Future Pricing Model
Future Pricing Model
Future price and the expected future spot prices: Future prices
keep on changing continuously. Thus future price can be an estimate of the
expected future spot price.
There are several theories which have made efforts to explain the
relationship between spot and futures prices. A few important of them are as
follows:
Some economists like Keynes and Hicks, have argued that futures
prices essentially reflect the carrying cost of the underlying assets. In other
words, the inter-relationship between spot and futures prices reflect the
carrying costs, i.e., the amount to be paid to store the asset from the present
time to the futures maturity time (date). For example, foodgrains on hand in
June can be carried forward to, or stored until, December. Cost of carry which
13
includes storage cost plus the interest paid to finance the asset less the
income earned on assets. For more understanding of the concept, let’s take
the following cases:
F0 = S0erT … (2.1)
T- Time to maturity
e- Constant
If F0 > S0erT, then the arbitrageurs will buy the asset and short forward
contracts on the assets. If F0 < S0erT they can short the asset and buy forward
contracts.
Case II: In case of an asset with income I, the forward price can be
calculated as:
Case III: In case of asset with yield q the forward price is given by:
F0 = S0e(r-q)T … (2.3)
In the similar fashion, the future price of a stock index paying dividend
can be calculated as follows:
14
Since dividend provides a known yield
F0 = S0e(r-q)T
F0 = 400 e(0.06-0.01)×0.25
= Rs. 405.03
If storage cost is also adjusted then the formula for calculating futures
prices becomes:
F0 = (S0 + U) erT.
Where U is the present value of all storage cost incurred during life
span of a contract.
Illustration 2.3: Assuming that one year futures contract on gold costs
Rs. 2 per 10 gm to store it with payment being made at the end of the year.
Spot price stands at Rs. 450 with risk-free interest rate of 7% p.a.
15
Here, U = 2e-0.07×1 = 1.865
F0 = S0e(r+u)T
Where u denotes the storage cost p.a. as a proportion of the spot price.
16
Current futures price = Expected futures spot price
The advocates of this approach J.M. Keynes, J.R. Hicks and N. Kalidor
argued the futures price as the market expectation of the price at the futures
date. Many traders and investors, especially those using futures market to
hedge, will be interested to study how today’s futures prices are related to
market expectations about futures prices. For example, there is general
expectation that the price of the gold next Oct 1, 2006 will be Rs. 7000 per 10
grams. The futures price today for Jan 1, 2007 must somewhat reflect this
expectation. If today’s futures price is Rs. 6800 of gold, going long futures will
yield an expected profit of
F0,t = E0 (St)
The above equation states that the futures price approximately equals
the spot price currently expected to prevail at the delivery date, and if, this
relationship did not hold, there would be attractive speculative opportunity.
Future prices are influenced by expectations prevailing currently.
17
This is also known as hypothesis of unbiased futures pricing because it
advocates that the futures price is an unbiased estimate of the futures spot
price, and on an average, the futures price will forecast the futures spot price
correctly.
It has been observed in many futures markets that the trading volume
of short hedging (sales) exceeds the volume of long hedging (purchases),
resulting in net short position. In such situation, Keynes has argued that, in
order to induce long speculators to take up the net-short-hedging volume, the
hedgers had to pay a risk premium to the speculators. As a result, the futures
price would generally be less than the expected futures spot price, by the
amount of risk premium which can be stated in equation as:
F=E–r
18
Where, F is futures price for a futures date, E is expected price at that
date and r is risk premium.
The risk and return relationship can be very well explained by CAPM
which suggests that systematic risk is important in return calculations. The
19
Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM) can also be used in determining the
prices of the futures.
Sometimes, the futures prices differ from expected future spot prices
even after adjusting for systematic risk because of unevenly distributed
demand by hedgers for futures positions. For example, if hedgers are
dominating in the market through short sales then long hedgers will receive
an expected profit in addition to any systematic risk premium. This theory is
called hedging pressure explanation. Let us explain the systematic risk
explanation by an example.
Suppose the current price of HLL share is Rs. 500 and Treasury Bill
rate is 10 per cent per year, assuming that HLL pays no dividend. On the
basis of stock index, the arbitrageurs will guarantee that the futures price of
HLL share after one year is:
= Ft,T = St (1 + rt,T)
Et (ST) = St (1 + rt*,T )
20
where Et (ST) is expected futures spot price at time T and rt*,T is
Thus, in this illustration, the futures price is less than the expected
futures spot price in equilibrium.
Briefly it can be stated that the difference between the futures price
and the expected futures spot price is the same as the difference between the
expected profit on riskless securities and that on pure asset with the
systematic price risk as the futures contract. Thus, future expected price will
be:
E t (S T ) − Ft,T
=
Pt*
= rt*,T – rt.T
where Pt is price of a pure asset with the same price risk as the
underlying asset of the futures contract, rt,T is expected rate return on that
asset and rt*,T –rt,T is premium of pure asset with same risk as futures over
21
Pt can be easily calculated as present value of the expected futures
price of the underlying asset:
E t (S T )
Pt =
1 + rt*,T
If the underlying asset of a futures contract is a pure asset then Pt* will
be equal to Pt and vice-versa. The discount rate rt*,T can be determined with
rt* = rf + β i (rm* − rf )
ρ im σ i
βi =
σm
The expected return on each pure asset is earned from the difference
between the current spot price and expected futures spot price. The CAPM
shows this difference as to be:
Thus, as stated earlier, the difference between the future price and the
expected futures spot price must be equal to this differential. Where βi is the
systematic risk.
22
E t (S t ) − Ft,T = β i (rm* − rf )Pt*
The earlier equation has an important view that futures prices can be
unbiased predictor of futures spot price only if the asset has zero systematic
risk, i.e., βi = 0. In such situation, the investor can diversify away the risk of
the futures position. In general, futures prices will reflect an equilibrium bias.
If βi > 0 (is positive) then, Ft,T < Et – (ST), and if Bi < 0, a long futures position
has negative systematic risk, such a position will yield an expected loss, so
Ft,T > Et–(ST). This situation purely reflects the CAPM. In brief, according to
CAPM, the expected return on a long futures position depends on the beta of
the futures contract if βi > 0, the futures price should rise overtime; if βi = 0,
the futures price should not change, and if βi < 0, the futures price should fall
over time and vice-versa in the case of short futures.
23