projects are
combined into one contract.
Special features can be very expensive and should be avoided where possible, and local knowledge is
important to achieving accurate estimates. Special features include:
• swamps/soft ground
• significant earthworks quantities
• large culvert and/or drain extensions
• intersection improvements
• expensive service relocations.
Construction period
The procedures outlined in this appendix assume that the construction of the passing lane is completed
within the first year.
Update factors
Update factors for user benefits and constructions costs should be used with these procedures. These
can be found on the Waka Kotahi website. When applying an update factor to the combined travel time
and vehicle operating costs, the adjustment factor for travel time costs should be used.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 380
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Step Action
A121, and are a result of analysis of 500m lengths using a 1500m moving average of these
parameters. The curvature, or degrees per kilometre specified in Table A121, is estimated by
summing the deviation angles of the horizontal curves from plans or aerial photography and
dividing by the road length. Rise and fall can be obtained from profile drawings or highway
information sheets. Alternatively, this profile and curve data can be obtained from surveyed
road geometry data.
3 Determine percentage of road with passing sight distance (% PSD) for each sub-section.
The % PSD is the proportion of the section that has visibility greater than 450m. This can be
calculated using surveyed gradient and horizontal curvature data.
In the absence of survey data, each sub-section can be classified according to terrain type,
based on average gradient and curvature. Terrain type sectioning can then be converted to
percentage passing sight distance using Table A122. Note that this method is not as accurate
and may not be sufficient in situations where the benefits are sensitive to % PSD, especially
where traffic volumes are higher.
In Table A122 PSD has been calculated as a moving average over 15km, with the PSD
ascribed to the centre 5km. This is the basis of the BCR graphs and should be observed when
applying the method. The curvature can be estimated as in step 2.
4 Use the analysis year AADT, and % PSD to calculate a BCR, using Figure A10 to Figure
A13.
If traffic growth is not 2% per year, multiply the BCR by the correction factors in Table A123. If
the traffic growth is not in Table A123, extrapolate or interpolate to obtain a correction factor.
The analysis is carried out in both directions, generally with a stagger between opposing
passing lanes where the terrain and available width allows.
5 Repeat step 4 using the predicted AADT for future years in increments of five years from the
analysis year, to identify when it may be worthwhile to adopt a strategy that involves more
frequent passing lanes.
Vertical terrain
Measure Straight Curved Windy Tortuous
Curvature, degrees per km 0–50 50–150 150–300 >300
Number of curves per km <1.0 1.0–3.0 3.0–6.0 >6.0
Average % passing sight distance 35 15 10 5
Percentage of road length with:
less than 25% sight distance 45 85 95 98
25 to 50% sight distance 30 15 5 2
50 to 75% sight distance 15 – – –
over 75% sight distance – – – –
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 381
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Traffic growth
AADT 0% 1% 2% 3% 4%
2000 0.80 0.90 1.00 1.10 1.21
3000 0.82 0.91 1.00 1.09 1.18
4000 0.84 0.92 1.00 1.08 1.16
6000 0.84 0.92 1.00 1.08 1.16
8000 0.84 0.92 1.00 1.08 1.15
10,000 0.86 0.93 1.00 1.07 1.15
Refinement of strategy
The following steps determine the location of passing lanes before evaluating individual passing lanes
(Table A126).
Step Action
6 Identify existing and planned passing lanes for each section where passing lanes can be
justified.
If existing passing lanes spacing ≤ calculated, then
no new passing lanes required
If existing passing lanes spacing > calculated, then
identify potential new sites at the calculated interval
Older sites are unlikely to be at set intervals (as part of a strategy) and judgement is required
in determining whether new sites are justified. Where relevant, identify possible sites for
future years.
7 Identify suitable sites. Sites should be within 1km of either side of the calculated spacing.
Construction cost, land availability and forward visibility at the exit merge are important
factors for site selection. Site spacing or length may be adjusted to balance passing demand
and opportunities. For wider spacing it will be necessary to combine each of the sub-sections
identified in step 1.
Where the strategy results in similar site spacing for each sub-section, this spacing must be
maintained over sub-section boundaries. If the optimal spacing for each sub-section results
in different desired site spacing for each sub-section, the overall strategy should be based on
the largest spacing, ie where the spacing changes from 5km in sub-section one to 10km in
sub-section two, then the spacing should be increased to the higher values (10km) over the
boundary.
Any inbound sites in the vicinity of towns should commence at least 5km from the urban
speed limit, unless reasons for a closer facility can be justified. This normally requires
modelling using TRARR.
Use the following guidance to maximise passing lane benefits:
• Select locations where large numbers of vehicles are observed travelling in slow
moving platoons.
• Select locations where there is the greatest speed differential between slow and fast
vehicles (for example, on steep grades).
• Locate sites leading away from congestion (such as urban areas).
• Where possible locate sites on sections with existing no-overtaking lines to maximise
the increase in net passing opportunities.
• Avoid significant intersections (particularly right-turn bays).
• Consider site lengths of between 800m and 1500m in most rural areas – shorter
lengths are unlikely to release all platooned vehicles and little benefit is gained from
excessively long lengths.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 382
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Step Action
• Do not locate the merge area at the end of the sites where there is limited forward
sight distance or where there is a sudden reduction in the desired speed, eg at a
tight horizontal curve.
