Elasticity Min
Elasticity Min
Elasticity Min
CONTENTS
Price elasticity of demand
Elastic demand
Inelastic demand
Special cases of price elasticity of demand
Uses of price elasticity of demand
Determinants of price elasticity of demand
Cross elasticity of demand
XED for substitutes
XED for complements
Income elasticity of demand (YED)
Price elasticity of supply (PES)
Factors influencing PES
Price elasticity of demand
Price elasticity of demand
Price elasticity of demand (PED) measures the degree of responsiveness of quantity demanded for a
product following a change in its price.
For example, if a cinema increases its ticket price from $10 to $11 and this leads to demand falling from
3500 to 3325 customers per week, then the PED for cinema tickets is calculated as :
Elastic demand
Demand is said to be price elastic if there is a relatively large change in the quantity demanded of a
product following a change in its price: that is, buyers are very responsive to changes in price.
If the PED for a product is greater than 1 (ignoring the minus sign), then demand is price elastic.
This is because the percentage change in quantity demanded is larger than the percentage change
in the price of the product
A rise in price from $4 to$5 causes a proportionately larger fall in quantity demanded: from 20
units to 10 units.
Total expenditure falls from $80 (the blue area) to $50 (the pink area).
If a price change causes a relatively small change in the quantity demanded, then demand is said to be price
inelastic that is, buyers are not highly responsive to changes in price.
This is because the percentage change in quantity demanded is smaller than the percentage change in the
price.
A rise in price from $4 to $8 causes a proportionately smaller fall in quantity demanded: from 20 units to 15
units.
Total expenditure rises from $80 (the blue area) to $120 (the pink area)
Unit elasticity
If the PED for a product is equal to 1 (ignoring the minus sign), then demand has unitary price elasticity: that is, the
percentage change in the quantity demanded is proportional to the change in the price.
Price and quantity change in exactly the same proportion. Any rise in price will be exactly offset by a fall in quantity,
leaving total consumer expenditure unchanged
If the PED for a product is equal to 0, then demand is perfectly price inelastic: that is, a change in price has no impact
on the quantity demanded. This suggests that there is absolutely no substitute for such a product, so suppliers can
charge whatever price they like.
Irrespective of the price charged, consumers are willing and able to buy the same amount.
If the PED for a product is equal to infinity (∞) then demand is perfectly price elastic: that is, a change in price leads to
zero quantity demanded. This suggests that customers switch to buying other substitute products if suppliers raise
their price.
At a price of $10 per unit, consumers are not prepared to buy any of this product; however, if price falls to $9, they will
buy all that is available. The relative change in quantity demanded here is infinite, since the original demand was zero.
A firm while fixing the price of the market has to determine whether its product is of elastic or inelastic
nature.
If the product is inelastic, the producer can earn a profit by setting a high price.
If the product is elastic, the producer must set low or at least a reasonable price so that the consumers are
attracted to buy the goods.
For example, fuel is a necessity for consumers. Therefore, firms that run the market of fuel can generate
profit even by setting a high price for fuel. On the other hand, luxury goods have a high price elasticity of
demand because they are sensitive to price changes.
Firms that rely on exports will generally benefit from lower exchange rates (as the price of exports
become cheaper) and thus will become more price competitive. This assumes that the PED for exports is
elastic.
Price discrimination
This occurs when firms charge different customers different prices for essentially the same product
because of differences in their PED. For example, theme parks charge adults different prices from children
and they also offer discounts for families and annual pass holders.
For example, products such as alcohol, tobacco and petrol are price inelastic in demand, so government
taxes on these products can quite easily be passed on to customers without much impact on the quantity
demanded.
The more substitutes there are for a good and the closer they are, the more people will
switch to these alternatives when the price of the good rises: the greater, therefore, will be
the price elasticity of demand.
A good example would be in the case of canned drinks where there are many types of cola,
iced tea and fruit juice so a small change in price could see quite large changes in what
consumers purchase.
The higher the proportion of our income we spend on a good, the more we will be forced to
cut consumption when its price rises: the bigger will be the income effect and the more
elastic will be the demand
For example, a 10% increase in the price of a flight to China will have a bigger impact than a
10% rise in the price of a bus trip into town.
When price rises, people may take a time to adjust their consumption patterns and find
alternatives.
Inelastic
demand Price elastic
elasticity demand
of demand
Det
erm
Speciasl inan
ts
case
u se s
Cross elasticity of demand
Cross elasticity of demand (XED) is a numerical measure of the responsiveness of the quantity
demanded for one product following a change in the price of another related product, ceteris paribus.
XED =
Products that are substitutes for each other will have positive values for the XED
Two goods that are independent have a zero cross elasticity of demand
Products that are substitutes for each other will have positive values for the XED.
