Summary of Wallerstein On World System Theory
Summary of Wallerstein On World System Theory
Summary of Wallerstein On World System Theory
In his book, The Modern World System: Capitalist Agriculture and the
Origins of the European World Economy in the Sixteenth Century ,
Immanual Wallerstein develops a theoretical framework to understand the
historical changes involved in the rise of the modern world. The modern
world system, essentially capitalist in nature, followed the crisis of the
feudal system and helps explain the rise of Western Europe to world
supremacy between 1450 and 1670. According to Wallerstein, his theory
makes possible a comprehensive understanding of the external and internal
manifestations of the modernization process during this period and makes
possible analytically sound comparisons between different parts of the
world.
MEDIEVAL PRELUDE
1
1. Agricultural production fell or remained stagnant. This meant that the
burden of peasant producers increased as the ruling class expanded.
2. The economic cycle of the feudal economy had reached its optimum
level; afterwards the economy began to shrink.
2
techniques of modern capitalism enabled the modern world economy,
unlike earlier attempts, to extend beyond the political boundaries of any one
empire.
The Core
The core regions benefited the most from the capitalist world economy. For
the period under discussion, much of north-western Europe (England,
France, Holland) developed as the first core region. Politically, the states
within this part of Europe developed strong central governments, extensive
bureaucracies, and large mercenary armies. This permitted the local
bourgeoisie to obtain control over international commerce and extract
capital surpluses from this trade for their own benefit. As the rural
population expanded, the small but increasing number of landless wage
earners provided labour for farms and manufacturing activities. The switch
from feudal obligations to money rents in the aftermath of the feudal crisis
encouraged the rise of independent or yeoman farmers but squeezed out
many other peasants off the land. These impoverished peasants often moved
to the cities, providing cheap labour essential for the growth in urban
3
manufacturing. Agricultural productivity increased with the growing
predominance of the commercially-oriented independent farmer, the rise of
pastoralism, and improved farm technology.
The Periphery
On the other end of the scale lay the peripheral zones. These areas lacked
strong central governments or were controlled by other states, exported raw
materials to the core, and relied on coercive labour practices. The core
expropriated much of the capital surplus generated by the periphery
through unequal trade relations. Two areas, Eastern Europe (especially
Poland) and Latin America, exhibited characteristics of peripheral regions.
In Poland, kings lost power to the nobility as the region became a prime
exporter of wheat to the rest of Europe. To gain sufficient cheap and easily
controlled labour, landlords forced rural workers into a "second serfdom" on
their commercial estates. In Latin America, the Spanish and Portuguese
conquests destroyed indigenous authority structures and replaced them
with weak bureaucracies under the control of these European states.
Powerful local landlords of Hispanic origin became aristocratic capitalist
farmers. Enslavement of the native populations, the importation of African
slaves, and the coercive labour practices such as the encomienda and forced
mine labour made possible the export of cheap raw materials to Europe.
Labour systems in both peripheral areas differed from earlier forms in
medieval Europe in that they were established to produce goods for a
capitalist world economy and not merely for internal consumption.
Furthermore, the aristocracy both in Eastern Europe and Latin America
grew wealthy from their relationship with the world economy and could
draw on the strength of a central core region to maintain control.
4
The Semi-Periphery
Between the two extremes lie the semi-peripheries. These areas represented
either core regions in decline or peripheries attempting to improve their
relative position in the world economic system. They often also served as
buffers between the core and the peripheries. As such, semi-peripheries
exhibited tensions between the central government and a strong local
landed class. Good examples of declining cores that became semi-
peripheries during the period under study are Portugal and Spain. Other
semi-peripheries at this time were Italy, southern Germany, and southern
France. Economically, these regions retained limited but declining access to
international banking and the production of high-cost high-quality
manufactured goods. Unlike the core, however, they failed to predominate
in international trade and thus did not benefit to the same extent as the core.
With a weak capitalist rural economy, landlords in semi-peripheries
resorted to sharecropping. This lessened the risk of crop failure for
landowners, and made it possible at the same time to enjoy profits from the
land as well as the prestige that went with landownership.
External Areas
5
These areas maintained their own economic systems and, for the most part,
managed to remain outside the modern world economy. Russia fits this case
well. Unlike Poland, Russia's wheat served primarily to supply its internal
market. It traded with Asia as well as Europe; internal commerce remained
more important than trade with outside regions. Also, the considerable
power of the Russian state helped regulate the economy and limited foreign
commercial influence.
STAGES OF GROWTH
Stages 1 and 2:
This period follows the rise of the modern world system between 1450-
1670. When the Hapsburg Empire failed to convert the emerging world
economy to a world empire, all the existing western European states
attempted to strengthen their respective positions within the new world
system. In order to accomplish this move, most of the states consolidated
their internal political economic and social resources by:
a) Bureaucratization.
This process aided the limited but growing power of the king. By
increasing the state power to collect taxes, the kings eventually
6
increased state power to borrow money and thereby further expand
the state bureaucracy. At the end of this stage, the monarch had
become the supreme power and instituted what has been called
"absolute monarchy."
By 1640, north western European states secured their position as core states
in the emerging economy. Spain and northern Italy declined to semi-
7
peripheral status, while north eastern Europe and Iberian America became
peripheral zones. England gained ground steadily toward core status.
Long-distance trade with the Americas and the East provided enormous
profits, in excess of 200%-300%, for a small merchant elite. Smaller
merchants could not hope to enter this profiteering without substantial
capital and some state help. Eventually, the profits of the trans-Atlantic
trade filtered down and strengthened the merchants' hold over European
agriculture and industries. Merchants with sufficient power accumulated
profits through the purchase of goods prior to their production. By
controlling the costs of finished products, merchants could extend their
profit margin and control the internal markets. This powerful merchant
class provided the capital necessary for the industrialization of European
core states.
8
shifting emphasis on industrial production, the following reactions
characterized this period.
9
THEORETICAL REPRISE
10
political and economic conditions after the breakdown of feudalism
transformed north-western Europe into the predominant commercial and
political power. The geographic expansion of the capitalist world economy
altered political systems and labour conditions wherever it was able to
penetrate. Although the functioning of the world economy appears to create
increasingly larger disparities between the various types of economies, the
relationship between the core and its periphery and semi-periphery
remains relative, not constant. Technological advantages, for example, could
result in an expansion of the world economy overall, and precipitate
changes in some peripheral or semi-peripheral areas. However, Wallerstein
asserts that an analysis of the history of the capitalist world system shows
that it has brought about a skewed development in which economic and
social disparities between sections of the world economy have increased
rather than provided prosperity for all.
11