• The termination of sites in opposing directions should not be adjacent to each other.
• Ensure that sufficient shoulder width and merge space are provided, otherwise an
increase in lost-control and merging crashes could occur.
• Avoid costly physical restraints such as narrow bridges and culverts that require
widening.
Refer to Austroads (2003) Rural road design for further information.
8 Sections of prolonged gradient should be identified, as possible opportunities for
climbing lanes (or slow vehicle bays) using Table A125 below, which is adapted from
Austroads (2003) and considers the length of sustained gradient necessary to reduce the
speed of a heavy commercial vehicle to 40km/h. To assess the benefits of such sites a more
detailed analysis is required using rural simulation software (refer to Rural simulation for
assessing passing lanes).
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 383
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
– 5km
Flat terrainFlat Terrain, – 2%
spacing 5 kmtraffic growth 2%
Spacing, Traffic Growth
40.0
35.0
B/C Ratio (July 2005)
30.0
25.0
20.0
15.0
10.0
5.0
-
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100
% Passing Sight Distance
2000 AADT 3000 AADT 4000 AADT 6000 AADT 8000 AADT 10000 AADT
Flat terrain – 10
Flat Terrain, 10 –km
km spacing 2% Spacing,
traffic growth
2% Traffic Growth
40.0
35.0
B/C Ratio (July 2005)
30.0
25.0
20.0
15.0
10.0
5.0
-
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100
% Passing Sight Distance
2000 AADT 3000 AADT 4000 AADT 6000 AADT 8000 AADT 10000 AADT
35.0
B/C Ratio (July 2005)
30.0
25.0
20.0
15.0
10.0
5.0
-
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100
% Passing Sight Distance
2000 AADT 3000 AADT 4000 AADT 6000 AADT 8000 AADT 10000 AADT
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 384
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
30.0
B/C Ratio (July 2005)
25.0
20.0
15.0
10.0
5.0
-
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100
% Passing Sight Distance
2000 AADT 3000 AADT 4000 AADT 6000 AADT 8000 AADT 10000 AADT
terrain – 10km
Rolling Rolling Terrain, 10 –km
spacing 2%Spacing,
traffic growth
2% Traffic Growth
35.0
30.0
B/C Ratio (July 2005)
25.0
20.0
15.0
10.0
5.0
-
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100
% Passing Sight Distance
2000 AADT 3000 AADT 4000 AADT 6000 AADT 8000 AADT 10000 AADT
terrain – 20km
RollingRolling Terrain, 20 –km
spacing 2%Spacing,
traffic growth
2% Traffic Growth
35.0
30.0
B/C Ratio (July 2005)
25.0
20.0
15.0
10.0
5.0
-
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100
% Passing Sight Distance
2000 AADT 3000 AADT 4000 AADT 6000 AADT 8000 AADT 10000 AADT
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 385
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
20.0
B/C Ratio (July 2005)
15.0
10.0
5.0
-
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100
% Passing Sight Distance
2000 AADT 3000 AADT 4000 AADT 6000 AADT 8000 AADT 10000 AADT
Hilly– 10km
Hilly terrain spacing
Terrain, – 2%Spacing,
10 km traffic growth
2% Traffic Growth
25.0
20.0
B/C Ratio (July 2005)
15.0
10.0
5.0
-
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100
% Passing Sight Distance
2000 AADT 3000 AADT 4000 AADT 6000 AADT 8000 AADT 10000 AADT
20.0
B/C Ratio (July 2005)
15.0
10.0
5.0
-
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100
% Passing Sight Distance
2000 AADT 3000 AADT 4000 AADT 6000 AADT 8000 AADT 10000 AADT
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 386
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
20.0
B/C Ratio (July 2005)
15.0
10.0
5.0
-
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100
% Passing Sight Distance
2000 AADT 3000 AADT 4000 AADT 6000 AADT 8000 AADT 10000 AADT
20.0
B/C Ratio (July 2005)
15.0
10.0
5.0
-
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100
% Passing Sight Distance
2000 AADT 3000 AADT 4000 AADT 6000 AADT 8000 AADT 10000 AADT
20.0
B/C Ratio (July 2005)
15.0
10.0
5.0
-
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100
% Passing Sight Distance
2000 AADT 3000 AADT 4000 AADT 6000 AADT 8000 AADT 10000 AADT
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 387
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Step Action
1 Calculate the travel time and vehicle operating savings, using graphs in Figure A14. If
necessary multiply by the traffic growth correction factor in Table A127 and the travel time
update factor from the most recent update factors, available on the Waka Kotahi website. The
inputs to the graphs are:
• passing lane spacing (either 5, 10 or 20km – for isolated passing lanes use 20km
spacing)
• analysis year AADT
• % PSD (to calculate see Table A120).
2 Calculate the driver frustration savings, using graphs in Figure A15. If necessary, multiply
by the traffic growth correction factor in Table A128 and the driver frustration update factor from
the most recent update factors, available on the Waka Kotahi website.
3 Sum the road user benefits from steps 1 and 2. These are the road user benefits that need
to be adjusted to account for the site-specific characteristics such as passing lane length,
speed distribution and proportion of heavy traffic.