If the price of cars increases, then people can turn to motorbikes instead because of their more favourable
relative price. If the price of cars falls, then consumers will start to buy cars instead of motorbikes.
Assume that the current average market price of a car is $10,000 and current sales are 100 cars per day. This is
shown below.
Following a 2% decrease in the price of motorbikes (a substitute product), demand for cars falls from 100 units to
98 units per day at the original price. The demand curve for cars shifts from D0 to D1.
XED =
=+1
If the price of cars go up, the quantity demanded of cars will drop and so will the complementary demand for
car tyres. Vice versa.
Consider that the average price of car tyres (a complement to cars) falls by 5%. This encourages extra sales of
cars tyres and cars as well. The demand for cars rises to 101 per day at the original price. The demand curve for
cars shifts from D0 to D2.
XED =
= − 0.2
Income elasticity of demand (YED) is defined as a numerical measure of the responsiveness of the quantity demanded following a change in
income.
Normal goods
A positive income elasticity of demand is associated with normal goods. An increase in income will lead to a rise in demand for a
normal good.
An increase in income leads to an increase in the quantity demanded for a normal good. Conversely, a decrease in income leads to a
decrease in the quantity demanded for a normal good. Since there is a positive relationship, the YED has also has positive coefficient.
Examples of normal goods include food staples, clothing, and household appliances.
Necessity goods
Necessity goods are products and services that consumers will buy regardless of the changes in their income levels, therefore making
these products less sensitive to income change.
A necessity good is a type of normal good. Normal necessities have an income elasticity of demand of between 0 and +1. As income rises,
the demand for necessity goods rises by only a little : it is said that demand rises less than proportionately to income. Items such as staple
food products such as bread and vegetables are necessity goods. This is because they have a low income elasticity of demand.
Luxury goods
Luxury or superior goods have an income elasticity of demand greater than 1, which means they are income elastic.
This implies that consumer demand is more responsive to a change in income. The demand for luxury goods expands rapidly as people’s
incomes rise. Thus items such as cars and foreign holidays have a high income elasticity of demand. Other examples of luxury goods
include fine wines spirits, high quality chocolates and sports cars
Inferior goods
An increase in income will cause a decrease in the quantity demanded for an inferior good. Conversely, a decrease in income would cause
an increase in the quantity demanded for an inferior good. Here, the YED has a negative coefficient. The demand for inferior goods
actually decreases as people’s incomes rise beyond a certain level. An example of an inferior good is cheap margarine. As people earn
more, they switch to butter or better quality margarine.
This means that the demand for the good isn’t affected by a change in income.
Price elasticity of supply (PES) measures of the responsiveness of quantity supplied to a change in price.
For example, if the market price of beans increased from $2 per kilo to $2.20 per kilo, causing quantity supplied
to rise from 10000 units to 10 500 units, then the PES is calculated as:
The figure above below five supply curves each with different PES values.
PES
A= Perfectly inelastic 0
B= Relatively inelastic <1
C= Unitary elasticity 1
D= Relatively elastic >1
E= Perfectly elastic +∞
The price elasticity of supply can differ between products for several reasons
Products that can be produced quickly will have elastic supply, for example, pencils and notebooks can
be produced within a few days. Price elasticity of supply will be elastic for such products. By contrast, in
agricultural markets, the supply of fresh fruits and vegetables depends on the time it takes to harvest
them. It takes months for crops to be harvested and be ready for sale. Climatic conditions are beyond
the control of the suppliers. Hence, supply is less responsive to changes in price in the short run. The
supply is inelastic for agricultural products.
The perishability and the level of stocks is not the same for all products.
Products that can be stored easily and are non-perishable will have elastic supply. Some types of stock
(such as pencils ) are easier to store than others (such as fresh milk or fruits), so it will be easier to
increase supply if prices increase. Thus, stocks that can be stored easily will have an elastic supply
whereas stocks that are difficult to store will have an inelastic supply.
Products that are made with raw materials in short supply will have inelastic supply. However, if a firm
has unused raw materials, components and finished products that are available for use, then the firm is
able to respond quickly to a change in price, as it can supply these stocks on to the market. Products
whose raw materials are readily available will have a more elastic supply.
Products made by firms with spare capacity will have elastic supply. For example, a beverage company
can produce 10 000 cans of soft drink in just 60 seconds, thus it is very easy for the company with
plenty of spare production capacity to respond to changes in price. PES will be elastic. By contrast, if a
firm does not have spare capacity for a product, its PES will be inelastic.
Price Price g
in
influenSc
elasticity PE
of supply
Income
elasticity
of
demand
Producer r
surplus Consumues
surpl