ECON217Chapter5 Lecture
ECON217Chapter5 Lecture
Nadine Yamout
American University of Beirut
Spring 2022-2023
1
Class Outline
1. Demand Functions
2. Changes in Income
3. Changes in a Good’s Price
4. The Individual’s Demand Curve
5. Compensated (Hicksian) Demand Curves and Functions
6. Mathematical Development of Response to Price Changes
7. Class Summary
2
Demand Functions
Demand Functions
x1∗ = x1 (p1 , p2 , . . . , pn , I )
x2∗ = x2 (p1 , p2 , . . . , pn , I )
..
.
xn∗ = xn (p1 , p2 , . . . , pn , I )
• If there are only two goods, x and y, notation can be simplified as:
x∗ = x(px , py , I )
∗
y = y (px , py , I )
• The notation stresses that prices and income are “exogenous” to this
process; that is, these are parameters over which the individual has
no control at this stage of the analysis. 3
Homogeneity
• If we were to double all prices and income, then the optimal quantities
demanded would remain unchanged.
• Doubling all prices and income changes only the units by which we
count, not the “real” quantity of goods demanded.
• Doubling px , py , and I does not affect the budget constraint since
px x + py y = I is the same as 2px x + 2py y = 2I . Hence x ∗ , y ∗ will
still be same combination chosen.
• We can write this result as saying that, for any good xi,
• Since px /py does not change, the MRS will stay constant as the
worker moves to higher levels of satisfaction.
6
Increase in Income and Normal Goods
7
Increase in Income and Inferior Goods
8
Changes in a Good’s Price
Changes in a Good’s Price
• A change in the price of a good involves changing not only one of the
intercepts of the budget constraint but also its slope.
9
Graphical Analysis of Decrease in Price
10
Graphical Analysis of a Decrease in Price
12
Graphical Analysis of an Increase in Price
14
Price Changes for Inferior Goods
16
Construction of an Individual’s Demand Curve
17
Shifts in the Demand Curve
• The actual level of utility varies along the demand curve. The reason
this happens is that the demand curve is drawn on the assumption that
nominal income and other prices are held constant; hence a decline in
px makes this person better off by increasing his or her real purchasing
power.
• Although this is the most common way to impose the ceteris paribus
assumption indeveloping a demand curve, it is not the only way.
19
Construction of a Compensated Demand Curve
20
Compensated Demand Curves
22
Compensated and Uncompensated Demand Curves
• So, the compensated demand function for a good can be found from
the expenditure function by differentiation with respect to that good’s 24
Shepard’s Lemma
• One of the many insights that can be derived from Shephard’s lemma
concerns the slope of the compensated demand curve. Since the
expenditure function must be concave in prices then:
• The ambiguity that arises when substitution and income effects work
in opposite directions for Marshallian demand curves does not arise
in the case of compensated demand curves because they involve only
substitution effects.
25
Example: Compensated Demand Functions
• We will assume there are only two goods (x and y ) and focus on the
compensated demand function, x c (px , py , U), and its relationship to
the ordinary demand function, x(px , py , I ).
• By definition we know that the quantity demanded is identical for the
compensated and uncompensated demand functions when income is
exactly what is needed to attain the required utility level:
28
Substitution and Income Effects
∂x ∂x c ∂x ∂E
= − ·
∂px ∂px ∂E ∂px
• The first term is the slope of the compensated demand curve. But
that slope represents movement along a single indifference curve; it
is, in fact, what we called the substitution effect earlier.
• The second term reflects the way in which changes in px affect the
demand for x through changes in purchasing power. Therefore, this
term reflects the income effect. The negative sign reflects the inverse
relationship between changes in prices and changes in purchasing
power.
29
The Slutsky Equation
∂x ∂x ∂x
= −x
∂px ∂px U= constant ∂I
• The second term is the income effect and its sign depends on the sign
of ∂x/∂I :
• if x is a normal good, then ∂x/∂I > 0 and the entire income effect is
negative
• if x is an inferior good, then ∂x/∂I < 0 and the entire income effect
is positive
31
Example: Slutsky Decomposition
∂x(px , py , I ) −0.5I
=
∂px px2
• We wish to show that this is the sum of the two effects that Slutsky
identified.
32
Example: Slutsky Decomposition