4 Adjustment for the passing lane length. The benefits calculated in the previous steps are
based on passing lanes of 1km in length. Where individual passing lanes are less than 1km in
length, the benefits are reduced because a lesser number of platooned vehicles will be
released. Where the proposed passing lane is longer than 1km, additional benefits may result.
The formation of platoons depends on the spacing between passing lanes, therefore an
adjustment to the benefits is calculated based on the combined effect of passing lane length
and spacing, as provided in Table A129 and Table A130 below (intermediate values may be
interpolated).
5 Adjustment for the proportion of heavy traffic, by comparing the medium plus heavy vehicle
component of the traffic flow at the site with the component for rural strategic roads identified
from Table A46. For every percentage above the assumed 12% proportion of heavy vehicles
(rural strategic), increase the road user benefits by 1%. Similarly, for every percentage point
below the assumed 12% of heavy vehicles decrease the road user benefits by 1%.
Equation 1: Road user benefits (adjusted)
= 𝑅𝑜𝑎𝑑 𝑢𝑠𝑒𝑟 𝑏𝑒𝑛𝑒𝑓𝑖𝑡𝑠 (𝑢𝑛𝑎𝑑𝑗𝑢𝑠𝑡𝑒𝑑) × (1 + [𝑝𝑟𝑜𝑝 ℎ𝑒𝑎𝑣𝑦 𝑣𝑒ℎ𝑖𝑐𝑙𝑒𝑠 − 0.12])
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 388
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Step Action
6 Adjustment for differences in the speed distribution. This adjustment of road user benefits
(from step 5) is performed if the speed distribution at the site varies from the assumed 13.5%.
A current sample of vehicle speeds over the road sections being analysed is required.
The adjustment is to increase the road user benefits by 2.5% for each percentage point above
the assumed COV of speed of 13.5%. Similarly reduce the road user benefits for a lower COV.
Equation 2: Road user benefits (adjusted)
= 𝑅𝑜𝑎𝑑 𝑢𝑠𝑒𝑟 𝑏𝑒𝑛𝑒𝑓𝑖𝑡𝑠 (𝑢𝑛𝑎𝑑𝑗𝑢𝑠𝑡𝑒𝑑) × (1 + [𝐶𝑂𝑉 − 0.135] × 2.5)
7 Calculate crash costs savings, using graphs in Figure A16 to Figure A19 (interpolate or
extrapolate if necessary) and multiply with the appropriate traffic growth correction factors in
Table A131.
If the passing lane forms part of a rural realignment, or there are either five or more injury
crashes, or two or more serious and fatal crashes in any 1km section (up to 10km downstream
of the passing lane), then crash-by-crash analysis can be used. To determine if such an
analysis is appropriate, refer to Figure A1.
8 Calculate the BCR for the individual passing lanes using the cost estimates for the site and the
benefits calculated in the preceding steps. The BCR can be recalculated using the following
formula (if the unit costs are taken from Table A119).
Equation 3:
𝐵𝐶𝑅 (𝑐𝑎𝑙𝑐𝑢𝑙𝑎𝑡𝑒𝑑 𝑎𝑏𝑜𝑣𝑒) × 𝑇𝑎𝑏𝑙𝑒 𝐴7.4 𝑢𝑛𝑖𝑡 𝑐𝑜𝑠𝑡
𝐵𝐶𝑅 (𝑎𝑑𝑗𝑢𝑠𝑡𝑒𝑑) =
𝐿𝑜𝑐𝑎𝑙 𝑢𝑛𝑖𝑡 𝑐𝑜𝑠𝑡 (𝑝𝑒𝑟 𝑚)
Table A127: Traffic growth correction factors for travel time and VOC graphs
Table A128: Traffic growth correction factors for driver frustration graphs
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 389
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Table A129: Passing lane length factors for travel time delays and vehicle operating cost savings
Table A130: Passing lane length factors for frustration cost savings
AADT Passing lane length (m, excl tapers)
(veh/day) 400 600 800 1000 1200 1400 1600 1800 2000
2000 0.17 0.52 0.87 1.00 1.13 1.33 1.52 1.62 1.71
4000 0.13 0.48 0.82 1.00 1.18 1.30 1.41 1.50 1.59
6000 0.03 0.29 0.80 1.00 1.20 1.29 1.37 1.47 1.56
8000 0.02 0.15 0.60 1.00 1.21 1.30 1.38 1.48 1.58
10,000 0.01 0.09 0.38 0.82 1.21 1.31 1.40 1.51 1.61
12,000 0.01 0.07 0.27 0.57 1.03 1.32 1.43 1.55 1.66
14,000 0.01 0.05 0.20 0.43 0.78 1.17 1.47 1.59 1.71
16,000 0.00 0.04 0.16 0.34 0.61 0.92 1.32 1.61 1.73
18,000 0.00 0.03 0.13 0.28 0.50 0.75 1.08 1.47 1.75
20,000 0.00 0.03 0.11 0.23 0.42 0.63 0.90 1.23 1.62
22,000 0.00 0.02 0.09 0.20 0.36 0.53 0.77 1.05 1.38
24,000 0.00 0.02 0.08 0.17 0.31 0.46 0.66 0.91 1.19
26,000 0.00 0.02 0.07 0.15 0.27 0.41 0.58 0.80 1.05
Notes:
1. Shaded values show either excluded values 1.6–2km passing lane with 2000–4000 vpd or drop-off
in efficiency.
2. The values are for passing lanes on flattish gradient with 110km/h overtaking speed.
3. Refer to Waka Kotahi for passing lanes that lie outside of the above range of values.
4. These factors do not apply to passing lanes in 2+1 layouts (continuous alternating passing lanes).
5. One-way hourly flows were converted to AADT, using a 45%/55% directional split and a peak hourly
flow of 7.6% AADT.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 390
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Table A131: Traffic growth correction factors for crash savings graphs
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 391
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Figure A14: Graphs of vehicle operating cost and delay savings for all terrain
6,000,000
5,000,000
lane ($July 2002)
4,000,000
3,000,000
2,000,000
1,000,000
-
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100
% Passing Sight Distance
2000 AADT 3000 AADT 4000 AADT 6000 AADT 8000 AADT 10000 AADT
10km spacing – 2%
10traffic growth
km Spacing, 2% Traffic Growth
Time and VOC Savings, NPV/passing
7,000,000
6,000,000
lane ($July 2002)
5,000,000
4,000,000
3,000,000
2,000,000
1,000,000
-
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100
% Passing Sight Distance
2000 AADT 3000 AADT 4000 AADT 6000 AADT 8000 AADT 10000 AADT
7,000,000
6,000,000
lane ($July 2002)
5,000,000
4,000,000
3,000,000
2,000,000
1,000,000
-
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100
% Passing Sight Distance
2000 AADT 3000 AADT 4000 AADT 6000 AADT 8000 AADT 10000 AADT
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 392
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
180,000
Driver Frustration Benefits,
160,000
140,000
120,000
100,000
80,000
60,000
40,000
20,000
-
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100
% Passing Sight Distance
2000 AADT 3000 AADT 4000 AADT 6000 AADT 8000 AADT 10000 AADT
10km spacing – 2%
10 traffic growth
km Spacing, 2% Traffic Growth
100,000
NPV/passing lane ($July 2002)
90,000
Driver Frustration Benefits,
80,000
70,000
60,000
50,000
40,000
30,000
20,000
10,000
-
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100
% Passing Sight Distance
2000 AADT 3000 AADT 4000 AADT 6000 AADT 8000 AADT 10000 AADT
20km spacing – 2%
20traffic growth
km Spacing, 2% Traffic Growth
80,000
NPV/passing lane ($July 2002)
70,000
Driver Frustration Benefits,
60,000
50,000
40,000
30,000
20,000
10,000
-
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100
% Passing Sight Distance
2000 AADT 3000 AADT 4000 AADT 6000 AADT 8000 AADT 10000 AADT
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 393
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
600,000
500,000
400,000
300,000
200,000
100,000
-
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100
% Passing Sight Distance
2000 AADT 3000 AADT 4000 AADT 6000 AADT 8000 AADT 10000 AADT
1,000,000
800,000
600,000
400,000
200,000
-
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100
% Passing Sight Distance
2000 AADT 3000 AADT 4000 AADT 6000 AADT 8000 AADT 10000 AADT
2,000,000
1,500,000
1,000,000
500,000
-
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100
% Passing Sight Distance
2000 AADT 3000 AADT 4000 AADT 6000 AADT 8000 AADT 10000 AADT
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 394
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
900,000
NPV/passing lane ($July 2002)
Accident Reduction Benefits,
800,000
700,000
600,000
500,000
400,000
300,000
200,000
100,000
-
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100
% Passing Sight Distance
2000 AADT 3000 AADT 4000 AADT 6000 AADT 8000 AADT 10000 AADT
1,600,000
NPV/passing lane ($July 2002)
Accident Reduction Benefits,
1,400,000
1,200,000
1,000,000
800,000
600,000
400,000
200,000
-
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100
% Passing Sight Distance
2000 AADT 3000 AADT 4000 AADT 6000 AADT 8000 AADT 10000 AADT
terrain – Terrain,
RollingRolling 20km spacing – 2%
20 km traffic growth
Spacing, 2% Traffic Growth
3,500,000
NPV/passing lane ($July 2002)
Accident Reduction Benefits,
3,000,000
2,500,000
2,000,000
1,500,000
1,000,000
500,000
-
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100
% Passing Sight Distance
2000 AADT 3000 AADT 4000 AADT 6000 AADT 8000 AADT 10000 AADT
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 395
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
1,000,000
800,000
600,000
400,000
200,000
-
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100
% Passing Sight Distance
2000 AADT 3000 AADT 4000 AADT 6000 AADT 8000 AADT 10000 AADT
2,000,000
1,500,000
1,000,000
500,000
-
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100
% Passing Sight Distance
2000 AADT 3000 AADT 4000 AADT 6000 AADT 8000 AADT 10000 AADT
3,500,000
Accident Reduction Benefits,
3,000,000
2,500,000
2,000,000
1,500,000
1,000,000
500,000
-
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100
% Passing Sight Distance
2000 AADT 3000 AADT 4000 AADT 6000 AADT 8000 AADT 10000 AADT
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 396
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
1,200,000
1,000,000
800,000
600,000
400,000
200,000
-
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100
% Passing Sight Distance
2000 AADT 3000 AADT 4000 AADT 6000 AADT 8000 AADT 10000 AADT
2,000,000
1,500,000
1,000,000
500,000
-
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100
% Passing Sight Distance
2000 AADT 3000 AADT 4000 AADT 6000 AADT 8000 AADT 10000 AADT
Mountainous
Mountainous – 20km spacing
terrainTerrain, 20 km– Spacing,
2% traffic growth
2% Traffic Growth
5,000,000
4,500,000
NPV/passing lane ($July 2002)
Accident Reduction Benefits,
4,000,000
3,500,000
3,000,000
2,500,000
2,000,000
1,500,000
1,000,000
500,000
-
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100
% Passing Sight Distance
2000 AADT 3000 AADT 4000 AADT 6000 AADT 8000 AADT 10000 AADT
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 397
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
APPENDIX 5: PASSING LANES > RURAL SIMULATION FOR ASSESSING PASSING LANES
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 398
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Definitions
Bunching The proportion of vehicles travelling behind others in platoons. Calculated as the ratio
of following vehicles over total vehicles.
Climbing lane An additional lane provided on steep grades, where large and heavy vehicles travel at
reduced speeds.
Desired speed The speed that drivers would like to travel when not constrained by other traffic. This
is largely dependent on the road alignment. Also known as free speed or unimpeded
speed.
Following Vehicles that are sufficiently close to the vehicle in front to be affected by the speed of
vehicles the front vehicle. Vehicles with headways of less than six seconds are usually
considered to be following.
Free vehicles Vehicles able to travel at their desired speed. This includes vehicles on their own, ie
not part of a multi-vehicle platoon, and leading vehicles. Vehicles with headways of
more than six seconds are usually considered to be free.
Headway The amount of space between successive vehicles. Can be measured either by
distance or time. Usually measured from the front of one vehicle to the front of the
next.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 399
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Leading The vehicle at the head of a multi-vehicle platoon. Leading vehicles are able to travel
vehicles at their desired speed.
Merge area The zone at the end of the passing lane where the two lanes taper into one.
Overtaking An equivalent term for passing.
Passing lane An additional lane, providing two lanes in one direction. A common form of passing
lane. Typically, 400m to 2km in length. Also known as auxiliary lanes or climbing lanes
(on grades). For the purposes of analysis, the length of the passing lane does not
include the end tapers.
Passing Any measure designed to improve the likelihood of vehicles passing safely. These
opportunity include passing lanes, slow vehicle bays, shoulder widening, and improved passing
sight distance (eg realignments).
Platoon A group of vehicles clustered together (ie, small headways) and all travelling at
approximately the same speed as the leading vehicle. Also known as queues or
bunches. The size of the platoon is defined by the number of vehicles. A vehicle on its
own is considered a platoon of size one.
Sight distance The road distance ahead of the driver that is visible. This enables the driver to assess
whether it is safe to pass. Refer to Austroads (2003) for further information, especially
with regard to object and eye heights.
Slow vehicle A short section of shoulder marked as a lane for slow vehicles to move over and let
bay other vehicles pass. Typically up to 400m in length. Slow vehicles have to give way to
the main traffic flow at the end of the bay.
TRARR A rural road simulation package from ARRB transport research in Australia – the latest
version is TRARR 4 (Shepherd 1994). The name ‘TRARR’ is a contraction of ‘TRAffic
on Rural Roads’. TRARR uses various vehicle performance models together with
terrain data to establish, in detail, the speeds of vehicles at each location along the
road. This establishes the demand for passing and determines whether or not passing
manoeuvres may be executed. The outputs, mean travel times and journey speeds,
are used to calculate the benefits of various project options.
Back to 3.8 Impact on user experience … : Driver frustration related to passing lanes >>
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 400
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Time (years from time 4% discount rate SPPWF 3% discount rate 6% discount rate
zero in quarters from SPPWF SPPWF
1 July to 30 June) (sensitivity test) (sensitivity test)
0 1.000 1.0000 1.0000
0.25 0.9902 0.9926 0.9855
0.50 0.9806 0.9853 0.9713
0.75 0.9710 0.9781 0.9572
1.00 0.9615 0.9709 0.9433
1.25 0.9522 0.9637 0.9298
1.50 0.9429 0.9566 0.9163
1.75 0.9337 0.9496 0.9031
2.00 0.9246 0.9426 0.8900
2.25 0.9155 0.9357 0.8771
2.50 0.9066 0.9288 0.8644
2.75 0.8978 0.9219 0.8519
3.00 0.8890 0.9151 0.8396
3.25 0.8803 0.9084 0.8275
3.50 0.8717 0.9017 0.8155
3.75 0.8632 0.8951 0.8037
4.00 0.8548 0.8885 0.7921
4.25 0.8465 0.8819 0.7806
4.50 0.8382 0.8755 0.7693
4.75 0.8300 0.8690 0.7582
5.00 0.8219 0.8626 0.7473
5.25 0.8139 0.8563 0.7365
5.50 0.8060 0.8500 0.7258
5.75 0.7981 0.8437 0.7153
6.00 0.7903 0.8375 0.7050
6.25 0.7826 0.8313 0.6948
6.50 0.7750 0.8252 0.6847
6.75 0.7674 0.8191 0.6748
7.00 0.7599 0.8131 0.6651
7.25 0.7525 0.8071 0.6554
7.50 0.7452 0.8012 0.6460
7.75 0.7379 0.7953 0.6366
8.00 0.7307 0.7894 0.6274
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 401
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 402
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 403
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 404
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 405
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Risk description (risk source) Risk Risk events and Likelihood Risk rating
owner consequences
3.6 Wider economic impact – tourism
benefit
3.7 Changes in climate – CO2 valuation
3.8 Changes in access to social and
economic opportunities – user
experience
3.9 Other
4 Benefit realisation
4.1 Tourism
4.2 Dependency on overall economy
4.3 Dependency on future projects or
technology
4.4 Force majeure
4.5 Other future projects
4.6 Diversion from private vehicle
4.7 Supply relationships
4.8 Routing parameters
4.9 Other
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 406
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 407
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
The worksheet should be completed for the identified high risks. The risk categories are labelled R1 to
R17. Leave a risk category blank if it is not high risk. If it is high risk, but the impact cannot be quantified,
simply tick the relevant box. Where the risk impact can be broadly quantified, insert the expected
percentage impact on benefits, costs or the anticipated programme delay in the relevant box.
The worksheet also provides a means of combining the identified and quantified high benefit and cost
risks to give an indication of the impact of these high risks on the overall level of project risk relative to
what might normally be expected for a typical project at a late stage in project development.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 408
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Figure A20 illustrates the concept. If, for example, we estimate the baseline cost risk of a typical project to
be $1M ±12% (95% confidence limits) and the risk for a specific project is higher at ±18%, then the
relative risk indicator is 1.5, the ratio of the two values. Thus the ‘high’ risks identified for this project
increase the overall risk by 50% over what would normally be expected.
As the calculation takes no account of identified ‘low’ risk categories, the risk indicator is not a
comprehensive measure of the overall project risk – it is partly for this reason that it is termed an
‘indicator’. Until knowledge is gained of the performance of this indicator as a measure of risk and the
degree to which it varies from project to project, it will not be a factor in funding decisions.
The relative risk indicators labelled RC and RB should be computed using the formulae:
RB = [1 + (1/0.03) * ∑i (Vi – 0.0056)] 0.5
where Vi = (Ri/100)2 and the summation is only for Ri values in the table.
RC = [1 + (1/0.015) * ∑i (Vi – 0.0025)]0.5
where Vi = (Ri/100)2 and the summation is only for Ri values in the table. That is, the benefit risk is
computed from values R1 to R4 and R11 provided in the table and the cost risk from R5 to R10, where the
risks are converted from percentage, eg, 30%, to a fraction, eg, 0.3.
The relative risk indicators RB and RC thus calculated are combined to give the overall BCR relative risk
indicator RBCR as follows.
RBCR = [0.35 * RC2 + 0.65* RB2] 0.5
After the applying risk treatments and contingency, any residual risks shall be reported and quantified to
produce risk adjusted BCR. Use this worksheet along with the BCR risk tool (BCR optimism bias testing).
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 409
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Risk category Residual cost risk Residual benefit risk Residual programming risk
A worked example for Risk analysis worksheet 3: relative risk indicator calculation is provided in Appendix
8: Worked examples.
Back to 4. Evaluation procedures >>
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 410
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
APPENDIX 8: WORKED EXAMPLES > CONSUMER SURPLUS AND THE RULE OF HALF
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 411
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 412
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Back to 3.1 Impact on social cost of deaths and serious injuries >>
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 413
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Back to 3.6 Impact on network productivity and utilisation: Traffic congestion values >>
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 414
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
A B Signalised E
intersection
N
Township bypass
Arterial D
C 1800
v1 700
Traffic volumes and VC ratios at signalised intersection I are summarised in Table A140, Table A141,
Table A142 and Table A143.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 415
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
To To To To To E To E Sum
A B C D via town via
bypass
From A 0 0 1 82 1120 0 1203
B 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
C 4 0 0 11 20 0 35
D 249 0 2 0 60 0 311
E via town 947 0 9 252 0 0 1208
E via bypass 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
Sum 1200 0 12 345 1200 0 2757
To To To To To E To E Sum
A B C D via town via bypass
From A 0 0 1 82 420 700 1203
B 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
C 4 0 0 11 20 0 35
D 249 0 2 0 60 0 311
E via town 247 0 9 252 0 0 508
E via bypass 700 0 0 0 0 0 700
Sum 1200 0 12 345 500 700 2757
For road section, standard deviations of travel times in minutes are calculated by:
SD(TT) = S0 + (S - S0) / 1 + eb*(VC ratio - a))
For urban arterial: S = 0.89, b = -28, a = 1, S0 =0.117 (Table 69)
For urban retail road: S = 0.87, b = -16, a = 1, S0 =0.150 (Table 69)
For intersection C, standard deviations of delays in minutes for each movement are calculated by:
SD(TT) = S0 + (S - S0) / (1 + eb*(VC ratio - a))
For signalised intersection: S =1.25, b = -32, a = 1, S0 =0.120 (Table 69).
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 416
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
= 0.225 min
To A To B To C To D To E via To E via
town bypass
From A 0 0 0.225 0.225 0.254 0.117
B 0 0 0 0 0 0
C 0.225 0 0 0.120 0.168 0
D 0.225 0 0.120 0 0.168 0
E via town 0.254 0 0.168 0.168 0 0
E via bypass 0.117 0 0 0 0 0
Multiply the element in the flow matrix (Table A142 and Table A143) with the corresponding element in
the standard deviation matrix (Table A146 and Table A147) to derive the variability for each movement.
Sum each line to get the total for the approach. Add the final column together to derive the network-wide
variability.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 417
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
To To To To To E To E Sum
A B C D via town via
bypass
From A 0 0 0.248 20.008 306.880 0 327.136
B 0 0 0 0 0 0 0.000
C 0.976 0 0 1.320 3.360 0 5.656
D 60.756 0 0.240 0 10.080 0 71.076
E via town 256.637 0 1.512 42.336 0 0 300.485
E via bypass 0 0 0 0 0 0 0.000
Sum 318.369 0 2.000 63.664 320.320 0 704.353
To To To To To E To E Sum
A B C D via town via
bypass
From A 0 0 0.225 18.450 106.680 81.9 207.255
B 0 0 0 0 0 0 0.000
C 0.900 0 0 1.320 3.360 0 5.580
D 56.025 0 0.240 0 10.080 0 66.345
E via town 62.738 0 1.512 42.336 0 0 106.586
E via bypass 81.9 0 0 0 0 0 81.900
Sum 201.563 0 1.977 62.106 120.120 81.900 467.666
The total variability for 'do-minimum' is 704.353 veh/min and for 'activity option' is 467.666 veh/min.
Variability benefits per peak hour are calculated as:
0.9 × $15.13 × (704.353 - 467.666) / 60 × 30 % = $16.11/h
where: $15.13 is the value of travel time for morning commuter peak hour for urban arterial
(Table 16)
0.9 is the variability travel time factor
30% is the adjustment factor as there is only one major source of variability.
Back to full procedures for road improvement activities: Stage 4g. Impact on system reliability >>
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 418
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
• year 1: p
• year 2: p (1 - p)
• year 3: p (1 - p)2
• year n: p (1 - p) n - 1
and the probability of the bridge surviving to n years and then being replaced is therefore:
1 - p - p (1 - p) - p (1 - p)2 - … - p (1 - p)(n – 1) = (1 - p)n
The probability of survival to the end of year five is therefore:
(1 - 0.005)5 = 0.97525
In the event of earthquake damage, a temporary Bailey bridge would have to be erected while a new
permanent structure was being built. This would impose an additional cost on the road controlling
authority, which would not occur in the case of a planned replacement. There would also be disruption to
traffic at the time of the earthquake.
Calculating costs if risk occurs
Assume that the bridge replacement cost is $2.5 million over two years. Making the assumption that an
earthquake, if it occurred, would on average occur mid-year, it is then assumed that these costs are
distributed $1.5 million in the first year and $1.0 million in the next year.
Assume that the cost of erecting a temporary Bailey bridge is $0.2 million spread over six months, the
disruption cost during planned replacement of the bridge is zero (the old bridge remains open), and the
disruption cost of unplanned delays while the Bailey is being constructed is $0.5 million and disruption
during Bailey use (during the two years it takes to construct the new bridge) is $0.2 million per year.
If the bridge is destroyed before planned replacement, then the costs at the start of the year in which the
earthquake occurs are:
Roading costs $million
Bailey bridge $0.1 × 0.9713 (SPPWF yr 0.5)
$0.1 × 0.9433 (SPPWF yr 1.0)
Permanent replacement bridge $1.5 × 0.9433 (SPPWF yr 1.0)
$1.0 × 0.8900 (SPPWF yr 2.0)
total $2.496 million
Road user costs:
Initial disruption costs $0.5 × 0.9713 (SPPWF yr 0.5)
$0.2 × 0.5 × 0.9433 (SPPWF yr 1.0)
Ongoing disruption costs $0.2 × 0.9163 (SPPWF yr 1.5)
$0.2 × 0.5 × 0.8900 (SPPWF yr 2.0)
total $0.663 million
Where: SPPWF is the single payment present worth factor (Table A150).
Calculating expected values
The probability of the bridge being destroyed by an earthquake in each of years one, two three and four
are then multiplied by the above costs and benefits to give expected values in each year. The same is
done in year five for the costs of planned replacement of the bridge. The expected values of costs and
benefits in each year are then as follows.
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 419
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Back to full procedures for road improvement activities: Stage 4j. Other significant impacts …>>
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 420
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Year Capital cost O&M cost Revenue Funding gap Annual total SPPWF Net present
value
1 -$2,500,000 -$2,500,000 0.8929 -$2,232,143
2 -$2,500,000 -$484,600 $346,000 $1,064,809 -$1,573,791 0.7972 -$1,254,617
3 -$484,600 $356,380 $1,064,809 $936,589 0.7118 $666,645
4 -$484,600 $367,071 $1,064,809 $947,280 0.6355 $602,014
5 -$484,600 $378,084 $1,064,809 $958,292 0.5674 $543,761
6 -$484,600 $389,426 $1,064,809 $969,635 0.5066 $491,247
7 -$484,600 $401,109 $1,064,809 $981,318 0.4523 $443,898
8 -$484,600 $413,142 $1,064,809 $993,351 0.4039 $401,198
9 -$484,600 $425,536 $1,064,809 $1,005,745 0.3606 $362,682
10 -$484,600 $438,302 -$46,298 0.3220 -$14,907
11 -$484,600 $451,452 -$33,148 0.2875 -$9529
12 -$484,600 $464,995 -$19,605 0.2567 -$5032
13 -$484,600 $478,945 -$5655 0.2292 -$1296
14 -$484,600 $493,313 $8713 0.2046 $1783
15 -$484,600 $508,113 $23,513 0.1827 $4296
16 -$484,600 $523,356 $38,756 0.1631 -
17 -$484,600 $539,057 $54,457 0.1456 -
18 -$484,600 $555,228 $70,628 0.1300 -
19 -$484,600 $571,885 $87,285 0.1161 -
20 -$484,600 $589,042 $104,442 0.1037 -
21 -$484,600 $606,713 $122,113 0.0926 -
22 -$484,600 $624,914 $140,314 0.0826 -
Present value = $4,722,845 Sum of net present value = $0
Back to full procedures for public transport activities: Stage 7d. Calculate service provider’s funding gap >>
Discounting
Single payment present worth factor for a single period
For a section of road resealed 15 years after time zero at a cost of $50,000, the present value of the
reseal cost using a discount rate of 6% is:
Present value = $50,000 x SPPWF615 (Table 82)
= $50,000 x 0.4173
= $20,865
Single payment present worth factor for multiple periods
A project costing $2 million with a implementation period of 15 months starting in the 8th month after time
zero, has the following cash flow for expenditure:
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 421
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Month 19 20 21 22 23 24 Total
$ (000s) 50 50 100 100 0 0 300
The present value of the implementation expenditure is:
Using annual SPPWF from Table 82
Present value = ($400,000 + $1,300,000) × SPPWF61 + $300,000 × SPPWF62
= $1,700,000 × 0.9434 + $300,000 × 0.8900
= $1,870,780
A more accurate calculation using quarterly SPPWF from Table A150.
Present value = $150,000 × SPPWF60.75 + $450,000 × SPPWF61.00
+ $800,000 × SPPWF61.25 + $350,000 × SPPWF61.50
+ $250,000 × SPPWF61.75
= $150,000 × 0.9572 + $450,000 × 0.9433
+ $800,000 × 0.9298 + $350,000 × 0.9163
+ $250,000 × 0.9031
= $1,858,385
time zero
+1.25 years
900
$800k
Implementation expenditure
time zero
+1.00 years
time zero
+1.50 years
time zero
600 time zero +1.75 years
+0.75 years $450k
$350k
$300k$300k
300 $250k
$200k$200k $200k
$150k $150k
$100k $100k $100k$100k
$50k $50k $50k $50k $50k
0
8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22
Months after time zero
Quarterly cashflow Monthly cashflow
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 422
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Incremental BCRs
The concept of incremental cost–benefit analysis is illustrated in the figure below, which considers two
options – A and B.
The BCR for option B is 4.0 (4000/1000). Such a value would usually result in the project receiving a High
rating for the economic efficiency criteria considered under the Waka Kotahi funding allocation process.
The less-costly option A, with a BCR of 7.5 (3000/400), would receive the same High rating. However,
incremental cost–benefit analysis demonstrates that the incremental benefits gained by supporting option
B ahead of option A represent only a small return on the additional cost, as the incremental BCR is 1.7
((4000–3000)/(1000–400))
Option B
4000
Incremental benefits
= option B - option A
Option A
3000
Incremental costs
Present value benefits
2000
Benefits
= option A
1000
Costs
= option A
0
Do-minimum 0 200 400 600 800 1000 1200
Present value costs
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 423
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Next, calculate the incremental BCR of each higher cost option, discarding those below the target
incremental BCR as in Table A156.
Finally select the option that has the highest cost and an incremental BCR greater than the target
incremental BCR, which in this example is option D.
Back to 6.3 Incremental cost–benefit analysis: Procedure for calculating the incremental BCR>>
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 424
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
Back to Appendix 3. Traffic data and travel time estimation: Calculating bottleneck delay>>
Traffic signals
Basic data
Lane width 3.3m
Number of lanes 2
Approach grade +2%
Parking movements/h 20
Locality CBD
Arrival type Random
Signal type Actuated
Lane width factor (from Table A70) = 0.98
Approach grade factor (from Table A71) = 0.99
Parking factor (from Table A72) = 0.89
Locality factor (from Table A73) = 0.90
Saturation flow rate = 2000 × 0.98 × 0.99 × 0.89 × 0.90
= 1554 pcu/h
Arrival type (from Table A74) = 3
Delay adjustment factor (from Table A75) = 0.85
In using a traffic model to analyse this example intersection, a saturation flow rate of 1554 pcu/h shall be
used, and the resulting delays multiplied by 0.85.
Back to Appendix 3. Traffic data and travel time estimation: Traffic signals >>
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 425
BACK TO CONTENTS PAGE >>
APPENDIX 8: WORKED EXAMPLES > RISK ANALYSIS WORKSHEET 3: RELATIVE RISK INDICATOR CALCULATION
MONETISED BENEFITS AND COSTS MANUAL │ VERSION 1.5, AUGUST 2021 // 426